Report on the 2008 UK 10-40 GHz Spectrum Auction Ian Jewitt and Zhiyun Li∗ September 2008. Abstract This paper reports on the outcome of the 2008 UK 10-40 GHz Spectrum Auction which was one of the first implementations of (a variant of) the Clock-Proxy auction format as advocated by Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2006). The auction appeared to run smoothly and achieve a reasonably efficient outcome. For some bidders their supplementary bids tended to make many of their bids effectively redundant. The clock phase certainly lead to bidders focussing their attention on a manageable number of feasible packages as intended. However, the narrowness of this focussing, together with the redundant bids, reduced measured opportunity costs and may have lead to low revenues. 1 Introduction The format of the 2008 UK 10-40 GHz spectrum auction is a significant departure from the simultaneous ascending auctions which have typically been used for spectrum assignments both within the UK and around the world. The format can be viewed as a variant of the Clock-Proxy auction proposed by Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2006). The hoped for advantages of the format are summarised in the 2006 presentation (Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2006b)) as follows. The Clock Phase: takes linear prices as far as they will go, providing simplicity and flexibility for the bidders; expands substitution possibilities; minimises the scope for collusion; and eliminates exposure and threshold problems. The Proxy Phase: leads to an outcome in the core–efficiency with substantial seller revenues. ∗ The views expressed in this note are the authors’ own. This note was funded by Ofcom. 1 Although this is not the first instance of a Clock-Proxy auction to assign spectrum, differences1 between this auction and the only previous one we are aware of mean that there is likely to be substantial interest in the performance of the format in this application.2 The UK 2008 10-40 GHz process departed from the Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2006) Clock Proxy format by having 3 rather than 2 distinct bidding elements. The first two bidding elements took place in a primary stage which is itself effectively a (variant of the) Clock Proxy format. The purpose of this primary stage was to assign entitlements to quantities of bandwidth in certain spectrum ranges. The third bidding element, the assignment stage determined how these entitlements were distributed over the relevant spectrum. The first bidding element in the primary stage is conducted via an ascending clock auction in which package bidding takes place–bidders commit to prices for packages rather than their component parts. The second bidding element allows bidders to supplement their bids in the clock auction with a possibly large number of simultaneous supplementary bids–again these are on packages of lots. At the end of the primary bid stage the mechanism identifies the value maximising allocation consistent with the bids and determines the base prices. Base prices are determined according to a modified ‘second-price’ or Vickrey rule which is computationally burdensome and carried out on propriety Ofcom winner determination and pricing (WDP) software. A modified, rather than pure Vickrey pricing rule is advocated, in part, because Vickrey prices can lead to very low revenues for some configuration of reported preferences.3 The following example, adapted from these references, illustrates. Figure 1 lists some hypothetical bid data in 1 Trinidad and Tobago undertook such an auction on 23 June 2005, Market Design Incorporated advised. We have not been able to find details of the auction packaging or bids, but it is clear that there are important differences between the Trinidad and Tobago auction and the UK one. One difference is however aparent, the Trinidad and Tobago process fixed in advance the number of possible concession holders: there were to be two only. The clock phase of the auction determined which of the five qualified entrants would get the concessions and also determine the minimum price of bandwidth (See Telecommunications Authority of Trinidad and Tobago and Ausubel Cramton and Milgrom (2006b)). The fact that an important part of the assignment, determining the concession holders, is determined at the clock phase means that some of the features of the UK 10-40 GHz auction which are stressed in our analysis would be masked. 2 Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2005) in response to the FCC’s Public Notice DA 051267 called for a variation in the FCC’s proposed schedule for testing alternative auction models in favour of the Clock Proxy format. 3 See Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2006), Day and Milgrom (2007) and Day and Raghavan (2007) for more details. 2 bidderID bidderName units_1 units_2 units_3 units_4 units_5 units_6 units_7 bidAmount 1 Bidder 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1000000 2 Bidder 2 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1000000 2 Bidder 2 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1000000 3 Bidder 3 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1000000 3 Bidder 3 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1000000 Figure 1: Hypothetical bid data illustrating low Vickrey prices. TieIDbidderIDbidderName units_1 units_2 units_3 units_4 units_5 units_6 units_7 bidAmountoppCost basePrice 1 2 Bidder 2 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1000000 0 500000 1 3 Bidder 3 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1000000 0 500000 Figure 2: WDP software output for the data in figure 1. which there are 3 bidders; bidder one needs a unit of lots 3 and 4, bidders 2 and 3 only need one unit. The Vickrey prices are zero. It is clearly efficient to assign the lots to bidders 2 and 3 and a single lot is as valuable e.g. to the coalition of bidder 1 and 2 as two lots would be. The opportunity cost is zero as confirmed by the WDP software, see figure 2. Figure 2 also displays the higher base prices which splits equally