Effects of industrial conflict between and within organizations: Contagion in collective bargaining and the deterioration of work relations* Agnes Akkerman Department of Political Science and Public Administration, Radboud University & Department of Sociology, Utrecht University. E-mail: a.akkerman@fm.ru.nl René Torenvlied Department of Sociology, Utrecht University & Department of Sociology, University of Groningen. E-mail: r.torenvlied@uu.nl Abstract The present paper outlines the essentials of a new research program in industrial conflict. We study two different effects of industrial conflict. The first effect is on the contagion of industrial conflict between organizations and sectors. Whereas most micro-economic, explanatory studies of strikes assume that strikes are isolated events, the present paper argues that the dispersion of strategic information among negotiators and employees can explain why strikes sometimes occur in waves, and sometimes do not occur where expected. The second effect is on the work relations between management and employees, and between employees at the work floor. Whereas some case studies of strikes mention effects of conflict between strike participants and non-strikers, the present paper argues that systematic research is necessary to unravel the conditions under which industrial conflict affects employee wellbeing and productivity long after the settlement of a strike. 1. Introduction The current study of industrial conflict is dominated by attempts of scholars to explain the prevalence of industrial conflict in sectors and countries. For example, a prominent question in the industrial relations literature is: ―why do some countries exhibit more strikes than other countries?‖ The actual effects of strikes—although widely recognized in the literature—have received much less systematic scholarly attention. If a strike occurs, this may have profound effects beyond the actual industrial conflict, and beyond the stakes of the direct participants in bargaining. In the present paper we introduce a research program that studies the effects of strikes in two areas: (1) collective bargaining outside the immediate scope of the focal organizations, and (2) work relations among employees within the organizations that are affected by strikes. * Paper prepared for presentation at the annual meeting of the Dutch and Flemish Political Science Associations, Leuven, May 27-28. The authors acknowledge financial support from the ―Conflict and Security‖ program of the Dutch Organization for Scientific Research (NWO). Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 2 Most current explanations of industrial conflict consider strikes as independent and isolated events: the bargaining between negotiation partners is not affected by conflict elsewhere, and the conflict has neither an influence on other bargaining events. The microeconomic models developed in bargaining theory attribute the occurrence of a strike to its information-providing function: a strike provides negotiators with information about their relative strength. Thus, these models ignore the possibility that negotiators may reduce their uncertainty in the first place by looking around and informing themselves about what other negotiators do (or have done) in similar circumstances. The crude assumption of independence and isolation of strikes is not very plausible for two reasons. First, from the assumption follows that strike-waves and sudden rises of industrial conflict can only be understood as a coincidence, or as the consequence of macro (socio)-economic and political factors—which would affect negotiations in the fashion of an unexplainable, ‗invisible hand‘. Second, the assumption that bargaining parties are uninformed about what happens in the rest of the world is not very plausible. Modern collective bargaining practice makes use of well-trained and professional negotiators—often responsible for several collective bargaining negotiations—that are part of an extensive network of peers and other professional contacts. It would be rather naive to assume that negotiators ignore information from bargaining events, claims made by parties, employer‘s resistance, and worker‘s willingness to strike, and to assume that such information is not distributed among others and used in other bargaining events. This is the aim of the research project ―Contagious Conflict‖: to study how strategic bargaining information spreads between bargaining events, and how it is used for the mobilization of workers and in negotiations between employers and employees. The project further aims to study how bargaining institutions affect this spread of information and its use. Thus, the contagious conflict project contributes to a further and deeper explanation of industrial conflict. In addition, we argue that strikes do not only have an effect outside the realm of the organization involved in the strike, but also have a long-term after-effect on relations at the work floor between employees within the organization. Several case studies point at the negative effects of a strike for the quality of production and the overall productivity of a firm, even long after the strike is settled. Psychological studies show that strikes have long-term effects on employees‘ health and job-satisfaction. These empirical findings suggest that the social relations between both management and employees—as well as between those employees who joined the strike and those who did not—can become severely damaged by Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 3 the process of the strike. Systematic empirical research into the effects of strikes for social relations among employees (and management) within organizations lacks to date. To fill this gap, the project ―The Aftermath of Strikes‖, studies under what conditions social relations at the work floor are affected by strikes. 