Bureaucrats or Strategists? Competitive Strategy of China’s State-Owned Satellite Television Industry Richard Wang† December 2008 *** Preliminary and Incomplete. Comments Welcome. Please do not cite. *** Abstract An important goal set by the Chinese government in market reform is to promote scientific management among state-owned enterprises (SOE). This paper empirically investigates whether the reform has led Chinese state-owned satellite television channels to implement market competitive strategy. Using a near-census panel dataset, I examine programming portfolios and ratings performance of 30 channels from May 2002 to May 2004. I find the province-level government-owned satellite channels execute spatial differentiation strategy with respect to their common dominant competitor – the central government-owned CCTV1 channel. Moreover, channels exhibit sensitivities to market demand variations when implementing their strategies. Channels that compete more directly with CCTV1 for national audience demonstrate greater responsiveness. In addition, satellite channels are aware of their own ability when selecting strategies. The overall behavior of the satellite channels offer coherent support that they are competing strategically. † Ph.D. Student, Business & Public Policy Group, Haas School of Business, University of California at Berkeley. I am grateful to Paul Gertler, John Morgan and seminar participants at the Haas School of Business for their valuable comments. I am also indebted to L. Bai, Matthew Brosenne, Cedric Lam, Z. Liu, X.F. Lu, Louise Wang, and B. Zhang for sharing with me their industry knowledge. The ratings dataset was generously provided by CSM Media Research. All errors are my own. Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Introduction The approach taken by the Chinese government to market reform is different from the ones followed by other transition economies, notably in the area of reforming stateowned enterprises (SOEs). Unlike those in Russia and CEE countries, many large enterprises remain state-owned in China today. While institutions such as IMF and the World Bank advocated privatization of SOEs (e.g. the “Washington Consensus”), the Chinese government instead relied on corporatization – to make SOEs operate as if they were private firms facing competitive markets (World Bank, 1995; Shirley, 1999; Nolan, 2001; Qian, 2002). The Chinese SOE reform has been implemented in stages (Qian, 2000). In the 1990’s, despite empowered with greater autonomy and decentralization of management decisions, the SOEs were not performing up to expectations. At the Fifteenth Congress of the Chinese Communist Party in 1997, the government stepped up the reform process by approving a program known as zhuada fangxiao (literal translation being “grasping the large and letting go the small”, or “managing successfully large enterprises while invigorating small ones”).1 In 1999, the Central Committee of the Chinese Communist Party followed up with a Decision document to elaborate on the program. According to the Decision, a target is set for large SOEs to adopt modern enterprise system (MES) by 2010. An important aspect under the MES is to promote scientific management among SOEs. The Decision stated, “Enterprises should adapt themselves to the market, formulate and implement clear strategies for development, technological innovations and Zhuada fanxiao began as a quite reform in the mid-1990’s and was formally adopted by the Chinese central government in 1997. 1 2 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang marketing, and timely readjust these strategies in accordance with the changes in the market.”2 In this paper, I investigate whether Chinese SOEs are reforming in line with the government’s MES goal that they are sensitive to market environment changes and implementing corresponding competitive strategies. I study the Chinese national television industry which consists of a central governmentowned China Central Television (CCTV) and 31 province-level government-owned satellite channels.3 The industry setting resembles a dominant firm competitive fringe (DFCF) structure, with CCTV’s flagship channel – CCTV1 – taking up thirty percent of the national audience share. In a DFCF situation under market economies, one would expect the dominant player to focus on the mass market while fringe players operate around it. In particular to the media broadcasting industry, the competitive fringe should spatially differentiate their programming from that of the dominant firm. By analyzing a near-census panel dataset of China’s national television programming lineup and ratings from May 2002 to May 2004, I find evidence on satellite channels strategizing their programming lineups as if they were competing under a market economy DFCF setting. In addition to differentiating their programming from that of CCTV1, the satellite channels demonstrate sensitivities towards variations in market demand conditions as 2 The Decision of the Central Committee of The Communist Party of China on Major Issues Concerning The Reform and Development of State-Owned Enterprises, Fourth Plenum of the 15th CPC Central Committee, September 22, 1999; English translation by the Legal Information Center of Peking University (www.lawinfochina.com). 3 In addition to CCTV and 31 province-level satellite channels, the national television market also consists of the Education channel which takes up less than a fraction of a percent in audience share. Tibet, Xinjiang and Inner Mongolia television stations operate separate satellite channels in Tibetan, Uygur and Mongolian languages in addition to their Mandarin language channels. In 2004, the regulatory agency also permitted 5 municipal level channels to broadcast nationally, with Shenzhen satellite channel being the first of its kind to launch on May 28, 2004. In this paper, I focus only on the competition between CCTV1 and 30 of the 31 province-level Mandarin language satellite channels (Tibet satellite channel is excluded). 3 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang well as the degree of direct competition with the dominant player. The overall evidence presented in this paper support the argument that the state-owned satellite channels are competing strategically. This paper relates to the debate on SOE reform policy among the three main schools of thoughts: privatization, competition and institution. Proponents of privatization argue that, without ridding government ownership, SOEs will be influenced by political objectives and therefore cannot achieve economic efficiency (e.g. Shleifer and Vishny, 1994). On the other hand, proponents of competition and institution argue that, by introducing competitions and enhancing institutional environments, the Chinese market reform has led SOEs to rising performance without privatization (e.g. Groves et al., 1994; Li, 1997). While much focus has been on measuring performance, fewer studies have examined SOE market competitive strategy – a subject alien to SOE managers under the planned economy system prior to the market reform. A contribution of this paper is to study whether Chinese SOE reform absent of privatization has led SOEs to adopt strategic management practices. The contributions of this study go further than that of measuring Chinese SOE reform progress. SOEs still accounted for thirty percent of China’s total investment in fixed assets and employed over 61 million workers as recently as in 2006.4 At the Fifteenth Congress in 1997, then Chinese President Jiang Zemin emphasized “the state-owned sector must be in a dominant position in major industries and key areas that concern the life-blood of the national economy.” SOEs that survive the market transition will play an 4 China Statistical Yearbook 2007. National Bureau of Statistics of China. 4 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang important role in shaping future industry landscapes, and firms operating in China are likely to compete with incumbent SOEs (Nolan, 2001). Gaining a better understanding on SOE competitive strategy is therefore crucial to comprehending Chinese business environments. The paper proceeds as follows. I present a literature review on SOE reform and on competitive strategy specific to the broadcasting industry. I then provide an institutional overview of the Chinese national television market, followed by stating the hypotheses. In turn, I describe the data and empirical specifications. After presenting the empirical results, I close with concluding remarks. Literature Review Literature on SOE Reform Policy Debate There are three main schools of thoughts in the SOE reform debate: privatizing ownership, promoting competition and improving institutions. The privatization literature argument is based on the property rights theory and principal-agent theory. Property rights theory (e.g. Grossman and Hart, 1986) proposes individuals respond to incentives and the pattern of incentives is shaped by property rights structure. With no individual or group clearly identified as the residual claimant, SOEs therefore will operate with low levels of efficiencies. The principal-agent theory (e.g. Sappington, 1991) argues that the agents do not share the same objectives as the principals but the latter lack perfect control over the former due to information asymmetry. The principal-agent problem is worse under public than private ownership due to more severe information asymmetry, causing 5 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang greater difficulty for the government to hold SOE managers accountable. This line of literature proposes privatization as the solution to improving SOE performance. The competition literature argues that market competition, not property rights, as the main driver of firm performance. Their proposition is based on incentive and information effects. Competition in markets generates incentive effects by punishing managers of inefficient firms with diminished returns (Porter, 1980). Competition also reveals information about relative performance of firms (Holmstrom, 1982), thus alleviating the principal-agent information asymmetry problem. However, the privatization literature counter-argues that even in competitive markets, SOE would remain inefficient because without separating the ownership from government, politicians would sidetrack SOEs to pursue political objectives (Shleifer and Vishny, 1994). The institutional reform literature is built on the New Institutional Economics argument that markets are organized according to institutions (Williamson, 1975, 1985; North, 1991). It addresses SOE reform from a macro- and a micro-environment perspective. The macro aspect highlights the importance of institutions external to the firm, such as independent judiciary, capable bureaucracy, and checks and balances in the governments (e.g. Levy and Spiller, 1996). The micro aspect places managers and managerial motivation on center stage, proposing that government offering realistic incentives to SOE managers can improve organization performance. Nolan wrote “the vast bulk of managers within large companies are stimulated to effective performance by appropriate contracts and by non-pecuniary motivation, rather than by ownership” (1995, p.316). 6 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Compared to privatization and competition, the institutionally oriented approach to SOE reform is perceived to be still in infancy stage and in need of empirical evidence in respect of transforming economies (Hassard et al., 2007, p. 32). In the context of Chinese SOE reform policy, researchers tend to advocate promoting competition and improving institutions over privatization (Lin et al., 1998; Qian, 1999). Lin et al. (1998) stressed that fair competition policy, accompanied by releasing the SOEs from policy burden, is a necessary condition for successful SOE reform. On building market-supporting institutions, Qian (1999) argued that central government institutional policies such as regional decentralization of government, encouragement of entry and expansion of non-state firms, together with financial reforms have released the potential for managerial incentives and competition. Literature on Chinese SOE Literature on Chinese SOEs has focused on governance (e.g. Boisot and Child, 1988), incentive mechanisms (e.g. Gordon and Li, 1991; Groves et al., 1994), and performances (e.g. Li, 1997; Bai et al., 1997; Jefferson et al., 2000). Researchers have also examined SOE non-market strategy through the political economy lens (e.g. Qian and Roland, 1998; Oi, 2005). In recent years, researchers are becoming more interested in examining SOE business strategies (e.g. Wang, 2006; Fernandez and Fernandez-Stembridge, 2007; Zhang 2008). These newer studies, mostly qualitative based, generally indicate that SOE managers are making decisions strategically. 7 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang On the other hand, quantitative empirical studies on Chinese SOE market competitive strategy have been few and far in between (e.g. Tan and Litschert 1994, White 2000). A number of reasons may be behind the apparent lack of research in this area. Even in the post market reform era, the government still maintains substantial influence over SOEs by imposing non-market objectives and resource allocations, which in turn promotes SOEs to exercise non-market strategies such as cultivating relationships with their bureaucratic superiors and negotiating for soft-budget allowances as an alternative to market strategy (Chen and Faure, 1995; Peng, 2000). Data availability is another concern. Most empirical studies on Chinese enterprises until recently have relied on survey or cross-sectional data. Researchers have pointed out the limitation of using such data especially under the high velocity Chinese business environment (Hoskisson et al. 2000). While SOE data is becoming increasingly available, the consistency and reliability of the data remains questionable (Peng et al. 2001). Nevertheless, SOEs’ significant presence in key Chinese industries supports the need for research on their competitive strategy. Literature on Competitive Strategy in Broadcasting Industry The seminal work by Steiner (1952) on broadcast programming choice adopted an economic approach and sought to explain how audience as rational consumers would, given different program options available, maximize their satisfaction. Steiner’s analysis is an extension of the classic Hotelling (1929) model of product spatial differentiation. Subsequent research followed Steiner’s basic premises and made improvements by relaxing the assumptions. The Beebe (1977) model, for example, permits viewers to rank multiple program choices above the no-viewing alternative. Contemporary models have 8 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang been developed when cable technology became available which vastly increased the number of channels and enabled pay-television. For instance, Spence and Owen (1977) and Wildman and Owen (1985) incorporated viewers’ willingness-to-pay to in their paytelevision models.5 Extending the line of advertiser-support broadcasting models of Steiner and Beebe, the more sophisticated models by Noam (1987) and Waterman (1990) treated the programming space as a one-dimensional continuum instead of discrete programming choices. A common theme of advertiser-support models is that the channels have strong incentives to occupy the programming space where density of viewer preference is highest but they maintain some level of spatial distances to avoid excessive thinning of viewer population. Institutional Background Television broadcasting in China began in 1958 when the central government started broadcasting around the Beijing area on which is now known as the China Central Television, or CCTV. Nevertheless, it was not until the 1980’s and more so in the 90’s when the general public began to own television sets that the television industry took off. In 2005, 97.9 percent of urban Chinese households and 95.8% of rural ones own at least one television set (China TV Rating Yearbook, 2006).6 It is estimated that the television 5 There exists a large literature on television programming strategy which relaxes the viewer rationality assumption. Instead, it focuses on viewer behaviors such as inertia or inheritance effects (e.g. Webster 1985, Tiedge and Ksobiech 1986, Walker 1988.) Along this line of study, programming strategies such as hammocking, tent-poling and counterprogramming are introduced. The empirical analysis in this paper, however, is based on the Steiner, Beebe, Noam line of competitive strategy models. 6 The data quoted from this section, unless specified otherwise, is from China TV Rating Yearbook from 2003 to 2006. 9 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang medium reaches over 95.3% of the Chinese population. Television watching is one of the nation’s favorite pastimes. In 2005, an average Chinese spends 174 minutes watching television per day (compared to 155 minutes for an average American in 20067). Primetime in China starts at 7:00pm and last until 11pm, with prime-time audience size over five times that of non-prime time. The primary mandate of television stations in China is to ensure timely dissemination of government announcements to citizens in every part of the country. In the 1980s, television transmission relied on terrestrial broadcasting which required numerous television stations in order to guarantee national coverage. At the peak, there were over 3,000 television stations in China. The arrival of satellite and cable technologies in the 1990s greatly improved the efficiency of television signal delivery, making the terrestrial broadcast system highly redundant. Industry restructuring was needed. The current industry landscape was shaped in 2001 when the central government regulatory agency, the State Administration of Film Radio and Television (SARFT), ordered merging of terrestrial, cable, and satellite channels to form essentially three tiers of television stations. The top tier is occupied by the China Central Television (CCTV), which is own and operated by the central government. The second tier consists of 31 province-level stations, which are owned by the province-level governments. The third tier consists of the local stations owned by municipality, prefecture and county-level governments. Each television station operates multiple channels. For example, CCTV currently operates 16 channels (with CCTV1 being their flagship channel) and the 7 “Special Report: America by the Numbers”, Time Magazine (p.44), November 26, 2007 10 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Shanghai station operates 11. In 2004, there were 314 television stations in China carrying 2,389 channels. As part of the restructuring, each of the 31 province-level television stations uplink one of their Mandarin language channels to satellite broadcast. This dramatically transformed the national television competitive landscape where, before the restructuring, provincelevel stations used to focus only on domestic province audience and did not compete with others for national audience. Consistent with the Chinese government’s competition promotion policy (Lin et al., 1998), the post reform industry structure offers a level playing field on which each province-level satellite channels compete. On distribution of television signals to households, unlike in the US and European countries where households install their own satellite dish, local cable companies aggregate broadcast signals from the satellite channels together with those from CCTV and local stations, and deliver the programming contents to households via cable. Table 1 summarizes the household coverage by the satellite channels. Table 2 presents market shares of main broadcaster categories from 2002 to 2004. The market shares are split almost evenly between national broadcasters (i.e. CCTV and satellite channels) and local broadcasters. Satellite channels take up approximately 16% of overall television viewership, or about one third of the national broadcast market share. Of all the national channels, CCTV1 alone takes up about 30 percent of the national market share in 2002. 