Review We will spend up to 30 minutes reviewing Exam 1 • Know how your answers were graded. • Know how to correct your mistakes. Your final exam is cumulative, and may contain similar questions. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 1 Deep Thought I can picture in my mind a world without war, a world without hate. And I can picture us attacking that world, because they’d never expect it. ~ Jack Handey. (Translation: Today’s lesson teaches you how to get the best deal for yourself from bargaining.) BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 2 Acknowledgements Acknowledgements Although much of the course content in Part II is covered in the Krugman textbook, the PowerPoint slides for the lessons are self-contained, and are your primary text. Thanks to the following students for insights used in the Part II lesson slides: Fabrizio Alliata Karissa Garcia BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 3 Overview Overview BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 4 Overview Part II Overview Supply and Demand Analysis from Part I helps consumers make satisfying choices, helps managers make profitable decisions, and helps governments make effective public policies when there are impersonal competitive markets of large numbers of firms and customers and workers. Game Theory in Part II now completes supply and demand analysis when personal decisions interact. For example, if Carlos tries to sell shoes and Aleisha tries to buy shoes on eBay, each competes with many potential shoe sellers or buyers, with price determined by aggregate supply and demand. But if, instead, Aleisha happens to walk by Carlos’s trading stall outside the Tijuana Wax Museum, they become tied to a few potential shoe sellers or buyers in Tijuana, and they negotiate a sales price separate from the worldwide competitive market. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 5 Overview Each lesson in Part II is divided into examples. Each example asks a Question and supplies an Answer. The questions are like the questions on your exams: A game is described verbally and you are asked questions about its solution. You must formulate the game (identifying players, strategies, payoffs, …) then answer those questions by solving the game. Many examples also include a Comment about what general lesson you learn from the example. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 6 Overview Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining Example 1: Bargaining verses Competition Example 2: Rollback Solutions Example 3: Take-it-or-Leave-it Offers Example 4: Counter Offers Example 5: Bargaining with Depreciation Summary Review Questions Lesson II.2 Bargaining and Impatience Lesson II.3 Sequential Quantity Competition BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 7 Overview Lesson 1 formulates and solves the following games: Example 2: Century Mark Game. Has a simple solution, found by starting at the end of the game and rolling back to the beginning. Examples 3, 4, 5: Sequential Bargaining Games. Have unique rollback solutions. The solution favors the first mover, and so favors aggressors. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 8 Example 1: Bargaining verses Competition Example 1: Bargaining verses Competition BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 9 Example 1: Bargaining verses Competition Question: Suppose • Aleisha is willing to offer up to $59 to buy a pair of shoes. • Brad, to pay $44; Claudia, $34.01; Darren, $24; Edwina, $10. Suppose • Andrew is willing to accept down to $8 to sell a pair of shoes. • Betty, to sell $20; Carlos, $34; Donna, $48; Engelbert, $62. Compute the competitive-equilibrium price of shoes if all 10 people trade shoes on eBay? (Ignore shipping costs.) Alternatively, suppose Aleisha and Carlos do not use eBay, but Aleisha walks by Carlos’s trading stall outside the Tijuana Wax Museum. Compute the gains if they trade a pair of shoes. Compute the price of shoes if they divide the gains 50-50. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 10 Example 1: Bargaining verses Competition Answer: Competitive Markets have Many Independent Buyers ... • Aleisha is willing to offer up to $59 to buy a pair of shoes. • Brad, $44; Claudia, $34.01; Darren, $24; Edwina, $10. Aleisha Brad Claudia Darren Edwina BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 11 Example 1: Bargaining verses Competition … and Many Independent Sellers • Andrew is willing to accept down to $8 to sell a pair of shoes. • Betty, $20; Carlos, $34; Donna, $48; Engelbert, $62. Aleisha Engelbert Brad Donna Claudia Carlos Darren Betty Edwina Andrew BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 12 Example 1: Bargaining verses Competition Demand equals Supply determines Competitive Price • At some price between $34 and $34.01, Aleisha, Brad and Claudia each buy 1 pair, and Andrew, Betty and Carlos each sell. Aleisha Engelbert Brad Donna Claudia Carlos Darren Betty Edwina Andrew BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 13 Example 1: Bargaining verses Competition Bargaining Occurs with One Buyer and One Seller If Aleisha and Carlos meet separate from the competitive market, then the gains if they