2. Contagious Conflict: effects of strikes on other bargaining events A remarkable feature of industrial conflict, such as strikes, is that it sometimes ‗spreads all over the country like a forest fire‘, while in other times it is limited to a single sector or firm. Standard bargaining models in economics and industrial relations studies offer little explanation for this phenomenon (Hicks 1932, Reder and Neumann 1980, Mauro 1982). These models attribute strikes to information problems of bargaining partners to assess each other‘s bargaining power. Under full information, all bargaining partners perfectly calculate their capacities to endure conflict, and peacefully reach an outcome. Under imperfect or asymmetric information, miscalculations lead to mistakes in strategic behavior. These theories regard strikes as dysfunctional incidents. In a world of static bargaining power, industrial conflict would never recur. But, in reality we observe that industrial conflict continues to occur, even in well-established bargaining relations. Current comparative research in industrial relations focuses on (exogenous) parameters of political and socio-economic systems to explain differences in strike activity between countries (Franzosi 1995), for example through the presence of central bargaining institutions, a social dialogue (such as the Dutch ‗Polder Model) or arbitration. However, this explanation assumes that strikes occur independently, and provides no answer for the contagion of industrial conflict. Little is yet known about how bargaining in one firm or sector is affected by industrial conflict in other firms or sectors. Both bargaining theory and comparative research in industrial relations ignore the mechanisms that relate strikes—or other forms of industrial conflict—to each other. Studies of more violent forms of collective conflict, such as civil war, reveal patterns of violence comparable to strikes: some are isolated events whereas others spread over the country or region in sequential patterns. Scholars of violent conflict clearly demonstrate the presence of contagion effects (Holden 1986, Hegre et al. 2001, Gleditisch 2007). There is one theoretical-empirical approach in industrial relations, mobilization theory, which acknowledges that (industrial) conflict is contagious and which made some major contributions (Oliver and Meyers 1998). The core idea in mobilization theory is that unions Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 4 and their members (workers) learn about a changed balance in bargaining power through ‗example strikes‘ (Conell and Cohn 1995). Faced with imperfect information, unions permanently observe industrial conflict in order to obtain information about their bargaining power vis à vis employers. Example strikes yield valuable information about worker grievances and employer responses (Ibid. 367). When unions learn about the favorability of strike conditions, strikes become contagious. However, mobilization theory has two crucial drawbacks. The first drawback is that it exclusively focuses on a unitary union/worker actor to explain a proliferation of strikes. Mobilization theory boldly assumes that trade union negotiators and workers share a common interest and common information. Thus, it does not acknowledge the specific role of professional (trade union) negotiators to stimulate or discourage a strike. In addition, mobilization theory completely disregards the crucial role of the employer as a bargaining partner! Professional negotiators for employers may also learn from industrial conflict. They could very well anticipate a favorable bargaining position of employees by giving in to their demands before a costly strike. But then strikes could also prevent the further contagion of conflict. Consequently, the puzzle remains: why do some strikes stimulate other strikes, while others remain isolated events and prevent social partners from engaging in future strikes? The second drawback of mobilization theory is that it suffers from a selection bias in empirical studies: these are limited to the spread of conflicts, and do not incorporate a study of isolated events. Consequently, an empirical test of mobilization theory is problematic, since variation in the dependent variable is absent (McAdam and Paulsen 1993, Soule, 2004) and the theory cannot provide us with conditions under which strategic information leads to appeasement so that conflict does not spread. Research question: Under which conditions does industrial conflict lead to contagion effects and under which conditions does it lead to appeasing effects? This gap in our understanding of how industrial conflict in one firm/sector affects bargaining in another firm/sector still severely hinders industrial relation practice. If we are able to identify the conditions under which industrial conflict spreads or not, we contribute to labor peace and reduce important economic and social costs. Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 5 2.1 Theoretical background In order to provide an explanation for the contagion of industrial conflict, the project aims to integrate the three approaches mentioned above: (1) bargaining theory, which focuses on the interactions between professional negotiators for employers and employees; (2) mobilization theory, which focuses on the decisions of workers to participate in industrial conflict; (3) the comparative approach, which focuses on economic and social-political institutions. Below, we describe this integration on the basis of five elements of a theory of contagion: (a) actors involved; (b) use of strategic information; (c) channels for diffusion; (d) behavioral options, and (e) impact of institutional arrangements. Actors involved. Bargaining theory and mobilization theory focus on different sets of actors. Bargaining theory focuses on the interactions between professional negotiators for employees and employers to explain the outcomes of labor negotiations. However, bargaining theory disregards the worker as a crucial actor. This is highly unrealistic, as the phenomenon of ‗wildcat strikes‘ shows. These are strikes not organized by a union, but strikes that develop spontaneously and often expand rapidly, for example those recently in the United Kingdom in response to lay-offs (The Economist 2009). Most wild cat strikes often are hastily recognized by trade unions. Hence, interactions between trade union negotiators and members explain the spread of industrial conflict. Mobilization theory studies the effects of information from co-workers and the mass-media on the decision of workers to participate in industrial conflict. The theory explains the emergence of social movements (Hedstrom 1994) from the behavior of a unitary actor. Thus, mobilization theory disregards the intervening influence of trade union negotiators and negotiators for the employer on workers‘ decision to participate in conflict. Yet, trade union negotiators and workers often have different and sometimes conflicting interests (Ross and Irwin 1951; Kochan 1980). Ashenfelter and Johnsons‘ bargaining theory (1969) even explains strikes as a union‘s instrument to reduce workers‘ high expectations about collective bargaining outcomes, masking its inability to negotiate better conditions. Unsuccessful strikes produce more realistic expectations about bargaining outcomes. A theoretical explanation for the spread of industrial conflict combines actor assumptions from both theories. Therefore, we distinguish between three types of actors and their interactions: the negotiator for employees, the negotiator for employers, and the worker. Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 6 Use of strategic information. Bargaining theory and mobilization theory focus on a different use of strategic information by actors in their decision to engage in industrial conflict. Bargaining theory does not inform us how strategic bargaining information is obtained and processed by negotiators. Reder and Neuman (1980) and McConell (1993) limit their analysis to learning from information obtained within the same bargaining event—ignoring potential learning from strategic information from other negotiations. Thus, we are still poorly informed about the question of why some bargaining parties suffer from information problems and engage in industrial conflict, while other parties manage to reach agreement without the burden of incomplete information. Mobilization theory assumes that workers learn from strategic information obtained from industrial conflict in other events (Biggs 2002, Soule 2004, Meyer 2000, Andrews and Biggs 2006). The diffusion of industrial conflict depends on two mechanisms. First, workers must have access to strategic information, either through informal, personal relations, or through non-relational sources, such as the mass-media. Second, workers must decide whether the strategic information obtained is useful (Klandermans 1984). Mobilization theory assumes that the key mechanism to assess usefulness is identification: the worker uses information from a source who is comparable to himself. Thus, the rule-of-thumb is: ‗how do other workers like me behave?‘ (McAdam and Rucht 1993 p. 63). The predicted behavior is imitation. ‗Example strikes‘ show that workers learn from strategic information about the outcomes of industrial conflict: learning about successes in one firm/industry may drive workers in another industry to engage in a strike. Conell and Cohn (1995) found that also lost strikes inspired other workers to engage in a subsequent strike. However, it is quite unrealistic to assume that professional negotiators base their bargaining strategy on the outcomes of other conflicts solely. Negotiators need strategic information about: the resistance of unions/employers to engage in conflict; the judicial, social or political acceptability of means of protest; potential for the mobilization of workers; specific costs and benefits associated with the conflict. A theoretical explanation for the spread of industrial conflict must incorporate the use of various types of strategic information by both professional negotiators and workers to alter or persist in their strategy. The use of strategic information depends upon the access to (multiple) trustworthy sources of information (Centola and Macy 2007). Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 7 Channels for information diffusion. Trustworthiness of information depends on closed and strong network relations between actors (Raub and Weesie 1990). Thus, we expect that professional negotiators who are tied together in cohesive (sub)networks, exchange strategic information. Mobilization theory makes a distinction between relational channels of information and non-relational channels, such as the mass-media or meetings and gatherings (Bohstedt and Williams 1988, McAdam and Rucht 1993, Biggs, 2005). Studies of violent conflict report that the mass-media are the main channel through which information flows between groups (Haas and Stack 1993; Holden 1986; Meyers 2000; Andrews and Bigg 2006). A theoretical explanation for the spread of industrial conflict incorporates both relational and non-relational channels for information diffusion. The more actors must rely on nonrelational channels, the