The Impact of Contingent Liabilities upon Government Solvency: The Case of Colombia Abstract The accumulation of contingent liabilities, which may be overlooked in the traditional fiscal analyses limited to flow variables such as the budget deficit, may result in higher vulnerability and hidden fiscal risks. Empirical literature has revealed the faults in the traditional deficit measurements as they overlook off-budget liabilities. These contingent liabilities render government solvency vulnerable to shocks; namely, exogenous or endogenous events which result in an unexpected drain of government resources. This paper presents a theoretical model in which these shocks are included as a “jump” in the country’s solvency constraint. in such a way that a country with an apparently sound fiscal stance, can suddenly be deemed insolvent. This fact is exemplified further with an analysis of Colombia’s fiscal imbalances, where despite having traditionally low levels of deficit and debt, the inclusion of contingent and implicit liabilities in the public sector’s balance sheet results in a negative net worth of approximately 90% of GDP. 1 1. Motivation The sustainability of public finances lies at the core of sound macroeconomic policy-making. The concept of fiscal sustainability is associated with the risk of debt default. It is intrinsically a dynamic concept as it entails complying with the government’s intertemporal budget constraint. This ultimately requires for the current net market value of debt to be smaller than the present discounted value of current and future government surpluses. Hence, a fiscal financial programme is sustainable if it ensures the solvency of the government (Buiter, 2003). According to Bean and Buiter, cited by Blejer and Cheasty (1991): “ A government is solvent if its spending programme, its tax transfer programme and its planned future use of seigniorage are consistent with its outstanding, initial, financial and real assets and liabilities (in the sense that the present value of its spending programme is equal to its comprehensive net worth).” (pg 1668). However, the public sector in reality is more than the national central entity that extracts taxes and undertakes expenditure. It comprises public enterprises, the public share of the social security system, subnational levels of government, and it should also include the guarantees issued to concessions of infrastructure projects undertaken by the private sector, as well as contingencies like the eventual bailouts to the financial system, or rescue operations of public enterprises. The definition of solvency should therefore include this broader understanding of the public sector, since the sources of uncertainty and the magnitude of eventual financial setbacks can be bigger than those directly related to the functioning of the central government. Therefore fiscal sustainability directly depends on the government’s net worth and hence demands the construction of a comprehensive consolidated public sector balance sheet. This implies that a complete and accurate picture of sustainability of the public finances should include all financial assets and liabilities of the general government, including all off budget expenditures and receipts, such as contingent claims and liabilities (Buiter, 2003). 2 Explicit contingent liabilities constitute legal obligations of the government to undertake certain expenditures if a particular event occurs, and are not directly associated with any budgetary programme. “A government’s commitment to accept obligations contingent on future events amounts to a hidden subsidy and may cause immediate distortions in the markets and result in a major unexpected drain on government finances in the future” (Polackova, 1998). Additionally, implicit contingent liabilities are associated with expectations of government intervention, leading to a problem of moral hazard, the scope of which depends on the magnitude of government led minimisation of market failures, and of financial setbacks in branches of the public administration. The importance of taking into consideration both explicit and implicit contingent liabilities when determining the sustainability of fiscal policy is evidenced by the fact that these have the power to dramatically and rapidly alter the perspective of a government’s solvency. While a nation may appear to be solvent at some point in time, liabilities triggered by a determined event at an uncertain moment may suddenly deem it insolvent. In this context, “liabilities” should be understood as net-liabilities, or changes in public sector net worth, since the solvency condition can be affected by variations in both assets and liabilities. The latter sets forth the dynamic nature of fiscal policy making and the importance of efficient risk allocation through time. This in turn supports a stock (intertemporal) based approach towards fiscal policy making, related to public sector net worth, as opposed to an analysis limited to the achievement of flow variable targets such as debt and deficit levels. A flow approach to fiscal sustainability disregards the fact that the issuance of contingent liabilities may not impact the current budget, while having severe cash-flow implications for the future, which under a dynamic analysis may reveal a situation of insolvency (Easterly, 1999). The reduction of current deficits through time reallocation of revenue and expenditure flows may overlook or even elevate fiscal risks. Apparently sound financial fiscal packages may favour budget programmes that do not immediately require cash, temporarily hiding the underlying fiscal cost. This implies that short–term flow stability does not necessarily mean fiscal sustainability. Prudent fiscal policy making must be based upon dynamically efficient strategies. Such strategies need to be based upon a comprehensive public sector balance sheet, 3 which incorporates the stocks of contingent liabilities and assets (i.e. the present discounted value –PDV- of tax revenues or contributions to the public social security system, which can be also subject to shocks). This should allow for the evaluation of risk exposure through time, according to the costs of providing for such risks and the State’s ability to manage risk and absorb contingent losses. The purpose of this paper is to expose the fragility of government solvency due to the presence of contingent liabilities. It will be shown how the accumulation of contingent and implicit liabilities mounts to a hidden risk, not perceived in annual flow variables. The latter provides evidence for how traditional budget deficit measures can lead to misleading results regarding long term fiscal policy sustainability. The paper is divided into 7 sections including this motivation. The next section presents the international evidence on public sector contingent liabilities, a topic which recently has received growing attention. Section 3 deals with the impact of contingent and implicit liabilities upon government solvency within the framework of a theoretical model of sovereign debt, following the set-up used by Miller and Zhang (1999). Contingent liabilities are introduced as shocks upon the government’s capacity to pay its debt. These are modelled as jumps which follow a Poisson process. Such a framework evidences how contingent liabilities affect a government’s solvency through their impact upon the solvency constraint. A particular case in which contingent and implicit liabilities can deem a country insolvent is illustrated in section 4, where an amplified version of Colombia’s public sector balance sheet, including such liabilities, results in a negative net worth of approximately 90% of GDP. An identification of the most important contingent and implicit liabilities, the manner in which these have been accumulated is the subject of section 5. Section 6 discusses the institutional arrangements devised to control them, and section 7 concludes. 