between bidders 2 and 3 the smallest amount they must pay so that the loser is unable to ‘offer’ the auctioneer more for the two packages. To summarise, one of the main motivations of the Ausubel, Cramton, Milgrom (2006) Clock-Proxy auction is to protect against the very low revenues which sometimes arise from charging opportunity costs as in a Vickrey Auction (zero revenue in the example). In the above example, the procedure is successful in this regard since the base prices exceed opportunity costs by a significant amount. Figure 3 presents the 10-40 GHz auction outcome. Columns 4-10 detail the assignments of the Lots, column 11 the amount bid for these assignments by the 10 bidders. Column 12 details the opportunity cost (Vickrey prices) and column 13 the base prices payable by these bidders. We have added to the output of the WDP software a final column which simply details the starting or reserve prices for the lots. There are two striking feature of this data. First, the bid amounts considerably exceed both the opportunity cost and base prices. Second, the base price for each package is either equal to the opportunity cost or it is equal to the reserve price. This means that, in the event, given the bids4 , as far as revenue is concerned the modified 4 Note however that bidders might have had incentives to behave differently if Vickrey 3 TieID bidderID bidderName units_1 units_2 units_3 units_4 units_5 units_6 units_7 bidAmount oppCost basePrice ReservePrice 2 1 Arqiva 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 1599000 260500 260500 120000 2 2 BT 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1001000 179000 179000 60000 2 3 Digiweb 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 142000 39000 39000 20000 2 4 Faultbasic 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 750000 0 30000 30000 2 5 MLL 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 250000 179000 179000 90000 2 6 Orange 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 2999999 261000 261000 120000 2 7 RedM 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 34000 1000 10000 10000 2 8 TMobile 8 0 0 0 0 2 1 8500000 319000 319000 230000 2 9 Transfinite 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 97000 0 20000 20000 2 10 UKBB 0 0 0 0 0 0 4 420000 0 120000 120000 Figure 3: Primary Stage Assignment and Base Prices. Note specifically BP = max{OC, RP }. second price rule achieved only what Vickrey pricing would have achieved. Figure 3 details only the outcome of the primary stage of the 10-40 GHz auction. When more than one winning bidders demand the lots in a band, a new round of assignment stage bid is required to decide the final lot assignment. It is also a sealed-bid auction and allocations and prices are again determined on a modified Vickrey basis using the WDP software. The logic of this relies on the within band differences of valuations being of second order importance compared to between band differences. In the event, this was borne out by the bidding behaviour. The main conclusions of this paper are as follows. The clock phase of the auction appears to have had a marked impact on the subset of valuations which were effectively reported by bidders throughout the primary bid phase. This is consistent with what the auction format is designed to achieve: bidders receive information during the clock stage which enables them to focus their attention on plausible outcomes and this reduces the combinatoric complexity of the task of reporting "valuations" via bids. This focussing lead to a successful outcome in the sense that the format elicited consistent bids which lead to the allocation of all the spectrum. With some reservations5 the allocation was probably reasonably efficient consistent with the stated objectives of Ofcom. From the point of view of achieving high revenues– not an objective of Ofcom, but of interest for other potential adopters of the format, the auction appears to have generated rather low prices. Inspection of the data shows that bidders focussed heavily on the assignments thrown up by the clock phase and this lead to low opportunity costs given reported preferences (low Vickrey prices). The situation was exacerbated by many pricing had been adopted. See for example Day and Milgrom’s (2007) discussion of bidder shills. 5 Briefly detailed in section 4.4. 4 bidders making a large number of "redundant" bids leading to there being far fewer "effective" bids than the number of actual bids made during the auction. Due to the sparsity of effective bids, the modified second price rule simply did not have any leverage to protect revenue as discussed above and displayed in figure 3. 2 The Primary Bid Stage 2.1 Spectrum Packaging and Combinatorics Spectrum Packaging The process was for spectrum at 10-40 GHz. One of the design features of the auction was to group the ten 10 GHz sublots, the two National 28GHz sublots and the six sublots each of National 32 GHz and National 40 GHz. This grouping reduces the number of packages on which bidders have to deal with in the primary stage of the auction at the cost of having an extra (assignment stage) stage, see Figure 4. Number of lots Spectrum Eligibility Points per lot Lots 1 - National 10 GHz 10 1 Lots 2 - National 28 GHz 2 6 Lots 3 - First Sub-National 28 GHz 1 2 Lots 4 - Second Sub-National 28 GHz 1 1 Lots 5 - Third Sub-National 28 GHz 1 3 Lots 6 - National 32 GHz 6 6 Lots 7 - National 40 GHz 6 3 Figure 4: The Grouping within Lots and associated Eligibility Points. Notwithstanding the grouping of sublots, there are potentially a large number of distinct packages for bidders to consider in the primary bid stage. Specifically, a bidder with the full amount of eligibility points can choose to bid on 12, 935 distinct non-null packages6 . This is a large but a distinctly computable number and is certainly much less than the over 134 million packages which would have resulted without grouping. 