more they use identification as a filter to assess the trustworthiness of information. Whether or not the diffusion of strategic information results in a spread of industrial conflict, further depends upon the behavioral options of actors, and the institutions for conflict resolution. Behavioral options of actors. Remarkably, mobilization theory assumes that workers have only two behavioral options. They can either mimic the conflict of others, or ignore that conflict. But, there are much more effects of learning from strategic information than pure imitation. Bargaining theory describes the behavioral options of negotiators for using strategic information. They can alter their strategy, that is: adjust their claims, reframe their grievances, be more patient, or otherwise alter their input in the bargaining process. Because negotiators and workers interact, different combinations of behavior are possible. We discuss the three most important. In the first place, negotiators and workers could simply imitate the behavior of others. For example, when employees learn a wage claim rewarded elsewhere, they could become eager to make the same demand. In the second place, the negotiator for employees or for the employer could decide to a unilateral adjustment of strategy. For example when an employer becomes informed about the strength of a union and its resources for mobilization, he could anticipate a strike and reward the claim without conflict. In the third place, both negotiators for employees and for the employer could decide to a mutual adjustment of strategy. Better information about the causes of a conflict and the interests/strength of the other party could inspire both parties to find a common solution. Clearly, simple imitation is a catalyst of conflict, while unilateral and mutual adjustment could lead to appeasement and the prevention of industrial conflict. A theoretical explanation for the spread of industrial conflict must incorporate such conditions. Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 8 Impact of institutional arrangements and bargaining structure. In advanced capitalist societies industrial relations are highly institutionalized, involving diverse instruments and arrangements for the resolution of industrial conflict. Comparative industrial research reports conditions that explain differences in strike levels between countries, such as: centralized wage bargaining and arbitration institutions (Clegg 1976); presence of socialist parties in government (Korpi and Shalev 1979); a social dialogue, like the Dutch Labor Foundation (Visser and Hemerijck 1997) and the Belgian National Labour Council; state involvement in tri-partite consultation, like the Dutch Socio-economic Council; interventions, like collective agreement extension procedures. Institutions for the resolution of industrial conflict are an integral part of a theoretical explanation for the spread of industrial conflict. In the first place, they affect the access of negotiators to trustworthy strategic information. A social dialogue and tri-partite consultation procedure are platforms in which employer negotiators and unions meet and discuss on a regular basis. In the second place, the institutions partly affect the result of bargaining between the negotiators for employers and employees. 2.2. Approach & methods The overall objective of the project is to determine under what conditions industrial conflict leads to contagion or to appeasing processes. The theoretical background identifies three main mechanisms that drive contagion: (a) use of strategic information in collective bargaining between negotiators for employees and employers; (b) role of mass-media, and communication between workers, unions, and the employer in worker mobilization; (c) impact of institutional arrangements. This distinction drives a research design which comprises of three interrelated subprojects: one subproject (PhD) focuses on collective bargaining, one subproject (PhD) focuses on worker mobilization, and one subproject (postdoc) focuses on the impact of institutional arrangements. The approach and research design aim to create variation in the independent variables in order to test hypotheses. Firstly, we select two countries for a comparative analysis of the impact of institutional arrangements: Belgium and The Netherlands. Both countries are comparable on a large number of socio-economic indicators, but differ in their institutional arrangements for industrial relations and the level of industrial conflict. Secondly, within each country we follow a multi-stage sampling design. We start by selecting potential ‗trigger events‘, that is: events that express a minimal level of industrial conflict, such as a protest Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 9 meeting, work stoppage, or strike. Subsequently, a number of collective bargaining negotiations are randomly selected from the population of negotiations that started during, or shortly after the trigger event. For all selected negotiations, the characteristics of the bargaining process are analyzed (project 1). For each negotiation, we randomly select a sample of workers, large enough to generalize to the population of workers in the firm/industry (project 2). In addition to surveys and network analysis, experiments in the Nijmegen Decision Lab are planned. These experiments complement the research design for two purposes. First, the main question of the project is whether negotiators and workers adjust their strategies on the basis of information from ‗trigger‘ conflicts. Computer-aided experiments allow to systematically vary (sources of and types of) strategic information under controlled conditions. Second, the