Do UN Sanctions Strengthen the International Presence of the EU? Spyros Blavoukos* and Dimitris Bourantonis** Abstract In many cases, the EU not only participates in the imposition of UN sanctions but actively sets the agenda and shapes their content, as a coercive means to bring a recalcitrant state into order especially when protracted negotiations fail to deliver. By default, this course of action constitutes an act of actorness, raising the international profile of the EU and signaling a significant presence in varying degrees in multilateral negotiations. However, some of these cases are also indications of limited effectiveness in the EU international interactions, revealing a considerable actornesseffectiveness gap. We account for this gap by reference to the bargaining power of the EU, identifying its key determinants that are related with the modality of EU engagement in multilateral diplomacy and revolve around the EU structural assets and institutional features as well as the bargaining environment. We use this analytical framework to account for the EU role in the negotiations over the Iranian nuclear program, questioning whether the UN sanctions do indicate always a strong EU international presence. * Spyros Blavoukos, Lecturer, Department of International and European Economic Studies, Athens University of Economics and Business, sblavo@aueb.gr ** Dimitris Bourantonis, Associate Professor, Department of International and European Economic Studies, Athens University of Economics and Business, bouranto@aueb.gr FIRST DRAFT PLEASE, DO NOT QUOTE WITHOUT AUTHORS’ PERMISSION Paper prepared for the Third Global International Studies Conference August 17-20, 2011 - Porto, Portugal 1 Introduction For an international organization (IO) that legitimately expresses the international community, imposing sanctions suggests that all other means of intervention have not brought the targeted recalcitrant international actor into order. Such sanctions usually constitute an indication of the IO’s strength and commitment, illustrating the degree of cohesion and homogeneity among its constituent member-states that have agreed to this course of action. However, they may also reveal certain weaknesses of the IO in question, most important of which is the IO’s limited bargaining power and effectiveness, especially if they follow protracted negotiations that have led to a deadend. For the EU, participating within the UN framework in the imposition of such sanctions has by default positive connotations, considered an illustration of international actorness. The argument goes that such collective actions strengthen the EU international presence, indicating the EU capacity to engage in a constructive manner with the rest of the international community in actions with possible far reaching political implications. Drawing on the EU engagement in the negotiations over the Iranian nuclear program, we argue that a more nuanced and focused look of the EU participation in sanction imposition at the UN level is necessary. Whereas there is little denying the fact of the positive EU role in the building up of the sanction regime against Iran per se, questions arise as to why the EU failed to achieve a breakthrough in the preceding negotiations in which she was the primary interlocutor of the Iranian government. In that light, should sanctions be seen as a failure of the EU international aspirations, rather than emphasizing the success of having all EU-27 on board for such a political course of action? In other words, could sanctions send opposite signals undermining the EU international presence rather than strengthening it? Thus, we do not ask whether the EU has been an actor or not in the negotiations over Iran’s nuclear program. This has been well documented in the literature and the answer comes clearly to the positive. We ask whether the EU has been an effective actor in this process. To our understanding, actorness and effectiveness are not linked directly. Analytically, the concept of actorness reflects the intra-EU dimension of the EU international interactions, that is the internal capacity of the EU to emerge as a cohesive, authoritative and autonomous player in the international arena and become recognized by the other negotiating partners as such. Effectiveness is related mostly 2 with the output dimension of these interactions, capturing primarily the degree of goal attainment for the EU (Groen and Niemann 2011: 7). In that respect, effectiveness along side other criteria like efficiency and relevance for the priority stakeholders of the EU – i.e. the constituent member-states- constitute indicators of the EU international performance (Jørgensen and Oberthür, forthcoming). We argue that the missing link between actorness and effectiveness is bargaining power. In the EU case, this link revolves around how EU structural features filter the EU political and economic assets to create the EU negotiating capital that leads to tangible negotiating outcomes within a specific bargaining environment. In that respect, we draw on institutionalist accounts of the EU bargaining behavior that have well captured the idiosyncratic modus operandi of the EU (Groenleer and van Schaik 2007; Meunier 2000; Clark et al 2000). In fluid and dynamic negotiations, these features may either hinder agreement or become a blessing in disguise, allowing ‘tied hands’ bargaining tactics and the realization of the maximum of concessions from the other side of the table. We complement them by insights of the negotiation literature that contribute to our better understanding of the Iranian case that constitutes the empirical focus our work. In the next section, we elaborate on the institutionalist and political determinants of the EU bargaining power, linking the concept of actorness with effectiveness in international negotiations. Then, we present an overview of the EU engagement in the negotiating quagmire over the Iranian nuclear program. Following that, we discuss this engagement in light of the insights of the first section, before concluding with the possible generalizable findings of our paper. Bargaining Power in Multilateral Negotiations: Bridging the ActornessEffectiveness Gap The discussion over the international dimension of the EU was long held captive to the overarching ontological question about the ‘nature of the EU beast’, creating a tense academic debate about whether the EU could and should be analyzed along the lines of traditional approaches to International Relations (IR). In parallel to the inconclusive academic debate, intra-EU policy advances and institutional developments in the European integration process have always had important externalities, forcing interactions of the EC/EU structures