Siemens Wind Power / August 2014 SCOE – Society’s costs of electricity: How society should find its optimal energy mix © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. siemens.com Can society afford (offshore) wind power? ? © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 2 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Levelized Cost of Electricity – The standard yardstick for comparing technologies © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 3 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Introduction LCOE is too short-sighted for deciding on an economy’s power mix Judging electricity sources only by levelised cost of energy (LCOE) stems from ages where electricity production was by definition bigscale and localised at load centers. Social costs Hidden Subsidies LCOE LCOE Transmission needs With new energy sources entering the scene, this approach falls short. In this analysis, we try to shed a fair light to total-economy costs and benefits of energy production, comparing Wind Offshore vs its alternatives. Geopolitical risks Variability Employment effects © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 4 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Approach Revealing the true cost and the macro-economic costs of energy: SCOE – Society‘s costs of electricity SCOE Components Examples • Fuel + OPEX + CAPEX + CO2 • • UK: Reduced tax on fossil fuels Waste disposal and desaster costs • Grid reinforcements needed for renewable integration • Capacity payments to gas plants for providing backup LCOE „Ex-works“ electricity price Hidden subsidies Transmission costs Variability costs System costs + LCOE • Decline of house prices around power plants & wind farms Social costs • Job creation: Direct, indirect (suppliers) and induced (by additional consumption) Economy & employment • Hedging against fuel price risk for imported fuels True cost of electricity Geopolitical impact SCOE: Society’s costs of electricity Macro-economic cost of electricity © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 5 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 SCOE Analysis United Kingdom Projection for 2025 SCOE: Society's costs of electricity [EUR/MWh] Legend LCOE Split: CAPEX OPEX Fuel CO2 Projection for United Kingdom in 2025 - Average Scenario Nuclear LCOE Coal Gas Photovoltaics Wind On Wind Off 79,2 115,3 82,9 105,2 55,4 95,0 0,0 58,4 26,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 59,8 2,5 0,5 0,0 0,0 0,0 Transmission 0,0 0,0 0,0 6,6 2,0 2,0 Variability 0,9 0,5 0,0 15,2 14,3 13,4 140,0 118,3 83,5 127,0 71,6 110,4 0,1 0,1 0,1 0,0 4,8 0,0 -33,0 -10,5 0,0 -49,4 -16,1 -49,4 - thereof CO2 Cost subsidies LCOE + System costs Social impact Employment effects Geopolitical impact SCOE 0,0 1,7 5,4 0,0 0,0 0,0 107,2 109,6 89,0 77,6 60,4 60,9 E W ST SCC / CWN / 2014-08-26 / Projection for United Kingdom in 2025 - Average Scenario With certain pre-requisites in place, Offshore can be among the most competitive electricity sources in the UK by 2025, while Gas is the most competitive backup. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 6 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power / CWN / E W ST SCC SCOE Analysis Germany Projection for 2025 Legend LCOE Split: CAPEX OPEX SCOE: Society's costs of electricity [EUR/MWh] Fuel CO2 Projection for Germany in 2025 - custom Scenario Nuclear LCOE w/o CO2 Coal Gas Photovoltaics Wind On Wind Off 79,2 80,3 67,3 100,2 55,4 95,0 0,0 23,4 10,4 0,0 0,0 0,0 47,4 0,0 0,4 0,0 0,0 0,0 Transmission 0,0 0,0 0,0 3,2 2,8 Variability 1,0 0,5 0,0 15,4 14,5 13,6 127,6 80,8 67,8 126,4 73,1 111,4 0,1 0,1 0,1 0,0 4,0 0,0 -34,1 -6,2 0,0 -49,3 -19,4 -49,0 0,3 2,5 5,9 0,0 0,0 0,0 93,8 77,2 73,8 77,1 57,8 62,3 - thereof CO2 Cost subsidies LCOE + system costs Social impact Employment effects Geopolitical impact SCOE 10,8 E W ST SCC / CWN / 2014-08-26 / Projection for Germany in 2025 - custom Scenario With certain pre-requisites in place, Offshore can be among the most competitive electricity sources in Germany by 2025, while Gas is the most competitive backup. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 7 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power / CWN / E W ST SCC The analysis will try to bring some substantiation into a set of hypotheses 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mid-term, Wind Offshore can significantly reduce the gap to grid parity. Wind Offshore – like other renewables – requires an early refurbishment of transmission grids and intermittency leveling facilities like backups or storage. Conventional technologies‘ costs that have not been fully addressed to their cost base, giving them an ill-founded advantage. A fair price of CO2 emissions would make wind energy‘s environmental benefits far more obvious. While Wind Onshore is already close to grid parity, its expansion is reaching limits. Wind power creates more local employment and positive GDP impacts than other energy sources. Wind power is a natural hedge against fuel price changes and allows geopolitical independency © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 8 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 0 The analysis will try to bring some substantiation into a set of hypotheses 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mid-term, Wind Offshore can significantly reduce the gap to grid parity. Wind Offshore – like other renewables – requires an early refurbishment of transmission grids and intermittency leveling facilities like backups or storage. Conventional technologies‘ costs that have not been fully addressed to their cost base, giving them an ill-founded advantage. A fair price of CO2 emissions would make wind energy‘s environmental benefits far more obvious. While Wind Onshore is already close to grid parity, its expansion is reaching limits. Wind power creates more local employment and positive GDP impacts than other energy sources. Wind power is a natural hedge against fuel price changes and allows geopolitical independency © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 9 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 0 Reducing the gap to grid parity Wind Offshore is only at the start of its learning curve with a lot of cost reductions to come Technology lifetime Installed global capacity Years GW Coal 113 Gas 75 Nuclear 63 Photovoltaics 38 Wind Onshore Wind Offshore 33 23 Coal 1970 Gas 1600 Nuclear 401 Photovoltaics 113 Wind Onshore Wind Offshore 318 7 Status:Data as of end 2013 Although being the youngest electricity source and having had only limited chance yet to gain experience, Wind Offshore shows significant cost reductions. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 10 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 0 Offshore can achieve major cost reductions by using the scale potential of offshore Onshore Feature Offshore Today Future Turbine rating [MW] 3 6 10 Rotor diameter [m] 101 154 195 Swept area [m²] 8.012 18.627 29.865 Load factors [%] 40 54 54 Annual energy production [GWh] 10,5 28,4 47,3 Powered homes 2.262 6.106 10.177 Note: Turbines for IEC Class I (High wind speed) Airbus 380 Soccer field Assumptions: Household consumption per year: 4648 kWh © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 11 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 0 Reducing the gap to grid parity Offshore cost reduction is effective in multiple areas Image courtesy of Bladt Industries A/S Turbines Foundations Grid access Operations & Maintenance § Reduce component cost § Standardize offshore foundation design § Reduce grid access complexity § Increase turbine component quality § Increase energy production efficiency § Industrialise manufacturing § Innovative grid solutions § Reduce O&M hours and visits frequency § Drive scale effects and industrialisation Wind Offshore will be able to realise scale effects in terms of size and utilisation that will exceed onshore performance, resulting in better efficiency. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 12 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 0 Forecasting Wind Offshore with learning curve methodology will lead to LCOE of 70-90 EUR/MWh in 2030 – fully in line with the range of Gas & Coal Offshore Levelised Cost of Electricity (LCOE) EUR/MWh 250 Assumed underlying onshore wind offshore learning curve i.e. same rate of cost improvement (11,5%) for each doubling of capacity 200 LCOE range Gas/Coal incl CO2 150 Prognos/Fichtner 2013: 120km, 50m Prognos/Fichtner 2013: 120km, 50m 100 Conservative progression (9,5% learning rate) Prognos/Fichtner 2013: 120km, 50m Datapoints pilot projects near shore Optimistic progression (13,5% learning rate) 50 project data points typical conditions 0 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Annual installations GW 0,0 2020 15,0 0,0 0,1 1,3 2025 12,9 2030 11,1 4,0 Source: Own analysis based on learning curve approach, supported by datat from Prognos/Fichtner 2013: Cost reduction potentials of offshore wind power in Germany http://www.offshore-stiftung.com/60005/Uploaded/SOW_Download|EN_ShortVersion_CostReductionPotentialsofOffshoreWindPower.pdf © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 13 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 1 The analysis will try to bring some substantiation into a set of hypotheses 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mid-term, Wind Offshore can significantly reduce the gap to grid parity. Wind Offshore – like other renewables – requires an early refurbishment of transmission grids and intermittency leveling facilities like backups or storage. Conventional technologies‘ costs that have not been fully addressed to their cost base, giving them an ill-founded advantage. A fair price of CO2 emissions would make wind energy‘s environmental benefits far more obvious. While Wind Onshore is already close to grid parity, its expansion is reaching limits. Wind power creates more local employment and positive GDP impacts than other energy sources. Wind power is a natural hedge against fuel price changes and allows geopolitical independency © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 14 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Transmission and backup requirements Renewables requires changes in the architecture of the onshore energy grid. Total Comments Grid investments onshore mEUR 3.838 OPEX costs p.a. mEUR 38 1 % of CAPEX p.a. Grid lifetime Years 40 Discount rate % 10 Annual electricity production offshore TWh Additional grid costs EUR/MWh 219 1,97 Source: National Grid 2011, The Crown Estate: Offshore Transmission Network Feasibility Study http://www.nationalgrid.com/NR/rdonlyres/4FBE15A0-B244-4BEF-87DC-8D0B7D792EAE/ 49346/Part1MainBodysection191.pdf Comments: Assumption offshore load factors: 50% Existing electricity grids have been designed for high-capacity conventional power plants close to load centers. A greater share of renewables will now demand for an early one-time refurbishment of transmission grids, allowing for more decentralised and production-optimised grid designs. This is a one-time investment, like building the grids was a century ago. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 15 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 1 Transmission and backup requirements Renewables requires changes in the architecture of the energy grid. Surplus on electricity from Grid reinforcement Total Additional grid costs p.a. mEUR Annual electricity production by renewablesTWh Additional grid costs EUR/MWh 946 269 3,5 Wind Offshore Share Coal transport North Sea Southern Germany2 183 66 2,8 5,0 Transmission capacity needed until 2022 in Germany Sources 1 DENA Netzstudie II, Dez 2010 http://www.dena.de/fileadmin/user_upload/Publikationen/Erneuerbare/Dokumente/Endbericht_dena-Netzstudie_II.PDF 2 VBG PowerTech 9/2007: Steinkohlekraftwerke: Konzepte und Faktoren der Standortauswahl http://www.steag-energyservices.com/fileadmin/user_upload/steagenergyservices.com/downloads/veroeffentlichungen/ Assumptions: Wind Offshore has a share of all grid costs proportional to its installed capacity Installed capacities 2020: Offshore 14 GW, Wind Onshore 37 GW, Photovoltaics: 18 GW Capacity factors: Wind Offshore 54%, Wind Onshore 42%, Photovoltaics 11% Transporting electricity is cheaper than transporting the base fuel! Planned transmission lines In construction/consented Existing electricity grids have been designed for high-capacity conventional power plants close to load centers. A greater share of renewables will now demand for an early one-time refurbishment of transmission grids, allowing for more decentralised and production-optimised grid designs. This is a one-time investment, like building the grids was a century ago. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 16 14-12-01 Source: DENA Netzenwicklungsplan 2013 http://www.netzentwicklungsplan.de/NEP_2013_Teil_I.pdf Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 1 Transmission and backup requirements In a state-of-the-art grid, the geographical distribution of wind farms reduces intermittency Wind farms spread over a distance show less interdependency in output than single turbines A North Sea super grid can allow for further compensation of intermittency Power Output correlation of ~2000 UK wind sites Distance between recording sites [km] Source: http://www.eci.ox.ac.uk/publications/downloads/sinden06-windresource.pdf Source: http://allenandyork.wordpress.com/2011/09/ Geographical distribution of wind farms allows an inter-grid compensation of intermittency: “There is always wind blowing somewhere!”. A European initiative for a super-grid will help to level out production and deman © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 17 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 1 1 Transmission and backup requirements In many countries, wind offshore is close to load centers. Source: SEDAC - Socioeconomic Data and Applications Center of NASA 2000 http://www.nasa.gov/images/content/712130main_8246931247_e60f3c09fb_o.jpg 40 % of the world population live within 100 km from the shore. For many big cities like in the US, China and Latin America, offshore wind requires less investment into transmission than onshore. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 18 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 1 Calculation of intermittency compensation Offshore wind has far less fluctuation in power output than other renewables Offshore winds have less spread in wind speeds vs the average, resulting in a more stable power © output. Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 19 14-12-01 An offshore turbine operates at rated power for 2200 hrs per year, while low wind onshore only reaches 640 hrs. Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 1 Calculation of intermittency compensation Rationale for calculating intermittency compensation costs: Gas is the most efficient backup mid-term Wind output MW 1 GW of wind installed 1000 Demand 750 500 250 Wind output 0 0 Backup capacity of ~ 880 MW Gas needed 2000 4000 6000 8000 Cumulated hours p.a. Gas backup output MW 1000 Compensation of Gas plant for CAPEX/fixed OPEX for the amount of time where it is not running at 60% load factor Demand Gas output 750 500 250 0 0 2000 4000 6000 8000 Cumulated hours p.a. To estimate intermittency costs, a gas backup capacity of 88% of installed wind capacity is assumed. The gas power plant is compensated for the time being idle by a payment for their CAPEX and fixed OPEX ~ 15 EUR/MWh. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 20 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 4 An 80% renewables scenario in Germany cannot be realised without significant share of offshore wind; offshore wind helps to reduce residual capacities. Even with PV and wind onshore built to their technical limits, they can only deliver 80 % of the renewable electricity needed Colours: Residual power standard deviation (GW) Annual Electricity demand and potential supply for Germany in an 80% renewable scheme Primary energy demand supply 100 66 95 162 TWh 20% Renewable Mix with minimal residual power Standardabweichung der Residuallast (GW ) demand Share of wind in renewables portfolio 37 GW Offshore Wind needed to close the gap Gap Other To minimise the need for residual capacity to compensate intermittency, an even higher offshore wind share is advised 390 TWh 80% = 800 TWh p.a. Renewable Electricity 248 TWh Technical maximum wind onshore: 198 GW Technical maximum photovoltaics: 275 GW 64 90 62 85 60 80 58 56 75 54 70 52 65 Primary energy demand Gap to 80% renewable supply Electricity supply Source: Fraunhofer IWES 2013: Energiewirtschaftliche Studie zur Bedeutung der Offshore-Windenergie. Kurzfassung http://www.fraunhofer.de/content/dam/zv/de/forschungsthemen/energie/ Energiewirtschaftliche-Bedeutung-von-Offshore-Windenergie.pdf 50 60 48 55 50 0 46 20 40 60 80 AnteilShare Offshore der W indstromerzeugung ofanoffshore in total wind(%) 100 Residual capacity needs can be minimised with a mix of 20% PV, 30% wind onshore and 50% wind offshore © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 21 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 2 The analysis will try to bring some substantiation into a set of hypotheses 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mid-term, Wind Offshore can significantly reduce the gap to grid parity. Wind Offshore – like other renewables – requires an early refurbishment of transmission grids and intermittency leveling facilities like backups or storage. Conventional technologies‘ costs that have not been fully addressed to their cost base, giving them an ill-founded advantage. A fair price of CO2 emissions would make wind energy‘s