experiments serve as a means for developing and testing the training program for negotiators, as described in the dissemination and communication plan. 2.3 Subprojects Subproject 1 (PhD). Learning from strikes: The use of strategic information in collective bargaining. A core hypothesis of the project is that professional negotiators for employers and employees use strategic information from other industrial conflicts when they have access to trustworthy sources of information about that conflict. The dependent variables in this subproject are: (a) negotiators‘ decisions to adjust their strategy; (b) the resulting level of conflict in collective bargaining. This subproject studies whether sequences of conflict in collective bargaining can be understood as the result of inadequacies in the transmission of strategic information in networks. The main research questions of this subproject are: o How do professional negotiators obtain strategic information about other bargaining events (including conflicts) from their social network, institutionalized networks, and mass-media coverage? o How do negotiators interact with workers and exchange strategic information? o To what extent, and under what conditions does the information obtained result in an adjustment of bargaining strategies? o Under what conditions do the adjusted strategies lead to conflict events, or to an appeasement? The design of this subproject is a multi-level diffusion study of strategic information in the networks of professional negotiators, using in-depth expert interviews and questionnaires. Networks will be measured and analyzed using social network methodology (Wasserman and Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 10 Faust 1994). Members of the dissemination board (see section 5) warrant access to the negotiators. Computer-aided experiments study the (adjustments of) strategies of negotiators in collective bargaining negotiation under conditions of: (a) trustworthiness of information; (b) availability of information channels; (c) communication with workers (including union members). Subproject 2 (PhD). Industrial conflict as a catalyst: the role of unions in worker mobilization. To date, mobilization theory has ignored the impact of the union negotiator in the decision of workers to participate (or not) in industrial conflict. This subproject studies whether workers‘ willingness to participate in industrial action (or to accept bargaining outcomes) can be understood as the result of strategic information passed on by: union negotiators, union representatives like shop stewards,1 or the employer. The dependent variables in this subproject are: (a) the decision of workers to engage in industrial conflict, (b) workers‘ aggregate willingness to engage in industrial conflict, or accept a bargaining outcome, indicated by voting results or actual participation in conflict. The main research questions of this subproject are: o How do workers obtain strategic information about other bargaining events (including conflicts) from their social network, their employer, union representatives and mass-media coverage? o How do workers interact with workers and exchange strategic information? o To what extent, and under what conditions, does this information result in an adjustment of workers‘ willingness to participate in industrial conflict or accept a bargaining outcome? The design of this subproject involves a survey under workers (including both union members and non-union members). In addition, computer-aided experiments study participation decisions of workers under conditions of: (a) trustworthiness of information; (b) availability of information channels; (c) communication with union representatives and employer. Subproject 3 (Post doc). The diffusion of industrial conflict in different institutional settings In the first stage of the project the postdoc coordinates the development of theory, hypotheses, and data collection of all three subprojects. Thus, integration of all subprojects within the overall project is assured. In the final stage of the project (s)he integrates results from all subprojects in one comprehensive study. The core hypothesis of subproject 3 is that bargaining institutions interfere with the diffusion of strategic bargaining information. The dependent variable is the proportion of 1 Shop stewards are workers who are representatives of the union (in Dutch ‘kaderleden). Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 11 conflict events in the population of bargaining events. Theoretically, this subproject elaborates current institutional theories with hypotheses and results from subprojects 1 and 2. Empirically, it extends current international data collection on industrial conflicts for at least two additional countries—all in close collaboration with country-experts from the European Industrial Relations Observatory Online (EIRO) and the International Labor Organization. The current availability of data on industrial conflict is limited because it (a) is limited to the aggregated, sector level; (b) lacks information on crucial features of industrial conflict, such as starting/end dates; success/failure indicators; unions and employers involved, and substantive issues); (c) is limited to strikes (and lock-outs), ignoring other forms of industrial conflicts; (d) lacks a uniform definition of industrial conflict. Hence, the data collected in subproject 3 aims to obtain international comparable micro-macro data for testing hypotheses derived from the overarching project, as well as replicating relevant sociological and economic studies with more valid, reliable and richer data. The data-set will be public domain. 