with the outer world. They shape the perceptions and expectations of other international actors, thus clearly 3 indicating some form of international presence for the EU (Allen and Smith 1990). However, presence does not necessarily connote purposive external action, but may derive as an unintended consequence of domestic policy-making processes, like the creation of the Single Market or the Economic and Monetary Union. The concept of actorness has taken the debate a step forward in the sense that it assumes deliberative and active functioning in international politics (Jupille and Caporaso 1998; Sjöstedt 1977; Cosgrove and Twitchett 1970). In other words, actorness relates to the capacity to act, whereas presence simply indicates a function of being rather than acting. It entails a degree of independence from the external environment, i.e. no full subjection to another actor, but also a degree of autonomy from the internal constituents, thus indicating a political entity capable of formulating purposes, reaching decisions, and engaging in purposive action (Bretherton and Vogler 2006). Thus, internal and external delimitation is crucial in the understanding of the concept. The second important point is that it is a relational concept, in the sense that its attribution to any political unit is an intersubjective process not only based on own perceptions but also requiring the recognition of the other units involved in any political process. In the EU context, it does not suffice for the EU to claim international actorness, it also needs to be recognized by states, non-state actors, and international organizations as an actor in the world stage. There are different sets of criteria in the literature used to assess actorness. Cosgrove and Twitchett (1970) identify three mutually interdependent tests of actorness: the degree of autonomous decision-making power, performance of continuing functions with an impact on inter-state relations, and an acknowledgement of the importance of the would-be actor by its members and other international actors. Jupille and Caporaso (1998) ascertain actorness on the basis of four criteria: recognition, authority, cohesion, and autonomy. The first criterion refers to the acceptance of the actor in question by other actors as a legitimate interlocutor; the second one to the would-be actor’s legal competence to act in a specific field; the third to its capacity to articulate consistent policy preferences; and the fourth, to institutional distinctiveness, i.e. capacity to function independently from its constituent members. Groen and Niemann (2011) use a variation of these criteria, focusing for reasons of parsimony only on cohesion and autonomy, arguing that the other two are redundant. Bretherton and Vogler (2006) propose five basic requirements for actorness: shared commitment to a set of overarching values and 4 principles, the identification of policy priorities and the formulation of coherent policies, the ability to negotiate effectively with other actors in the international system, the availability of appropriate policy instruments, and the domestic legitimation of decision-making in the relevant fields with an external dimension. The latter set is the only one that explicitly associates actorness with effective bargaining, considering it a prerequisite for actor capacity. We posit that this criterion is problematic, simply because a political unit in lack of bargaining capacity may still be an international actor albeit an ineffective one. More specifically for the EU, limited bargaining capacity may undermine the EU outreach and impact in international interactions (cf. Jørgensen 2009: 203-207), but does not nullify the actorness potential of the EU altogether. However, purposive actors do engage in international interactions in pursuit of own goals and objectives and effectiveness is attained on the basis of achieving these objectives. Setting aside very few cases of power asymmetries of such magnitude that bring about unilateral actions by some actors to meet their objectives, all external activities of an actor entail negotiations, in which bargaining capacity and power are crucial for the accomplishment of the identified goals. Thus, bargaining power emerges as the missing link between actorness and international effectiveness. Then, the question arises what are the determinants of the bargaining power of an international actor? Obviously, structural determinants of socio-economic and political-military nature constitute the starting point of any such discussion, together with any other form of cultural or historical influence that can be translated into negotiating capital. However, institutionalist accounts have also pointed out the significance of internal policymaking processes and the aggregation function of heterogeneous domestic preferences (Tsebelis 2002, 1995; Clark et al 2000).1 The underlying point is that domestic actors embrace or reject the outcome of an international negotiation considering its impact on their prosperity. Every international agreement with economic and political implications has a (re)distributive aspect, which triggers private and aggregate welfare shifts and affects subsequently domestic actors’ policy preferences (Milner and Keohane 1996: 15-16).2 In that 1 Clearly, this line of analysis assumes a political actor of non-unitary nature, departing from traditional realist perceptions about the nature of the state and the indivisibility of the national interest. 2 For example, an international economic agreement generates an exogenous easing of economic exchanges (the resurgence of protectionism, leading to exogenous worsening of exchanges, cannot be precluded a priori; this changes the direction but not the essence of the following analysis). As a result, 5 respect, how the negotiating positions are moulded in the first place and how negotiating outcomes are ratified in the end also affect crucially the bargaining power of a political actor in international negotiations (Hagan 1995: 122-3; Huelshoff 1994: 265-266).3 The EU case does not depart too much from the logic of the ‘two-level games’, that connects the domestic (i.e. intra-EU) and international levels of analysis, attributing to the statesmen the role of the ‘hinge’ between the two levels (Putnam 1988). Therein as well, the institutional architecture casts its impact on the bargaining power of the EU in international negotiations, the standard assumption being that the EU is handicapped internationally by the complexity of its institutional functioning and the limitations on the competence of the negotiators. Furthermore, the protracted process of intra-EU policymaking to aggregate member-states’ preferences in preparation of the