6 This number does not take account of the eligibility cap for all bidders of 42 eligibility points 5 Eligibility points The purpose of assigning eligibility points for each lot is to determine the terms of trade with which bidders are allowed to transfer demand from one package of lots to another during the clock phase and for subsequent supplementary bids. Bidders lose eligibility7 if they fail to bid and the loss of eligibility restricts their available choices both within the clock phase and the supplementary bid phase. This gives bidders incentives to bid actively during the clock phase. The various lots were assigned eligibility points as detailed in Figure 4. One hopes that the eligibility points will correspond to some intrinsic value of the lots which is expected to be reflected in the valuations of bidders. Of course this is a guess at market valuations which can impact on the efficiency of the auction. There are other alternatives,8 but the one adopted has the advantage of simplicity. In the event the final clock prices were (in £000) 69, 707, 97, 37, 130, 594, 151. This series is strongly positively correlated with the eligibility points per lot 1, 6, 2, 1, 3, 6, 3, having a correlation coefficient of approximately 0.96. Although this high correlation certainly does not establish the correctness of the choice of eligibility points, neither does it provide evidence against. Bidder Initial Eligibility Arqiva BT Digiweb Faultbasic MLL Orange RedM TMobile Transfinite UKBB 24 42 7 9 25 18 2 26 12 42 End ClockPhase Eligibility 13 15 2 6 0 18 0 23 2 3 E: Eligibility of BP: Base Price BP/E Acquired Lots (£000's) 12 6 2 3 9 12 1 23 2 12 260.5 179 39 30 179 261 10 319 20 120 21.7 29.8 19.5 10 19.9 21.7 10 13.9 10 10 Figure 5: Base Prices per aquired Eligibility Points by Bidder Since all bidders began with a legislated maximum of not more than 42 eligibly points, the number of possible bids is much reduced–there are only 7 Specifically, during the clock phase bidders cannot ’spend’ more eligibility than they spent in the past. During the supplementary bid phase bidders can bid unrestricted amounts (i.e. no limit on maximum) for lots within their end of clock phase eligibility but are restricted in how much they can bid on packages which exceed this eligibility. 8 For instance, and specifically, Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2006) propose a ‘revealed preference’ activity rule. 6 6, 928 possible packages. In practice, most bidders began with fewer than the maximum eligibility points, RedM with only two initial eligibility points has only five feasible packages. Evidently, given these numbers, it is not completely beyond the bounds of reason that bidders might enter bids for each distinct package within their entitlement constraint. Post clock phase combinatorics At the termination of the clock phase, the number of eligibility points remaining for the bidders will typically be reduced and in the 10-40 GHz auction the eligibility of all bidders was indeed reduced for all bidders except one (Orange). UKBB started with 42 but ended with only 3; T-Mobile started with 26 and ended with 23. Column 4 of Figure 6 gives details for all bidders. Column 5 of Figure 6 illustrates that for many bidders the scale of the problem of detailing within eligibility bids, was perhaps not impossibly large. Bidder Initial Eligibility Initial number of possible packages End clock-phase Number of withinEligibility eligibility post clock packages Arqiva 24 1885 13 334 BT 42 6928 15 499 Digiweb 7 65 2 5 Faultbasic 9 123 6 45 MLL 25 2108 0 0 Orange 18 840 18 840 RedM 2 5 0 0 TMobile 26 2329 23 1672 Transfinite 12 267 2 5 UKBB 42 6928 3 267 Figure 6: Eligibility combinatorics: The number of potential packages on which bidders may wish to bid: initial and within eligiblity post-clock phase. Figure 7 displays the actual numbers of bids made by each bidder both in the clock phase and in the supplementary bid phase of the principal stage of the auction. Figure 7 also decomposes the supplementary bids into those which exceeded the terminal eligibility following the clock phase (for which prices were bounded by clock prices) and those within this eligibility for which the prices were not so bounded. At the supplementary bid stage the auction rules distinguish between bids which exceed the bidders terminal eligibility and those which do not. Bidders are allowed to post unrestricted bids for packages within their terminal eligibility but are constrained by the ruling clock prices (when the bidder had sufficient eligibility) for bids on 7 packages which exceed their terminal eligibility. This means that if prices have risen during the clock phase, there may be little purpose in making lots of ineffectual bids for initial rather than final eligibility. The clock phase therefore reduces the size of the combinatoric valuation problem and provides some price information which may be useful in further focussing bids. The potential importance of the within eligibility distinction is illustrated by T-Mobile’s bidding: for supplementary bid packages exceeding terminal eligibility, the average bid was £737, 500, for supplementary bid packages not exceeding terminal eligibility the average bid was £6, 894, 470. clock sealed sealed exceeding terminal eligibility sealed not exceeding terminal eligibility Arqiva 17 22 0 22 BT 17 544 425 119 Digiweb 17 1 0 1 Faultbasic 17 12 6 6 MLL 9 15 9 6 Orange 17 4 0 4 Bidder\Bi ds RedM 9 2 1 1 TMobile 17 106 14 92 Transfinite 17 1 0 1 UKBB 17 3 2 1 Figure 7: The number of actual bids by bidder and type of bid 2.2 Redundant and Effective Bids A very noticeable feature of the bidding is that some bidders made a large number of redundant (or more accurately almost redundant) bids so that the effective registration of reported values was much less than the number of bids entered. We will illustrate with the following selection of the last few supplementary bids from one of the bidders (BT). Figure 8 displays the bid amount as the second column and the package bid for in the seven subsequent columns. Note that the amount of the bid in the first row is at least as large as any subsequent bid but the package corresponding to this bid is a subset of all but two of the other packages bid for. Essentially,9 this 9 