were to trade a pair of shoes is the difference between willingness to pay and willingness to sell. • Aleisha is willing to offer $59 to buy a pair of shoes. • Carlos is willing to accept $34 to sell a pair of shoes. • The gain from trade is the difference, $25 = $59-$34. If Aleisha and Carlos divided the gains from trade 50-50, then each gets $12.50 gain, meaning Aleisha pays price $46.50 = $59.00-$12.50, and Carlos receives price $46.50 = $34.00+$12.50 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 14 Example 1: Rollback Solutions Example 2: Rollback Solutions BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 15 Example 2: Rollback Solutions Comment: Whether Aleisha and Carlos divide the gains from trade 50-50 or 99-1 or some other division depends on the rules for the sequence of bargaining offers and counteroffers. Consider an instructive game to illustrate the best way to make any sequence of decisions. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 16 Example 2: Rollback Solutions Question: Consider the Century Mark Game • Played by pairs of players taking turns. • At each turn, each player chooses a number between 1 and 10 inclusive. • This choice is added to sum of all previous choices (the initial sum is 0). • The first player to take the cumulative sum to 100 or more wins. How should you play the game if you were the first player? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 17 Example 2: Rollback Solutions Answer: Start at the end of the game and work backward. This is called backward induction and it defines a rollback solution, or rollback equilibrium. In the Century Mark Game, first ask: What number gets you to 100 next turn? If you bring the cumulative sum to 89, you can take the cumulative sum to 100 on your next turn and win no matter what your opponent does. (Whatever your opponent does, you can make the sum of your two moves equal 11, and 89+11 = 100.) BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 18 Example 2: Rollback Solutions Complete Rollback Solution • If you bring the cumulative sum to 89 on one turn, you can take the cumulative sum to 100 on your next turn and win no matter what your opponent does. (Whatever your opponent does, you can make the sum of your two moves equal 11.) • Hence, if you bring the cumulative sum to 78 on one turn, you can take the cumulative sum to 89 on your next turn (and so eventually win) no matter what your opponent does. • And so on for sums 67, 56, 45, 34, 23, 12. • Hence, if you play 1 on your first turn, you can bring the cumulative sum to 12 on your next turn (and so eventually win) no matter what your opponent does. • That solution is a strategy --- a complete plan of actions no matter what your opponent does. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 19 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Bargaining Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Bargaining BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 20 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Bargaining Comment 1: Bargaining Games have three parts. • Players or bargainers are managers, customers, or workers, typically considered two at the time. • Strategies are offers to divide a fixed positive gain from an agreement, the rejection of such an offer, or the acceptance of such an offer. The most common agreements is trading a good at a particular price. • Manager strategies include a price at which to sell a consumption good or a wage to buy workers’ time. • Customer strategies include a price at which to buy. • Worker strategies include a wage at which to sell. • Payoffs are percentage shares of the gain from an agreement, if there is an agreement, or zero if there were no agreement. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 21 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Bargaining Comment 2: Bargaining Games in Part II assume Rationality and Perfect Information are Common Knowledge. • Rationality means players are perfect calculators and perfect followers of their best strategies. Players have perfect knowledge of their own interests. • Perfect Information means players know the bargaining rules and all offers that have taken place. • Common Knowledge of rationality and perfect information means all players assume all other players are rational and have perfect information, and all players assume all other players assume all other players are rational and have perfect information, and so on. • In contrast, poker professionals (sharks) do not assume bad players (fish or suckers) are rational. Sharks try to trick fish. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 22 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Bargaining Question: Suppose Buyer Bob values the bag of fresh beans in front of him at 1 dollar and Seller Sabitha has no alternative buyers and has no other value for the beans. Suppose there is only enough time before his tour bus leaves for Buyer Bob to make one offer to Seller Sabitha for the bag of beans. Seller Sabitha must either accept or reject that offer. Which of the prices $0.01, $0.50, or $0.98 should Buyer Bob offer? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 23 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Bargaining Answer: Follow two steps to define any Bargaining Game: Determine the total gain from an agreement. When the agreement means trading a good at a particular price, the gain is the maximum price the buyer were willing to pay minus the minimum price the seller were willing to receive. Here, total gain is $1. Strategies are then percentage shares of the gain from trade. Here, prices $0.01, $0.50, or $0.98 means Bob takes 99 percent, 50 percent, or 2 percent of the gain from trade. Determine the bargaining rules. Here, Bob makes an offer that Sabitha accepts or rejects. Either way, the game is then over. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 24 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Bargaining Comment: Many Sequential-Move Games have complex rollback solutions requiring a game tree to predict future responses to current actions. Game trees or extensive forms consist of nodes and branches. Nodes are connected to one another by the branches, and come in two types. Some nodes are decision nodes, where a player chooses an action branch to another node. The other nodes are terminal nodes, where players receive the outcomes of the actions taken by themselves and all other players. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 25 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Bargaining Answer (continued): Here is a Game Tree where payoffs list the gains from trade, with payoffs to the first player to act (Bob, the proposer) listed first. Proposer I take 99% of the gain from trade I take 50% of the gain from trade I take 2% of the gain from trade Responder Responder Responder Accept Reject Accept Reject Accept Reject 99,1 0,0 50,50 0,0 2,98 0,0 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 26 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Offers Starting at the end of the game, Bob predicts rational responses to alternative proposals. Sabitha should accept anything as being better than nothing. Proposer I take 99% of the gain from trade I take 50% of the gain from trade I take 2% of the gain from trade Responder Responder Responder Accept Reject Accept Reject Accept Reject 99,1 0,0 50,50 0,0 2,98 0,0 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 27 Example 3: Take-it-or-leave-it Offers Rolling back to the beginning of the game, determine Bob’s rational proposal, where Bob assumes Sabitha is rational. Bob should offer to take 99%. Proposer I take 99% of the gain from trade I take 50% of the gain from trade I take 2% of the gain from trade Responder Responder Responder Accept Reject Accept Reject Accept Reject 99,1 0,0 50,50 0,0 2,98 0,0 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 28 Example 4: Counter Offers Example 4: Counter Offers BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 29 Example 4: Counter Offers Comment: Bargainers can get most of the gains from trade by making take-it-or-leave-it offers. So it is best for Buyer Bob to make an offer on a bag of beans just as his tour bus is about to leave. To try to counter the take-it-or-leave-it strategy and get more of the gains from trade, Seller Sabitha can try to make a (quick) counter offer. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 30 Example 4: Counter Offers Question: Suppose Buyer Bob values the bag of fresh beans in front of him at 1 dollar and Seller Sabitha has no alternative buyers and has no other value for the beans. But now suppose there is only enough time before his tour bus leaves for Bob to make one offer to Sabitha for the bag of beans and for Sabitha to either to accept or to reject and to make a counteroffer that Bob must either accept or reject. Will trade occur? If so, at what price? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 31 Example 4: Counter Offers Answer: To consider all possible price offers (offers by Bob to buy or counteroffers by Sabitha to sell), consider a bargaining payoff table: Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sabitha's Gain Offered 1 Sabitha 100 ? ? 2 Bob 100 ? ? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 32 Example 4: Counter Offers Starting 1 bargaining round from the end of the game, Sabitha either accepts Bob’s offer or makes a counteroffer that Bob must either accept or reject. Bob should accept anything as being better than nothing. So, Sabitha can get away with the whole gain from trade minus a pittance, leaving Bob with the pittance (essentially, a zero gain to Bob). Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sabitha's Gain Offered 1 Sabitha 100 0 100 2 Bob 100 ? ? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 33 Example 4: Counter Offers Rolling back to the beginning (2 bargaining rounds from the end of the game), Sabitha could reject any offer and get 100 percent in the next round. So, Bob’s best acceptable offer leaves Sabitha with 100 percent, and Bob with 0 percent. That is, trade occurs, and Bob pays $1. Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sabitha's Gain Offered 1 Sabitha 100 0 100 2 Bob 100 0 100 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 34 Example 4: Counter Offers Comment: Listening to a counteroffer thus eliminates all the gains from trade that would otherwise have gone to the player making a take-it-or-leave-it offer. Bob should have refused to listen and, so, forced Sabitha to take or leave a first offer of a pittance to Sabitha. Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sabitha's Gain Offered 1 Sabitha 100 0 100 2 Bob 100 0 100 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 35 Example 5: Bargaining with Depreciation Example 5: Bargaining with Depreciation BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 36 Example 5: Bargaining with Depreciation Comment: Bargaining rules change if the value of the good depreciates like ice cream in the time it takes to make counteroffers to offers, and counter-counteroffers to counteroffers and so on. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 37 Example 5: Bargaining with Depreciation Question: Suppose Buyer Bob values an ice cream bar at 1 dollar and Seller Sam has no alternative buyers and has no other value for the ice cream. Suppose Bob can make the first offer to Sam, who can accept or make a counter offer to Bob, who in turn can accept or make a counter offer to Sam. Offers alternate thereafter. But each counter offer takes valuable time which melts the ice cream and, so, reduces the initial value of the ice cream by 50 cents. What initial price should Buyer Bob offer? Should Seller Sam accept that first offer? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 38 Example 5: Counteroffers with Depreciation Answer: To consider all possible price offers (offers by Bob to buy or offers by Sam to sell), consider another bargaining payoff table. The game ends if an offer is accepted or the ice cream is completely melted and worthless, and gains are measured as a percentage of the $1.00 gain from trading the ice cream before it starts melting. Rounds to Meltdown Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sam's Gain Offered 1 Sam 50 ? ? 2 Bob 100 ? ? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 39 Example 5: Counteroffers with Depreciation Starting 1 bargaining round from the end of the game, when the ice cream has 50 percent of its original value, Bob should accept anything as being better than nothing. So, Sam can get away with the whole 50 percent minus a pittance, leaving Bob with the pittance. Rounds to Meltdown Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sam's Gain Offered 1 Sam 50 0 50 2 Bob 100 ? ? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 40 Example 5: Counteroffers with Depreciation Rolling back to the beginning of the game, 2 steps to meltdown, when the ice cream has 100 percent of its original value, Sam could reject any offer and get 50 percent in the next round. So, Bob’s best acceptable offer leaves Sam with 50 percent plus a pittance, and Bob with 50 percent minus a pittance. Rounds to Meltdown Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sam's Gain Offered 1 Sam 50 0 50 2 Bob 100 50 50 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 41 Example 5: Counteroffers with Depreciation Buyer Bob should thus initially offer price $0.50 for the ice cream, and Seller Sam should accept that first offer. That gives Bob 50 percent of the gain from trade and Sam 50 percent. Rounds to Meltdown Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sam's Gain Offered 1 Sam 50 0 50 2 Bob 100 50 50 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 42 Example 6: Bargaining with Depreciation Example 6: Bargaining with Depreciation BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 43 Example 6: Bargaining with Depreciation Question: Suppose Buyer Bob values an ice cream bar at 1 dollar and Seller Sam has no alternative buyers and has no other value for the ice cream. Suppose Bob can make the first offer to Sam, who can accept or make a counter offer to Bob, who in turn can accept or make a counter offer to Sam. Offers alternate thereafter. But each counter offer takes valuable time which melts the ice cream and, so, reduces the initial value of the ice cream by 33 1/3 cents. What initial price should Buyer Bob offer? Should Seller Sam accept that first offer? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 44 Example 6: Counteroffers with Depreciation Answer: To consider all possible price offers (offers by Bob to buy or offers by Sam to sell), consider another bargaining payoff table. The game ends if an offer is accepted or the ice cream is completely melted and worthless, and gains are measured as a percentage of the $1.00 gain from trading the ice cream before it starts melting. Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered Sams's Gain Offered 1 Bob ? ? ? 2 Sam ? ? ? 3 Bob ? ? ? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 45 Example 6: Counteroffers with Depreciation Starting 1 bargaining round from the end of the game, when the ice cream has 33 1/3 percent of its original value, Sam should accept anything as being better than nothing. So, Bob can get away with the whole 33 1/3 percent minus a pittance, leaving Sam with the pittance. Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered 1 Bob 33 1/3 33 1/3 2 Sam 3 Bob BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining Sams's Gain Offered 0 46 Example 6: Counteroffers with Depreciation Rolling back 2 steps to meltdown, when the ice cream has 66 2/3 percent of its original value, Bob could reject any offer and get 33 1/3 percent in the next round. So, Sam’s best acceptable offer leaves Bob with 33 1/3 percent plus a pittance, and Sam with 33 1/3 percent minus a pittance. Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered 1 Bob 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 2 Sam 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 3 Bob 100 ? ? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining Sams's Gain Offered 47 Example 6: Counteroffers with Depreciation Rolling back to the beginning of the game, 3 steps to meltdown, when the ice cream has 100 percent of its original value, Sam could reject any offer and get 33 1/3 percent in the next round. So, Bob’s best acceptable offer leaves Sam with 33 1/3 percent plus a pittance, and Bob with 66 2/3 percent minus a pittance. Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered 1 Bob 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 2 Sam 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 3 Bob 100 66 2/3 33 1/3 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining Sams's Gain Offered 48 Example 5: Counteroffers with Depreciation Buyer Bob should thus initially offer price $1/3 for the ice cream, and Seller Sam should accept that first offer. That gives Bob 66 2/3 percent of the gain from trade and Sam 33 1/3 percent. Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide Bob's Gain Offered 1 Bob 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 2 Sam 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 3 Bob 100 66 2/3 33 1/3 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining Sams's Gain Offered 49 Example 5: Counteroffers with Depreciation Comment: The players in that counter offer game did not actually make any counteroffers, but the possibility of counteroffers affected the initial offer. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 50 Summary Summary BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 51 Summary A bargainers’ shares of the fixed positive gain from an agreement depends solely on the sequence of who makes offers and on any depreciation of the gains from an agreement over the bargaining rounds. In particular, the bargainers’ shares are independent of the level of the gain from an agreement. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 52 Summary A bargaining payoff table for Bargainers A and B, with Bargainer A making the only offer: B should accept anything as being better than nothing. After deducing that, A’s best acceptable offer to B is a pittance, leaving A with 100 percent. Rounds to End of Game 1 Offer by T otal Gain to Divide A's Gain Offered B's Gain Offered A 100 100 0 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 53 Summary A bargaining payoff table for Bargainers A and B, with Bargainer A making the first offer, when the potential gains from bargaining fully depreciate after 2 rounds: Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide A's Gain Offered B's Gain Offered 1 B 50 0 50 2 A 100 50 50 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 54 Summary Rounds to Gain A's Gain B's Gain Starting 1 bargaining round from End of Offer by TtootalDivide Offered Offered Game the end, when the gain has 1 B 50 0 50 33 1/3 percent of its original 2 A 100 50 50 value, A should accept anything as being better than nothing. After deducing that, B’s best acceptable offer to A is a pittance, leaving B with 25 percent. Rolling back to the beginning, when the gain has 100 percent of its original value, B could reject any offer and get 50 percent in the next round. After deducing that, A’s best acceptable offer to B is 50 percent plus a pittance, leaving A with 50 percent. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 55 Summary A bargaining payoff table for Bargainers A and B, with Bargainer A making the first offer, when the potential gains from bargaining fully depreciate after 3 rounds: Rounds to End of Game Offer by T otal Gain to Divide A's Gain Offered 1 A 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 2 B 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 3 A 100 66 2/3 33 1/3 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining B's Gain Offered 56 Summary Rounds to Starting 1 bargaining round from the End of Offer by Game end, when the gain has 33 1/3 percent 1 A of its original value, B should accept 2 B anything as being better than nothing. 3 A After deducing that, A’s best acceptable offer to B is a pittance, leaving A with 25 percent. T otal Gain to Divide A's Gain Offered B's Gain Offered 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 100 66 2/3 33 1/3 Rolling back to 2 rounds from the end, when the gain has 66 2/3 percent of its original value, A could reject any offer and get 33 1/3 percent in the next round. After deducing that, B’s best acceptable offer to A is 33 1/3 percent plus a pittance, leaving B with 33 1/3 percent. Rolling back to the beginning, when the gain has 100 percent of its original value, B could reject any offer and get 33 1/3 percent in the next round. After deducing that, A’s best acceptable offer to B is 33 1/3 percent plus a pittance, leaving A with 66 2/3 percent. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 57 Review Questions Review Questions You should try to answer some of the following questions before the next class. You will not turn in your answers, but students may request to discuss their answers to begin the next class. Your upcoming Exam 1 and cumulative Final Exam will contain some similar questions, so you should eventually consider every review question before taking your exams. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 58 Review Questions Review Question 1 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 59 Review Questions Question 1. Consider union-management negotiations over wages for workers during Easter Weekend at Medieval Times Dinner Theatre. The weekend lasts Saturday and Sunday. Each day Medieval Times operates, it makes a profit of $10,000. On the Friday night before the weekend, the employee’s union confronts the management over wages. The union presents its demand. The management either accepts or rejects it and returns the next day with a counteroffer. Medieval Times can open only on those days after an agreement is reached the night before. What initial wage demand should the union make? Should management accept that demand? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 60 Review Questions Answer 1: To consider all possible wage offers (offers by the Union to sell labor or offers by Management to buy labor), consider another bargaining payoff table. The game ends if an offer is accepted or if the weekend ends without an accepted offer. Gains are measured as a percentage of the $20,000 gain from accepting the Union’s initial offer. Rounds to End of Game Offer by 1 Mgmt. 50 ? ? 2 Union 100 ? ? T otal Gain Union's Gain Mgmt's Gain to Divide Offered Offered BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 61 Review Questions Rounds to Gain Union's Gain Mgmt's Gain Starting 1 bargaining round from End of Offer by TtootalDivide Offered Offered Game the end of the game, when a 1 Mgmt. 50 0 50 contract has 50 percent of its 2 Union 100 50 50 original value, the Union should accept anything as being better than nothing. So, Management can get away with the whole 50 percent minus a pittance, leaving the Union with the pittance. Rolling back to the beginning of the game, 2 bargaining rounds from the end, when a contract has 100 percent of its original value, Management could reject any offer and get 50 percent in the next round. So, the Union’s best acceptable offer leaves Management with 50 percent plus a pittance, and the union with 25 percent minus a pittance. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 62 Review Questions The Union’s initial wage demand should be for 50% of the $20,000 profits, or $10,000, and management should accept that demand. Rounds to End of Game Offer by 1 Mgmt. 50 0 50 2 Union 100 50 50 T otal Gain Union's Gain Mgmt's Gain to Divide Offered Offered BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 63 Review Questions Review Question 2 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 64 Review Questions Question 2. Consider negotiations over wages for adjunct Management Science Professors at the Business Administration Division of Seaver College of Pepperdine University. Pepperdine seeks a professor for the next 3 semesters. The only candidate is willing to work for $15,000 per semester and Pepperdine is willing to pay up to $25,000 per semester, so the potential gains from trade are $10,000 per semester. Before the first semester, Pepperdine confronts the candidate over wages. Pepperdine presents its offer. The candidate either accepts it or rejects it and returns the next semester with a counteroffer. Offers alternate thereafter. Employment only occurs in those semesters after an agreement is reached. What percentage of the gains from trade should Pepperdine offer? Should the candidate accept that initial offer? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 65 Review Questions Answer 2: To consider all possible wage offers (offers by Pepperdine to buy labor by the candidate to sell labor), consider another bargaining payoff table. The game ends if an offer is accepted or if the three semesters end without an accepted offer, and gains are measured as a percentage of the $30,000 gain from accepting Pepperdine’s offer before the first semester. Rounds to End of Game Pepperdine's Candidate's T otal Gain Gain Gain to Divide Offered Offered Offer by 1 Pepperdine 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 2 Candidate 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 3 Pepperdine 100 66 2/3 33 1/3 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 66 Review Questions Rounds to Pepperdine's Candidate's Gain Starting 1 bargaining round from End of Offer by TtootalDivide Gain Gain Game Offered Offered the end of the game, when a 1 Pepperdine 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 contract has 33 1/3 percent of its 2 Candidate 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 3 Pepperdine 100 ? ? original value, the Candidate should accept anything as being better than nothing. So, Pepperdine can get away with the whole 33 1/3 percent minus a pittance, leaving the Candidate with the pittance. Rolling back to 2 bargaining rounds from the end, when a contract has 66 2/3 percent of its original value, Pepperdine could reject any offer and get 33 1/3 percent in the next round. So, the Candidate’s best acceptable offer leaves Pepperdine with 33 1/3 percent plus a pittance, and the Candidate with 33 1/3 percent minus a pittance. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 67 Review Questions Rounds to Pepperdine's Candidate's T otal Gain Rolling back to 3 bargaining End of Offer by Gain Gain to Divide Game Offered Offered rounds before the end, when a 1 Pepperdine 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 2 Candidate 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 contract has 100 percent of its 3 Pepperdine 100 66 2/3 33 1/3 original value, the Candidate could reject any offer and get 33 1/3 percent in the next round. So, Pepperdine’s best acceptable offer leaves the Candidate with 33 1/3 percent plus a pittance, and Pepperdine with 66 2/3 percent minus a pittance. Pepperdine’s initial wage offer should be for Pepperdine to keep 66 2/3 percent of the $30,000 gain from employment for all three semesters, and the Candidate should accept that initial offer and, so, keep 33 1/3 percent of the $30,000 gain. In particular, since the Candidate is willing to work for $45,000 for all three semesters, he should be paid $45,000 + $10,000 = $55,000. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 68 Review Questions Review Question 3 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 69 Review Questions Question 3. Two companies, one in Dallas and one in LA, are using the same Boston-based lawyer, William Alan Shatner (aka, Captain Kirk). Each firm needs Shatner’s services in January, February, and March. As a result of coordinating schedules, Shatner could each month make a triangle route (Boston-Dallas-LA) rather than making two separate trips. The airfares each month are: Triangle $1000, Boston-Dallas roundtrip $400, Boston-LA roundtrip $800 Before the January trip, Dallas (the Dallas company) confronts LA (the LA company) over its share of the triangle airfare. Dallas presents its offer. LA either accepts it for each of the three trips, or rejects it and returns after the January trip with a counteroffer. After the January trip, Dallas either accepts that counteroffer for each of the remaining two trips, or rejects it and returns after the February trip with a counteroffer. After the February trip, LA either accepts that counteroffer for the remaining trip, or rejects it and ends the game. What percentage of the gains from trade should Dallas offer? Should LA accept that initial offer? BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 70 Review Questions Answer 3: To consider all possible offers to split the gains from an agreement on splitting the cost of the triangle route, consider another bargaining payoff table. The game ends if an offer is accepted or if the three months end without an accepted agreement, and gains are measured as a percentage of the gain from using the triangle route for all three months. Rounds to End of Game Offer by 1 Dallas 33 1/3 ? ? 2 LA 66 2/3 ? ? 3 Dallas 100 ? ? T otal Gain Dallas's Gain to Divide Offered BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining LA's Gain Offered 71 Review Questions Rounds to Gain Dallas's Gain LA's Gain Starting 1 bargaining round from End of Offer by TtootalDivide Offered Offered Game the end of the game, when an 1 Dallas 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 2 LA 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 agreement has 33 1/3 percent of 3 Dallas 100 ? ? its original value, LA should accept anything as being better than nothing. So, Dallas can get away with the whole 33 1/3 percent minus a pittance, leaving the LA with the pittance. Rolling back to 2 bargaining rounds from the end, when an agreement has 66 2/3 percent of its original value, Dallas could reject any offer and get 33 1/3 percent in the next round. So, the LA’s best acceptable offer leaves Dallas with 33 1/3 percent plus a pittance, and LA with 33 1/3 percent minus a pittance. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 72 Review Questions Rounds to T otal Gain Dallas's Gain LA's Gain Rolling back to 3 bargaining End of Offer by to Divide Offered Offered Game rounds before the end, when an 1 Dallas 33 1/3 33 1/3 0 2 LA 66 2/3 33 1/3 33 1/3 agreement has 100 percent of its 3 Dallas 100 66 2/3 33 1/3 original value, LA could reject any offer and get 33 1/3 percent in the next round. So, Dallas’s best acceptable offer leaves LA with 33 1/3 percent plus a pittance, and Dallas with 66 2/3 percent minus a pittance. Recall, the airfares each month are: Triangle $1000, BostonDallas roundtrip $400, Boston-LA roundtrip $800. In particular, the gain from three triangle trips is 3x(1200-1000) = 600. Dallas’s initial offer should be for Dallas to keep 66 2/3 percent of the $600 gain, or $400. So Dallas pays 3x400-400 = $800. Likewise, LA gains $200 and pays 3x800-200 = $2200. BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 73 BA 210 Introduction to Microeconomics End of Lesson II.1 BA 210 Lesson II.1 Strategic Bargaining 74