coming negotiations demarcates clearly the contract zone of the EU depriving the negotiators from one crucial element, i.e. uncertainty. Finally, the multilateral nature of the EU and the hard-fought intra-EU negotiations to forge a common position suggests that the EU negotiators at the international level are inflexible, heavily constrained by the tight mandate they have received from the constituent member-states (Meunier 2000: 105-6). However, these constraints may also advance the bargaining power of the EU in line with Schelling’s ‘paradox of weakness’ (Schelling 1960: 19), turning the liability of internal institutional bottlenecks into assets (cf. Evans et al 1993; Mayer 1992). relative prices of the different sectoral outputs change, since production surpluses can be disposed internationally instead of suppressing commodities prices in the domestic market. Consequently, the owners of production factors in abundance in the country will experience an appreciation of the value of the factors they own, whereas factors in scarcity before liberalisation will lose some of their value. The analysis here is limited to flows of goods, but, mutatis mutandis, the arguments hold for capital flows and investments. In addition, aggregate social welfare may be improved, given that in a closed economy, price differentials distort resources allocation. Without protection and existing barriers, production factors will be invested in a more efficient manner into production activities closer to the country’s international comparative advantage. 3 In direct ratification processes (i.e. referendums), democratically elected statesmen usually have small ‘win sets’, suggesting there is an inverse relationship between the scope of political enfranchisement and the win set size (Putnam 1988: 448-450). The more groups and private domestic actors participate in the ratification process, the greater and more direct the need of statesmen to accommodate their preferences. In cases of indirect ratification (e.g. through the Parliament), domestic political and partisan practices affect the win set size. Strong partisan discipline can increase the relative autonomy of national negotiators. United, single-party governments with a solid parliamentary majority face less constraints than coalition governments in a parliament where no party commands a majority or than a single party government politically fragmented. ‘Strong’ governments, based on solid parliamentary and electoral majority, are expected to enjoy a greater negotiating autonomy, which enhances the chances of an international agreement. ‘Weak’ governments, suffering from divided decision-making capacity and intra-partisan strives, are more easily penetrated by interest groups, thus restraining their negotiating flexibility. 6 In that respect, internal decision-making rules and negotiating competence emerge as the crucial institutional determinants of the EU bargaining power, delimiting the framework of delegation to EU negotiators (Meunier 2005). In terms of the former, the degree of fragmentation4 and the set of rules that defines the policymaking mode among and within executive poles have a strong effect on the capacity of an actor to adopt and support negotiating positions that depart from the status quo (Tsebelis 1995). Multiple veto points and unanimity are assuring that narrow national interests of member-states will be warranted by the final outcome. In contrast, majority voting facilitates the smooth functioning of the EU governance system, but does not provide enough reassurance to particularistic national preferences (Kerremans 1998: 88). Thus, the fragmented EU policymaking system and the constraining decision-making rules in most thematic areas make life hard for EU negotiators, affecting also their negotiating competence. The modality of ratification of an international agreement at the EU level by member-states at the Council level and the European Parliament offers numerous opportunities for agency controlling, curtailing the autonomy potential of the EU negotiator. At the same time, the membership heterogeneity of the Council restrains severely the negotiating flexibility, authority and credibility of the EU negotiator, for example, in making concessions, offering side payments, etc. The EU negotiator has to bear in mind constantly the tight mandate to avoid ratification failures at the cost of bargaining effectiveness, missing important opportunities to broker an international agreement (Meunier 2000: 111-2; Meunier and Nicolaidis 1999). This discussion on the decision-making rules and the negotiating competence is very much related with the degree of preference heterogeneity among the EU member-states in the first place and whether the aggregation function operates smoothly. Considerable congruence of the constituent principals in the first place -or goal cohesion in the language of Jupille and Caporaso (1998)- clearly strengthens the EU international actorness but has an ambivalent effect on the EU bargaining power. It does convey an image of unity and solid backing to the EU negotiators but it does not allow for the instrumental exploitation of internal strives. In contrast, tactical or 4 By fragmentation, we refer to the existence or not of multiple executive poles, like in the Presidential or bicameral systems, as well as the cohesion within a single executive pole. At the EU level, this reflects the heterogeneity of member-states, each one pushing forward an own policy agenda. In fragmented policymaking systems, capacity to reach decisions is constrained to the benefit of control, since shared competence among autonomous executive poles suggests a number of restrictive checkpoints to the final outcome (Tsebelis 2002: 19-63). 