4 2. International Evidence of the Relevance of Contingent Liabilities Contingent liabilities represent a major source of fiscal risk, as uncertain events trigger a substantial drain of governments’ resources when they are compelled to assume off-budget obligations. Recent examples provide evidence of the manner in which contingent liabilities have represented an important challenge to government finances. According to Polackova and Shick (2002), the explicit and implicit government insurance schemes in the domestic banking sector that emerged from the 1997 financial crisis in East Asia added approximately 50% of GDP to the stock of government debt in Indonesia, 30% in Thailand and over 20% in Japan and Korea. Similar schemes in the 1980’s generated a fiscal cost of over 40% of GDP in Chile and approximately 25% in Cote de Ivoire, Uruguay and Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela. In the 1990’s, Brazil and Argentina exhibited an escalation in their debt levels as the central government had to bail out commitments made at sub-national government levels. Malaysia, Mexico and Pakistan presented a severe deterioration in their fiscal stances due to defaults on government guarantees that had been issued to promote private participation in infrastructure. Furthermore, Kharas and Mishra (1999) find that the inclusion of contingent liabilities in the analysis of fiscal imbalances provides evidence supporting a relation between budget deficits and currency crises. According to these authors “the lack of evidence on the relationship between currency crises and budget deficits has arisen primarily because budget deficits as measured and reported do not truly reflect the actual fiscal position of the countries”. Blejer and Cheasty (1991) provide an analysis of deficit measurement and state that the deficit has tended to be restricted to a summary of government transactions during a single budget period, usually one year, disregarding their long run implications. Hence fiscal policy analysis based upon conventional deficit measures represents a flow approach to fiscal sustainability, which they assert can be “misleading and inadequate”. Based upon the deficiencies of traditional deficit measures in analyzing a country’s fiscal stance, Blejer and Cheasty (1991) promote balance-sheet-based deficit measures which are consistent with the dynamic framework of fiscal policy. Namely, they support a stock approach to public finances as it provides an intertemporal rather than annual framework. Such an approach stresses the 5 incidence of contingent liabilities upon fiscal sustainability, evidencing its effects on fiscal imbalances, which can’t be observed in the short run. According to Blejer and Cheasty (1991), the conventional deficit can be severely affected by revenues which create liabilities for the future or expenditures which represent the liquidation of past liabilities. This evidences the vulnerability of such measure to shocks, which in turn poses great risks upon government solvency. For example, higher social insurance contributions, which are accounted for as higher revenues may overstate the government’s ability to pay as they actually confer entitlements on contributors and as such commit the government to higher future spending. On the other hand, they are contingent claims, depending on demographic changes and susceptible to variations in government legislation, hence the magnitude of the outlays is difficult to determine. Such problems are exacerbated when dealing with unfunded pension schemes. An additional example is provided by the way the conventional deficit can dramatically be elevated in any year by a government’s payment of previously guaranteed debt or insurance contracts, such as exchange guarantees or bail outs of underwritten entities, such as insolvent public enterprises. The government usually fails to make provisions for expected defaults, hence “the costs of risk bearing are not spread out over the life of the risk, but are charged only upon realization of the risk’s downside” (Blejer and Cheasty 1991). Hence the same authors conclude that “[…] at any time the conventional deficit provides an over-optimistic indicator of government’s long-run ability to pay, because it does not factor in the expected future cost of entitlements and contingent liabilities assumed by government. Moreover, the calculation of the expected cost of contingent claims is complicated by the possibility of moral hazard.” Taking into consideration the deficiencies of conventional deficit measures, Kharas and Mishra (1999) construct an alternative measure denominated the actuarial budget deficit, which is a stock concept, and name the difference between the two the hidden deficit. The authors show that hidden deficits have stemmed mainly from the cost of realization of contingent liabilities and realized risks in the government debt portafolio. Subsequently they provide empirical evidence of currency crisis being systematically linked to the size of hidden deficits for Malaysia, Indonesia, Korea, Philippines and Thailand. This is particularly important considering that all of these countries exhibited either small budget deficits or surpluses. 6 Hence, it can be seen that contingent liabilities, have dramatic effects upon flow variables such as the traditional deficit, thereby representing a major source of instability while challenging government solvency. Conventional flow variables do not provide a complete picture of a country’s fiscal stance, making the accumulation of hidden liabilities possible and therefore elevating an unperceived fiscal risk. The consequences of this are only appreciated in the long run, when they entail substantial fiscal costs. 7 3. The Model A flow budget identity, which determines the levels of debt and deficit, while useful for assessing the fiscal stance at any given moment in time, does not highlight the dynamic nature of the financing constraint that the public sector typically faces (Agenor and Montiel, 1996; Kotlikoff, 1999 and 1993; Poterba, 1997). The sustainability of fiscal policy is determined by the government’s compliance of an intertemporal budget constraint. The latter can be expressed in terms of a solvency constraint: D s g s e r s t ds t (1) Where D is the stock of total public debt, τs is tax revenue at time s, gs is government expenditure at time s and r is the real interest rate. According to equation 1, a government is solvent if the present discounted value of future resources available to it for debt service is at least equal to the face value of its initial stock of debt. If this holds, the government will be able to service its debt on market terms (Agenor and Montiel, 1996). Nevertheless, equation (1) is deterministic and hence doesn’t account for the risk or uncertainty which may be associated to the government’s expenditures and revenues. Hence complying with equation 1 doesn’t imply that the government will remain to be solvent in the event of a contingency which demands a sudden increase in government expenditure. As it will be exhibited through an example of Colombia’s finances, a country’s net worth will be more exposed to such contingencies, the more contingent liabilities it has accumulated. Contingent and direct implicit liabilities mount to hidden liabilities which attempt against government solvency by increasing its vulnerability to shocks. With the purpose of theoretically illustrating the effects of contingent liabilities upon the solvency constraint, Miller and Zhang’s (1999) version of Bartolini and Dixit’s (1991) model of sovereign debt will be used as an analytical framework. Hence equation (1) can be re-written as: 8 D X s e r s t ds (2) t where Xs = s g s , and is reinterpreted as the country’s capacity to pay its debt. Assuming that the country’s capacity to pay exhibits a growth rate of µ so that: X t X t dt it is obtained that t X s er s t ds = (3)1 Xt , thereby the solvency constraint is reduced to: r D Xt r (4) Hence a country is considered to be solvent as long as its stock of debt is less than the present discounted value of its capacity to pay (W); D W . When X t rD (and µ is positive), the country is always able to service its debt in full out of current surplus. But, when Xt<rD, full payment of interest requires the issue of new debt to satisfy: D t X t rDt (5) The dynamics of debt and capacity to pay are depicted in Graph (3). The two Eigen Vectors are the vertical axis and the line W which represents the solvency constraint. 