3. The aftermath of strikes: effects of strikes for relations within the organization. Most strikes are resolved within a few days. Their material costs, in terms of production losses, are well-documented in micro- and macroeconomic research. Nevertheless, the aftermath of strikes is often long-lasting and involves personal and relational costs that may have profound long-term effects on production. During strikes, fault-lines arise: between management and employees, but also between groups of employees. During strikes, emotional confrontations occur between employees on strike and those who ―break‖ the strike and remain at work. (Francis, 1985; Getman, 1998). The core hypothesis of the project is that fault-lines developed during strikes can have longlasting effects for work relations when persisting after a strike has been settled. Associated problems of cooperation and lack of motivation combined with socially detrimental behaviour, such as harassment and bullying, further affect productivity. Economic research on the consequences of strikes focuses on the volume and quality of production (Addison & Teixeira, 2009; Krueger & Mas 2003; Mas, 2006). Although these studies mention obstruction and cooperation problems as probable causes of sub-optimal production after strikes, they fail to specify causal mechanisms that link strikes to economic performance. Psychological research reports prolonged effects of strikes on workers‘ psychological health and job satisfaction (Barling & Milligan, 1987; Kelloway et.al. 1993; Fowler, et.al., 2009). Although they verify that strikes have strong effects on occupational Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 12 health, these studies cannot explain why employees experience stress long after the dispute— the stressor—was settled (up to six months). Fowler et.al. (2009) suggest that social factors are responsible for continuation of stress. Indeed, sociological and anthropological research indicates that social factors are responsible for a prolonged experience of stress and frustration. Case-studies of severe strikes reveal strong and destructive cleavages between management and employees, as well as between groups of employees (MacDowell, 1993). These studies show that overt hostilities persist after dispute settlement between the former strikers and strike-breakers and report instances of physical and verbal harassment (Frances, 1985; Brunsden & Hill, 2009; Waddington et.al 1994). Strike-breakers are put aside as ―blacklegs‖ or ―scabs‖ in union terminology, effectively splitting teams, organizations, and sometimes whole communities (Francis, 1985; Waddington et.al., 1994; Getman, 1999). The lack of solidarity demonstrated by strike-breakers induces sentiments of ―betrayal‖ in those who strike, thereby creating sharp fault-lines between employees. Although offering rich descriptions, these case-studies suffer from selection bias: only effects of long and severe strikes are analyzed. The studies do not inform us why some strikes lead to insurmountable schisms, while others do not affect workrelations. Thus, systematic research about the effects of strikes on work-relations is virtually absent. Research questions: (a) Under which conditions does conflict between managers and employees, and between groups of employees, persist after the settlement of a strike, and under which conditions does this conflict dissolve? (b) How does this conflict affect the relations between management and employees, and the relations among employees? Identifying the mechanisms that explain how industrial conflict affects social relations between employees contributes to our understanding of how (industrial) conflict persistently affects production and employee well-being long after settlement of the strike. 3.1 Theoretical background This project develops and tests a theory that explains how industrial conflict creates fault-lines between groups of employees and management, and specifies the conditions under which these fault-lines persist. Social cohesion theory suggests the presence of an external threat to Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 13 explain sharp fault-line between groups (Stein, 1976). Over time, conflicting groups become more cohesive internally, and develop negative stereotypes of the other group, triggering polarization and disruptive conflicts (Nelson, 1989). Although a strike makes management the natural ―out-group‖, it does not explain out-group sentiments between groups of workers. The harsh relations between groups of employees can be explained by a solidarity norm. This norm explains strikers‘ contempt for strike-breakers and their strong out-group sentiments towards them. Case-study research (Brunsden & Hill, 2009; Waddington et.al, 1994) shows that strike-breakers break a solidarity norm and pose an immediate threat to strikers: strikers‘ success depends on the degree to which the production process is disrupted–and thus on the number of employees on strike. Moreover, because strikers incur considerable costs (e.g. loss of income) and risk future repercussions by the employer, those who continue working are considered free-riders. Social disapproval and punishment of free-riders serve to reinforce solidarity norms (Gächter & Fehr, 1999; Casari & Luini, 2009). The punishment of free riders increases with the deviation of the free rider from the average investment of the other members (Fehr & Gächter, 2002). In reaction, strike-breakers may develop strong out-group sentiments towards strikers (Falk et. al., 2005). Conflict between management and strikers An ideal-type settlement of a strike resolves all conflict issues between the union and employer. If not all issues are resolved, some external threat will continue to exist after settlement. Thus, the perceived effectiveness of the settlement (by both management and strikers) will positively affect the quality of work relations between management and strikers after the strike (Hypothesis I). Conflict between groups of employees Settlement of a strike not automatically restores work relations between strikers and nonstrikers. We expect that the strength of the solidarity norm negatively affects work relations between strikers and non-strikers (Hypothesis II). Moreover, we expect that the perceived need to reinforce the solidarity norm will negatively affect work relations (Hypothesis III). The perceived need to norm reinforcement depends on (a) the expected future need for solidarity and (b) on free riders deviation of the investments strikers made (e.g. loss of income and repercussions by the employer). 