11 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang The satellite channels are regulated by SARFT which is an executive branch under the State Council. Among other duties, SARFT reviews and approves the content of television programs. Once a program is approved, satellite channels are free to acquire the rights from the producer for broadcast. Although satellite channels are required to file their programming lineups to SARFT one month in advance, they are autonomous in making their own daily operational and business decisions. Financially, the satellite channels are receiving diminishing financial support from the province-level governments and are increasingly relying on advertising revenues. In 2005, satellite channels total advertising revenue is estimated at CNY37.4 billion. A recent survey indicated that advertising revenue account for over 90 percent of satellite channels’ revenues (Blue Book of China’s Media 2007). As a New York Times article describes the situation, “[G]overnment support for Chinese television is dwindling, creating a burst of commercialism as stations compete for viewers and advertising dollars.”8 In summary, the policies concerning provision of access to satellite infrastructure, hardened budget constraints and decentralization of business decisions are consistent with the government’s overall competition and institutional approach to SOE reform. (Lin et al., 1998; Qian, 1999). Hypotheses Baseline Differentiation Hypothesis 8 “Upstart from Chinese Province Masters the Art of TV Titillation”, The New York Times, Nov 25, 2005. 12 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang The objective of this empirical study is to explore whether state-owned satellite channels are competing strategically under China’s SOE reform policy. As a baseline, if they exhibit differentiation activities (as prescribed by the Steiner Beebe and Noam models) towards their common dominant competitor, CCTV1, it will lend support to the argument that they are indeed competing strategically in the national television market. Therefore, I hypothesize that: H1: Satellite channels respond to CCTV1 programming changes by differentiating their programming portfolios from that of CCTV1. Building on top of the baseline hypothesis, I examine whether and how satellite channels adapt their strategies under various market demand, direct competition and ability type conditions, as well as their selection of alternative strategies. Market Demand Condition Strategically competitive broadcasters should demonstrate sensitivities to different demand conditions that vary across markets. The simplest distinction of television markets is by prime time. Prime time market demand is different from that of non-prime time in two ways: (1) the prime time market has higher demand, and (2) the prime time market has a more diverse mix of audiences which offers support to greater variety of programming that otherwise would be unprofitable in non-prime time markets. 13 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Operating under the advertiser-supported revenue model, satellite channels have the highest stakes in the 7:00pm to 11:00pm prime time timeslots. Therefore, they should respond more diligently to CCTV1 programming portfolio changes in these timeslots. At the same time, the more diverse mix of audiences in prime time market offers the channels more viable space to differentiate from CCTV1. The effects of higher demand and greater audience diversity encourage and facilitate greater response from satellite channels during prime time. Therefore, I hypothesize that: H2: Satellite channels respond greater to CCTV1 programming portfolio changes during prime time. Direct Competition When two channels have significant overlaps in their target audiences, they are considered in direct competition with one another. Should a channel modifies its programming portfolio, the other should respond more if the two are direct competitors than if they are not. At the same time, the need for responding to programming portfolio changes is also dependent on the two channels’ relative abilities to capture audience. Low ability (low type) channels try harder to avoid direct competition with high ability ones (high type) through differentiating their programming portfolio. When a competitor modifies its programming portfolio, a low type channel would respond more than a high type one. 14 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Let’s apply the above argument to the Chinese television context. The Chinese national television market, M, can be considered as a composition of all province-level markets, mj, i.e. M = {m1, m2, …, mj, …}. Since advertisers prefer television channels to capture financially wealthy audiences, the economic values of each province-level market are therefore different depending on their audience’s wealth. Let vj V = {v1, v2, …, vj, …} be the value of mj and V is assumed common and known to every satellite channel. On the other hand, the ability of capturing the audience from mj is different for each satellite channel. Let cij be the cost of satellite channel i to capture the audience from mj. A higher cost cij indicates channel i has lower ability to capture audience from mj. The channels originally have private information about their types but as they interact over time they eventually learn about the types of others. Therefore I assume that cij is common knowledge. I express the profit potential ij from mj to satellite channel i as ij = ijvj – cij. The term ij [0,1] can be considered as channel i’s expectation of the fraction of mj that it can capture. Similar to the cost structure, I assume the values of ij are commonly known due to repeated interactions among the channels. Based on the expected profitability of the markets and assuming the channels care about maximizing profits, each satellite channel constructs its target market list, Ti M, that yields the highest expected combined profit for the channel. The degree of direct competition between satellite channel i and CCTV1 is reflected by the overlap of Ti and TCCTV1. 15 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang I assume that each channel possesses competitive advantage over others in capturing audience from its home-province market, i.e. cii < cji. The costs (production, marketing research, promotion, etc.) associated with offering a television program tailored to a province are likely lower for the home-province satellite channel than for those from outside provinces. Given the competitive advantage at the home market, satellite channel i will more likely to include its home market in Ti. This is especially likely if its home market is of high v. On the other hand, conditioning on a satellite channel’s ability, a low value home market will likely drive the channel to focus more on outside markets. Imagine two satellite channels, A and B, of similar ability but A is based in a high value home province while B is not. Compared to A, B has higher incentive to compete in outside markets. Since CCTV1 targets the entire national television market, B is in greater direct competition with CCTV1 than A. Given the satellite channels are strategic, B should demonstrate greater responses to CCTV1 programming portfolio changes than A. Empirically, I use province-level GDP per capita to proxy for v. GDP per capita is a frequently used, first-cut indicator of audience wealth in the advertising industry. Based on the direct competition argument, I hypothesize that: H3: Satellite channels based in high GDP per capita provinces respond less to CCTV1 programming portfolio changes. 