7 procedural cohesion, i.e. the EU capacity to overcome internal divergence of preferences by means of side payments, issue linkages etc., may on the one hand undermine negotiating flexibility, in the sense that deviation from the negotiation mandate may lead to the unraveling of the package deal, but on the other hand it also renders the other negotiating partners more receptive to the EU proposals. Thus, the type of EU cohesion also affects her bargaining power. Besides these endogenous parameters that condition the EU bargaining power (structural assets, institutional features, and type of cohesion), we need to be aware that bargaining power is also a relational concept and that it takes two to tango. In that sense, the outcome of multilateral negotiations are not solely dependent on the EU inputs in the bargaining process; multilateral negotiations are inherently complex processes with their own characteristics and dynamics. Thus, any account of the EU intervention should be heavily contextualized, looking at the structure and content of the specific multilateral negotiations under examination. The negotiation structure refers to the number and attributes of the negotiating partners, revealing patterns of power asymmetries and influence, as well as the stages and sequencing of the negotiations per se.5 The negotiation content captures mainly the nature of the bargaining agenda, the main issue there being whether the EU is a reformist demandeur or a conservative proponent of the status quo (Meunier 2000: 112-15). The EU and the Negotiations over the Iranian Nuclear Program Stage 1: Setting the agenda and delimiting the negotiating space The starting point of the EU engagement with the Iranian nuclear program is the articulation of the European Security Strategy (ESS) and the EU strategy against the proliferation of Weapons of Mass Destruction (WMD) in 2003. This brought the EU in a course of direct confrontation with Iran that had been long accused for pursuing a 5 International negotiations consist normally of a series of phases, comprising a pre-negotiation stage where participants agree basically on the negotiation agenda, the formal negotiation stage, where the actual negotiations take place, and the post-negotiation stage where either the details of the agreement are finalised or the agreement is implemented (Gulliver 1979; Saunders 1985). Multilateral negotiations conform to this general rule, with additional analytical concerns regarding the number of participants and their status/role in the negotiations (Touval 1989: 160-162). The preparatory nature of the pre-negotiation stage often leads to a common understanding or an agreement framework, within which the detailed and formal agreement will be sought afterwards (Zartman 1978: 67-86). This underlying agreement can be reflected in the content of the negotiation agenda, the clarification of which delimits the boundaries of the potential agreement. In an adversary relationship, in particular, a proposed agenda is more often than not prejudicial rather than neutral; thence the agreement on it consequently outlines the content of the final agreement (Berridge 2005: 33). 8 scientific program of uranium enrichment, aiming at the development of nuclear weaponry. The attempted EU efforts to dissuade Iran from entering the club of nuclear powers have been closely associated with the motivation of EU memberstates and their desire to re-establish the EU international credentials after the highly divisive Iraq crisis (Dryburgh 2008). The original minilateral format of the negotiating team in charge of the talks with Iran comprised only France, the UK, and Germany. In realist terms, these three countries constituted the two main political powers that are permanent members of the UN Security Council and the main trading partner of Iran in the EU. Following intra-EU pressures for a closer collective EU engagement and addressing calls for the explicit recognition of the EU role in the negotiating process, the High Representative (HR) joined the trio in autumn 2004 to increase the authority and legitimacy of the negotiating team that now spoke more authoritatively on behalf of the EU as a whole (Harnish 2007: 5). Taking distances from the US approach that regarded the use of force as an essential component of addressing non-proliferation challenges, the EU firmly placed the negotiations with Iran on the basis of diplomatic containment, with emphasis on the use of political and economic ‘sticks and carrots’ rather than military means. The EU negotiating course of action was already identified in the context of the EES, the WMD strategy and the successive EU Council decisions. The latter, taken under unanimity rule, had to accommodate the divergent preferences of the EU memberstates and especially their reluctance in varying degrees to adopt a more muscular approach to the issue. These official documents that constituted the backbone of the EU policy and were parts of the broader holistic EU approach to international relations delimited the agenda of the EU negotiating team with Iran, i.e. the EU-3 and the HR, providing a clear picture of the EU negotiating objectives. The advantage was that this strong emphasis on non-military ways of handling the crisis made the EU a more attractive negotiating partner for Iran. At the same time, though, it deprived the EU from a very powerful coercive mechanism to achieve the declared negotiating objectives. Having explicitly rejected the use of military force as counter-productive, the EU had to invoke the potential intervention of the US factor to the negotiations to exercise additional pressure on the Iranian government for further concession along the demands of the international community. According to the Council, negotiations with Iran should lead to a long-term verifiable arrangement with Tehran to suspend permanently and fully its nuclear 9 program (based on uranium enrichment related and reprocessing activities) as well as implement relevant international legal instruments.6 In that respect, the EU demanded the maximum from Iran, offering though little for exchange. The EU was blamed to follow a constraint-based strategy rather than an incentive-based one, not accompanying exercised pressures with concrete and credible assurances to the Iranian government that a commitment to the Non-Proliferation Treaty regime would not jeopardise the national economic interests. Whereas the ‘sticks’ were evident, setting for example strict preconditions for holding talks with Iran for a long-term arrangement, like an immediate halt to the ongoing uranium conversion, the ‘carrots’ failed to catch up. Only a series of vague incentives were offered, at various stages of this first phase of the negotiations, including cooperation in the areas of trade, technology exchange and security, without, however, entering into details on their contents and implementation modality (Santini 2010: 476). Still, at this stage, this hard line bore fruit and Iran publicly declared its intention to suspend voluntarily the enrichment process in January 2004. The driving force behind such move on the part of Iranian government was its concern of being referred by the IAEA, and under the US pressure, to the UN Security Council that would set an uncomfortable parallel with Iraq. Iran also sought to establish better relations with the international community and especially with the EU that appeared an appealing interlocutor, willing to seek progress in the full spectrum of EU-Iranian relations as soon as the nuclear issue was settled. In that context and after successive visits of the HR to Tehran, the EU-3 plus the HR proposed a deal to Iran on 21 October 2004 that led to the EU-Iran agreement signed in Paris on 14 November 2004. Iran agreed to freeze its uranium enrichment activities and to sign the IAEA Protocol, allowing intrusive inspections of nuclear sites in exchange for trade, technology benefits and security guarantees the EU promised to offer.7 However, the follow up to the Paris agreement was stigmatized by the EU failure to deliver on the promises made in the course of the negotiations and meet the Iranian expectations.8 By March 2005, Iran became very frustrated with the EU and perceived the Paris Agreement as extremely long on demands and absurdly short on 6 Council of the EU, 2004. Presidency Coclusions, 14292/04, Brussels, 4-5 November. Security guarantees entailed entertaining the Iranian security concerns for its neighbours, especially Israel. 