3.2. Approach & methods Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 14 The project applies a longitudinal multi-level design, using data about work relations in four organizations that experienced a strike. A survey will be held at three moments: (1) during, or immediately after the strike; (2) two months after, and (3) six months after the settlement of the strike. This design enables us to analyse changes in attitudes and behaviour within employees over time and within/between groups of employees over time (participants, nonparticipants, and management). Such a design is appropriate since a pre-event survey is unfeasible: we cannot predict the occurrence of a strike before mobilization starts and faultlines already develop (Klandermans & Staggenborg, 2002). Two aspects of work relations are measured within and between groups: cohesion and conflict. We use cohesion scales developed by e.g. Sargent & Sue-Chan (2001) and interpersonal conflict scales developed by e.g. Jehn (1994, 1995). 4. Conclusion In the present paper we challenged current explanations of industrial conflict, which consider strikes as being independent and isolated events: the bargaining between negotiation partners is not affected by conflict elsewhere, and the conflict has neither an influence on other bargaining events. By contrast, we argued that strikes are not isolated in space from on other bargaining events, and are not isolated in time from their consequences for relations at the work floor. Correspondingly, this paper described two important avenues for industrial relations research, and outlined the details of a comprehensive research program in these directions. The aim of the research program is to move from explanations of the prevalence of industrial conflict in sectors and countries to the actual effects of strikes. Effects of strikes are most profound in two areas of study: (1) collective bargaining outside the immediate scope of the focal organizations, and (2) work relations among employees within the organizations that are affected by strikes. For each of these two areas, the paper described a series of interrelated research projects. References Addison,J.T. & P.Teixeira (2009), ‗Are Good Industrial Relations Good for the Economy?, German Economic Review 10(3):253-69. Analoui,F. and A.Kakabadse (1993), ‗Industrial Conflict and its Expressions‘, Employee Relations 15(1):46-62. Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 15 Andrews, K.T. and M. Biggs (2006), ‗The Dynamics of Protest Diffusion: Movement Organizations, Social Networks, and News Media in the 1960 Sit-Ins‘. American Sociological Review 71 (5), 752-777. Ashenfelter, O. and G.E. Johnson (1969), ‗Bargaining Theory, Trade Unions, and Industrial Strike Activity‘, American Economic Review, 59 (1),35-49. Barling,J. & J.Milligan (1987), ‗Some Psychological Consequences of Striking: A Six Month, Longitudinal Study‘, Journal of Occupational Behaviour. 8(2):127-137. Biggs, M. (2002), ‗Strikes as Sequences of Interaction: The American Strike Wave of 1886‘ Social Science History 26 (2), 297-300. Biggs, M. (2005), ‗Strikes as Forest Fires: Chicago and Paris in the Late Nineteenth Century‘, American Journal of Sociology 110 (6), 1684-1714. Bohstedt, J. and D.E. Williams (1988), ‗The Diffusion of Riots: the Patterns of 1766, 1795, and 1801 in Devonshire‘, Journal of Interdisciplary History 19 (1), 1-24. Brunsden,V. & R.Hill (2009), ‗Firefighters‘ Experience of Strike: An Interpretative Phenomenological Analysis Case Study‘, The Irish Journal of Psychology. 30(1-2):99115. Carless,S.A. & C. DePaola (2000), The Measurement of Cohesion in Work Teams, Small Groups Research, 13(1):71-88. Casari,M. & L.Luini (2009) ‗Group Cooperation under Alternative Peer Punishment Technologies: An Experiment, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 71(2):273282 Centola, D. and M. Macy (2007), ‗Complex Contagion and the Weakness of Long Ties‘ American Journal of Socioloy 113 (3), 702-734. Clegg, H.A. (1976). Trade Unionism under Collective Bargaining. A Theory based on Comparisons of Six Countries. London: Basil Blackwell. Conell, C. and S. Cohn (1995) Learning form Other People‘s Actions: Environmental Variation and Diffusion in French Coal Mining Strikes, 1890-1935. American Journal of Sociology 101 (2),366-403. DeDreu,C.K.W. & L.R Weingart (2003), ‗Task Versus Relationship Conflict, Team Performance, and Team Member Satisfaction: A Meta-Analysis‘, Journal of Applied Psychology. 88(4): 741–749. Falk,A., E.Fehr & U.Fishbacker (2005), ‗Driving Forces Behind Informal Sanctions‘, Econometrica.73(6):2017-2030. Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 16 Fehr, E. & S. Gächter (2002), ‗Altruistic Punishment in Humans‘, Nature. 415 (Jan 10th):137140. Fowler,J.L. A.J.Gudmundsson & L.M. Whicker (2009). ‗The Psychological Impact of Industrial Strikes: Does Involvement in Union Activity during Strikes make a Difference?