16 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang High-Low Ability Types Besides home province market values, the degree to which a satellite responds to CCTV1 programming portfolio is also dependent on the satellite channel’s ability to capture audience. Low type channels try harder to avoid direct competition with CCTV1 through greater differentiation in their programming portfolio. However, directly measuring a satellite channel’s ability, such as its cost structure, is difficult as cost data is sparse and often unreliable. Instead, I construct a measure of home market audience dependency based on ratings as a proxy for ability. Nevertheless, since the ratings of channel i in mj is an endogenous outcome of target market strategies and abilities of all channels, this proxy deserves further elaboration. Imagine again two satellite channels, A and B. This time both are based in home province markets of similar values but they are of different ability types. Let A be the high type channel while B is the low type channel. Given their comparable home province market values, they are similarly attracted to compete in outside markets but differentially constrained by their types. When A and B are located in low GDP per capita provinces, both are attracted to outside markets but A will have greater ability than B to capture audience from outside provinces, which will be reflected in A’s ratings performance. Therefore, conditioning on home province market GDP per capita, a high type channel will have lower dependency on home province audience while a low type channel will have high dependency. Based on the argument that low ability channels try harder to differentiate from the dominant channel, I hypothesize that: 17 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang H4: Satellite channels based in lower GDP per capita provinces and have higher dependency on home province audience respond greater to CCTV1 programming portfolio changes. Niche Strategy Continuing with the example, if A and B are both based in high GDP per capita provinces, they do not face the economic pressure to compete in outside market as if they were based in low GDP per capita home markets. They have the fortune of choosing between focusing at home market – adopt a market segmentation strategy (Porter 1980) – or to compete in outside markets. In this case, the dependency of audience from home province reflects the channel’s choice of strategy rather than ability, with higher home province audience dependency reflecting the channel’s pursuit of market segmentation strategy. Should a channel adopt the market segmentation strategy, it would tailor its programming portfolio to suit the preference of the niche target audience and therefore be less sensitive towards CCTV1 portfolio changes. I hypothesize that: H5: Satellite channels based in higher GDP per capita provinces and have higher dependency on home-province audience respond less to CCTV1 programming portfolio changes. 18 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Data, Measures, and Specifications Datasets I combine three dataset for the empirical analysis. The first dataset contains complete daily programming lineups from 8am to midnight for 30 satellite channels (one for each province except Tibet) and CCTV1 from May 2002 to May 2004. The dataset includes the title of the show, the channel and date of broadcast, the start and end time of the show, and the category to which the show is classified. Sample prime time programming lineups for CCTV1, Hunan satellite channel and Shanghai satellite channel are provided in Tables 3a to 3c. Note that, unlike television programming in the US, Chinese television channels do not exactly follow hourly or half-hourly program slots. For instance, between 9pm and 10pm, CCTV1 aired a news program from 21:00 to 21:20 and a documentary from 21:24 to 21:53, while Shanghai satellite channel broadcasted a drama from 21:15 to 21:53 followed by a music video from 21:53 to 21:59, and Hunan satellite channel broadcasted a news program from 21:34 to 21:56 following an earlier drama. The second dataset contains 15-minute timeslot monthly average ratings of the 30 satellite channels in each of the 30 provincial capital cities. The programming line up and ratings datasets are collected by CSM Market Research (CSM) using peoplemeter panels.9 The ratings data are generated through stratified sampling drawn proportionally to their incidence in the population. The CSM peoplemeter is an electronic device similar to the ones used by Nielsen Media Research in the US. Attached to the television set, the peoplemeter automatically records the minute-by-minute viewing behavior of each 9 CSM Media Research (www.csm.com.cn) is subsidiary of the TNS Group (http://www.tnsglobal.com). 19 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang member in the household. These proprietary programming lineup and ratings datasets are considered reliable and are widely used by Chinese television stations, advertisers and regulators (Yuan and Webster 2006). The third dataset contains publicly available information on GDP per capita of Chinese provinces in 2002. Programming Portfolio Vector and Spatial Distance I measure the spatial distance between two channels’ programming portfolio as the angle between their program portfolio vectors in orthogonal dimensions of product space. This measure is constructed similarly to the one used by Sweeting (2006) to study US radio stations music play lists. As a stylized example, let there be only two categories of television programs – sports and drama. Say, in the 8:00pm to 8:15pm timeslot in January 2003 (total of 31days x 15min/day x 60sec/min = 27900 seconds of air time), Channel A broadcasted 9300 seconds of sports and 18600 seconds of drama while Channel B broadcasted 18600 seconds of sports and 9300 seconds of drama. The programming portfolio vectors for A and B will be [9300 18600] and [18600 9300], respectively. Using vector dot products, I calculate the angle between the two channels’ programming portfolio vectors. The angle ranges from zero to 1.5708, or /2, radians. An angle of zero radians indicates that the two channels broadcast exactly the same categories of shows, while an angle of 1.5708 radians indicates the two channels broadcast shows of completely different categories. In this example, the angle between channel A and B is 0.6435 radians. 20 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang CSM classified each program into one of 81 categories, such as domestic drama, foreign movies, weather report, etc. The programming portfolio space is therefore 81dimensional. However, the dot product calculation of the angle between the portfolio vectors and the interpretation of the radians are the same as the above stylized example. Empirical Strategy (1) Distributive Lag Models I employ a distributive lag model (Equation 1) to test the baseline hypotheses: Dijt = + Dijt-1 + (Dijt- – Dijt-( +1)) + channel_fe + timeslot_fe + year-month_fe + ijt Eq. 1 The dependent variable, Dijt, is the programming portfolio distance between satellite channel i with respect to CCTV1 in timeslot j in year-month t. The total number of observations in the dataset is 48,000 (30 satellite channels x 64 timeslots x 25 months). Distributive lag model requires lag observations which is constructed using the earlier portion of the panel dataset. Hence the actual number of observations available, depending the length of lag chosen, is less than 48,000. The key independent variables are the lag differences in spatial distance between a satellite channel and CCTV1, Dijt- – Dijt-( +1). Should CCTV1 changes its programming in a way such that it approaches a satellite channel, under differentiation strategy, the satellite channel should move away from CCTV1 in subsequent periods. The one-month lag distance variable (Dijt-1) captures the channels consistency over time about their programming portfolios. 21 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang To test hypotheses 2-5, I include the interaction terms to the distributive lag model (Equation 2). Dijt = + Dijt-1 + Dijt-1∙IndepVar + (Dijt- – Dijt-( +1)) + (Dijt- – Dijt-( +1)) ∙ IndepVar + IndepVar + channel_fe + timeslot_fe + year-month_fe +ijt Eq. 2 Three independent variables, pt, gdp and home, are interacted with the lagged spatial terms. The dummy variable pt is set to one if timeslot j falls under prime time hours from 7pm to 11pm. The variable gdp measures the per capita GDP of the satellite channel’s home province normalized by the national average. In the regressions, I used either gdp or its logged value lgdp. The reason for using logged value is to alleviate potential problems caused by the large disparities in GDP per capita between the provinces. At the extreme ends, Shanghai’s GDP per capita is over 13 times greater than Guizhou’s.10 The variable home measures the channel’s dependency on home province audience in each timeslot. To address endogeneity concerns, home is calculated by averaging the home province audience ratings in each timeslot using only the first four months of the dataset (i.e. the pre-sample portion of the dataset, from May 2002 to August 2002). Summary statistics are presented in Table 4. Geographical illustrations of gdp and mean values of home are presented in Figures 1 and 2. 10 In the US in 2006, the extreme GDP per capita states are Delaware and Mississippi, with the ratio between them at 2.46 (or 5.17 if one compares Washington DC with Mississippi). In the European Union in 2007, the extremes are those from Luxembourg and Bulgaria, with the ratio of 6.85. 