environmental benefits far more obvious. While Wind Onshore is already close to grid parity, its expansion is reaching limits. Wind power creates more local employment and positive GDP impacts than other energy sources. Wind power is a natural hedge against fuel price changes and allows geopolitical independency © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 22 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 1 Different nature of cost-base and price-base subsidies: We don‘t count renewable price subsidies as they don‘t distort the cost base Structure of cost-base subsidies e.g. government carrying costs caused by producer Structure of price-base subsidies e.g. feed-in-tariff or price premium Line of visibility Line of visibility 4,0 4,0 0,0 4,0 5,0 1,0 2,0 3,0 3,0 2,0 True costs Cost-base subsidy 2,0 1,0 Apparent costs Profit Price • Cost-base subsidies create an apparent or visible cost base that seems lower than the true cost (when addressed by cause) • Example: The disposal costs for nuclear waste are not fully carried by the plant operator; hence he does not show the full costs he causes True costs Cost- Apparent base costs subsidy Profit Real price Subsidy Subsidised price • Pure price-base subsidies have true costs at the same level as apparent costs (no hidden costs). • The subsidy is used to lower the real price to a competitive price level • There are no hidden costs behind the line of visibility SCOE is focusing on comparing the true costs of electricity generation. That is why cost-base subsidies are included, but price-based subsidies are not. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 23 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 2 Conventional technologies‘ costs have been receiving subsidies up to today that lower their apparent cost base. Global direct subsidies estimates Per-Country direct Subsidies to conventional fuels 2010 2010 Fossile Fuels 16,8 Renewables 7,0 Global Germany United Kingdom EUR/MWh EUR/MWh EUR/MWh Hard Coal Natural Gas Nuclear Power 43,7 2,5 0,4 0,5 33,4 45,1 Sources: Sources: BNEF Press Release July 29, 2010: Subsidies … Energy consumption: Eurostat 2010 Subsidies: OECD (http://www.oecd.org/site/tadffss/), Financial Times (http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/fda9ea9a-ac29-11e2-a06300144feabdc0.html#axzz2V9jJs2J9) FÖS 2011 (http://www.foes.de/pdf/2012-08-Was_Strom_wirklich_kostet_lang.pdf) Only subsidy components considered that lower cost base of technology IEA 2012, Key world energy statistics Assumptions: Net efficiency gas: 60%, coal: 45% Conventional energy sources have received several kinds of governmental support during their introduction phase to allow for quick and efficient scale-up. Many of these subsidy mechanisms are still in place. To create a level playing ground, all subsidies have to be made transparent. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 24 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Climate Change Prevention A fair CO2 price of 40 EUR/t would give coal a cost surplus of 22 EUR/MWh Lifecycle CO2 emission Cost for CO2 Cost Increase kg/MWh EUR/MWh EUR/MWh Nuclear 12 Coal 781 Gas 429 0,1 0,5 +0,4 7,8 31,2 4,3 17,1 +23,4 +12,9 Photovoltaics 41 0,4 1,6 +1,2 Wind Onshore 11 0,1 0,4 +0,3 Wind Offshore 12 0,1 0,5 +0,4 Today: 10 EUR/t CO2 Future: 40 EUR/t CO2 Sources: IPCC 2014, Working Group III: "Climate Change 2014:Mitigation of Climate Change", Annex III, page 10: http://report.mitigation2014.org/drafts/final-draft-postplenary/ipcc_wg3_ar5_final-draft_postplenary_annex-iii.pdf Assumption of 40 EUR/to as a lower end of fair CO2 price: McKinsey 2007: http://www.epa.gov/oar/caaac/coaltech/2007_05_mckinsey.pdf © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 25 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 3 2 Especially nuclear plant operators are not held responsible for all costs in their value chain “At Pennsylvania’s Three Mile Island in 1979, one reactor partially melted in the worst U.S. accident, earning a 5 rating. Its $973 million repair and cleanup took almost 12 years to complete” (Bloomberg, 30.03.2011) In addition to the currently known subsidies, there are hidden cost risk due to environmental damage or catastrophies which tax payers have to come up for. We assumed a virtual insurance fee against nuclear desasters of 14 EUR/MWh.1 Sources: 1 Versicherungsforum Leipzig 2011: Berechnung einer risikoadaquaten Versicherungspramie zur Deckung der Haftpflichtrisiken, die aus dem Betrieb von Kernkraftwerken resultieren http://www.bee-ev.de/_downloads/publikationen/studien/2011/110511_BEE-Studie_Versicherungsforen_KKW.pdf © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 26 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 3 The analysis will try to bring some substantiation into a set of hypotheses 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mid-term, Wind Offshore can significantly reduce the gap to grid parity. Wind Offshore – like other renewables – requires an early refurbishment of transmission grids and intermittency leveling facilities like backups or storage. Conventional technologies‘ costs that have not been fully addressed to their cost base, giving them an ill-founded advantage. A fair price of CO2 emissions would make wind energy‘s environmental benefits far more obvious. While Wind Onshore is already close to grid parity, its expansion is reaching limits. Wind power creates more local employment and positive GDP impacts than other energy sources. Wind power is a natural hedge against fuel price changes and allows geopolitical independency © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 27 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 The CO2 emissions assigned to burning fuel are not capturing the whole story Fuel generation During mining: • Energy and auxiliary materials for well operations Fuel distribution • fuel consumption for transportation • Pipeline leakage Power plant construction Power plant operations • Auxiliary power, • Energy and raw people and material materials for transport and construction logistics • Operations of auxiliary equipment and transport to site Burning fuel • Chemical conversion of carbon share of fuel to CO2 Direct emissions base for CO2 certificate trade Lifecycle emissions determining impact on CO2 concentration in the atmosphere © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 28 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Environmental impact We use two different approaches to measure the impact of carbon dioxide 1• Fair value of CO2 view: 2• Powerplant operators view • Regardless of local legislation, we address a price to CO2 emissions that is considered high enough to compensate the adverse effects • • Calculation: Lifecycle emissions per MWh x fair CO price (=40 EUR/to) Based on assumptions of CO2 prices given by local authorities (e.g. national governments, EU), we calculate what an operator needs to pay for his direct emissions • Calculation: Direct emissions per MWh x certificate price (depending on location) UK Example 2025 Price tag EUR/to CO2 80 2 724 kg/MWh @ 80,7 EUR/to 70 58 60 EUR/MWh el 50 1 40 781 kg/MWh @ 40 EUR/to 30 20 31 10 EUR/MWh el 0 0 200 400 600 800 CO2 Emissions kg/MWh Even if self-imposed CO2 prices are not in place, the environmental damage comes at a cost. Therefore we use a fair value as a second referencein case the self-imposed mechanisms fall short. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 29 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 3 Climate Change prevention Government aims to put a fair price to CO2 will make especially coal-fired power plants less competitive. Carbon price floor targets United Kingdom EUR/t CO2 100 CO2 lifetime average price for a power plant going online in this year* 90 80 70 Fair CO2 price 87 81 Marginal costs of CO2 reduction measures to keep global warming below 2°C: 87 67 60 62 50 40-50 EUR/t2 40 CO2 carbon price floor per year 37 30 20 2 Source: McKinsey, http://www.epa.gov/oar/caaac/c oaltech/2007_05_mckinsey.pdf 10 0 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 Source: UK Department of Energy and Climate Change: Updated short-term traded carbon values used for UK public policy appraisal, Oct 2012 https://w w w .gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/41794/6667-update-short-term-traded-carbon-values-f or-uk-publ.pdf * A power plant going online in 2025 will pay CO2 taxes from 2025-2055 (30 years lifetime). For LCOE, the lifetime discounted value of CO2 emission is considered, not only the one in the starting year. Recently low CO2 certificate prices are not reflecting actual cost of CO2, but are a result of too optimistic demand forecast. Corrective action required by EU governments to reach fair pricing of CO2. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 30 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 4 The analysis will try to bring some substantiation into a set of hypotheses 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mid-term, Wind Offshore can significantly reduce the gap to grid parity. Wind Offshore – like other renewables – requires an early refurbishment of transmission grids and intermittency leveling facilities like backups or storage. Conventional technologies‘ costs that have not been fully addressed to their cost base, giving them an ill-founded advantage. A fair price of CO2 emissions would make wind energy‘s environmental benefits far more obvious. While Wind Onshore is already close to grid parity, its expansion is reaching limits. Wind power creates more local employment and positive GDP impacts than other energy sources. Wind power is a natural hedge against fuel price changes and allows geopolitical independency © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 31 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 4 In onshore, the industry already demonstrated an impressive track record of cost reduction, with grid parity in reach Learning curve: Onshore Levelised Cost of Electricity (LCOE) EUR/MWh 350 300 Assumed underlying onshore wind learning curve i.e. same rate of cost improvement (13%) for each doubling of capacity 250 200 LCOE range Gas/Coal incl CO2 Conservative progression (10 % learning rate) 150 Siemens forecast (Low wind) 100 50 Real wind power data points 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Siemens forecast (high wind) 2005 Annual installations actuals and forecast GW 0,4 0,2 1,3 2010 32,8 4,0 2015 37,3 Variable cost range Gas/Coal incl CO2 2020 38,9 2025 46,8 Optimistic progression (16% learning rate) 2030 49,6 11,3 Source: own analysis by learning curve methodology of known LCOE datapoints and market installation actuals and forecasts © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 32 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 4 But high wind sites are already utilised to a great extent. Mid/low wind sites can still be extended, but will have higher costs. Distribution of installations in Germany Status: End 2012 Wind resources Germany Power density MW/km² Installed fleet: ~ 31 GW (End 2012) Source: Fraunhofer IWES 2013: Windenergie Report Deutschalnd 2012, http://windmonitor.iwes.fraunhofer.de/bilder/upload/Windenergie_Report_Deutschland_2012.pdf Mean wind speed m/s Total potential: ~ 198 GW (=2% of land usage) Source: BWE 2012, Potenzial der Windenergienutzung an Land http://www.wind-energie.de/sites/default/files/download/publication/studie-zum-potenzial-der-windenergienutzungland/bwe_potenzialstudie_kurzfassung_2012-03.pdf © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 33 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Some studies assume that property values decline around onshore wind farms; social acceptance is also influenced by visual impact Hypotheses One of the major obstacles to wind onshore is reluctance against the visual impact Findings House prices decline around wind farms by ~3% in a 5 km radius1 Result Result Per MWh, the house price decline accounts for ~4-5 EUR 5 km 9d 7d Wind farm, 12 turbines d= rotor diameter Visually impacted area 1 Source: Note: Heintzelman/Tuttle 2011: Values in the Wind. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/Delivery.cfm/SSRN_ID1887196_code1021813.pdf?abstractid=1803601&mirid=3 Other recent sources say there are no relations between wind farms and house prices. To have a safe assumption, we used one of the more pessimistic cases. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 34 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 4 4 Social Impact Visual impact by wind farms will rise significantly if current offshore plans are replaced by onshore wind UK Onshore Wind Farm Density Today UK Onshore Wind Farm Density 2030 with all offshore plans moved onshore Average distance between wind farms: 31,3 km Average distance between wind farms: 12,4 km Land area from where wind farms visible: 15% Land area from where wind farms visible: 99% 50km 50km 10km 10km Legend: visually affected are of one single wind farm Assumptions Legend: visually affected are of one single wind farm Assumptions Onshore additional installations Of fshore plans move onshore Average onshore w indfarm size Average turbine rating Visibility around w ind farm 0 0 12,0 2,3 5,0 (0% of 5,85 GW) (0% of 35 GW) turbines MW km Onshore additional installations Of fshore plans move onshore Average onshore w indfarm size Average turbine rating Visibility around w ind farm 5,85 35 12,0 3,0 5,0 (100% of 5,85 GW) (100% of 35 GW) turbines MW km © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 35 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 4 Social Impact Visual impact by wind farms will rise significantly if current offshore plans are replaced by onshore wind DE Onshore Wind Farm Density Today DE Onshore Wind Farm Density 2030 with all offshore plans moved onshore Average distance between wind farms: 14,1 km Average distance between wind farms: 11,7 km Land area from where wind farms visible: 72% Average wind farms visible: 1,1 Legend: visually affected are of one single wind farm Assumptions 50km 50km 10km 10km Legend: visually affected are of one single wind farm Assumptions Onshore additional installations Of fshore plans move onshore Average onshore w indf arm size Average turbine rating Visibility around w ind f arm 0 0 12,0 2,3 5,0 (0% of 10 GW) (0% of 15 GW) turbines MW km Onshore additional installations Of fshore plans move onshore Average onshore w indfarm size Average turbine rating Visibility around w ind farm 10 15 12,0 3,0 5,0 (100% of 10 GW) (100% of 15 GW) turbines MW km © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 36 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Social Impact Studies show that consumers are willing to accept higher electricity prices for lower visual impact. People’s willingness to pay to get offshore wind farms out of sight is expected to reflect the onshore situation to the same extent. Sources: 1 Ladenburg/Dubgaard 2007: Willingness to Pay for Reduced Visual Disamenities from Off-Shore Wind Farms in Denmark. http://www.webmeets.com/files/papers/ERE/WC3/881/Willingness%20to%20Pay%20for%20Reduced%20Visual%20Disamenities%20from%20OffShore%20Wind%20Farms%20in%20Denmark.pdf 2 Navrud, S. (2004): MILJØKOSTNADER AV VINDKRAFT I NORGE Sammendragsrapport til SAMRAM-programmet.Norges Forskningsråd.Notat .Institutt for Økonomi og Ressursforvaltning.Universitetet for Miljø- og Biovitenskap (UMB). © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 37 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 4 5 The analysis will try to bring some substantiation into a set of hypotheses 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mid-term, Wind Offshore can significantly reduce the gap to grid parity. Wind Offshore – like other renewables – requires an early refurbishment of transmission grids and intermittency leveling facilities like backups or storage. Conventional technologies‘ costs that have not been fully addressed to their cost base, giving them an ill-founded advantage. A fair price of CO2 emissions would make wind energy‘s environmental benefits far more obvious. While Wind Onshore is already close to grid parity, its expansion is reaching limits. Wind power creates more local employment and positive GDP impacts than other energy sources. Wind power is a natural hedge against fuel price changes and allows geopolitical independency © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 38 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Localisation of supply chain Due to component size and high lot sizes, Wind Offshore is more suitable and in need for localisation Units to be installed for annual production of 10 TWh Drivers of localisation # Units Nuclear 1,0 Coal 2,0 Low unit # and relatively simple component logistics Very few items requiring sophisticated logistics 2,3 Gas Wind Offshore 366 turbines 1098 Blades 1464 Tower segments 27‘500‘000 PV modules Logistical complexity and component size Simple component logistics (container shipment) decreases need for local supply chain The critical mass for building a partially local supply chain is far lower for wind offshore than it is for other energy sources (especially conventionals) © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 39 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 5 5 Job creation by Wind Offshore The level of GDP impact depends on the scope of localisation (Scenario UK 2020) Gross GDP Return [% of LCOE] 73,0 Nuclear 36,0 Coal @ 0% local fuel Coal @ 50% local fuel Coal @ 100% local fuel Gas @ 0% local fuel Gas @ 50% local fuel Gas @ 100% local fuel Photovoltaics Assumptions 63,0 90,0 18,0 61,0 103,0 CAPEX local content % • Nuclear: 35 • Coal: 35 • Gas: 37 • PV: 40 • Wind