‘, Journal of Industrial Relations. 51(2): 227-243. Francis,H. (1985), ‗The Law, Oral Tradition and the Mining Community‘., Journal of Law and Society. 12(3):267-271. Franzosi, R. (1995), The Puzzle of Strikes. Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press. Gächter,S. & E.Fehr (1999), Collective Action as a Social Exchange‘, Journal of Economic and Behavior and Organization. 39(1999):341-369. Getman,J.G (1999). The Betrayal of Local 14. Ithaca New York: Cornell University Press. Gleditsh, K. S. (2007), ‗ Transnational Dimensions of Civil War‘, Journal of Peace Research 44 (3) 293-309. Haas, A. and S. Stack (1993), ‗Economic Development and Strikes: A Comparative Analysis, Sociological Quarterly 24(1), 43-58. Hedstrom, P. (1994), ‗Contagious Collectivities. On the Spatial Diffusion of Swedish Trade Unions, 1890-1949‘. American Journal of Sociology 99 (5), 1157-1179. Hegre, H. T. Ellingsen, S. Gates and N. P. Gleditsch (2001), Toward a Democratic Civil Peace? Democracy, Political Change, and Civil War, 1816-1992‘ The American Political Science Review 95(1), 33-48. Hicks, J. R. (1932), The Theory of Wages. New York and London: Macmillan. Hinds,P.J. & P.Mortensen (2005), ‗Understanding Conflict in Geographically Distributed Teams: The Moderating Effects of Shared Identity, Shared Contex, and Spontanious Communication‘, Organization Science. 16(3):290-307. Holden, R. T. (1986), ‗The Contagiousness of Aircraft Hijacking‘, American Journal of Sociology 91(4), 874-904. Jehn,K.A. (1994) ‗Enhancing Effectiveness: An Investigation of Advantages and Disadvantages of Value based intragroup conflict‘, Journal of Conflict Management. 5: 223-238. Jehn,K.A. (1995) ‗A Multimethod Examination of the Benefits and detriments of Intragroup Conflict‘, Administrative Science Quarterly. 40:256-282. Kelloway,E.K., K.Barling & A.Shah (1993), ‗Industrial Relations Stress and Job Satisfaction: Concurrent Effects and Mediation‘, Journal of Organizational Behaviour. 14(5):447-457. Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 17 Klandermans, B. (1984), ‗Mobilization and Participation: Social Psychological Expansions of Resource Mobilization Theory‘, American Sociological Review, 49(5),583-600. Klandermans,B. & S.Staggenborg (2002), Methods of Social Movements Research. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Kochan, T.A. (1980), Collective Bargaining and Industrial Relations. From Theory to Policy and Practice. Illinois: Irwin, Homewood. Korpi, W. and M. Shalev (1979), ‗Strikes, industrial relations and class conflict in capitalist societies.‘ British Journal of Sociology 30(2), 164-187. Krueger,R.A. & M.A.Mas (2004), ‗Strikes, Scabs, and Tread Separations: Labor Strife and the Production of Defective Bridgestone/Firestone Tires‘. Journal of Political Ecnonomy. 112(2):253-289 MacDowell,L.S. (1993) ‗After the Strike. Labour Relations in Oshawa, 1937-1939‘. Industrial Relations. 48(4):691-711. Mas,A. (2007), ‗Labor Unrest and the Quality of Production: Evidence from the Construction Equipment Resale Market‘ NBER Working Paper Series, no. 13138 Mauro, M. J. (1982), ‗Strikes as a Result of Imperfect Information‘, Industrial and Labor Relations Review 35 (4), 522-538. McAdam, D. and D. Rucht (1993), ‗The Cross-National Diffusion of Movement Ideas‘, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 528. 56-74. McAdam, D. and R. Paulsen (1993), ‗Specifying the Relationship between Social Ties and Activism‘. American Journal of Sociology 99 (3), 640-667. McConell, S. (1989), ‗Strikes, Wages and Private Information‘, The American Economic Review 79 (4), 801-815. Meyers, D. T. (2000), ‗The Diffusion of Collective Violence: Infectiousness, Susceptibility, and Mass Media Networks‘‘ , The American Journal of Sociology 106(1), 173-208. Nelson,R.E. (1989) ‗The Strength of Strong Ties: Social Networks and Intergroup Conflict in Organizations‘. The Academy of Management Journal. 32(2):377-401. Oliver, P. E. and D. J. Myers, (1998) ―Diffusion Models of Cycles of Protests as a Theory of Social Movements‖ . Paper Presented at the International Sociological Associations Meetings, Montreal. Raub, W. and J. Weesie (1990), ‗Reputation and Efficiency in Social Interactions: An Example of Network Effects‘, American Journal of Sociology, 96 (3), 626-54. Reder, M. W. and G. R. Neumann (1980), ‗Conflict and Contract: The Cases of Strikes‘, The Journal of Political Economy, vol 88(5), 867-886. Effects of Industrial Conflict – Akkerman and Torenvlied 18 Ross, A.M. and D. Irwin (1951), ‗Strike experience in five countries, 1927-1947: An interpretation‘, Industrial and Labor Relations Review 4(3), 321-342. Sargent,L.D. & D.Sue-Chan (2001) ‗Does Diversity Affect Group Efficacy?: The Intervening Role of Cohesion and Task Interdependence‘. Small Group Research 32(4):426-450, Soule, S. A. (2004), ‗Diffusion Processes within and across Movements. In: D.A. Snow, S.A. Soule and H. Kriesi (eds.) The Blackwell Companion to Social Movements. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing. Stein,A.A. (1976) ‗Conflict and Cohesion A Review of the Literature‘. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 20(1):143-172 The Economist, (2009). ‗Discontent, Wintry, and Otherwise. February 5th Visser, J and A.C. Hemerijck (1997), ‘A Dutch Miracle: Job Growth, Welfare Reform and Corporatism in the Netherlands‘. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press. Waddington,D.B. Dicks & C.Critcher (1994) ‗Community Responses to Pit Closure in the Post-Strike Era‘ Community Development Journal, 29(2):141-150. Wasserman, S. and K. Faust (1994), Social Network Analysis. Methods and Applications. Cambridge/ New York: Cambridge University Press.