8 The only ‘carrots’ the EU was able to offer at this time were those of membership in the World Trade Organization and spare parts of airplanes. Even these timid offers became possible only after intense negotiations with and final approval by the US. 7 10 offers. The Iranian government threatened to resume uranium enrichment and in May 2005 took the initiative to elaborate and present to the EU its own counter-proposal for resolving the nuclear issue.9 The EU never responded to the Iranian proposal, counting on the expected victory of former President Rafsajani in the coming Presidential elections in Iran just three months away. According to the EU expectations, the new President, who was considered a moderate political figure, would provide a more convenient interlocutor for the settling of the issue in line with the EU preferences (Sauer 2008: 277). Stage 2: The involvement of the UN and the imposition of sanctions The mid-2005 Iranian Presidential elections constitute the critical milestone in the negotiations. To the great surprise of the EU, the hardliner fraction of Ahmadinejad won the August 2005 elections, opening the second phase of the negotiations. This second phase was more complicated and confrontational, differing from the first one in terms of institutional format and political context. Without prior consultation with the international community, the new regime took immediately the decision to resume its uranium enrichment activities declaring publicly that Iran was entitled to its own nuclear fuel cycle. In parallel, Iran denied the IAEA inspectors access to its nuclear facilities, crossing the EU red line. The EU response was to stop negotiations with Iran and start contemplating the option of a coercive diplomacy as the only viable route to compel Iran to stop its uranium enrichment program and return to the negotiating table. In this context, the EU referred, for the first time, the issue of Iran’s non-compliance to the IAEA and, managing to forge the necessary consensus among the veto-bearer states (principally Russia and China), ensured the passage of an IAEA Resolution in September 2005. The EU-drafted Resolution called Iran to comply with its IAEA obligations, otherwise its file would be sent to the UNSC for further action.10 In the light of the continued intransigence of Iran, the IAEA finally sent the Iran file to the UNSC in February 9 Iran offered to produce only low enrichment uranium including the assembly, installation and testing of 3000 gas centrifuges at Natanz under strict continuous inspections procedures conducted not only by the IAEA but also by EU-3 nationals. In exchange, Iran sought from the EU to provide it with new light-water nuclear power reactors; to guarantee Iran’s access to advanced and nuclear technology and to the EU markets for its goods, to recognize Iran as a major source of energy supply for Europe, etc. See ‘General Framework for objective guarantees, firm guarantees and firm commitments’, 3 May 2005, available at http://www.css.ethz.ch/Documents/20050323_Iran_Proposal_Steering_Cmte.pdf. 10 IAEA, Board of Governors, Implementation of the NPT Safeguards Agreement in the Islamic Republic of Iran, Vienna, 24 September 2005. 11 2006, after an EU initiative that materialized the EU Council decision of 30/31 January 2006. This decision marked a significant shift in the EU attitude with regard to the Iranian issue. While this decision reiterated the EU’s commitment to a diplomatic solution to the issue, the EU called and prepared the ground for the direct involvement of the UNSC, recognizing that this was not a dispute between Iran and Europe, but one between Iran and the international community. In that context, the EU called its member states to coordinate closely their future actions in the UN in collaboration with non-EU partners. This development stiffened further the position of the Iranian government that publicly announced the acceleration of its enrichment program. The EU attempt to raise the stakes at the negotiating table by involving directly the UNSC and the other permanent members failed as Iran did not feel at least threatened. In the words of the German Foreign Minister, Joschka Fischer, ‘…the disastrous US-led war in Iraq had caused Iran’s leaders to conclude that the leading Western power has been weakened to the point that is dependent on Iran’s goodwill and that high oil prices have made the West all the more wary of a serious confrontation’.11 From mid-2006 onwards, initially the US and subsequently the two other permanent UNSC members, i.e. Russia and China, joined the EU-3 group. In this process, the HR emerged as the prime interlocutor for the ‘EU3+3’ team in the direct negotiations with the Iranian government, playing a critical role in the efforts to cement the team’s unity. In a final effort to bring the controversy to an end, Solana presented in June 2006 to the Iranian government an offer of technological assistance to develop a modern civil nuclear power program and a framework of expanded cooperation with the EU3+3 in political and economic fields in exchange for the immediate suspension of the uranium enrichment process and implementation of the Additional Protocol of IAEA.12 At the same time, he conveyed orally the message to the Iranian negotiations that there would be serious consequences for Iran if it failed to comply with its international obligations. As Iran did not respond positively to the offer, the EU Council by its decision of 17 July 2006 paved the way for the imposition by the UNSC of punitive measures (i.e. sanctions) against Iran. The decision provided that ‘since Iran has given no See Joschka Fischer, ‘The Case for bargaining with Iran’, Washington Post, 29 May 2006. See EU Doc. S202/06, ‘Elements of a proposal to Iran as approved on 1 June 2006 at the meeting in Vienna of China, France, Germany, The Russian Federation, the United States of America and the European Union’. 