Onshore: 25-39 • Wind Offshore: 27-40 53,0 Wind Onshore low localisation Local tower manufacturing Local rotor manufacturing & assembly Local nacelle assembly Wind Onshore with max localisation 67,5 2,6 11,7 4,8 86,6 Wind Offshore low localisation Local foundation manufacturing Local tower manufacturing Local rotor manufacturing & assembly Rotor Export (100% on top) Local nacelle assembly Wind Offshore max localisation 62,0 6,0 1,5 6,6 4,4 5,4 85,9 Share of domestic fuel %: • Gas: 0-50-100 • Coal 0-50-100 • Nuclear 100 Sources: Own analysis, mainly based on Ernst&Young 2012: Analysis of the value creation potential of wind energy policies (Link) Assumptions: CAPEX GDP impact is comparable for all conventional technologies (nuclear, coal gas) © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 40 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 5 While coal relies to a great extent on exploitation of fossil resources with low value add impact, wind value chain is consisting of multiple layers of value add activities Main value add components LCOE Split by % Coal Fossil resources Fuel Mining & Processing 47% Mining Equipment Wind OPEX 10% Spare parts Monitoring Servicing CAPEX 43% Parts mfg Component assy Construction & erection OPEX Fleet operations Servicing Spare parts Monitoring 26% Copper mfg Generator assy Steel mfg CAPEX Nacelle assy Tower mfg Installation 74 % Tool mfg Raw mat mfg Blade mfg © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 41 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 5 Offshore wind has superior local effects on employment – creating wealth for the economy • It creates more local employment opportunities and has a more positive impact on GDP than any other energy source. • Especially in structurally weak areas in urgent need of jobs and investment. 21‘000 billion job years For every billion EUR invested in wind power, 21‘000 people are employed for one year in the EU. Sources: Already more than 35% of contracts awarded for the production & installation of Offshore Wind farms go to UK companies 86% of service contracts are allocated locally. Ernst&Young 2011: Analysis of the value creation potential of wind energy policies (Link) BVG Associates 2011: UK content analysis of Robin Rigg offshore wind farm (Link) BVG Associates 2012: UK content analysis of Robin Rigg Offshore Wind Farm O&M (Link) © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 42 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 5 Job creation by Wind Offshore Wind Offshore helps regions and sectors with structural problems to raise employment Germany Offshore Industry: • 90% of value add created in small and medium-sized enterprises1 • Already 18‘000 dedicated jobs, especially in Northern Germany2 • Creating employment in structurally lagging region and sectors Wind offshore is especially catching up for job losses in rural areas and in the marine sector, reducing structural unemployment 1 PwC, http://www.pwc.de/de/energiewende/offshore-windenergie-kommt-gewaltig-in-fahrt.jhtml 2 Handelsblatt: http://www.handelsblatt.com/unternehmen/industrie/hochsee-windkraft-tausende-jobs-in-offshore-branche-in-gefahr/8274098.html © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 43 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Myth: Offshore only gives employment to Northern countries in Germany Fact: Offshore Wind creates value-add and employment all across Germany Share of Offshore Turbine Value-add [%] 18% 13% 12% Source: PwC/wab 2012: Volle Kraft aus Hochseewind http://www.wab.net/images/stories/PDF/studien/Volle_Kraft_aus_Hochseewind_PwC_WAB.pdf Confidential © Siemens AG 2013 All rights reserved. Page 44 June 27, 2013 Christoph Neemann / E W ST MC 5 Wind power costs are man-power intensive; moreover, a high proportion is sourced locally United Kingdom fuel import rates and sources Cost elements of LCOE in % of total LCOE (excluding CO2 costs) 74 Fuel imports 26 82 18 Fuel imports 43 10 19 6 CAPEX OPEX Sources: 47 75 Fuel LCOE: Siemens-internal analysis Gas & Coal imports and sources: https://www.gov.uk/government/publications © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 45 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 5 Job creation by Wind Offshore Once built up, a local supply chain can also serve export markets Offshore Installation Targets/Estimates Northern European Countries in GW by 2030 (*2020) United Kingdom Germany France Netherlands* Sweden* Denmark* Belgium* Total ex UK 38,0 15,0 15,0 6,0 3,0 2,8 2,0 41,8 Building expertise on crafting wind turbines can lead to a benefitial export business case, fostering local growth and employment © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 46 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 6 The analysis will try to bring some substantiation into a set of hypotheses 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mid-term, Wind Offshore can significantly reduce the gap to grid parity. Wind Offshore – like other renewables – requires an early refurbishment of transmission grids and intermittency leveling facilities like backups or storage. Conventional technologies‘ costs that have not been fully addressed to their cost base, giving them an ill-founded advantage. A fair price of CO2 emissions would make wind energy‘s environmental benefits far more obvious. While Wind Onshore is already close to grid parity, its expansion is reaching limits. Wind power creates more local employment and positive GDP impacts than other energy sources. Wind power is a natural hedge against fuel price changes and allows geopolitical independency © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 47 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 6 Geopolitical independency Fossil fuel prices are volatile and subject to geopolitical sensitivities. Henry hub Natural gas spot price USD/mmBTU Hard coal prices USD/to, Central Appalachian 14 350 