It is important to note that under the rules of the auction, bids which are "redundant" in this sense can impact on the outcome of the auction. Both the assignment and revenue can be changed. The reason is to do with the tie breaking rules of the auction. For 8 means that BT signals to the auction, for example, that it is as content with one unit of lot 6 as it is with 6 units of lot 6 plus 2 of lot 7 (the last bid). Hence, the only effective bids in figure 8 are the three highlighted in italics. Proceeding in a similar way with the whole set of bids, many other bids can be deleted–including some clock bids. Bid BT BT BT BT BT BT BT BT BT BT BT BT BT 1001000 1001000 1000500 1000500 1001000 1001000 1001000 1001000 1001000 1001000 1001000 1001000 1001000 Lot 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Lot 2 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Lot 3 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Lot 4 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Lot 5 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Lot 6 1 1 0 0 1 1 1 2 2 2 4 5 6 Lot 7 0 2 1 2 3 4 5 3 4 6 2 2 2 Figure 8: Illustration of redundant bids Many bidders had such redundant bids which markedly reduced the number of effective bids below the number of actual bids detailed in figure 7. Figure 9 details this effective bid deficit. One sees that the case of BT is particularly marked–out of 561 bids only 2 were effective in the sense we are using the word. As bidders added supplementary bids, sometimes the effective number of bids were therefore reduced–bids were made redundant by subsequent supplementary bids. More bidding generally meant less effective bids. This marked ‘reduction’ in the quantity of effective bids may well have had significant consequences for the outcome of the auction, we discuss this via some counterfactual alternatives in section 2.3. The effective bid data are sufficiently reduced that we can get a good grasp of the mechanisms behind the outcome by listing the effective bids for the majority of the bidders for whom the number of effective bids were single digits. Figure 10 displays the list of effective bids made by these 8 bidders. In total there are only 31 bids in contrast to the 700 or so by these bidders in the actual auction. The highest bids for each of the 8 bidders are highlighted in italics, for MLL there are two equally high bids (but select the assignments with equal value of bids, the auction prefers to select the one that assigns most spectrum (for which the starting prices are charged). Sections 2.3.1 and 2.4 discuss further. 9 Bidder Arqiva BT Digiweb Faultbasic MLL Orange RedM TMobile Transfinite UKBB clock bids sealed bids 17 17 17 17 9 17 9 17 17 17 22 544 1 12 15 4 2 106 1 3 total effective sealed effective bids bids 22 22 2 2 1 3 1 2 6 6 3 3 2 2 106 106 0 3 3 7 Figure 9: The Effective Bid deficit: numbers of actual and effective bids for each seller. bid for unit of lot 2 at £250, 000). Suppose each bidder were assigned the package on which it bid highest, this is a feasible assignment since there is a nonnegative excess supply for each Lot. This assignment, at zero price is in the core and it is evidently also bidder optimal. Hence, the auction rules applied only to this subset of bidders establishes a zero price–or rather, the bidders are required to pay the starting (reserve) prices for the individual lots they receive. This conclusion is confirmed by running the auction WDP software for the data in figure 10, the results are displayed as figure 11. In the next section (section 2.3) we also carry out this calculation on the original bid data but with all the bids of Arqiva and T-Mobile deleted, the calculations give different results because of the treatment of lots which are in excess supply. The main point is that bidders listed in figure 10 ended up expressing rather little demand. 2.3 Discussion of Counterfactual Outcomes The total number of eligibility points required to purchase all lots is 82 which, at reserve of £10K per eligibility point, would cost £820,000. In the event, the auction raised a revenue of £1,434,630, i.e. somewhat less than twice the reserve price. In this section we explore the effect on revenues of a number of counterfactual bidding scenarios. 10 Lot 1 BT BT Digiweb Digiweb Digiweb FaultBasic FaultBasic MLL MLL MLL MLL MLL MLL Orange Orange Orange RedM RedM RedM RedM RedM Transfinite Transfinite Transfinite UKBB UKBB UKBB UKBB UKBB UKBB UKBB Total Demand Supply XS Supply Lot 2 0 0 4 3 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 4 10 6 Lot 3 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 1 Lot 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 Lot 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 Lot 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 Lot 7 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 2 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 6 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 2 2 4 3 1 2 1 2 6 4 Bid 1,000,500 1,001,000 200,000 198,000 142,000 535,000 750,000 250,000 50,000 250,000 60,000 110,000 34,000 2,999,999 1,492,957 2,857,887 29,000 34,000 179,000 79,000 97,000 179000 79000 97000 394,000 599,000 420,000 378,000 170,001 302,000 500,001 Figure 10: Complete list of effective bids for bidders other than Arquiva and TMobile. Note that supply exceeds the value maximising assignment for these bidders. Outcome of the Primary Bid Stage run on the data in Figure 10. TieID bidderID bidderNa units_1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 BT Digiweb FaultBasic MLL Orange RedM Transfinite UKBB 0 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 units_2 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 units_3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 units_4 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 units_5 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 units_6 1 0 0 0 2 1 1 1 units_7 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 bidAmou oppCost 1001000 200000 750000 250000 2999999 179000 179000 599000 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 basePrice 60000 40000 30000 60000 120000 60000 60000 120000 550000 Figure 11: Calculation of Assignment and Base Prices from data of Figure 10. 