1 Which implies that X t X 0 e t 9 Graph 3: Capacity to Pay and Debt Dynamics Dt Debt explodes over time X 0 W There may be liquidity problems D 0 Debt level will converge to zero 1/r-µ 1/r Xt The line D 0 represents the liquidity constraint, implying that current capacity to pay is sufficient to comply with current debt servicing. If the debt level is above the net present value of the capacity to pay (W), debt will be explosive and the country will be deemed insolvent. If a country is situated between the solvency and liquidity constraints, it is solvent, though may face liquidity problems, as debt and the capacity to pay are both growing. In the region to the right of the liquidity constraint, the capacity to pay is growing faster than debt and hence the country is growing out of debt. Taking contingent liabilities into consideration implies allowing for variable X to jump downwards in the event that such liabilities are triggered; therefore X is subject to shocks. Assuming that the risk of a contingent liability is exercised according to a Poisson process of a parameter λ, where the associated density function is e t dt 1 , it is obtained that X faces a 0 probability λdt of jumping downwards at time t. If such a jump takes place X will be reduced to 10 a share of its initial value, becoming φX, where φ is a variable between zero and one. This represents the manner in which a country’s capacity to pay is diminished as a result of a sudden drain of resources derived from a hidden liability, such as the exercise of a government guarantee. Therefore, after the shock, the present discounted value at time t of the country’s capacity to pay is reduced to φ Xt r (6) The present discounted value of the capacity to pay, between time zero and time t is: t rs X s e ds 0 X0 1 e r t r (7) Therefore, the total present discounted value at time zero, of the country’s capacity to pay, subject to a downward shock at time t is obtained by discounting equation 6 to time zero and adding it to equation (7): X0 1 e r t 1 r (8) Weighting equation (7) by the probability of occurrence of the shock the new present discounted value of the capacity to pay is obtained (W’). r 1 e X0 r t 1 e t 0 X r 0 r r (9) r where < 1, given that φ<1. r 11 r The term β = captures the effect upon the solvency constraint of a one-off r contingent liability. The solvency constraint will now be: Xt X D t < r r (10) This result is depicted in Graph (4). The shocks implied by contingent liabilities lead to a change in the slope of the solvency constraint. Hence a country that seems to be in the region in which it is growing out of debt can suddenly prove to be insolvent as the solvency constraint becomes more restrictive. Therefore, if a country is located in zone Z in Graph (4), with a debt level equal to D(0), and a contingent liability is triggered, pivoting the solvency constraint from W to W’, it will suddenly pass from a situation in which it is solvent, to one in which it is not. Essentially, the region in which the country is solvent is reduced, and the present discounted value of the country’s capacity to pay is no longer sufficient to pay the initial level of debt. 12 Graph 4: Capacity to Pay and Debt Dynamics with one-off Contingent Liabilities Dt W W’ W>D(0)>W’ Debt explo des over time 1/r-µ Government is solvent Z D(0) D(0)>W D(0)<W’ β/r-µ 1/r Xt Equation (10) depicts how the extent to which the solvency constraint becomes more restrictive depends on which in turn is a function of . The latter determines the impact of contingent liabilities on long term public finances. According to equation (6), a contingent liability reduces the net present value of a country’s capacity to pay in a proportion (1- ). The analysis of the impact of contingent liabilities upon fiscal sustainability depends on the magnitude of . As it will be seen through the analysis of the case of Colombia, depends on the type of contingent liabilities a country is exposed to. Its magnitude is in occasions very difficult to estimate as it is a long term variable which depends on a variety of uncertain factors. Equation (10) also sets forth that government solvency is independent of budget deficits or surpluses at determined moments in time. This implies that effective fiscal policy management can not be limited to controlling such flow variables, but requires restricting parameter (1- ). 13 This entails limiting and providing for the accumulation of contingent liabilities in order to minimize the exposure shocks and, thereby, reduce fiscal risk. 14 4. Evidence from Colombia Analyzing Colombia’s fiscal stance within this theoretical framework captures the manner in which contingent liabilities affect the Nation’s solvency. Indeed, a country with apparently sound fiscal indicators is revealed to be insolvent when taking into account the stocks of contingent liabilities. This evidences the “fragility” of government solvency given the vulnerability of its net worth, as it is exposed to the negative shocks associated with contingencies. Relative to most of South America, until the mid 1990’s, Colombia was characterized by its prudential fiscal management. This was denoted in relatively low and stable deficit and debt levels which implied a controlled level of fiscal imbalance. Graph 5: Public Sector Deficit 1.00% 2000 2002 (pr) % of GDP -2.00% 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 -1.00% 1986 0.00% -3.00% -4.00% -5.00% -6.00% -7.00% -8.00% Source: Ministry of Finance and National Planning Ministry, Colombia 15 Graph 6: Public Debt as a Share of GDP 60 50 % GDP 40 External 30 Internal 20 10 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0 Source: Ministry of Finance and National Planning Ministry, Colombia According to Easterly and Yuravliver (2002) a stock approach, namely balance sheet accounting, “can produce a better long run perspective on fiscal sustainability than can be obtained from conventional deficit measures”. ¨This approach implies the assessment of whether the public sector net worth is positive or negative. If it is negative, then sustainability will require that the present discounted value of the flows of government revenues minus consumption be sufficient to cover the negative net worth. The official estimation of the Colombian public sector balance sheet as of 1997 drew a positive value for the public sector net worth equal to 62.3% of GDP. Table 1: Consolidated Public Sector Balance Sheet, 1997 (as a percent of 1997 GDP) 140.5 Total Assets Current Assets 29.5 Fixed Assets 110.9 78.2 Total Liabilities Current Liabilities 26.1 Long Run Liabilities 51.8 Net Worth 62.3 Total Liabilities + Government Net Worth 140.5 Source: Contaduría General de la Nación, Colombia. 