Cross-border Trade in Network-bound Energy Products: Competition Related Issues Brendan Oviedo Centre of Energy Petroleum Mineral Law and Policy University of Dundee Scotland Competition Provisions in Regional Trade Agreements Istanbul, Turkey 31 July – 1 August Table of Contents 1. Introduction …………………………………………………………………….. 3 2. The Liberalization of Electricity and Natural Gas Markets ………………… 3 3. Competition Related Issues in Electricity and Natural Gas Markets ………8 3.1 Market Structures and Market Concentration ………………………8 3.2 The Network ………………………………………………………….10 3.3 Long Term Contracts ………………………………………………. 11 4. Explicit Regulation or Competition? …………………………………………13 5. Competition Provisions in Regional Trade Agreements applicable to Crossborder Trade of Electricity and Natural Gas: The Way Forward? .................14 6. Conclusions …………………………………………………………………… 15 2 1. Introduction Electricity and natural gas (NG) are network bound energy products. They depend on their corresponding networks for their transportation. For electricity and NG cross-border trade to take place domestic markets need to be interconnected. Without interconnecting networks cross-border trade of these products will be inexistent. Anticompetitive practices by private undertakings in interconnected electricity and NG markets could distort or restrict cross-border trade flows. The purpose of this paper is to try to determine the platform from which these anticompetitive practices could be effectively dealt with. In order to try to answer this question, Chapter two below will review the liberalization process of electricity and NG markets. Chapter three is destined to identify potential anticompetitive practices that can negatively affect crossborder trade of electricity and NG. For that purpose such Chapter will review market structures, ownership concentration of undertakings in the market, the specific characteristics that networks have, and the long term contracts entered by electricity and NG market undertakings in order to finance upstream and downstream infrastructure projects. The application of competition law and/or explicit regulation to the markets in question will be addressed in Chapter four. Chapter five will lay out the findings of all the previous chapters in order to identify the possible supranational dimension of the competition issues that could affect crossborder trade of electricity and NG. Chapter six concludes. 2. The Liberalization of Electricity and Natural Gas Markets There are three physical activities that can be identified in electricity markets. These are generation (production), transmission and distribution. Electricity is generated through the transformation of primary (sun, wind, water, etc.) and secondary (oil, gas, coal, uranium, etc.) sources of energy. As electricity 3 cannot be stored once these primary and secondary sources are transformed the produced electricity will have to be injected into the transmission network. The electricity will then be transported on high voltage transmission lines until it reaches the distribution network where the voltage will be reduced in order to be delivered to final consumers. NG is primordially composed by methane (CH4). However NG can usually be found together with oil, water, and other gases in oil, gas and condensate fields. The production of NG involves separating the methane from these other elements. After NG is produced to become “pipeline quality” gas it is injected into high pressure pipelines and transported over long distances, as production sites are not usually located near the markets where NG is consumed. After the high pressure transmission, the NG pressure is reduced and pumped into low pressure distribution networks for its delivery to consumers. However, NG can be stored for an indefinite period of time and storage facilities can usually be found at different points of the pipeline network. This largely depends on the consumption intensity pattern of certain locations. Now then, before electricity and NG markets were liberalized, their structure generally consisted on the existence of vertically integrated utilities responsible of all physical activities within national borders. These companies held monopolistic rights over the production, transmission and distribution (and storage in the case of NG) of electricity and NG. They owned their entire market infrastructure and rendered all the services required to deliver electricity and NG to consumers. There was relatively no cross-border trade in electricity and if it did take place it would occur, as in the case of NG, among vertically integrated companies. In most cases, these vertically integrated companies were state owned. The state ownership of these companies was sustained on the idea that the industry’s potential monopolistic behaviour would most likely be prevented if 4 the ownership of the infrastructure was held by the State1 since electricity and NG markets as a whole were considered to be natural monopolies2. The monopolistic perception of electricity markets responded to the natural monopoly characteristics of transmission and distribution networks, the required synchronization between generation and transmission activities and the costs arising thereof, the long term planning of generation and transmission projects and the economy of scale nature that generation activities have3. The above perception was not entirely different for NG markets. The NG market was, and in some markets still is, vertically integrated. Producers owned transmission and distribution infrastructure, transmission companies owned distribution and production facilities and distributors owned transmission and distribution assets4. In Western Europe the market was controlled by “gatekeepers” at national borders (transmission firms) and at local areas (distribution firms)5. These companies usually held monopoly rights for NG imports, exports, transmission and distribution and were partially or fully state owned. During the 1970’s oil crisis it was discovered that independent power producers in the United States (US) could operate in a manner that would not endanger the reliability of the network. This implied that electricity production was not a natural monopoly6 per se. This was not the case for NG. The production of NG has and still is dominated by large oil companies. 1 IEA, Electricity Market Reform 21 (Paris, France: Head of Publications Service, OECD/IEA, 1999) 2 See Id, at 20 3 Hunt, Sally, Making Competition Work in Electricity 25-26 (New York: Wiley, 2002). 4 De Vany, A., and Walls, W.D., The Emerging New Order in Natural Gas: Markets versus Regulation 5 (Westport, Conn. : Quorum Books, 1995) 5 Stern, J., Competition and Liberalization in European Gas Markets: A Diversity of Models 10 (London : Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1998) 6 See IEA, supra note 4, at 22-23. 