11 2.3.1 Impact of deleting two bidders (Arqiva and T-Mobile). We saw in section 2.2 that many of the bidders had made rather few effective bids, notwithstanding the much larger number of actual bids made. Here we evaluate via the auction WDP software the result of the primary bid stage in the counterfactual situation in which only the bidders listed in figure 10 were present (and in which they made the same bids). Outcome of the Primary Bid Stage (with Arqiva and T-Mobile not present) TieID bidderID bidderName units_1 units_2 units_3 units_4 units_5 units_6 units_7 bidAmount oppCost basePrice 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 9 10 BT Digiweb Faultbasic MLL Orange RedM Transfinite UKBB 4 4 0 2 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 3 0 1 1 2 0 0 1 0 0 0 2 1001000 200000 750000 250000 2999999 34000 179000 599000 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 240000 40000 30000 110000 180000 10000 60000 120000 790000 Figure 12: Ofcom software calculation of Primary Stage Assignement and Base Prices resulting from the deleting 2 bidders (Arquiva and TMobile). The sparsity of bidding leads to low prices. Comparing figure 12 with figure 11, there are some discrepancies. Looking at figure 12, we see that MLL is allocated 2 units of Lot 1, 1 unit of Lot 2 and 1 unit of Lot 7 for which MLL bid £250,000, whereas in figure 10 MLL has no such effective bid. The reason is that because of MLL’s effective bid of £250,000 for a single unit of Lot 2 we have eliminated, in constructing figure 10, the bid which determines MLL’s assignment in the figure 12. Essentially, the reason is that there is excess demand for the other lots and the auction mechanism has a revenue tie-breaking rule which chooses to allocate this spectrum at the starting prices. This illustrates what we pointed out in section 2.2, that our usage of language in defining "redundant bids" and "effective bids" is something of an oversimplification. Nevertheless the language remains useful in analysing the auction outcome. 2.3.2 "Pay as bid" Clock stage Another counterfactual of interest is what would have happened if the auction had terminated after the clock phase but now with bidders paying their terminal bids. If bidders did not change their behaviour then the revenue would have been substantially higher - over £6.7m. Under these counterfactual conditions, the actual auction earned less than a quarter of the (counterfactual) "pay as bid" clock auction. 12 Of course, bidders may well have had incentives to bid very differently. In particular, the incentive to halt price increases through demand reduction may have been more acute. Given the feature that bidders cannot, in the supplementary bid phase, expand their demand at higher prices than those pertaining in the clock phase10 , there seems no strong reason for this to be the case. It is difficult to think that bidders believed that they had marked incentives to bid above their valuations in the clock auction so it does seem that the revenue only managed to capture a small share of this value11 . 2.3.3 Pseudo Clock Auction: Impact of deleting all supplementary bids If one takes the view that some of the supplementary bids may have been illconsidered and resulting in a sparsity of effective bids, a natural comparison involves deleting some of the bids from the supplementary bid stage of the auction. The second table in Figure 13 provides a natural comparison–what would have happened if the auction had been terminated after the clock stage but otherwise under the same rules. If bidders did not change their behaviour then we see, the revenue increases from approximately £1.4m to £2.7m i.e. under these conditions revenue would have nearly doubled. The big question is whether bidders would be likely to change their behaviour. In our view, there is no strong evidence that behaviour during the clock phase would have been much different. Unless the supplementary bids are deliberately misleading12 many have the appearance of something of an afterthought. Some bidders may have expected the auction to be more or less over after the clock stage. Second, as we will discuss later, most bidders tended to bid for their putative clock allocations in the supplementary bid phase. 2.3.4 Impact of deleting BT’s supplementary bids only. We have seen that although BT made the most bids, only 2 were effective. The supplementary bids cancelled out the clock bids to the possible detriment to auction revenues. Suppose we delete all the supplementary bids from BT, in this case the software shows that the assignment is impacted 10 Ausubel Cramton and Milgrom (2006) proposed a relaxed (revealed preference) activity rule in contrast to the unrelaxed activity rule of this auction. 11 It is worth noting in this respect that Ofcom’s stated objectives are efficiency rather than revenue. However, Ausubel, Cramton Milgrom (2005) emphasise both revenue and efficiency considerations. 12 Since the data are public, bidders might wish to confuse Ofcom, business rivals and potential competitors in future auctions with similar formats. 13 Outcome of the Primary Bid Stage bidderName units_1 units_2 units_3 units_4 units_5 units_6 units_7 Arqiva BT Digiweb Faultbasic MLL Orange RedM TMobile Transfinite UKBB 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 8 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 2 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 4 bidAmount oppCost basePrice 1,599,000 1,001,000 142,000 750,000 250,000 2,999,999 34,000 8,500,000 97,000 420,000 260,500 179,000 39,000 0 179,000 261,000 1,000 319,000 0 0 260,500 179,000 39,000 30,000 179,000 261,000 10,000 319,000 20,000 120,000 1,417,500 Outcome of the Primary Bid Stage (Clock Bids Only Evaluated) bidderName units_1 units_2 units_3 units_4 units_5 units_6 units_7 Arqiva BT Digiweb Faultbasic MLL Orange RedM TMobile Transfinite UKBB 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 8 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 3 0 2 0 0 0 3 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 1 bidAmount oppCost basePrice 1,451,000 918,000 138,000 281,000 0 1,782,000 0 1,891,000 97,000 151,000 747,000 454,000 0 205,000 0 604,000 0 616,000 24,000 6,000 747,000 454,000 20,000 205,000 0 604,000 0 616,000 24,000 30,000 2,700,000 Figure 13: The Primary Bid Stage Outcome compared with the counterfactual calculation on the Clock Phase data only. mainly by BT now registering a positive value for units of Lot 7 with the result that BT gains 2 units of 40 GHz at the expense of UKBB. BT pays and extra £11, 000 for these two lots. UKBB receives one unit of Lot 6 as a by-product at the expense of MLL. As a result, MLL pays £149, 000 less than before but all other bidders pay more. The impact on final revenue is an increase of £86, 500. 