Public Expenditure and Finance in the UK Economy 1 Public-sector expenditure 1.1 Public-sector expenditure is the name given to spending by central government, local government and public corporations, e.g. the Post Office, the BBC. Plans for public-sector spending are published annually along with the Budget. These plans show intended spending for the coming 3 years. 1.2 Types of public-sector spending • Capital spending. This helps to create productive capacity, e.g. hospitals, urban renewal and transport infrastructure. • Current spending. This covers day-to-day running costs of government, e.g. the pay of public-sector workers. • Transfer payments. A transfer payment is defined as a payment to an individual or firm for which there is no economic b enefit given in return, e.g. pensions, unemployment benefit, child benefit, grants and subsidies. They are called transfer payments because money is transferred from taxpayers to those who qualify for benefit. The distinction between types of spending is important because capital and current spending diverts resources from the private sector; whereas transfer payments do not absorb resources but redistribute income and spending power within the private sector. Most of the Government’s capital and current expenditure is on public and merit goods and services. 1.3 A public good or service is one which benefits everyone in society, e.g. defence, street-lighting. A public good cannot be provided by the private sector because of the difficulty in getting all its consumers to pay. Government, therefore, has to provide public goods and raise the required revenue from general taxation. 1.4 Merit goods or services, e.g. healthcare, education, are considered to be socially desirable but would be under produced if left to private enterprise. Merit goods or services are given to those people who merit (i.e. need) them, either free or at reduced prices. These are paid for out of taxation and in some cases, e.g. medical prescriptions, by charging consumers a proportio n of the price. 1.5 Trends in public-sector expenditure Changing total In recent years there has been an increase in Government expenditure in the economy. This has been due mainly to increases in spending on health, education and transport. Changing pattern Increases in spending on health and education have been proportionately greater than on other programmes. Defence spending has fallen because of the end of the ‘cold war’, which has given us a ‘peace dividend’. Social security spending has increased because the ageing population has led to more spending on retirement pension. However, there have been reductions in areas such housing where – as part of its privatisation policy – government has limited its spending on building new council houses. Spending on support for industry has also become less important. There is strong debate among economists and politicians about the merits of public-sector expenditure. 1.6 Case for reducing growth in public spending • Income tax can be reduced which will increase incentives and increase consumers’ freedom to choose how to spend their incomes. • Government borrowing can be reduced. • Resources can be released for use by the private sector. It is thought by some that the private sector uses resources more efficiently. 1.7 Case against cuts in growth of public spending • Most public-sector spending is on UK-produced output which creates employment in the UK. If given back to consumers by reducing tax, it may be spent on imports. • Capital spending is the easiest for government to cut but this reduces the country’s infrastructure, which in turn reduces the efficiency of the economy, e.g. there have been major cuts in recent years in housing. • Resources released from the public sector are not automatica lly taken up by the private sector. They may remain unemployed. • Lower-income groups are the most dependent on public spending, not only on benefits but also on services such as housing and public transport. 2 Taxation 2.1 Types of taxation Direct taxes Direct taxes are defined as those taxes which are taken directly from individuals and firms. They are levied by the Inland Revenue department. They are mainly taxes on income and wealth, e.g.: • • • • • • • income tax national insurance contributions – although not called a tax, in fact it is corporation tax – levied on company profits council tax – levied on the value of a householder’s house capital gains tax – levied on the increase in value of assets inheritance tax – levied on a deceased person’s estate stamp duties – levied on the change of ownership of houses and land. Indirect taxes Indirect taxes are levied indirectly, i.e. the payer of the tax to government passes on the burden of the tax, usually to a customer. These are collected by the Customs and Excise Department. They include: • Value Added Tax (VAT) – levied on a wide range of goods and services. Some goods, e.g. children’s clothes, books and basic foodstuffs are zero rated • customs duties – taxes on imports • excise duties – taxes on petrol, tobacco and alcohol • petrol revenue tax – tax on North Sea oil companies • motor vehicle duties. 