16 Nevertheless, this balance sheet estimation excluded all contingent liabilities. The inclusion of the latter, as was subsequently demonstrated by Echeverry et al (1999 and 2000), revealed the weakness of Colombia’s public finances, as the government was proved to be insolvent. Table 2: Amplified Public Sector Balance Sheet (as a percent of 1997 GDP) Total Assets Current Assets Fixed Assets Total Liabilities Current Liabilities Long run Liabilities Contingent liabilities Pension liabilities Non Pension liabilities Direct liabilities Other Liabilities 162.3 29.5 132.8 252.2 26.1 225.8 174.0 159.2 14.8 51.8 0.3 Net Worth -89.9 Total Liabilities + Government Net Worth 162.3 Source: Echeverry and Navas (2000) The construction of the amplified balance sheet implied the inclusion of both explicit and implicit contingent liabilities, as well as the re-estimation of direct liabilities and assets. The crucial issue in constructing a comprehensive amplified balance sheet is determining what should be included as contingent liability and how it should be quantified. According to Polackova (1998), fiscal risk can be divided in four categories, depending on the characteristics of the liabilities. The latter can be direct or contingent, and in either case, explicit or implicit. While direct liabilities are obligations that will arise with certainty, contingent liabilities depend on being triggered by a discrete event. The probability and magnitude of such contingency may be exogenous, as is the case of a natural disaster, or endogenous in the case of the increasing provision of State guarantees. 17 Explicit liabilities are specific obligations of the government, established by a particular law or contract. Examples include the repayment of sovereign debt and repayment of nonperforming laws guaranteed by the government. Implicit liabilities in turn respond to a moral obligation of the government, which is not established in any contract but is based on public expectations. Examples include State intervention in the event of default of a large bank on non guaranteed obligations. The amplified balance sheet for Colombia included explicit contingent liabilities such as public body debt guarantees and guarantees for infrastructure contracts. Similarly, the implicit contingent liabilities included the bailing out of financial institutions, bailing out of regional bodies (public enterprises, regional and municipal governments), natural disasters, contingencies arising from legal actions against the Nation, constitutional obligations with no contractual basis and the anticipated cost of peace negotiations (Table 3). Both, assets and liabilities need to be recalculated, as contingencies can affect either of them. The revaluation of assets amounts to 162.3% of GDP, in contrast to the 140.4% reflected in the official balance due to a recalculation of the value of natural resources such as oil and coal reserves in addition to the inclusion of the electromagnetic spectrum as a source of income. On the other hand, government liabilities rise from 78.2% of GDP to 252.2% after the recalculation of pension and contingent liabilities. This translates as a deterioration of government net worth from 62.3% to -89.9% of GDP. In order for the transversality condition to hold, so as to ensure solvency, such net worth should equal the present discounted value of a future flow of fiscal surpluses. Roughly, the present discounted value of a perpetual surplus of x, at a discount rate of r and a GDP growth rate of g, would be x/ (r - g). Considering that the average real interest rate of domestic and foreign public sector debt in Colombia over the past two decades has been 8% (Trujillo, 1999), while the average GDP growth rate has been 3.5% the required primary surplus would approximately be 4.04% of GDP to cover a negative net worth of 89.9%. Nevertheless, when considering the deficit for the consolidated public sector it must be taken into account that the Central Government has already included a yearly transfer of 3% of GDP to cover pension liabilities. Hence, the latter is already accounted as part of the deficit. Taking this transfer into 18 account, over a period of fifty years, significantly reduces the total PDV of the pension liability from 160% of GDP to approximately 100% of GDP2. This implies that taking into consideration these governmental transfers aimed at financing pension liabilities increases the government net worth from -89.9% to -30.7%. Therefore it is necessary to re-calculate of the flow of net surplus required to cover such negative net worth, in order to take into account the consolidated public sector finances. This results in a surplus value of 1.38% of GDP. Data on public finances in Colombia3 indicate that such a value has never been achieved in the past fifty years. This calculation was performed using the same discount rate that was used in calculating the flow of surplus required to cover the negative net worth of 89.9% of GDP, namely 4.5%. 3 Sources include Banco de la Republica (the Colombian Central Bank) and the Ministry of Finance 2 19 Table 3: Contingent Liabilties CONTINGENCIES Natural Disasters Earthquakes Floods Financial Entities Bail Out Pension Liabilities Percent of GDP 1.1 1.1 0.01 2.2 159.2 Infrastructure Roads Airports Energy Telecommunications Mass Transportation 6 0.1 0.7 0.5 0.2 4.4 Foreign Debt 0.7 Judicial Decisions 0.2 Territorial Debt 0.5 Peace 4.1 TOTAL 174.0 Source: Echeverry et al (1999) The inclusion of “hidden” liabilities in the public sector’s balance sheet unveils the unsustainability of fiscal policy in Colombia. Contingent liabilities and the implicit liability represented by the pension debt mount to 174% of GDP. This evidence stresses the incidence of such liabilities in public finance dynamics and hence government solvency, an issue which is not apparent when focusing only on conventional deficit or debt measures. 20 5. The accumulation of contingent liabilities in Colombia Infrastructure The privatization of State functions, accompanied by implicit or explicit government guarantees has become an important cause for the increasing fiscal risk and uncertainty currently faced by governments. State guarantees and insurance schemes represent an alternative to budgetary subsidies and direct financing of financial services, which has become a common method of government support. “These off-budget programmes and obligations involve hidden fiscal costs with implicit and contingent liabilities that may result into excessive requirements for public financing in the medium and long term” (Polackova, 1998). This has been the case in Colombia in the sector of infrastructure, where contracts between the public and the private sector have become a considerable source of contingent liabilities, as State guarantees represent an important incentive to attract private investment. Across the guarantees issued, the net present value of contingent liabilities in the infrastructure sector was estimated at approximately 6% of GDP. The 1991 Constitution provided the judicial tools that allowed for the private sector to provide goods and services which had previously remained as a State monopoly. This led to private investment in roads, energy and telecommunications, through contracts in which the Nation assumed a great share of the risk, which was translated into contingent liabilities. In contracts for the concession of road construction, rehabilitation and maintenance, the State granted traffic volume guarantees and to a lesser extent excess cost guarantees (Echeverry and Navas, 2000)4. The former are invoked if anticipated income falls below an agreed minimal level, related to predicted traffic volume. However, if income rises above an allowed maximum it becomes a contingent asset and the excess is returned to the State. Nevertheless, the financial sustainability of most road projects has been uncertain, given to lower levels of demand than were expected. Effective traffic has been between 74% and 85% of the Excess cost guarantees forced the State to assume the totality of the initial 30% of excess costs in construction, and a 75% of those between 30% and 50%. 