2.3.5 Impact of deleting Arqiva’s supplementary bids only. Arqiva’s supplementary bids were all effective ones, but figure 15 shows that they had rather little impact on the auction outcome. Arqiva itself would have won more spectrum (Lot 4) at a cost of £23K. Taking Arqiva’s supplementary bids at face value this additional unit of spectrum was revealed to be not worth the cost. The auction revenue is about £7K higher. 2.3.6 Impact of deleting T-Mobile’s supplementary bids only. After BT, T-Mobile exercised the largest number of supplementary bids. In contrast to BT, but as with Arqiva, (most of) T-Mobile’s supplementary bids were "effective" in the sense used above–they did not cancel each other out. It is interesting to note that if T-Mobile’s supplementary bids alone 14 Outcome of the Primary Bid Stage (with BT’s Supplementary Bids Deleted) TieID bidderID bidderName units_1 units_2 units_3 units_4 units_5 units_6 units_7 bidAmount oppCost basePrice 1 1 Arqiva 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 1599000 212000 267000 1 2 BT 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 896000 190000 190000 1 3 Digiweb 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 142000 50000 50000 1 4 Faultbasic 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 750000 0 55000 1 5 MLL 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 60000 22000 30000 1 6 Orange 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 2999999 294000 294000 1 7 RedM 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 34000 1000 34000 1 8 TMobile 8 0 0 0 0 2 1 8500000 352000 352000 1 9 Transfinite 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 97000 0 20000 1 10 UKBB 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 599000 212000 212000 1504000 Figure 14: The Primary Bid Stage Outcome with the Supplementary Bids of BT deleted. Outcome of the Primary Bid Stage (with Arqiva's Supplementary Bids Deleted) TieID bidderID bidderNa units_1 units_2 units_3 units_4 units_5 units_6 units_7 bidAmou oppCost basePrice 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 2 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 4 1451000 1001000 142000 750000 250000 2999999 29000 8500000 79000 420000 Arqiva BT Digiweb Faultbasic MLL Orange RedM TMobile Transfinite UKBB 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 8 0 0 283500 179000 39000 0 179000 279000 18000 337000 0 0 283500 179000 39000 30000 179000 279000 20000 337000 30000 120000 1496500 Figure 15: The Primary Bid Stage Outcome with the Supplementary Bids of Arqiva deleted. 15 Outcome of the Primary Bid Stage (with T-Mobile's Supplementary Bids deleted) bidderName Arqiva BT Digiweb Faultbasic MLL Orange RedM TMobile Transfinite UKBB units_1 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 8 0 0 units_2 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 units_3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 units_4 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 units_5 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 units_6 0 1 0 0 1 2 0 2 0 0 units_7 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 4 bidAmount oppCost basePrice 1,599,000 1,001,000 142,000 750,000 250,000 2,999,999 34,000 1,891,000 97,000 420,000 260,500 179,000 39,000 0 179,000 261,000 1,000 319,000 0 0 260,500 179,000 39,000 30,000 179,000 261,000 10,000 319,000 20,000 120,000 1,417,500 Figure 16: The Primary Bid Stage Outcome with the Supplementary Bids of T-Mobile deleted. are deleted and the primary bid stage outcome recalculated, one finds that the outcome is unaffected. In other words, even though T-Mobile made a large number of effective supplementary bids, none of them impacted on the outcome of the auction. The reason for this rests largely with the sparsity of effective bids from other bidders. 2.4 Starting versus Reserve Prices: A Strange Feature We return to the discussion of assignment and pricing when supply exceeds demand for a particular lot. It seems the following situation can arise. Bidder 1 bids £1m for a 42 eligibility point package and also bids £1m for a small subset of that package, say Lot 3. According to our definition of section 2.2, only the second bid is effective. All other bidders only bid on packages which include Lot 3 in the first round of the clock auction and then bid for zero lots in the second round, no other bidders enter any supplementary bids. Hence, since Bidder 1’s bids are revenue maximising and inconsistent with all other bids, Bidder 1 wins. The auction WDP software assigns 42 eligibility points to Bidder 1–even though according to Bidder 1’s bids, 41 of those eligibility points have no value. The rest of the spectrum is retained by Ofcom even though the other bidders did bid for the other spectrum (in combination with Lot 3). Note that Bidder 1 will not pay the zero opportunity cost, or £10K for item 3, but £420K for the 42 eligibility points worth of spectrum assigned. Evidently, Bidder 1 would rather pay £10K for the lesser package according to the values expressed by his or her bids. Hence, the outcome is not a bidder optimal core allocation. An alternative would be to treat the starting prices, i.e. reserve prices as bids in determining the assignment. 