12 300 10 250 8 200 6 150 4 100 2 50 0 01/'06 01/'07 01/'08 01/'09 01/'10 01/'11 01/'12 01/'13 0 Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration (http://www.eia.gov) Fuel prices of conventional sources, especially natural gas are volatile; moreover the limitations of their availability create a bottleneck risk. Approach to valuation of geopolitical impact: Import share of fuel x fuel costs x hedging premium (~17 % for gas) = geopolitical costs Hedging premium derived from long-term (2 years) future hedges on fuel prices © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 48 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Can society afford (offshore) wind power? ! ? How can society afford not to do (offshore) wind power? © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 49 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Summary: Why SCOE changes the way you look at the electricity mix Onshore und Offshore Wind will be the most cost competitive electricity sources on macro-economic level by 2025 The continued build-out of wind power will take place less out of political reasons, but out of economical reasons Flexible gas power plants are the most cost-efficient backup technology © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 50 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Annex Restricted © Siemens Wind Power 20XX All rights reserved. Page 51 14-12-01 Author / Department Summary of Key assumptions Projection for United Kingdom in 2025 – Average Scenario Summary of Key assumptions Projection for United Kingdom in 2025 - custom Scenario Technology-specific assumptions Topic LCOE Item Units General Nuclear Fuel costs EUR/MWh_therm 4 Capacity factors % 92 Environment CO2 emission rate g/MWh 0 CO2 price EUR/t 81 CO2 costs per MWh EUR/MWh 0 Baseload level % of rated power 94 Intermittency Fixed costs of gas backup EUR/MWh 15,2 Transmission grid investment kEUR/MW Transmission Distribution grid investment kEUR/MW Avg house price decline % 5,0 Impact radius house prices km 3,0 Average population density vs country average % 20 Social Average House price value total country EUR/sqm 1.953 Average living space per person sqm/person 44 House price level vs average % 50 Local content CAPEX % 35 Economy Local content OPEX % 80 Domestic fuel share % 95 Geopolitical Hedging costs % of fuel price 8,3 Coal Gas Photovoltaics Wind Onshore Wind Offshore 10 86 330 26 63 200 11 0 37 0 54 0 58 97 26 100 0 0 0 6 0 12 5,0 3,0 5,0 3,0 61 0,0 0,0 61 5,5 3,0 0,0 0,0 35 80 34 11,6 35 80 22 16,5 35 80 0 0,0 35 80 0 0,0 38 80 0 0,0 92 General assumptions Topic Economy Item GVA Multiplier CAPEX GVA Multiplier OPEX GVA Multiplier Fuel Units Value 1,67 1,33 1,14 E W ST MC / CWN / 2014-08-25 / Projection for United Kingdom in 2025 - custom Scenario © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 52 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 Summary of Key assumptions Projection for Germany in 2025 – Average Scenario Summary of Key assumptions Projection for Germany in 2025 - custom Scenario Technology-specific assumptions Topic LCOE Item Units Fuel costs EUR/MWh_therm Capacity factors % Environment CO2 emission rate g/MWh CO2 price EUR/t CO2 costs per MWh EUR/MWh Baseload level % of rated power Intermittency Fixed costs of gas backup EUR/MWh Transmission grid investment kEUR/MW p.a Transmission Distribution grid investment kEUR/MW Avg house price decline % Impact radius house prices km Average population density vs country average % Social Average House price value total country EUR/sqm Average living space per person sqm/person House price level vs average % Local content CAPEX % Economy Local content OPEX % Domestic fuel share % Geopolitical Hedging costs % of fuel price General Nuclear Coal Photovoltaics Gas Wind Onshore Wind Offshore 4 92 0 10 86 330 26 63 200 11 0 37 0 54 0 0 94 23 97 10 100 0 0 0 6 0 12 100 5,5 3,0 0,0 0,0 35 80 0 0,0 35 80 0 0,0 32 15,2 13 5,0 3,0 5,0 3,0 5,0 3,0 100 0,0 0,0 35 80 0 8,3 35 80 0 11,6 35 80 14 16,5 35 80 0 0,0 20 1.800 45 50 General assumptions Item Topic Economy GVA Multiplier CAPEX GVA Multiplier OPEX GVA Multiplier Fuel Units Value 1,67 1,51 1,14 E W ST MC / CWN / 2014-08-25 / Projection for Germany in 2025 - custom Scenario © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 53 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 5 Evaluation principle GDP Impact Key drivers are local value-add and multipliers for indirect and induced labour. Rationale of gross economic impact Fuel OPEX 0-100% 75-85% x 1,14 Domestic Fuel x 1,39 Domestic OPEX CAPEX LCOE Split 10-50% x 1,67 Domestic CAPEX Local content Fuel impact OPEX Impact CAPEX Impact Domestic GDP Gross Value-add Multipliers Economic benefit • All money spent on electricity, i.e. LCOE, can be traced back to fuel, CAPEX and OPEX. • An economy only benefits from these spendings if they take place locally • The domestic value add is defined as the sum of localised profits and local labour. These two elements will go into the GDP. • The local value add triggers further employment up the value chain. This effect is reflected by multipliers that differ by the type of work conducted. • Example: A blade manufacturing facility will most likely trigger a higher local production of glas fibers or moulds at suppliers. Close to the new manufacturing site, a bakery, a supermarket and a hotel will open, creating further employment. © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 56 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014 5 Economic impact Compensation for high gross effect Gross economic impact „Economic advantage“ Minimum 86,0 Nuclear 71,0 Coal Gas 65,0 94,0 Photovoltaics Minimum Wind Onshore Wind Offshore 56,0 100,0 “Economical advantage” is the delta to the energy source with the lowest gross economic impact . © Siemens Wind Power 2014. All rights reserved. Page 57 14-12-01 Siemens Wind Power August 20, 2014