2.2 What makes a good tax? Adam Smith, the famous eighteenth-century Scottish economist laid down four principles (or ‘canons’, as he called them) for a good tax. (a) Equity. Taxes should relate to the taxpayer’s ability to pay. (b) Efficiency. Taxes should be reasonably inexpensive to collect, i.e. the cost of collection should form a small percentage of the revenue collected and they should not have negative side-effects such as reducing work incentives for individuals. (c) Certainty. The taxpayer should be clearly aware how much is due, and when and where to pay. (d) Convenience. Taxes should be payable at a time and place that suits the taxpayer. Not all taxes levied in the UK adhere to these principles. 2.3 Progressive and regressive taxes A progressive tax is one which takes account of people’s ability to pay, i.e. it follows Smith’s principle of equity. A progressive tax takes a larger percentage of income as income rises. Most direct taxes are of this type. A regressive tax takes no account of people’s ability to pay. Lower -income earners pay a higher percentage of their income in tax. Most indirect taxes are regressive, e.g. duties on alcohol, petrol, road tax are fixed amounts of money which are the same for everybody. VAT, although an indirect tax, takes some account of ability to pay in that some essential items such as food, children’s clothes and shoes, which account for a large proportion of a low income earner’s spending, are zero rated and household fuel is rated at 5%. Nevertheless VAT is a regressive tax. 2.4 Trends in taxation Cuts in business taxes, e.g. corporation tax and business rates The aim has been to allow firms to earn higher profits and so encourage investment. The UK now has lower business taxes than most other European countries, which helps to attract inward investment. Shift from direct to indirect tax In the 1980s Conservative Governments star ted to restructure taxation by shifting the balance away from direct taxation towards indirect taxation and this policy was continued in the 1990s. The restructuring was done by simplifying and reducing rates of income tax. The Conservatives believed that lowering rates of income tax would encourage enterprise and effort. The top rate has been cut from 83% in 1979 to 40%; standard rate from 33% to 22%. There is also now a starting rate of 10%. The share of income tax in total tax revenue has fallen from 45% to 25%. The loss in revenue from income tax cuts was largely recouped from VAT which has been raised and extended to a wider range of goods and services. Excise duties on tobacco, alcohol and motoring have been increased by more than inflation. The effect of the restructuring has been to tilt the balance of taxation away from earning to spending and to make the tax system more regressive. A further effect has been a widening of the gap between rich and poor. The Labour Government elected in 1997 gave a promise that it would not raise income tax nor extend VAT. However, it has started to narrow the rich –poor gap by a reform of other taxes. 2.5 Case for cuts in income tax • Tax revenue may increase. High rates of income tax encourage people to exploit every possible loophole to avoid tax and they encourage some people to break the law in order to evade tax. Cutting rates may remove this evasion. • Incentives are increased. If marginal rates of tax are reduced then people will be able to keep more of any additional income they earn. This may act as an incentive to work harder or to seek promotion. Lower tax rates may also encourage some of the voluntary unemployed to work. As people work harder and earn more, the tax revenue in total may rise. The potential revenue from income tax cuts can be illustrated by the Laffer curve (Laffer is a US economist). Since no revenue can be expected from tax rates of 0%, the curve of tax revenue rises as tax rates rise but eventually falls because of disincentives, evasion and avoidance, until at 100% rates tax revenue would return to zero. The difficulty for a Government is knowing which tax rate would yield the highest tax revenue. Tax revenue Tax rate 2.6 Case against cuts in income tax • Some economists argue that tax revenue may not increase. A higher disposable income from working the same or fewer hours may encourage people to take more leisure time. • The demand side of the economy may be over stimulated . This leads to inflation. • Inequalities are likely to widen. Since income tax is progressive, cuts are likely to favour those on higher incomes while those on low incomes who are not liable to income tax will gain no benefit. If, as has been the case, government switches to more taxes on expenditure, which tend to be regressive, then those on low incomes are further disadvantaged. 