16 3 The Assignment Stage After the primary stage bid round, when there are more than one winning bidders demanding the lots in a band, a new round of assignment stage bid is required to determine the final allocation of lots. Like the supplementary bid round, the assignment bid round is a sealed-bid auction. Relevant bidders submit their bids to Ofcom, and the winning bids are those compatible bids with the largest amount bid. The prices payable by the bidders in the assignment stage are called Top-Up prices, which are core prices that generate a bidder-Pareto optimal allocation (Cramton, et al. 2006, Chapter 3 and 5; Day and Raghavan, 2007). Although the grouping of lots in the primary bid phase reduces the number of packages for that stage, it potentially does so at the cost of introducing other complications. For the philosophy behind the grouping and sequential auction design to be valid, it is important that the tail does not wag the dog. It is predicated on the assumption that the within group assignments are of second order importance to the first stage. 3.1 Bidding The striking aspect of the bids is that Orange appears to have had strong views on which lots it received and bid significantly higher (£105K) for its preferred assignment than any other bids. This bid was significantly less than Orange’s primary stage bid for the two lots of this spectrum which it was assigned (approximately £3m). The relative magnitudes of these bids appears to corroborate the view that the within Lot assignment was indeed of second order importance. 17 Bidder BT BT BT BT BT BT MLL MLL MLL MLL MLL MLL Orange Orange Orange Orange Orange TMobile TMobile TMobile TMobile TMobile 32GHz Nat band Frequecy Assignment Stage Bid option Lot 1 0 Lot 2 10000 Lot 3 5000 Lot 4 4000 Lot 5 9000 Lot 6 0 Lot 1 0 Lot 2 3000 Lot 3 5000 Lot 4 5000 Lot 5 3000 Lot 6 0 Lots 1 and 2 105000 Lots 2 and 3 15000 Lots 3 and 4 0 Lots 4 and 5 15000 Lots 5 and 6 15000 Lots 1 and 2 20229 Lots 2 and 3 15151 Lots 3 and 4 10099 Lots 4 and 5 5048 Lots 5 and 6 0 Assignment stage bids for 32 GHz lots. 4 4.1 Evaluation and Conclusions The auction mechanics and correspondence with the documentation The auction mechanics seemed to work reasonably smoothly–although we have not shared in bidder feedback. 4.2 Bidder behaviour Some bidders appear not to have been prepared. Some of the documentation may have been obscure. We did not make a systematic search of documentation available to bidders prior to the auction, but found the translation of essentially mathematical concepts from legal phraseology a challenge. A recommendation for any future auctions using similar formats is to invest heavily in helping bidders via a multiplicity of software promptings and other tools. For instance, we would recommend a device which pointed 18 out to bidders when they bid more for a subset of lots than a superset–or made them choose ‘more consistent’ different bids. The suspicion of lack of bidder preparedness makes it hard to gauge the potential of the format in situations where bidders have spent more resources in preparing. However, the reservations detailed below about low revenues might remain a feature even with well-prepared bidders. 4.3 Revenue The auction seems very likely to have produced low revenue. One wonders to what extent low revenue is a natural outcome for such auctions. If we paraphrase the theory behind the auction format, insofar as it can be taken from13 Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2006). There are two problems14 with Vickrey auctions which the Clock Proxy design is intended to overcome. 1. Combinatoric complexity For even moderate numbers of objects, there are too many potential combinations of objects on which to make bids. 2. Vickrey outcomes are not necessarily ‘competitive’. Specifically, outcomes are not in the core when the auctioneer is included as an agent with preferences increasing in auction revenues. This means that Vickrey outcomes can yield very low revenues. The Ausubel, Cramton and Milgrom (2006) Clock Proxy auction and the UK 2008 10-40GHz Spectrum auction deals with these problems by two separate devices. The first is that rather than simply ask bidders to produce an unfeasibly long list of sealed bid valuations for packages, there is a preceding clock phase to the auction. The progress of prices and bids during the clock phase gives guidance to the bidders so that they are better able to gauge which packages are likely to be of interest to them. In short, the clock phase is designed to reduce the number of bids and to focus only on relevant ones. The second is that rather than calculate prices according to the Vickrey opportunity cost formula, this is modified to guarantee that the assignment is in the core. Of all core assignments, the bidder optimal one is chosen. This is supposed to guarantee ‘reasonable’ revenues given reported valuations. So, the clock phase should help bidders to report most of the valuations which are likely to be relevant and the Vickrey pricing modification should 13 14 See also, e.g. Day and Milgrom (2007). Note however that Ofcom’s stated aim is to maximise efficiency rather than revenue. 19 help stop the revenues becoming too low (at some potentially troublesome constellations of preferences). There is a real sense in which these two objectives are in conflict. Helping bidders reduce the number of bids they need to make in addition to the bids corresponding to the eventual assignment reduces the reported opportunity cost of that assignment. The problem–for revenue–arises when the clock phase does its job too well and bidders jump from the end of the clock phase to immediately reporting high valuations for packages which together constitute a feasible assignment. This kills the opportunity cost of the assignment and notwithstanding the modified Vickrey rule can easily lead to low revenues. It is very instructive to compare the final clock bids with the highest supplementary bids for each of the bidders. Arqiva Arqiva made its highest supplementary bid, £1, 600K, for the same package as it made its final clock phase bid on (0, 2, 0, 1, 0, 0, 0). Arqiva also made a