22 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Distributive lag models are commonly used to investigate how past events influence current decisions or outcomes of firms (e.g. Pakes and Griliches, 1984). An advantage of using such simple model is that it allows for events that happened multiple periods ago to shape current outcomes, thus offering more insights on how time dependent decisions are made. On the other hand, there are two issues of concern with this specification. By only measuring a scalar distance between two channels, this specification will not be able to capture programming changes that do not affect the distance. For example, if CCTV1 broadcasts news only in a timeslot while a satellite channel broadcasts sports only in the first month but switches to drama only the next, the distance measure between the two channels does not change. Fortunately, this specification offers a conservative measurement of differentiation because any changes in distance will imply a change in programming strategy by at least one channel. The second concern of using the proposed specification is that it does not identify the causality of the channel positioning dynamics. Specifically, the model is silent about whether the changes in distance between two channels are caused by movements from which one. Therefore, an alternative identification strategy is required to supplement the distributive lag model. (2) CCTV1 Policy Change To address the identification concern, I test further the baseline hypothesis by studying a central government policy change that permitted CCTV1 to pursue a market-oriented programming strategy.11 Under this new policy, CCTV1 in May 2003 revamped its 11 The CCTV1 policy change is a result of the macro reform plan on the Chinese cultural industry announced by then Chinese President Jiang Zemin in his report given at the 16th Party Congress on November 8 2002. The following is an excerpt of the official English translation of his report (People’s Daily Online, Nov 18 2002): “It is necessary to push forward cultural restructuring in light of the 23 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang programming lineups by introducing television drama and entertainment shows in multiple timeslots while preserving others, such as the 7:00pm national news (xinwenlianbo). I identify satellite channels’ differentiation strategy by observing how satellite channels responded to CCTV1 programming changes subsequent to this policy. Conceptually, if the spatial location of CCTV1 programming approaches that of satellite channel i in timeslot j, a subsequent change in programming by channel i in timeslot j in such a way that their relative distance increases will lend support to the differentiation hypothesis (see Figure 3). As a concrete example, Figure 4 illustrates the programming portfolio distances between each of the 30 satellite channels with respect to CCTV1 in the 10:00-10:15am timeslot. Each small graph represents a satellite channel, with the y-axis indicating the distance from CCTV1 in radians and the x-axis indicating year-month from May 2002 to May 2004. Prior to the policy change, CCTV1 broadcasted a general news program, “News at 10:00” (xinwen 10:00). On Thursday May 1 2003, the “News at 10:00” program was replaced by a television drama. During the same period, several satellite stations were broadcasting television dramas in the 10:00-10:15am timeslot. With CCTV1 replacing the news program with a drama, the graphs indicate a discontinuous spatial distance drop characteristics of the development of socialist spiritual civilization and laws governing it and in response to the needs of the growing socialist market economy. We must lose no time in working out overall planning for cultural restructuring. We must integrate the deepening of reform with structural adjustment and promotion of development and straighten out the relationship between the government and cultural enterprises and institutions. We must build up a legal system concerning culture and intensify macrocontrol. We should deepen the internal reform of cultural enterprises and institutions and gradually establish a management system and operational mechanism favorable to arousing the initiative of cultural workers, encouraging innovation and bringing forth more top-notch works and more outstanding personnel. In compliance with the principle of both enriching culture and intensifying management, we should improve the system of markets for cultural products and their management mechanism to create a social climate favorable for a flourishing socialist culture.” 24 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang in May 2003 for those channels which also broadcasted drama. In subsequent months, there is a trend showing that these channels migrated their programming portfolio away from that of CCTV1. I study the CCTV1 policy change using a diff-in-diff model (Equation 3). Dijt = + ∙Impactij ∙PostPolicyt ∙Trendt +∙Impactij ∙PostPolicyt ∙Trendt2 + Impactij ∙PostPolicyt + PostPolicyt ∙Trendt + PostPolicyt ∙Trendt2 + Trendt + Trendt2 + PostPolicyt channel_fei + timeslot_fej + ijt Eq. 3 The Impact dummy variable indicates whether CCTV1’s new programming location has significantly approached that of satellite channel i in timeslot j. To assign Impact = 1, I compared the average distance between CCTV1 and satellite channel i in timeslot j in the three months after May 2003 with the average distance of the same from May 2002 to April 2003. If the post policy distance is 3 standard deviations less than that of the pre policy distance, then Impact is set to one, otherwise zero. I also repeat the test using 1 and 2 standard deviations as the definition for Impact. The variable Postpolicy is a dummy which equals one for observations after May 2003 and zero otherwise. The Trend integer variable ranges from 1 to 25 with May 2002 as month 1 and May 2004 as month 25. I include also a quadratic term, Trend2, to accommodate for nonlinear responses over time. The key independent variables are the interaction terms Impact ∙PostPolicy ∙Trend and Impact ∙PostPolicy ∙Trend2. If satellite channels differentiate from CCTV1, the coefficient for Impact ∙PostPolicy ∙Trend should be positive. As for the Impact ∙PostPolicy ∙Trend2 coefficient, I expect it to be negative as the new distances between the satellite channels and CCTV1 stabilize over time. 25 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Results Baseline Results (1) Distributive Lag Model The result for testing the baseline hypothesis is summarized in Table 5. The regression results confirm that satellite channels adjust the spatial distance between their own portfolios with CCTV1’s. The negative coefficients indicate that the distance between a satellite channel and CCTV1 will increase if it has experienced a decrease in previous months. I include in the model lag variables ranging from one to four months. The satellite channels respond over a period of about 3 months, indicating that portfolio adjustments take place over time instead of instantaneously. Since CCTV1’s movements over four months ago seem to have no effect on the satellite channels, I will use a 3-month window in subsequent regression models. The Durbin-Watson statistics are around 2, indicating that serial correlation problem is not significant. To address the concern that programming in one timeslot is closely related to the adjacent ones, I ran the regression with sub-samples of the data using only one timeslot in each hour. Table 6 presents the regression outputs generated by different sub-samples. They are qualitatively similar to the full sample analysis results. (2) CCTV1 Policy Change The results for the diff-in-diff model are presented in Table 7. Consistent with the differentiation prediction, the coefficients for Impact ∙PostPolicy ∙Trend and Impact 26 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang ∙PostPolicy ∙Trend2 terms are positive and negative, respectively. Using one standard deviation as the impact definition, both coefficients are statistically significant at the 1 percent level. When using two and three standard deviations for the impact definition, the signs of the coefficients remain steady but the level of significance decreases. Overall, the diff-in-diff regression results are consistent with the ones generated by the distributive lag model. Moreover, the diff-in-diff results confirmed the causality of the differentiation process between CCTV1 and the satellite channels. Other Results With the baseline hypothesis identified, I test Hypotheses 2 to 5 using the distributive lag model. The results are as follows. Market Demand Conditions (H2): The results in Table 8 show that satellite channels are more responsive to CCTV1’s programming changes in prime time hours. Compared to the baseline results, the satellite channels respond with a greater magnitude during prime time. This is particularly the case in the first month subsequent to CCTV1 programming changes. Their longer-term lagged responses (two to three months subsequent to CCTV1 programming changes) are not significantly different from those of the baseline results. Direct Competitions (H3): Recall that a lower home province market value will more likely induce a satellite channel to seek outside markets. This in turn places the satellite channel in greater direct competition with CCTV1. Under direct competition, a channel should demonstrate higher responsiveness to CCTV1 programming changes. The results 27 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang in Table 9 show the effect of home province GDP per capita on a satellite channel’s response to CCTV1 programming changes. Column (2) employs per capita GDP normalized by the national average while Column (3) employs the logged value of the normalized GDP per capita. Both sets of results show that channels with higher home market values respond less to CCTV1. When logged normalized GDP per capita was used, though the coefficient for the first