3 Public Sector Net Cash Requirement (PSNCR) 3.1 PSNCR. The PSNCR is defined as the borrowing of the public sector, i.e. central government, local authorities and public corporations. There is a need for the public sector to borrow if its expenditure is greater than its income. The main factor in this is usually a central government budget deficit. The PSNCR is measured in £ billion and as a percentage of GDP. It is financed by selling bonds, gilt-edged securities and treasury bills to financial institutions and to citizens. In some years the PSNCR may be negative. In this case the government is running a budget surplus and is then able to repay debt. 3.2 The Budget. A Government must plan what it wants to spend and how it is going to finance its expenditure. This plan is usually done once a year and is presented to parliament as the Budget. However, the Budget may be used for purposes other than just a financial plan. This is covere d in Topic 4 Government Economic Policies. Budget deficit If central government income is less than central government spending, this is called a budget deficit. You should note that the Budget is as much a political exercise as an instrument of economic policy. For example, in the run-up to an election measures in the Budget may be taken to win political support which may be against the interest of the economy at that time. 3.3 National debt. The national debt is the total amount of accumulated debt , i.e. the total amount which the public sector owes to those who have loaned it money. If in one year there is a PSNCR, then the national debt will increase. A budget surplus will reduce the national debt. 3.4 Why government needs to control the PSNCR. A high PSNCR may cause the following problems: • ‘Crowding out’ – high Government borrowing may starve the private sector of funds for investment. • Interest rates may have to rise to encourage lenders to lend to Government. The UK Government usually has l ittle difficulty in borrowing money because lenders have confidence in its ability to repay. However, when the borrowing requirement is large it may have to offer higher rates of interest to attract extra funds. This also increases the cost of borrowing for the private sector. • Inflation. Monetarists believe that if Government borrowing is financed by borrowing from banks then the money supply increases and causes inflation. • National Debt is increased – this leads to higher repayments of debt interest in the future which have to be financed by higher taxes or reductions in other spending programmes. • EMU. A condition for membership of Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) in Europe is that in any year the PSNCR should be no more than 3% of GDP and the national debt should be no more than 40% of GDP. Government therefore has to try to stick to these requirements. 3.5 Difficulties in controlling Government borrowing . It is difficult for governments to control their borrowing because of the difficulty in pred icting the economic cycle. The amount of money the government spends and receives from taxation fluctuates with the economic cycle. In periods of economic growth and rising employment spending on benefits decreases while tax revenues increase from higher incomes, consumer spending and business profits. The opposite happens during a recession! 3.6 UK trends The recession of 1990–2 had increased the PSNCR. Tax revenues fell but public expenditure on unemployment benefits and social securi ty payments increased. The government could have increased tax rates to reduce the Public Sector Borrowing Requirement (PSBR) but the economy was too weak to stand this. From 1994 to 1997, the PSBR fell. As the economy recovered from recession, tax revenues increased as GDP increased and government felt able to increase taxes. The new Labour Government of 1997 set a tough target for government borrowing and intended to achieve it by maintaining strict control of public sector spending, and raising some taxes (although it had a commitment not to raise income tax or extend VAT). It restored the ‘golden rule’ of fiscal policy. Golden Rule of Fiscal Policy The golden rule is that in the long run government borrowing should only be allowed to finance capital expenditure rather than current expenditure. The thinking is that capital spending, such as new hospitals and roads, will benefit present and future generations and should be paid for by those who benefit now and in the future. Current spending, such as teachers’ salaries, school books, etc. should be paid for now by taxing the generation who benefit from this spending. The Chancellor has modified this by stating that borrowing to fund current spending should be neutral over the economic cycle , i.e. it may need to borrow during years of recession but that this should be repaid out of budget surpluses in years of growth. The 1997 and 1998 Budgets were both tight, i.e. taxes were higher than spending. The public finances improved to the exte nt that instead of having to borrow the Government was able to repay debt. In 1999 and 2000 public finances continued to improve and the Chancellor was able to reduce tax receipts in the Budget of 1999 without having to borrow. Since 2001 public borrowing has grown as the economy and tax revenues have not grown as fast as the Chancellor predicted and because of very large increases in capital spending in health and education. Note that although the figures are very large, they are a small percentage of GD P, e.g. the national debt of the UK will be 35% of GDP in 2005, compared with 50% in the USA and Germany and 80% in Japan.