very near bid on a subset of this package, it bid £1, 599K on the package (0, 2, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0) which is the one it was eventually assigned. BT BT bid its highest supplementary bid of £1, 001K for the same package as it made its final clock phase bid on (0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 2). BT also bid £1, 001K of hundreds of other packages including (0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 0) which it was eventually assigned. Faultbasic Faultbasic bid £350K in the supplementary round on the package of its final clock phase bid (0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 0, 1). Its highest supplementary bid of £750K was for a subset (0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 0, 0) of this package. Faultbasic was eventually assigned this subset. MLL MLL ended the clock phase with zero eligibility but made its highest supplementary bid of £250K on its final non null clock bid (0, 1, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0). MLL also bid £250K on 10 other packages, including (0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 1) which it was eventually assigned. Orange Orange made its maximum supplementary bid £2, 999, 999 on its final clock phase package (0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 3, 0) but also bid the same amount on the subset (0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 2, 0) which it was eventually assigned. RedM RedM ended the clock phase with zero eligibility but made its highest supplementary bid of £34K on its final non null clock bid (0, 0, 0, 1, 0, 0, 0). RedM was eventually assigned this package. 20 T-Mobile T-Mobile made its maximum supplementary bid of £8.5m on the same package as its final clock phase bid. T-Mobile was eventually assigned this package. Transfinite Transfinite only made one supplementary bid. This bid was on the same package as its final clock phase bid and was in the same amount–evidently a redundant bid. UKBB UK Broadband terminated the clock phase with a bid of £151, 000 for the package (0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 1) but made its highest supplementary bid of £500, 001 for the package (0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 1). Eventually, UK Broadband was assigned the package (0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 4) on which it had made the bid £420, 000 during the clock phase15 . To summarise, all but one of the bidders made their highest supplementary bid either on their final clock phase package, or on a subset of it. In behaving in this way, bidders are clearly using the clock phase of the auction to focus their attention on a selection of packages in a way consistent with the philosophy of the auction design. Arguably, however, from the point of view of revenue, bidders have ‘gone too far’ in this respect. It seems likely that this bidding behaviour has lead to lower revenues than might have obtained, for example, in an ascending clock auction with pay as bid pricing. In the auction this bidding behaviour was a feature both for bidders who had a large proportion of effective bids (e.g. T-Mobile) and for those which had a low proportion. In other words, the marked reduction in the number of effective bids displayed in figure 9 is likely to have exacerbated any ‘shortfall’ in revenue, but may not have been its root cause. 4.4 Efficiency UK Spectrum awards are not designed to achieve maximum revenues, so the low-revenue feature highlighted above is not necessarily a major issue in this context. The assignment seems to have been more stable than the prices in the sense that the assignment appears to vary less in the various counterfactual situations we have discussed so far. Compared to the putative assignment at the end of the Clock Phase, the final assignment gives more spectrum to the three bidders MLL, RedM and UK Broadband. This spectrum came at the expense of Arqiva, BT and Orange who all bid the same or very nearly the 15 It is worth observing that Lot 7 finished the clock phase in excess supply. 21 same for subsets of their putative Clock Phase packages as proper subsets of those packages. It is noticeable that the spectrum flows from bidders who generally expressed high values to those who generally expressed low values. One possibility is that the small bidders have found niches between the expressed valuations of the large bidders which would not have been present under the fuller expression of valuations which would have been represented by a larger number of effective bids. However, this interpretation is speculative. One suspects that the auction worked quite well in allowing bidders who needed certain lots and valued them highly e.g. T-Mobile and Orange to acquire the appropriate spectrum. 5 References Ausubel, Lawrence M., Peter Cramton, and Paul Milgrom (2005) “Comments on Experimental Design for Evaluating FCC Spectrum Auction Alternatives”, 1 June, 2005http://wireless.fcc.gov/auctions/isas/Ausubel_et_al.pdf. Ausubel, Lawrence M., Peter Cramton and Paul Milgrom, 2006, “The Clock Proxy Auction: A Practicable Combinatorial Auction Design”, in Cramton, Yoav, Shoham and Steinberg (Eds.), 2006. Ausubel, Lawrence M., Peter Cramton and Paul Milgrom, 2006b, “The Clock Proxy Auction: A Practicable Combinatorial Auction Design”, Presentation National Telecommunications and Information Administration Advanced Technology Forum, http://www.ntia.doc.gov/forums/2006/specman/ntia_cramton.pdf. Cramton, Peter, Yoav, Shoham and Richard, Steinberg, 2006, Combinatorial Auctions, MIT Press. Day, Robert W. and Paul Milgrom, 2007, “Core-Selecting Package Auctions”, to appear International Journal of Game Theory. Day, Robert W. and S. Raghavan, 2007, “Fair Payments for Efficient Allocations in Public Sector Combinatorial Auctions”, Management Science, 53(9), pp. 1389-1406. Ofcom, The Wireless Telegraphy (Licence Award) (No.2), Regulations 2007. Telecommunications Authority of Trinidad and Tobago, First Steps toward a Liberalised Telecommunications Sector, http://www.tatt.org.tt/auction.htm. 22