month response was not statistically significant at 10 percent level, it has the predicted sign. Ability Types (H4): Lower ability satellite channels try harder to avoid direct competition with CCTV1 and therefore should differentiate more responsively. These lower ability channels are identified by their high dependencies on home market audience in the presample period. This is especially the case for those channels based in low GDP per capita provinces which give them stronger incentives to compete in outside provinces. Column (2) in Table 10 shows that under general conditions, satellite channel timeslots with higher dependencies on home market audience respond greater to CCTV1 programming changes. Column (3) further separates the channel timeslots by interacting home market audience share with home province GDP per capita. Satellite channels based in low economic value home markets clearly respond more to CCTV1 changes (e.g. coefficient for the home_cctv1_12 changed from -0.102 to -0.285). The results remain qualitatively unchanged when I used logged values of GDP per capita in column (4). Niche Strategy (H5): When a satellite channel adopts a niche strategy, it should demonstrate little response to CCTV1 programming changes. Channels based in high 28 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang value home markets have greater incentive to pursue a niche strategy and their dependency on home market audience will reflect their strategy choice. In column (3) of Table 10, the coefficient of gdp_home_cctv1_12 is positive and significant, indicating that channels based in high GDP per capita provinces with high dependency on home province market audience respond less to CCTV1 changes. Although the coefficients for gdp_home_cctv1_23 and gdp_home_cctv1_34 are negative, they are statistically insignificant. The results are stronger when I used logged values of GDP per capita in column (4). Concluding Remarks An important goal set by the Chinese government for market reform is to have SOEs adopt scientific management practices. In this study, I investigate whether the reform has led state-owned satellite television channels to implement market competitive strategy. I find the satellite channels execute spatial differentiation strategy with respect to their common dominant competitor, CCTV1, as firms in market economies would do under a DFCF industry structure. Moreover, channels exhibit sensitivities to market demand variations when implementing their strategies. Channels that compete more directly with CCTV1 for national audience demonstrate greater strategic responses. In addition, satellite channels are also aware of their own abilities when choosing and executing their strategies. The overall behavior of the satellite channels offer coherent supports that they are competing strategically. 29 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang A drawback of this study is the lack of comparison with privately-owned television channels. The absence of private operators in the Chinese television broadcasting industry prohibits this study to compare competitive strategies of the state-owned channels with those of privately-owned ones. Similarly, benchmarking of state-owned channels’ ratings and financial performances with those of private ones is not possible. On the other hand, the absence of private channels in the empirical setting demonstrates that competitions need not originate from private firms but can come from other SOEs. This speaks to the policy argument on opening up markets to private competitions, especially when the government is hesitant to involve non-state participants in industries of strategic importance. Another policy question is the welfare implications of strategic behaviors by SOEs. On one hand, the government desires SOE to be strategically competitive under the postWTO accession era. On the other hand, the execution of competitive strategies could potentially lower welfare. For instance, under strategic entry deterrence situations the incumbent firms may build excess capacities (Dixit, 1979), set predatory prices (Milgrom and Roberts, 1982), or deviate from optimal product diversification (Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977), thus causing harm to social welfare. The empirical findings in this study may shed light on SOE competitions in other Chinese industries. With improvements in transportation and communication infrastructures, many SOEs are competing with one another in the national market. Like the television channels, SOEs are often heterogeneous in terms of resources. For example, the Chinese 30 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang state-owned commercial airline industry consists of three key aviation enterprise groups – Air China, China Eastern Airlines and China Southern Airlines – along with a dozen of smaller regional airlines such as Hainan Airlines and Shanghai Airlines. They compete for domestic air travelers. Analogous to the CCTV - satellite channel relationship, there exist significant resource heterogeneity between the three key airlines operating under the central government umbrella and the fringe airlines supported mainly by province-level governments (Fernandez and Fernandez-Stembridge, 2007). For private firms operating in China, understanding SOE competitive strategy is essential since many key industries are occupied by incumbent SOEs (Nolan, 2001). The failure of multinational oil companies like Exxon and BP in competing with the two SOE oil industry groups – China National Petroleum Corporation and China Petroleum Group – for the Chinese petroleum market is a classic example (Peng, 2000). Finally, after thirty years of SOE reform, the Chinese government continues to search for policy directions. A Wall Street Journal article in January 2008 wrote, “fundamental differences are emerging within the Chinese government about how best to modernize a key industry.”12 The diversity of China’s industries and the pace at which the country is changing offer a fertile field for business strategy and government policy research. 12 “Government Divided Over Air China”, Wall Street Journal, January 9, 2008. 31 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang References Bai, C.E., D.D. Li and Y. Wang (1997). “Enterprise Productivity and Efficiency: When Is Up Really Down?”, Journal of Comparative Economics 24: 265-280. Beebe, J.H. (1977). “Institutional Structure and Program Choices in Television Markets”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 91(1): 15-37. Boisot, M. and J. Child (1988). “The Iron Law of Fiefs: Bureaucratic Failure and the Problem of Governance in the Chinese Economic Reforms”, Administrative Science Quarterly 33(4): 507-527. Blue Book of China’s Media (2007), Tsinghua University and Social Science Documentation Publishing House. Beijing. Chen D. and G.O. Faure (1995). “When Chinese Companies Negotiate with Their Government”, Organization Studies 16(27): 27-54. China Statistical Yearbook (2007). National Bureau of Statistics of China. China TV Rating Yearbook (2003). Beijing Broadcasting Institute. Beijing. China TV Rating Yearbook (2004). Huaxia Publishing Company Ltd. Beijing. China TV Rating Yearbook (2005). Communication University of China. Beijing. China TV Rating Yearbook (2006). Communication University of China. Beijing. Dixit, A. (1979). “A Model of Duopoly Suggesting a Theory of Entry Barriers”, Bell Journal of Economics 10(1): 20-32. Dixit, A. and J. Stiglitz (1977). “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity”, American Economic Review 67(3): 297-308. Fernandez J.A. and L. Fernandez-Stembridge (2007). China’s State-Owned Enterprise Reforms: An Industrial and CEO Approach, New York: Routledge. Gordon, R.H. and W. Li (1991). “Chinese Enterprise Behavior under the Reforms”, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 81(2): 202-206. Grossman, S. and O. Hart (1986). “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration”, Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691-720. Groves, T., Y. Hong, J. Mcmillan and B. Naughton (1994). “Autonomy and Incentives in Chinese State Enterprises”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(1): 183-209. 32 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Hassard J., J. Sheehan, M. Zhou, J. Terpstra-Tong and J. Morris (2007). China’s State Enterprise Reform: From Marx to the Market, New York: Routledge. Heracieous, L. (2001). “When Local Beat Global: The Chinese Beer Industry”, Business Strategy Review 12(3): 37-45. Holmstrom, B. (1982). “Moral Hazards in Teams”, Bell Journal of Economics 13(2): 324-340. Hoskisson, R. E., L. Eden, C. M. Lau and M. Wright (2000). “Strategy in Emerging Economies”, Academy of Management Journal 43(3): 249-267. Hotelling, H. (1929). “Stability in Competition”, Economic Journal 39(153): 41-57. International Monetary Fund (2003). China Competing in the Global Economy, W. Tseng and M. Rodlauer (eds.), IMF. Jefferson, G.H., T.G. Rawski, L.Wang and Y. Zheng (2000). “Ownership, Productivity Change, and Financial Performance in Chinese Industry,” Journal of Comparative Economics 28: 786-813. Li, W. (1997). “The Impact of Economic Reform on the Performance of Chinese State Enterprises, 1980-1989,” Journal of Political Economy 105(5): 1080-1106. Lin J.Y., F. Cai, and Z. Li (1998). “Competition, Policy Burdens, and State-Owned Enterprise Reform”, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 88(2): 422-427. Lin J.Y., F. Cai, and Z. Li (2001). State-Owned Enterprise Reform in China, Chinese University Press: Hong Kong. Levy, B. and P. Spiller (eds) (1996). Regulations, Institutions and Commitment: Comparative Studies of Telecommunications, New York: Cambridge University Press. Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1977). “Predation, Reputation, and Entry Deterrence”, Journal of Economic Theory 27: 280-312. Nolan, P. (1995). China’s Rise, Russia’s Fall: Politics, Economics and Planning in the Transition from Stalinism, Basingstoke: Macmillan. Nolan, P. (2001). China and the Global Economy, Palgrave: New York. North, D. (1991). “Institutions”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1): 97-112. Oi, J.C. (2005). “Patterns of Corporate Restructuring in China: Political Constraints on Privatization”, China Journal 53: 115-136. 33 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Pakes, A. and Z. Griliches (1984). “Estimating Distributed Lags in Short Panels with an Application to the Specification of Depreciation Patterns and Capital Stock Constructs”, Review of Economic Studies 51(2): 243-62. Peng, M. W. (2000). Business Strategies in Transition Economies, Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications. Peng, M. W., Y. Lu, O. Shenkar and D. Y. L. Wang (2001). “Treasures in the China House – A Review of Management and Organizational Research on Greater China”, Journal of Business Research 52: 95-110. Porter, M.E. (1980). Competitive Strategy. New York: Free Press. Qian, Y. (1999). “The Institutional Foundations of China’s Market Transition”, paper prepared for the World Bank’s Annual Conference on Development Economics, 28-30 April, Washington DC. Qian, Y. (2000). “The Process of China’s Market Transition (1978-1998): The Evolutionary, Historical, and Comparative Perspectives”, Journal of International and Theoretical Economics 156(1): 151-171. Qian, Y. (2002). “How Reform Worked in China”, Working Paper, William Davidson Institute, No. 473. Qian, Y. and G. Roland (1998). “Federalism and the Soft Budget Constraint”, American Economic Review 88(5): 1143-1162. Sappington, D. (1991), “Incentives in Principal-Agent Relationships”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(2): 45-66. Shirley, M.M. (1999). “Bureaucrats in Business: The Role of Privatization versus Corporatization in State-Owned Enterprise Reform”, World Development 27(1): 115-136. Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny (1994). “Politicians and Firms”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(4): 995-1025. Spence, A. M. and B. M. Owen (1977). “Television Programming, Monopolistic Competition and Welfare”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91:103-126. Steiner, P.O. (1952). “Program Patterns and Preferences, and the Workability of Competition in Radio Broadcasting”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 66(2): 194-223. Sweeting, A. (2006) “Too Much Rock and Roll? Station Ownership, Programming and Listenership in the Music Radio Industry”, Working Paper. 34 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Tan, J.J. and R.J. Litschert (1994). “Environment-Strategy Relationship and Its Performance Implications: An Empirical Study of the Chinese Electronics Industry”, Strategic Management Journal 15: 1-20. Tiedge, J.T. and K.J. Ksobiech (1986). “The ‘Lead-In’ Strategy for Prime-Time TV: Does It Increase the Audience?”, Journal of Communication, 36(3): 51-63. Walker, J.R. (1988). “Inheritance Effect in the New Media Environment”, Journal of Broadcasting and Electronic Media 32(4): 391-401. Wang, J. (2006). Strategic Challenges and Strategic Response: The Transformation of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises, Oxford: Chandos Publishing Waterman, D. (1990). “Diversity, Quality, and Homogenization of Information Products in a Monopolistically Competitive Industry”, Unpublished manuscript. Webster, J.G. (1985), “Program Audience Duplication: A Study of Television Inheritance Effects”, Journal of Broadcasting and Electronic Media 29(2): 121-133. White, S. (2000). “Competition, Capabilities, and the Make, Buy, or Ally Decisions of Chinese State-Owned Firms”, Academy of Management Journal 43(3): 324-341. Wildman, S. S., and B. Owen (1985). “Program Competition, Diversity and Multichannel Bundling in the New Video Industry”, in Video Media Competition: Regulation, Economics, and Technology, ed. E. M. Noam. New York: Columbia University Press. Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New York: Free Press. Williamson, O.E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, New York: Free Press. World Bank (1997). Bureaucrats in Bossiness: The Economics and Politics of Government Ownership. Washington, DC: Oxford University Press. Wright, M., I. Filatotchev, R. E. Hoskisson, M. W. Peng (2005). “Strategy Research in Emerging Economies: Challenging the Conventional Wisdom”, Journal of Management Studies 42(1): 1-33. Yuan, E.J. and J.G. Webster (2006). “Channel Repertoires: Using Peoplemeter Data in Beijing”, Journal of Broadcasting & Electronic Media 50(3): 524-536. Zhang, Y. (2008). Large Chinese State-Owned Enterprises: Corporatization and Strategic Development, New York: Palgrave Macmillan 35 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Table 1 Satellite Television Household Coverage Year 2002 2003 2004 2005 National Household Coverage (percent) Urban Rural 89 40.2 89.2 42.1 89.5 58.1 89.6 71.8 Source: 2006 China TV Rating Yearbook Table 2 Audience Market Shares (%) Channels All CCTV Channels Provincial Satellite Others* 2002 Year 2003 2004 31.9 14.7 53.4 32.2 16.0 51.8 33.4 16.7 49.7 Source: 2006 China TV Rating Yearbook, p.227. * Others include province-level non-satellite channels, city- and township-level channels, and education channels. 36 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Table 3a Sample CCTV1 Prime Time Programming Lineup Wednesday January 15 2003 7:00pm – 11:00pm Title Start End Category National News 19:00:00 19:30:00 General News Commercials 19:30:00 19:31:05 Commercials Weather Forecast 19:31:05 19:35:20 Weather Forecast Commercials 19:35:20 19:38:50 Commercials Jiaodian Interview 19:38:50 19:50:50 News Commentary Commercials 19:50:50 19:57:40 Commercials Technology Expo 19:57:40 20:02:10 General Science Commercials 20:02:10 20:04:00 Commercials Da Shi 20:04:00 20:54:02 Domestic Drama Commercials 20:54:02 21:00:05 Commercials Xianzaibobao 21:00:05 21:20:00 General News Commercials 21:20:00 21:22:45 Commercials Program Guide 21:22:45 21:23:45 Program Guide Commercials 21:23:45 21:24:20 Commercials Around the World 21:24:20 21:53:45 Documentary Others Program Guide 21:53:45 21:54:45 Program Guide Commercials 21:54:45 22:00:00 Commercials World Report 22:00:00 22:17:00 General News Commercials 22:17:00 22:20:00 Commercials Nightly News 22:20:00 22:30:00 General News Commercials 22:30:00 22:32:00 Commercials Sports News 22:32:00 22:42:00 Sports News Commercials 22:42:00 22:47:00 Commercials Weather Forecast 22:47:00 22:52:00 Weather Forecast Commercials 22:52:00 22:56:00 Commercials Program Guide 22:56:00 22:57:00 Program Guide 37 Richard Wang Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Table 3b Sample Hunan Satellite Channel Prime Time Programming Lineup Wednesday January 15 2003 7:00pm – 11:00pm Title Start End Category National News 19:00:00 19:30:00 General News Commercials 19:30:00 19:33:00 Commercials 2003 NPC &CPPCC Conference 19:33:00 19:38:04 News Commentary Commercials 19:38:04 19:42:18 Commercials Qinshenshen Yumengmeng 19:42:18 20:35:35 Domestic Drama Commercials 20:35:35 20:40:29 Commercials Qinshenshen Yumengmeng 20:40:29 21:29:01 Domestic Drama Commercials 21:29:01 21:34:49 Commercials Nightly News 21:34:49 21:56:00 General News Xindongli Xinfazhan 21:56:00 22:10:59 Interview Commercials 22:10:59 22:15:16 Commercials Weather Station 22:15:16 22:17:46 Weather Forecast Commercials 22:17:46 22:18:54 Commercials Heibing 22:18:54 23:15:45 Domestic Drama Table 3c Sample Shanghai Satellite Channel Prime Time Programming Lineup Wednesday January 15 2003 7:00pm – 11:00pm Title Start End Category Nightly Sports News 19:00:00 19:30:00 Sports News Commercials 19:30:00 19:33:00 Commercials Renzai Shanghai 19:33:00 19:57:00 Documentary Commercials 19:57:00 20:00:00 Commercials Shanghai Satellite Channel News 20:00:00 20:27:50 General News Commercials 20:27:50 20:28:20 Commercials Weather Forecast 20:28:20 20:30:00 Weather Forecast Commercials 20:30:00 20:34:25 Commercials Dafuqingzhai 20:34:25 21:13:10 Domestic Drama Commercials 21:13:10 21:15:45 Commercials Dafuqingzhai 21:15:45 21:53:45 Domestic Drama Song of the Week 21:53:45 21:59:00 Music Others News At Ten 21:59:00 22:23:02 Foreign Language News Commercials 22:23:02 22:26:01 Commercials Weather Forecast 22:26:01 22:27:00 Weather Forecast Commercials 22:27:00 22:30:00 Commercials Nightline News 22:30:00 23:09:27 General News * Note: The original dataset contains title and category data in Chinese. The author translated the data into English. 