11 12 12 indication of willingness to engage seriously on the basis of the proposals …we will work for the adoption of measures under Article 41 of Chapter VII of the UN Charter’. According to the German Foreign Minister, the stick of economic sanctions was the most feared one in Tehran (Santini 2010: 480). Given the high Iranian dependence on economic cooperation with the West, the international community should take swift action in the UNSC against Tehran along these lines (Di Lorenzo and Ulrich 2006). Based on this EU decision, the EU-3 in close cooperation with the other three permanent members orchestrated a UNSC resolution imposing sanctions against Iran. However, due to the reservations raised by China and Russia, Resolution 1696 of 31 July 2006, drafted by the EU-3, gave only an ultimatum to Iran to suspend uranium enrichment by 31 August or face a subsequent UNSC resolution imposing economic sanctions. The subsequent rejection of the UNSC ultimatum sealed the EU turn to sanctions as engaging diplomacy seemed to have reached its limits.13 Whereas at the EU level the decision on sanctions appeared straightforward and non-controversial, in the UNSC things were more complicated. The EU3 had to mediate between the US on the one hand, which demanded the imposition of a comprehensive set of sanctions, and China and Russia on the other that still questioned the necessity and the extent to which Iran should be sanctioned (Sauer 2008: 279). Russia, in particular, that maintained close ties with Iran, was very sceptical on the sanctions option, citing the failure of the sanctions regime against Iraq in the 1990s (Santini 2010: 481). In an attempt to reconcile the positions of the two sides, the EU-3 watered down in successive drafts their sponsored resolution to accommodate the concerns of Russia and China. By Resolution 1737, of 23 December 2006, the UNSC imposed for the first time, a limited range of economic sanctions, including a ban on export and import of nuclear related materials and technological equipment and the freezing of the financial assets of a number of Iranian individuals and companies. The UNSC requested a report within 60 days from the Director General of IAEA on whether Iran had established full and sustained suspension of all activities mentioned in the Resolution and affirmed that the reviewing of the case in light of this report. In the statements of the five permanent members, these measures were characterised reversible if Iran suspended its enrichment-related activities, with the EU-3 in 13 See EU Council Decision of 16 October 2006; see also European Council Presidency Conclusions, 14-15 December 2006. 13 particular making it clear that they were still committed to a diplomatically negotiated solution. In February 2007, the IAEA Director-General submitted its report to the UNSC, as requested by UNSC Resolution 1737, clearly demonstrating Iran’s noncompliance. The submission of the report came at a time tensions between the US and Iran had been rising at the highest level. At the EU level, the HR circulated a document among the 27-member states that concluded that Iran was on course for acquiring nuclear weapons, constrained only by technical difficulties rather than UNSC resolutions.14 It also stated that it was hard to believe at least in the short run that Iran would be ready and willing to resume negotiations. These developments along with the US accusations of EU firms that continued to do business with Iran led the EU harden her position and ask for further sanctions.15 The effective interventions of the EU-3 culminated to the drafting and sponsoring of Resolution 1747 on 24 March 2007.16 In the mid-2007, the first cracks in the EU cohesion began to appear, as Germany embraced a more moderate approach towards Iran. These second thoughts on the adopted sanction strategy came after the statement of the IAEA’s Director, who called for greater flexibility since the current strategy to stop Iran’s nuclear program had been superseded by the achieved progress in the meantime.17 Other EU members, like Austria, Spain, Italy and Greece, expressed similar reservations about the continuation of this strategy, but the U-turn was avoided by increased US intervention that came in support of the EU hard liners, like the UK, France and the Netherlands. A compromise intra-EU package deal, in the form of two successive Council Decisions, comprised the authorisation of the HR to resume negotiations with the Iranian government and at the same time the reinstatement of the EU determination to consider additional measures in the immediate future to support the UNSC policy.18 See Daniel Dombey and Fidelius Schmid, ‘Iran on course for nuclear bomb, EU told’, Financial Times, 12 February 2007. 15 See EU Council decision of 5 March 2007. 16 The resolution imposed an arms embargo and a freeze on the assets of a number of Iranian individuals and companies, targeting the Iranian regime (especially the Revolutionary Guard Corps). It also blocked loans and other forms of financial assistance to the Iranian government and requested Iran to comply until the end of May 2007. 17 Daniel Dombey and Stephen Filder, ‘Strains grow over Strategy to reign in Iran’, Financial Times, 3 June 2007. 18 See the EU Council Decisions of 18 June 2007 and 15 October 2007. 14 14 This sealed the intra-EU cohesion and paved the way for the UNSC Resolution 1803, of 3 March 2008, again with the EU3 playing an instrumental role in its drafting.19 This new EU initiative for further sanctions shattered in the eyes of the Iranian government the EU as a credible negotiating interlocutor, with President Ahmadinejad stating that from that point onwards Iran would not talk to the EU anymore. The EU relations with Iran further deteriorated in June 2009 when Presidential elections were held and the EU (together with US) voiced doubts about the authenticity of the results and Ahmadinejad’s win. Only after the new US administration threatened Iran with additional sanctions that would bite after disclosures about a second uranium enrichment plant, did the Iranian government show some willingness to resume talks with the EU3+3. In this renewed effort to build an agreement framework, the EU diplomacy showed a more constructive face, suggesting some concessions, like the supply of nuclear fuel for the Tehran Research Reactor, in exchange for the suspension of the nuclear problem. However, the negotiations led to nowhere. From the beginning of 2010, the relations between the two sides reached the lowest ebb as Iran started to enrich low-enriched uranium to 20 per cent, which brought it even closer to a military threshold. This along with the agreement Iran reached with Turkey and Brazil, in May 2010, whereby the latter undertook to provide nuclear fuel to the Tehran Research Reactor, led the EU-3 plus the US to call for a new set of sanctions. Insisting on an all-or-nothing approach with no further offers or alternative options for Iran, they drafted and cosponsored Resolution 1929 of 9 June 2010.20 However, very much like their predecessors, they have not yet accomplished their primary objective vis-à-vis the Iranian nuclear program. Discussion Both negotiation stages feature a strong and active involvement of the EU, either in the form of the three member-states in the beginning, the addition of the HR at a subsequent stage, the forging of the ‘EU3+3’ team, or the intra-UNSC negotiations for the scope and content of the sanctions regime from 2006 onwards. Thus, EU 19 The Resolution called member states to inspect cargo bound to or from Iran and extended financial sanctions to additional Iranian companies and travel bans to additional Iranian individuals. 