4 21 guaranteed levels. Therefore, in average, since 1996, the government has had to pay approximately 0.012% of GDP every year due to guarantees (Reyes, 2002). The present discounted value (PDV) of this contingent liability, included in the amplified balance sheet is 0.1% of 1997 GDP. Similarly, the contract for the construction of the second runway at El Dorado International Airport (Bogota), includes traffic volume guarantees, which constitute a minimum income guarantee. Additionally the government is to provide compensation for tariff modifications. The liquidity for such guarantees has been ensured through the formation of a Government fund. The PDV of this contingency for the duration of the project (20 years) is 0.7% of 1997 GDP. In the telecommunications sector, Law 37 (1993) set Joint Venture contracts as the basis for the association of the public and private sector for investment projects. Within this scheme the State telecommunications company (Telecom) provided the existent infrastructure, while a private partner performed all new investment in order to install new telephone lines. To insure private agent participation Telecom guaranteed a cash flow, determined by the number of installed, projected or sold lines. If the project’s income falls below 90% than its forecasted value, the State must compensate its partner. The State guaranteed a profit rate of 12% in dollars, covering its partners against both commercial and currency risk. Once again, demand levels have fallen below expectations, generating an increasing pressure upon Telecom’s finances. According to the National Council of Economic and Social Policy of Colombia (CONPES), the State company is presently obliged to pay an amount between US$800 and US$1600, depending on the interpretation of the contracts. Private participation in electric energy generation is regulated by decree 700 of 1992, and has taken the shape of Power Purchase Agreements (PPA). The latter are contracts in which the private investors are committed to the construction of electric energy generation plants in exchange for a guarantee of energy purchase from the power distributors, for a period of 15 to 20 years, at an agreed rate. These payments are in turn guaranteed by the State either directly or through a decentralized agency. Nevertheless, these contracts have been granted under 22 onerous conditions, and the price at which purchases are agreed is above market price. Hence the Government has had to assume this difference. The PDV, until 2009, for existent guarantees under this scheme mount to 0.5% of 1997 GDP. The above, represent examples of explicit contingent liabilities, resultant from government contracts, all of which have a significant negative impact upon public finances. They provide evidence of how risk accumulated in a decentralized manner at a micro level can jeopardize macroeconomic stability in the longer term through their incidence upon government solvency. The financial sector In addition to these, there exist implicit contingent liabilities which are accepted by the government only after a failure takes place in the market and a bail-out is granted. “Contingent implicit liabilities often pose the greatest fiscal risk to governments. The event triggering the liability is uncertain, the value at risk difficult to evaluate, and the extent of the government involvement often difficult to predict. In short, it is very hard to identify and estimate the size of contingent liabilities” (Polackova, 1998). According to Polackova (1998), the financial system is a government’s most serious contingent liability. Considering that the soundness of the financial system is crucial to a country’s macroeconomic stability and economic growth, government’s have incentives to intervene providing liquidity, backing deposits, assuming bad loans and injecting equity capital in order to avoid a systemic crisis. These practices have the additional consequence of exacerbating the moral hazard problem in the financial sector. The fiscal costs associated to a financial crisis are both direct and indirect. The direct ones correspond to deposit insurance granted by the state; the indirect emerge from the too big to fail implicit guarantee for some financial intermediaries. The value included in the amplified public sector balance sheet in Echeverry et al. (1999), is associated to the direct costs incurred in through the financial sector bail out in Colombia in 1998/9. This is the cost of liquidation of insolvent public institutions, governmental payments to house owners in fulfilment of a Constitutional Court ruling which favoured mortgage debtors, and public schemes aimed at 23 the re-capitalization of private financial institutions that presented net worth deterioration. The contingent liability included in the amplified balance sheet represents the difference between the resources provided by the State through re-capitalization and those which are subsequently recovered in the future through the sale of financial institutions. This value varies between 1.24% and 1.68% of 1997 GDP depending on assumptions on the financial system’s recovery. On the other hand, according to Standard and Poor’s (2002): “While upfront costs are a superior measure of direct pressures on public finances stemming from banking crises, they fail to capture the potentially larger, albeit unquantifiable, indirect costs to the economy in the future. No matter how successfully handled, banking crises are always followed by a period of financial sector consolidation, during which credit is scarce and expensive, policy credibility and predictability weak, and consumer and investor confidence bearish. As a result, economic growth decelerates to below-trend rates, sometimes for extended periods, as the corporate and household sectors de-leverage. In addition to its obvious welfare and social implications, slower growth adversely impacts public finances by reducing fiscal revenues and pressuring expenditures.” Considering the perverse effects of stressed financial sectors upon macroeconomic stability, economic growth and governmental financial flexibility, Standard & Poor’s acknowledge their impact upon sovereign creditworthiness. Thus, they formally include an examination of the contingent risks posed by the financial sector in their sovereign risk analysis. Therefore, they develop a broader measure aimed at capturing both the direct and indirect costs incorporated in contingent liabilities associated to financial crises. Indirect economic costs include inefficiencies associated with credit scarcity and high interest rates, corporate and household deleveraging, the likelihood of excessive real economic adjustment and the opportunity cost of poorly invested capital yielding sub par returns. The proxy for both the direct fiscal and indirect economic costs of financial system stress is the gross level of problematic assets in the financial system, as a percentage of domestic credit, during a cyclical down turn (GPA). In this manner, Standard and Poor’s aims at analyzing banking systems as a contingent liability to the government in order to assess the fiscal stance of the sovereigns. 