38 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Table 4 Summary Statistics Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max 10% 25% 50% 75% 90% # of Unique Values Distance between cctv1 and satellite channel i in timeslot j in year-month t 48000 1.2071 0.4764 0 1.5708 .3565 .9746 1.4559 1.5669 1.5708 37372 cctv1_1 One month lag of cctv1 46080 1.2101 0.4741 0.0000 1.5708 0.3656 0.9817 1.4576 1.5669 1.5708 35937 cctv1_12 Difference in cctv1 between year-month t-1 and t-2 44160 -0.0033 0.2322 -1.5523 1.5708 -0.1862 -0.0358 0.0000 0.0394 0.1921 38135 cctv1_23 Difference in cctv1 between year-month t-2 and t-3 42240 -0.0032 0.2355 -1.5523 1.5708 -0.1879 -0.0366 0.0000 0.0401 0.1979 36468 cctv1_34 Difference in cctv1 between year-month t-3 and t-4 40320 -0.0036 0.2370 -1.5523 1.5708 -0.1919 -0.0364 0.0000 0.0414 0.2006 34774 pt Prime Time Timeslots Dummy (pt = 1 if timeslot j falls in 7:00pm – 11:00pm; 0 otherwise) 48000 0.2500 0.4330 0 1 - - - - - 2 gdp 2002 Provincial Per Capita GDP divided by National Average Per Capita GDP 48000 1.5604 1.2898 0.4602 6.0951 0.7308 0.8569 1.0699 1.7459 3.0035 30 lgdp Log of gdp 48000 0.2292 0.5976 -0.7761 1.8075 -0.3139 -0.1545 0.0675 0.5572 1.0909 30 home Average ratio of home market audience to total audience received by satellite channel i in timeslot j; Data taken in pre-sample period from May to August 2002 48000 0.3075 0.2374 0.0000 0.9833 0.0603 0.1178 0.2273 0.4638 0.6741 1918 Variable Description Dep. Variable cctv1 Indep. Variables 39 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Table 5 Baseline Differentiation Strategy (OLS) Dependent Variable: Distance in radians between satellite channel i w.r.t. to CCTV1 in timeslot j in month t. cctv1_12 (1) (2) (3) (4) -0.122*** (0.010) -0.148*** (0.011) -0.101*** (0.008) -0.164*** (0.012) -0.122*** (0.011) -0.048*** (0.009) 0.824*** (0.009) 0.223*** (0.019) 44160 0.805 1.975 0.836*** (0.008) 0.255*** (0.019) 42240 0.805 1.906 0.851*** (0.008) 0.204*** (0.017) 40320 0.811 1.980 -0.175*** (0.014) -0.123*** (0.013) -0.048*** (0.011) 0.010 (0.010) 0.844*** (0.009) 0.214*** (0.019) 38400 0.808 1.898 cctv1_23 cctv1_34 cctv1_45 cctv1_1 Constant Observations R-squared Durbin-Watson All regressions include channel fixed effects, timeslot fixed effects, and year-month fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses; SE clustered by channels. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Table 6 Baseline Differentiation Strategy (Sub-Sampling Timeslot by Quarter Hour) (1) Baseline result (Column (3) of Table 1-1). (2) Data from top of hour timeslots (quarter=1) (3) Data from 2nd quarter of hour timeslots (quarter=2) (4) Data from 3rd quarter of hour timeslots (quarter=3) (5) Data from bottom of hour timeslots (quarter=4) Dependent Variable: Distance in radians between satellite channel i w.r.t. to CCTV1 in timeslot j in month t. cctv1_12 cctv1_23 cctv1_34 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) -0.164*** (0.012) -0.122*** (0.011) -0.048*** (0.009) -0.180*** (0.023) -0.107*** (0.018) -0.084*** (0.017) 0.032** (0.014) 0.874*** (0.009) 0.180*** (0.018) 9600 0.850 -0.153*** (0.012) -0.145*** (0.014) -0.051*** (0.012) -0.007 (0.013) 0.842*** (0.014) 0.232*** (0.021) 9600 0.840 -0.165*** (0.017) -0.140*** (0.013) -0.034** (0.015) 0.009 (0.012) 0.817*** (0.011) 0.272*** (0.019) 9600 0.743 -0.178*** (0.021) -0.076*** (0.020) -0.011 (0.017) 0.019 (0.016) 0.815*** (0.021) 0.084*** (0.015) 9600 0.762 cctv1_45 cctv1_1 Constant Observations R-squared 0.851*** (0.008) 0.204*** (0.017) 40320 0.811 All regressions include channel fixed effects, timeslot fixed effects, and year-month fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses; SE clustered by channels. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 40 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Table 7 Baseline Differentiation Strategy (Diff-in-Diff) Dependent Variable: Distance in radians between satellite channel i w.r.t. to CCTV1 in timeslot j in month t. (1) i01pt i01pt2 (2) 0.086*** (0.019) -0.002*** (0.000) i02pt 0.065*** (0.022) -0.001** (0.001) i02pt2 i03pt 0.066** (0.029) -0.002* (0.001) i03pt2 i01p -1.330*** (0.173) i02p -1.128*** (0.195) i03p trend trend2 postpolicy pt pt2 constant Observations R-squared (3) 0.024*** (0.003) -0.002*** (0.000) 0.341*** (0.076) -0.045*** (0.008) 0.003*** (0.000) 1.245*** (0.075) 48000 0.519 0.024*** (0.003) -0.002*** (0.000) 0.174** (0.067) -0.033*** (0.007) 0.002*** (0.000) 1.258*** (0.075) 48000 0.508 -1.062*** (0.270) 0.024*** (0.003) -0.002*** (0.000) 0.085 (0.073) -0.028*** (0.008) 0.002*** (0.000) 1.280*** (0.075) 48000 0.492 All regressions include channel fixed effects and timeslot fixed effects fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses; SE clustered by channels * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% i01 dummy=1 when impact above 1SD for the channel_timeslot i02 dummy=1 when impact above 2SD for the channel_timeslot i03 dummy=1 when impact above 3SD for the channel_timeslot p, postpolicy dummy=1 when year-month is after May 2003, indicating post-policy t, trend time trend integer with May 2002 as 1 and May 2004 as 25 t2, trend2 square of t 41 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Table 8 Sensitivity to Prime Time Market Demand Conditions For comparison, column (1) is the baseline result (Column (3) of Table 1-1). Dependent Variable: Distance in radians between satellite channel i w.r.t. to CCTV1 in timeslot j in month t. cctv1_12 cctv1_23 cctv1_34 (1) (2) -0.164*** (0.012) -0.122*** (0.011) -0.048*** (0.009) -0.118*** (0.015) -0.119*** (0.013) -0.044*** (0.014) -0.146*** (0.023) -0.027 (0.019) -0.017 (0.020) 0.855*** (0.009) -0.187*** (0.018) -0.013 (0.016) 0.197*** (0.018) 40320 0.812 pt_cctv1_12 pt_cctv1_23 pt_cctv1_34 cctv1_1 0.851*** (0.008) pt pt_cctv1_1 Constant Observations R-squared 0.204*** (0.017) 40320 0.811 All regressions include channel fixed effects, timeslot fixed effects, and year-month fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses; SE clustered by channels. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 42 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Table 9 Sensitivity to Direct Competition with CCTV1 Dependent Variable: Distance in radians between satellite channel i w.r.t. to CCTV1 in timeslot j in month t. (1) (2) (3) Baseline regression results for comparison (Hypothesis 1) Effect of home province GDP per capita (H3: Direct Competition Hypothesis) Similar to (2) but employ Log GDP per capita cctv1_12 cctv1_23 cctv1_34 (1) (2) (3) -0.164*** (0.012) -0.122*** (0.011) -0.048*** (0.009) -0.200*** (0.017) -0.152*** (0.011) -0.070*** (0.014) 0.023** (0.009) 0.018*** (0.006) 0.013*** (0.004) -0.172*** (0.011) -0.132*** (0.010) -0.056*** (0.010) gdp_cctv1_12 gdp_cctv1_23 gdp_cctv1_34 lgdp_cctv1_12 lgdp_cctv1_23 lgdp_cctv1_34 cctv1_1 0.851*** (0.008) gdp_cctv1_1 0.844*** (0.010) 0.004 (0.003) lgdp_cctv1_1 Constant Observations R-squared 0.204*** (0.017) 40320 0.811 0.208*** (0.018) 40320 0.812 0.037 (0.024) 0.041** (0.016) 0.030** (0.012) 0.848*** (0.008) 0.011* (0.006) 0.211*** (0.018) 40320 0.812 All regressions include channel fixed effects, timeslot fixed effects, and year-month fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses; SE clustered by channels. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Note: Full data sample from May 2002 – May 2004; Data from May 2002 – August 2002 are used to construct the presample “homeshare” data; Data from September 2002 – May 2004 are used in the regressions: (30channels x 64timeslots x 21months = 40,320obs) 43 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Table 10 Ability Types and Niche Strategy Dependent Variable: Distance in radians between satellite channel i w.r.t. to CCTV1 in timeslot j in month t. cctv1_12 cctv1_23 cctv1_34 (1) (2) (3) (4) -0.164*** (0.012) -0.122*** (0.011) -0.048*** (0.009) -0.132*** (0.015) -0.126*** (0.018) -0.055*** (0.018) -0.102* (0.058) 0.017 (0.050) 0.027 (0.047) -0.118*** (0.023) -0.172*** (0.034) -0.072** (0.034) -0.285*** (0.076) 0.017 (0.078) -0.001 (0.077) 0.073** (0.031) -0.046 (0.042) -0.008 (0.035) -0.001 (0.013) 0.045* (0.024) 0.019 (0.018) -0.117*** (0.015) -0.121*** (0.019) -0.051** (0.019) -0.218*** (0.057) -0.041 (0.049) -0.016 (0.052) home_cctv1_12 home_cctv1_23 home_cctv1_34 gdp_home_cctv1_12 gdp_home_cctv1_23 gdp_home_cctv1_34 gdp_cctv1_12 gdp_cctv1_23 gdp_cctv1_34 lgdp_home_cctv1_12 lgdp_home_cctv1_23 lgdp_home_cctv1_34 lgdp_cctv1_12 lgdp_cctv1_23 lgdp_cctv1_34 home -0.044* (0.024) gdp_home Constant Observations R-squared 0.204*** (0.017) 40320 0.811 0.220*** (0.015) 40320 0.811 -0.043 (0.032) -0.002 (0.014) 0.220*** (0.017) 40320 0.812 0.218*** (0.077) -0.019 (0.080) 0.015 (0.069) -0.028 (0.026) 0.056 (0.041) 0.025 (0.032) -0.040 (0.027) -0.008 (0.025) 0.220*** (0.017) 40320 0.812 All regressions include channel fixed effects, timeslot fixed effects, and year-month fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses; SE clustered by channels. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Note: Full data sample from May 2002 – May 2004; Data from May 2002 – August 2002 are used to construct the presample homeshare (home) data; Data from September 2002 – May 2004 are used in the regressions: (30channels x 64timeslots x 21months = 40,320 obs) 44 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Figure 1 GDP Per Capita Distribution of Chinese Provinces 2002 Figure 2 Mean Ratings Dependency on Home Province Market Audience MayAugust 2002 45 Competitive Strategy of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Richard Wang Figure 3 CCTV1 Policy Change Setting Spatial Distance between CCTV1 and Satellite Channel i in timeslot j Year-Month Graphical illustration of baseline hypothesis (H1). The vertical axis represents the distance between a satellite channel and CCTV1. The horizontal axis represents time (between May 2002 – May 2005). The vertical dotted line marks the CCTV1 policy shift in May 2003. Figure 4 CCTV1 Policy Change at the 10:00-10:15am Timeslot 46