20 Expanding on the previous UNSC arms embargo, the Resolution prohibited Tehran from investing in sensitive nuclear activities abroad and banned all Iranian activities related to ballistic missiles that could deliver a nuclear weapon. It also imposed a comprehensive framework of cargo inspections to detect and stop Iran’s smuggling and acquisition of illicit materials or nuclear items. 15 actorness is seemingly undisputed, satisfying almost to full extent the main criteria of recognition, authority, cohesion, and autonomy. The EU was recognized as a legitimate interlocutor both by the Iranian regime and the international community – or at least the three permanent UNSC members. The authorization derived from successive Council and European Council decisions that authorized the HR plus the troika to speak in the negotiations on behalf of the EU. The EU3 enjoyed considerable autonomy in their diplomatic undertaking if we take into account the relatively vague mandate and the ex post legitimization of several initiatives, not without some grudging from other member-states for the limited consultation and information exchange in the name of confidentiality. Finally, intra-EU cohesion was high from the beginning, with the Iranian case fitting the policy objectives of the ESS and the EU strategy on the WMD. Still, in terms of stopping Iran from ‘going nuclear’, the EU appears ineffective in both stages, although of course the effectiveness of the imposed sanction regime remains to be assessed conclusively. Has that been due to limited bargaining power? From the endogenous parameters (i.e. structural assets, institutional features, and type of cohesion), structural assets are translated to bargaining power in a subjective way. In the first stage of the negotiations, the EU suffered from an overestimation of her own bargaining power, relying much on the economic and trade ties with Iran, their significance for the regime and the undisputed orthodoxy of conditionality policy. The EU perception was that the threat of halting economic cooperation or the ‘carrot’ of enhancing it would work miracles in convincing the regime to upturn the chosen policy. However, bargaining power asymmetries rely not only on structural features but also on the relative value attributed to each of them by the negotiating partners, as the EU realized bitterly from the successive rejections of her proposals. Institutional features, i.e. veto points and decision-making rules, are related with the type of cohesion in a given issue. Unanimity rule entailed significant potential institutional bottlenecks with an ambivalent effect on the EU negotiating power. But that is not of such relevance in the Iranian case since as mentioned above there already existed a large degree of congruence as a result of the articulation of ESS and WMD strategy. In a sense, the proactive engagement of the EU with these issues, in view also of the 2005 NPT negotiations, had already led to a considerable osmosis of the varying national preferences, taking away possible hurdles among EU 16 Nuclear Weapon States (NWS) and Non-Nuclear Weapon States (NNWS) and their diverging commitment to disarmament (Jørgensen 2009: 202). Having said that, although a common position had been forged in advance and military intervention was excluded from the beginning, there still existed within the EU some varying approaches on the exact balance between ‘sticks and carrots’ and this variation can arguably account for the EU ineffectiveness (Sauer 2008: 283-9). Although this constituent condition of the EU multilateral order did not paralyze the EU, as was the case in previous major international crises from the dissolution of Yugoslavia to Kossovo and Iraq, it did undermine the EU negotiating power in another respect. This intra-EU division was exploited not so much by the Iranian regime that counted more on the repercussions of the earlier transatlantic rift over Iraq and the exclusion of a military response, which the EU involvement in a way guaranteed rendering her the preferred interlocutor for Iran, but rather from the US. Every time the ‘EU doves’ seemed to prevail in the intra-EU game, the US factor would intervene to avoid a reversal of the EU policy to a more accommodating stance. In that respect, another external actor –not necessarily the direct negotiating interlocutor- capitalized on the internal heterogeneity to undermine a potentially more effective strategy. The latter point takes us directly to the issue of bargaining strategy and tactics and especially their interplay with cohesion. In the first stage, the EU relied heavily on a conditionality policy based on economic incentives, having a priori excluded the option of a more muscular response. Although it did provide some timid progress, like the 2004 Paris Agreement, it failed to achieve major breakthroughs, not least because the EU did not show the necessary flexibility to respond swiftly to the Iranian counter proposals. Acting by default rather than by tactical considerations, the EU did not take advantage of the 2005 Iranian agreement proposals, waiting for the Iranian electoral results. The results took everybody by surprise, changing completely the negotiating setting and leading to the securitization of the intra-EU debate and the inevitable hardening of the EU stance. A coercive discourse became hegemonic at the intra-EU level, leading to the active and effective pursuit of a sanction regime at the UNSC against Iran. Thus, the two negotiating stages may feature different underlying political discourses but share one common element, in the sense the EU has engaged in the negotiations in rather a monolithic way, very much again the result of her own 17 constitutive nature. The lack of even considering for tactical reasons alternatives has had a negative impact on