24 According to Standard and Poor’s methodology, the contingent liability of the financial sector in Colombia is estimated at a level between 3.9% and 7.8% of GDP5. Public Sector debt guarantees Additional implicit contingent liabilities are derived from public sector debt guarantees to subnational governments and enterprises. The latter have been exacerbated as a result of a process of increased decentralization set forth with the Constitution of 1991. Even though current legislation does not include explicit mechanisms through which the central government is to bail out sub-national governments, there exists an implicit obligation derived from the risks upon the central government’s debt due to imbalances at a sub-national level. Indeed, Colombia’s track record in servicing public debt has been impeccable for decades; this has implied that in several occasions the Central Government has been forced to service loans of sub-national Governments, as it has been the case of the Metro de Medellin and the Cali Public Utilities Enterprise (EMCALI), whose servicing capacity vanished years ago. EMCALI became financially unviable as a result of poor administration which was translated in low revenues and high labour costs, due mainly to poignant pension liabilities. Growing deficits led to the accumulation of unsustainable levels of domestic and external debt, and its subsequent default. The National government has guaranteed EMCALI’s external debt and has been forced to honour it. Furthermore, in the case of domestic debt, a crisis confronted by a sub-national government poses serious risks upon the stability of the financial sector. These factors lead to a problem of moral hazard regarding sub-national entities’ financial discipline. The 1991 Constitution granted sub-national entities with greater autonomy in their indebtedness capacity. Until 1993, the domestic credit operations performed by such entities Financial systems are placed in the six GPA ranges based on Standard & Poor's appraisal of financial institution management, prudential supervision, the pace of change in the regulatory and operating environment, the degree of macroeconomic imbalances and volatility, and the extent of systemic moral hazard in the country in question. Within this framework Colombia was placed in the GPA range of 15% - 30%. Subsequently the measure is calculated as a share of GDP, as it represents a better measure of pressures on fiscal and monetary policy deriving from financial sector stress. It is worth noting that the larger the financial sector and level of intermediation, ceteris paribus, the larger the contingent liability. 5 25 did not require of any previous control from the Finance Ministry besides their registration. At that time, regulation established that entities were entitled to greater indebtness if their debt service during the respective fiscal period was below 30% of the entity’s ordinary income. These facts, together with higher levels of current income, led to accelerated growth in subnational government debt. Only until 1997, through Law 358, was sub-national government debt limited constitutionally to levels which were proportional to the entities’ payment capacity. The latter was determined through indicators based upon the entities’ operational savings (a flow concept). Nevertheless, current regulation has proved insufficient to restrain sub-national government debt growth and ensure its quality, therefore leaving it to remain as an important implicit contingent liability for the national government. The valuation of a sub-national government bail out is based upon territorial entities’ debt levels with commercial banks. The latter is assessed according to the entities’ solvency and liquidity situation. Assuming that 50% of the debt which is at a critical level6 will not be paid generates a liability for the national government which mounts to 0.48% of 1997 GDP (Echeverry et al 1999). Pensions Through the amplification of Colombia’s public sector balance sheet, pension liabilities were revealed as the most poignant threat to fiscal sustainability given their size and long-term implications. Even though these constitute a direct implicit liability for the National government, their characteristics make them vulnerable to various contingencies which add greater uncertainty to the sustainability of fiscal policy, and thereby to governmental solvency. Colombia’s pension scheme until 1993 was a partially unfunded, defined benefit system. Being a pay-as-you-go (PAYG) system its sustainability is vulnerable to changes in demographic trends, mismanagement and economic downturns. The PDV of the implicit pension liability was estimated by Echeverry et al (1999) to be 159% of GDP. Nevertheless, subsequent assessment has led to a valuation of the PDV of the pension liability, between 2000 and 2050, to be 210% of GDP (Echeverry et al, 2001). Sub-national debt is considered to be critical if the ratio debt interests/operational savings is greater than 60%, and the ratio debt level/current income is greater than 80%. 6 26 Unfunded pension payments performed by the National government out of taxes have tripled between 1990 and 2002, passing from 0.8% to 3.0% of GDP. According to Echeverry et al (2001), in the absence of a major pension reform, the annual deficit associated to pension unfunded payments (within the PAYG system) would be approximately 6% of GDP during the next 20 years. The accumulation of such a liability is the result of a variety of factors, which were taken into consideration in its re-estimation. Primarily Colombia’s pension scheme was initially conceived in a decentralized fashion which disregarded the government’s intertemporal budget constraint. Hence as the appropriate reserves weren’t made, the pension deficit was financed with government debt. The situation has been aggravated by high administrative costs and corruption in the various State pension funds, in addition to the heterogeneity in benefits for different public employees implying excessive privileges for determined groups. Law 100 (1993) attempted to solve some of these issues, by allowing for the participation of private pension funds, characterized by defined contributions, and hence being fully funded. Nevertheless, this reform proved insufficient to resolve the unsustainability of Colombia’s pension scheme, while creating a greater burden to public finances through the guarantee of a minimum pension. The latter constitutes a contingent liability for the National government derived from the guarantee of a minimum wage to those pensioned from either the PAYG or defined contribution systems. A proxy of the value of such contingent liability was calculated for the defined contribution system in roughly US$ 3 billion (Echeverry et al, 2001)7. In order for the guarantee not to have to be invoked, and the defined contribution system to be self sustained, the Ministry of Finance estimated that current contribution reserves would have to earn a real profit rate of approximately 12%. In the Colombian economy this rate is between 5 and 6%. This indicates the imminent incidence of such a guarantee upon public finances. This exercise was performed assuming an individual that earns a minimum wage during his entire life, contributes 13.5% of his wage to a defined contribution system, during 1150 weeks (22.1 years) as required by law to be entitled to a pension. This implies he would have saved an amount equivalent to 74.8 minimum wages (of the year 2001). Assuming a 6% profit rate, this would represent 95 minimum wages (MW). If the individual lives 16 years after he is pensioned, he will be entitled to 192 MW. The difference between what he is entitled to and what he has saved is 97 MW, which will have to be paid by the State. Considering the wage structure of those affiliated in the defined contribution system by 2001, where approximately 80% of contributors to either system earn less than two MW, this represents a total value of US$3 bn. 7 27 Changes in demographic trends presently represent a threat to Colombia’s PAYG system. The aging of the population is reflected in a fall of the share of people within the age range of 20 – 45, constituting the major part of the working force, from 39% in year 2000 to 33% in year 2050. Similarly the share of population aged above sixty is rapidly increasing, passing from 7 to 22% in the next fifty years (Echeverry et al 2001). This reflects the generation of an important imbalance between contributors and beneficiaries of the PAYG system which may deem the pension system unsustainable, directly affecting government solvency. The problem is aggravated as contributors move from the PAYG system into the private funds, increasing the gap between contributions and benefits and thereby the government’s intertemporal fiscal imbalances. Based on these considerations, the Government presented to Congress a pension reform that was approved at the end of 2002. The latter reduced the PDV of the total pension liabilities in approximately 50% of GDP, according to the National Planning Ministry. Therefore, presently, the estimation of the PDV of the pension liability is approximately 160% of GDP, close to the initial calculation included in Tables 2 and 3. An additional contingency which has challenged the sustainability of the PAYG pension system has been economic recession. The economic downturn has led to increasing levels of both unemployment and informal employment, thereby reducing the levels of contributions to the pension system and deepening the system’s deficit. The National Planning Ministry in Colombia estimated that for these reasons, the pension system stopped receiving over US$ 330 million in the year 2000. The latter evidences a very interesting factor, namely, that the pension liability is endogenous to the business cycle via the fall in contributions. However, the effects of the endogeneity of contingent liabilities lies beyond the scope of this piece. Evidence provided so far proves the vulnerability of fiscal sustainability and thereby, of government solvency due to the presence of contingent and direct implicit liabilities for Colombia. Traditional measures of fiscal soundness do not evidence the risk placed upon the government’s net worth as it is exposed to shocks which trigger such liabilities and suddenly drain vast amounts of public resources. The accumulation of contingent and implicit liabilities entails an increased exposure to such shocks. 28 In terms of the theoretical model this can be represented as a jump in the solvency constraint which is suddenly made more restrictive. This is equivalent to the Colombian government initially being in zone Z, in graph (4), where it faced a problem of illiquidity but was growing out of debt, and suddenly being made insolvent due to the jumps associated to contingent and implicit liabilities. The uncertainty associated with the country’s fiscal stance has direct consequences upon the valuation of the government’s debt, the analysis of which is beyond the scope of this paper. 29 6. The Institutional Underpinnings As it was previously mentioned, confronting the fiscal risks associated to Colombia’s partially unfunded pension scheme has led to a structural pension reform, aiming at achieving a balance between contributions and benefits and reducing the PDV of the liabilities. Nevertheless, between the reform and governmental funding, the pension liability has been reduced in PDV to approximately 100% of GDP, therefore it continues to be a grave threat to long run financial sustainability. Furthermore, because of its nature, the pension debt remains to be a source of substantial instability for public finances, given that contributions continue to be subject to exogenous shocks which translate into contingent liabilities for the government which are presently not provided for. Contingent liabilities arising from government guarantees emerging from contracts with the private sector have set forth the inefficiencies in risk allocation. Poorly designed projects have been undertaken due to loopholes in government fiscal management which have made it possible for such projects to obtain government guarantees, with which the government assumes most of the risk. The government lacked regulation for the issuance and oversight of guarantees, in addition to other contingent liabilities. Furthermore, accounting rules required that outlays on contingent liabilities that fell due be acknowledged as investment overruns. In the budget, however, investments were already restricted. Lack of budgetary funds thus meant that payments due to the guarantee beneficiaries grew at high penalty interest rates. When the size and unpredictability of payments grew beyond the handling capacity of some public entities, budgetary adjustments (most notably in the so-called vigencias futuras, or future expenditure commitments) and structuring adjustments (in mechanisms that insure liquidity for the project) were made. These adjustments gave the government greater ability to honor its guarantees in a more timely fashion. Nevertheless this did not tackle fundamental problems in terms of both government liquidity and solvency. The government did not have the capability to value its obligations and more importantly did not have the adequate assets to offset its obligations. Handling contingent liabilities through vigencias futuras implied that future budgetary expenditures could be ear marked, ensuring budgeting while explicitly recognizing the 30 obligations. Even though this mechanism ensured the availability of funds to support liabilities in the short run, it introduced severe rigidities for future government budgets and was based on crude valuation methodologies for contingent liabilities. Liquidity provision mechanisms have taken the form of trusts or standby loan facilities, which imply important costs as the call for greater than necessary budget provisions and have failed in providing the liquidity required by private investors. Therefore recent projects have relied on the participation of financial intermediaries that manage the resources allocated to cover these liabilities when they emerge. Measures have been taken from a normative perspective through the issuance of Law 448 (1998) and Decree 423 (2001) which are aimed at providing liquidity as contingencies become effective. Law 448 regulated the valuation, budgeting and control of contingent liabilities; created the State Entities’ Contingency Fund and defined resources to be devoted to financing such liabilities. Namely, Law 448 establishes the obligation for public entities to budget contingent liabilities as debt service, implying that they must make appropriate provisions to face them. Decree 423 assigns the CONPES responsibility for establishing the guidelines for contractual relationships between public entities and the private sector in the development of infrastructure. Additionally it creates the State Policy for contractual risks, which determines the type of risk each sector is allowed to undertake, while unifying the economic policy on risk management. The Contingency Fund is meant to ensure a close relation between the value and the liquidity of guarantees in infrastructure projects. Government entities are to include in their budgets the contribution to the Fund that corresponds to the current year. This improves the credibility of guarantees, because deposits in the Fund constitute the offsetting asset required to cover the contingency, and the resources’ value is maintained over time as earned interests are reinvested. The Fund acts as an account in the sense that it is only held responsible for an amount equivalent to the contribution made by the respective entity. Deposits within the fund are broken down by both project and individual risk levels, therefore deposits made by different entities are not pooled together. In the event that the contingency does not arise, the entities’ payments may be reimbursed or transferred to other projects. 