the EU negotiating power (cf. Lax and Sebenius 1985). Conclusions Our point of departure is the gap between the EU international actorness and effectiveness. Throughout the 1980s and 1990s, research focused on the EU international presence in the first place; in the 1990s and early 2000s, emphasis shifted from presence to actorness, illustrating the emerging consensus in the EU literature on the international role and modality of EU engagement in international interactions. We posit that this is also a saturated topic, with relatively little dispute on whether the EU is an international actor or not. We should now move on to the third generation of research and examine issues of effectiveness and performance. Our contribution is the concept of the EU bargaining power as the missing link between actorness and effectiveness. We argue that the EU bargaining power depends on endogenous parameters like the EU structural assets, institutional features, and type of cohesion as well as the heavily contextualized structure and content of the specific multilateral negotiations under examination. Our empirical evidence draws on the EU experience with the Iranian nuclear program. Tentatively, our research suggests an overestimation of the EU bargaining power, revealing the subjective dimension of this concept. This brings into mind unfortunate memories of impressive past EU failures in the CFSP domain, like the infamous ‘hour of Europe’ in the Yugoslavian crisis in the beginning of 1990s. Has nothing changed since then? Our answer would come to the positive, arguing that the Iran case does not feature the structural divergence of member-states’ preferences, without claiming of course that this is necessarily due to a well operating intra-EU ‘aggregation function’. Still, the Iran case shows that more flexibility, authority and autonomy is required for the EU negotiators, be they institutional figures or groups of states, for strategic or tactical reasons. 18 References Berridge, G. R. (2005) Diplomacy: Theory and Practice. 3rd Edition (Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan). Bretherton, C. and J. Vogler (2006) ‘Conceptualizing actors and actorness’, in C. Bretherton and J. Vogler (eds.) The European Union as a Global Actor (London: Routledge). Clark, W. R., E. Duchesne, and S. Meunier (2000) ‘Domestic and International Asymmetries in United States–European Union Trade Negotiations’, International Negotiation 5, pp. 69-95. Cosgrove, C. A. and K. J. Twitchett (eds.) The new international actors: the United Nations and the European Economic Community (London: Macmillan). Evans, B. P., H. K. Jacobson and R. D. Putnam (1993) (eds.) Double-Edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics (Berkeley: University of California Press). Groen, L. and A. Niemann (2011) ‘EU actorness and effectiveness under politicl pressure at the Copenhagen climate change negotiations’, paper presented at 12th European Union Studies Association Conference, Boston, Massachusetts, 3-5 March. Groenleer, M. and L. Van Schaik (2007) ‘United We Stand? The European Union’s International Actorness in the Cases of the InternationalCriminal Court and the Kyoto Protocol’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 45 (5), pp. 969-998. Gulliver, P.H. (1979) Disputes and negotiations (New York: Academic Press). Hagan, J. D. (1995) ‘Domestic Political Explanation in the Analysis of Foreign Policy’, in L. Neack, J. A. K. Hey and P. J. Haney (eds.) Foreign Policy Analysis: Continuity and Change in Its Second Generation (New Jersey: Prentice Hall). Huelshoff, M. G. (1994) ‘Domestic Politics and Dynamic Issue Linkage: A Reformulation of Integration Theory’, International Studies Quarterly, 38, pp. 255279. Jørgensen, K-E. and S. Oberthür (2012) ‘Introduction: establishing a framework for assessing the EU’s performance in international institutions’, Journal of European Integration, forthcoming. Jørgensen, K-E. (2009) ‘The European Union in Multilateral Diplomacy’, The Hague Journal of Diplomacy, 4, pp. 189-209. 19 Jupille, J. and J. A. Caporaso (1998) ‘States, Agency and Rules: the European Union in Global Environmental Politics’, in C. Rhodes (ed.) The European Union in the World Community (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner), pp. 213-229. Kerremans, B. (1998) ‘The Political and Institutional Consequences of Widening: Capacity and Control in an Enlarged Council’ in P-H. Laurent and M. Maresceau (eds.) The State of the European Union: Deepening and Widening [Vol.4] (Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers). Lax, D. A. and J. K. Sebenius (1985) ‘The Power of Alternatives or the Limits to Negotiation’, Negotiation Journal, April. Mayer, F. W. (1992) ‘Managing Domestic Differences in International Negotiations: the Strategic Use of Internal Side-Payments’, International Organization, 46 (4), pp. 793-818. Meunier, S. (2005) Trading Voices: The European Union in International Commercial Negotiations (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Meunier, S. (2000) ‘What Single Voice? European Institutions and EU-U.S. Trade Negotiations’, International Organization, 54 (1), pp. 103-135. Meunier, S. and K. Nicolaidis (1999) ‘Who speaks for Europe? The delegation of trade authority in the EU’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 37, pp. 477-501. Milner, H.V. and R.O. Keohane (1996) ‘Internationalization and Domestic Politics: An Introduction’, in R.O. Keohane and H.V. Milner (eds.) Internationalization and Domestic Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Putnam, R. (1988) ‘Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: the Logic of Two-Level Games’, International Organization, 42 (3), pp. 427-460. Saunders, H. H. (1985) ‘We need a Larger Theory of Negotiation: The Importance of Pre-negotiating Phases’, Negotiation Journal, 1 (3), pp. 249-262. Schelling, T. C. (1960) The Strategy of Conflict (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press). Sjöstedt, G. (1977) The External Role of the European Community (Saxon House: Swedish Institute of International Affairs). Touval, S. (1989) ‘Multilateral Negotiation: An Analytic Approach’, Negotiation Journal, 5 (2), pp. 159-173. Tsebelis, G. (2002) Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work (Princeton: Princeton University Press). 20 Tsebelis, G. (1995) ‘Decision Making in Political Systems’, British Journal of Political Science, 25(3), pp. 289-325. Young, O. R. (1994) International Governance. Protecting the Environment in a Stateless Society (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press). Zartman, I. W. (1978) ‘Negotiation as a joint decision-making process’, in: I. W. Zartman (ed.) The Negotiation Process (Beverly Hill, Calif.: Sage). 21