31 7. Conclusions Government solvency is a long term concept immersed in a dynamic framework, hence its analysis can not be limited to the examination of flow variables such as annual budget deficits. A long term, stock perspective unveils the vulnerability of such flows to shocks which have dramatic effects on the government’s net worth, which is the basis for the determination of solvency. Nevertheless, the analysis of solvency is constructed upon flow variables such as annual deficits. Empirical literature has revealed the faults in the traditional deficit measurements as they overlook off-budget liabilities, such as contingent liabilities. These faults are ultimately translated in the analysis of government solvency, as the accumulation of contingent liabilities renders it vulnerable to shocks. A flow based approach to public finances provides incentives for the accumulation of contingent liabilities within fiscal adjustment frameworks, as these take the shape of deficit ceilings. This sets forth the importance of the quality of fiscal adjustment, stressing its consequences in terms of efficient risk allocation. Fiscal adjustment, aimed at complying with the government’s solvency constraint needs to be performed within an intertemporal framework which takes into consideration the long term implications of policies, including the risks they entail. Contingent liabilities have substantial effects upon flow variables, thereby representing a major source of instability while ultimately challenging government solvency. Conventional flow variables do not provide a complete picture of a country’s fiscal stance, making the accumulation of hidden liabilities possible and therefore elevating an unperceived fiscal risk. The consequences of this are only appreciated in the long run, when they entail substantial fiscal costs. The importance of taking into consideration contingent liabilities when determining the sustainability of fiscal policy is evidenced by the fact that these have the power to dramatically alter the perspective of a government’s solvency. While a nation may appear to be solvent at 32 some point in time, liabilities triggered by a determined event at an uncertain moment may suddenly deem it insolvent. The risk associated to the accumulation of contingent liabilities, can hence be expressed as the vulnerability of a government’s capacity to pay to “jumps”, which alter its solvency constraint making it more restrictive. This is exemplified by the case of Colombia, where the amplification of the government’s balance sheet through the inclusion of contingent and implicit liabilities reveals an otherwise hidden problem of insolvency. In terms of graph 4, this is equivalent to the Colombian government initially being in zone Z, where it faced a problem of illiquidity but was growing out of debt, and suddenly being made insolvent due to the jumps associated to contingent and implicit liabilities. The contingencies which reduce a government’s capacity to pay may be endogenous or exogenous. This paper has modeled contingent liabilities as exogenous shocks. Nevertheless, implicit liabilities such as pension liabilities are subject to shocks which are endogenous to the country’s economic performance. Further research should focus on endogenizing , as well as the probability of occurrence of shocks. Indeed. The value of may depend on certain characteristics of the public sector, in every country, or on institutional features. The study of these elements can shed light on the sources of unsustainable public finance dynamics observed in cases such as that of Argentina. Furthermore, the study of the triggering elements in different countries can improve our understanding to assess macroeconomic and debt default risks. In short, a stock based approach of public finances including the analysis of contingent liabilities exposes the vulnerability of fiscal solvency to shocks and is hence crucial in the determination of the sustainability of fiscal policy. 33 References Agenor, P. and P. Montiel, 1996. Development Macroeconomics, Princeton University Press, UK. Blejer, M. and A. Cheasty, 1991. “ The Measurement of Fiscal Deficits: Analytical and Methodological Issues”. Journal of Economic Literature, Vol XXIX, pp 1644-1678. Buiter, W. and C. Grafe, 2003. “Patching up the Pact: Some Suggestions for Enhancing Fiscal Sustainability and Macroeconomic Stability in an Enlarged European Union” Mimeo Contaduría General de la Nación 1996 – 1997, Balance General de la Nación e Información Financiera del Sector Público Colombiano 1996 y 1997, Colombia. Easterly, W. 1999. “When is Fiscal Adjustment an Illusion?”, Economic Policy, pg 57-86. Echeverry, J., V. Navas, J. Cardona and J. Gutierrez, 2002. “Dealing with Contingent Liabilities in Colombia” in Governments at Risk, ed H. Polackova, World Bank and Oxford University Press Echeverry, J., A. Escobar, C. Merchán, G. Piraquive and M. Santamaría, 2001. “Elementos para el Debate sobre una Nueva Reforma Pensional en Colombia”. Archivos de Macroeconomía No. 156, National Planning Ministry, Colombia. Echeverry, J., M. Angulo, G. Hernandez, I. Fainboim, C. Numpaque, G. Piraquive, C. Rodríguez and N. Salazar, 1999. “El Balance del Sector Público y la Sostenibilidad Fiscal en Colombia”. Archivos de Macroeconomía No. 115, National Planning Ministry, Colombia. Echeverry, J. and V. Navas, 2000. “Confronting Fiscal Imbalances via Intertemporal Economics, Politics and Justice” in Sustainable Public Sector Finance in Latin America, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Kharas, H. and D. Mishra, 1999. “Hidden Deficits and Currency Crises”. Mimeo World Bank. Kotlikoff, L., 1999. “From Deficit Delusion to the Fiscal Balance Rule: Looking from the Economically Meaningful Way to Assess Fiscal Policy” in Generational Accounting Around the World, ed. by A. Auerbach, L. Kotlikoff and W. Liebfritz. University of Chicago. Kotlikoff, L., 1993. Generational Accounting: Knowing Who Pays and When for What We Spend, MIT Press. Miller, M. and L. Zhang, 1999. “Creditor Panic, Asset Bubbles and Sharks: Three Views of the Asian Crisis” Ch. 10 in U. Dadush (eds) Private Capital Flows in the Age of Globalization, pg 222-240, Cheltenham UK. 34 Polackova, H. and A.Shick, 2002. (eds) Government at Risk: Contingent Liabilities and Fiscal Risk. World Bank and Oxford University Press, Washington, U.S.A. Polackova, H., 1998. “Contingent Government Liabilities: A Hidden Risk for Fiscal Stability” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1998, World Bank. Poterba, J. 1997, “Do Budget Rules Work?” in Fiscal Policy Lessons from Economic Research, ed. by A. Auerbach. MIT Press. Reyes, J. 2002. “Impacto Económico de las Garantías de la Nación en Proyectos de Infraestructura”, Mimeo, National Planning Department, Colombia. Standard and Poor’s, 2002. “Global Financial System Stress” Trujillo, E. 1998. “Cual es la Deuda Pública Sostenible?” Mimeo, National Planning Ministry, Colombia. 35