5 This non-monopolistic perception of electricity production directed efforts towards liberalizing electricity markets so as to introduce competition where competitive activities could be identified. The principle behind liberalizing electricity and NG markets is to ensure competition7. In order to achieve this, some electricity and NG markets have been restructured to enable competition where it is believed that this is possible. The modification of electricity and NG market structures has characterized their liberalization. This means breaking up the existing vertically integrated state company, privatizing its infrastructure, enabling potential competitors to enter the markets where competition is deemed possible, unbundling the activities that are potentially competitive from those that have natural monopoly characteristics and creating independent regulators to foresee the competitive performance of the markets8. Electricity generation (wholesale market) and retailing are considered to be competitive. In the case of NG these activities are production, storage and retailing. To enable competition in the wholesale electricity market, new undertakings were allowed to enter such market by unbundling the incumbent vertically integrated monopoly, privatizing its upstream assets and withdrawing its monopoly rights9. However, not only electricity producers take part in the wholesale market. Retailers that seek to procure electricity for their customers and financial traders also participate. 7 Lee, M., and Morand, C., Competition policy in the WTO and the FTAA: A Trojan Horse for International Trade Negotiations 5 (Ottawa: Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives, 2003) 8 For further information on the sequencing of the liberalization measures introduced in a given electricity market see Zhang, Y., Parker, D., and Kirkpatrick, C., Competition, Regulation, and Privatization of Electricity Generation in Developing Countries: Does the Sequencing of the Reforms Matter? Available at: http://www.competitionregulation.org.uk/publications/working_papers/WP62.pdf 9 Albers, M., Competition Law Issues Arising from the Liberalization Process in The Liberalization of Electricity and Natural Gas in the European Union 3-4 (Geradin, D., Ed.,The Hague; London : Kluwer Law International 2001 ) 6 Introducing competition into electricity and NG retailing implied that the transport component of the distribution activity was susceptible of being unbundled from the commercial activity of supplying electricity to consumers. This means that there would be a defined number of competing retailers which provide customers with the possibility to decide what retailers they wish to purchase their electricity from. It has been a gradual process of granting consumers with the right to decide who their supplier will be. The first consumers that have been granted this right were industrial consumers. Usually the have been residential consumers. This process has occurred both in the US and European Union (EU). Transmission and distribution activities are still considered to be natural monopolies as a consequence of their economies of scale and their network characteristics10. Moreover the high maintenance costs of the electricity grid and the impracticality of constructing unlimited power lines reflect the high degree in which electricity undertakings have to rely on transmission and distribution infrastructure11. Electricity and NG depend exclusively on transmission grids and pipeline networks respectively in order to trade. Furthermore, the possibility to engage in cross-border trade of these products will depend on the interconnectors that link exporting and importing countries’ domestic networks. Moreover long distance transmission of electricity is not economically feasible due to electricity loss, thus remaining regionally bound. NG transportation is also regional in nature. However this regional dimension has been overcome by the use of liquefied natural gas (LNG). LNG becomes a competitive option 10 See Id., 25 Pfrang, E, Towards Liberalisation of the European Electricity Markets: The Directive Concerning Common Rules for an Internal Market in Electricity in the Frame of the Competition and Internal Market Rules of the EC-treaty 19 (Frankfurt am Mein : Peter Lang, 1999) 11 7 as a means for NG transport over distances of around 4800 kilometres12. However, after the LNG is regasified it has be stored as NG or injected into pipelines for its transport and distribution to consumers. 3. Competition Related Issues in Electricity and Natural Gas Markets Although this is not an exhaustive assessment of all competition issues that may arise in electricity and NG markets which could affect cross-border trade, this paper intends to demonstrate that there are sufficient reasons to suggest that cross-border trade of electricity and NG could be subject to competition law. Private market barriers that can hamper cross-border trade of electricity and NG can depend among other things on the way markets are structured, the degree of concentration these markets have, the technical characteristics of the networks and the agreements commonly used to finance upstream and downstream infrastructure projects. 3.1 Market Structures and Concentration The liberalization of electricity and NG markets has been welcomed in a variety of countries. The most enthusiastic have restructured their entire markets, privatized its infrastructure, created an independent regulator, and unbundled the ownership of the network infrastructure from its operation to enable wholesale and retail competition. However not all countries have passionately embraced this liberalization movement. Countries electricity and NG market structures can vary depending on the degree of liberalization they were willing to undertake. 12 Stevens, P., Cross-border Oil and Gas Pipelines: Problems and Prospects 3 (Washington D.C., ESMAP, 2003) 8 These structures can range from having enabled wholesale competition, unbundled ownership from the operation of the network and allowing retail competition to solely privatizing the entire incumbent vertically integrated company. Some countries have not introduced competition at all and have left the vertically integrated structure of their markets unaltered and in public ownership. The differences between interconnected market structures engaged in trade could well circumscribe this trade to bilateral dealings between a dominant undertaking and a vertically integrated company. As mentioned above, bilateral cross-border exchanges of network bound energy products between vertically integrated firms was the rule before electricity and NG markets began to be liberalized. The post-liberalization of European electricity and NG markets has shown that undertakings that had previously acquired state owned infrastructure are prone to increase their market share by means of local and cross-border mergers and acquisitions13 (M&A) These M&A appear destined to create what are currently know as “national champions”. Cross industry M&A between electricity and NG firms can also have anticompetitive effects if access to NG for electricity generation is restricted to competitors of the merged or acquiring firm. These situations will evidently increase the possibilities for anticompetitive cross-border effects, through the abuse of a newly attained dominant position in one or more interconnected markets, the celebration of agreements between related firms located in different ends of interconnected markets, etc. However it has to be bared in mind that these M&A could also produce 13 Jamasb, T., and Pollitt, M, Electricity Market Reform in the European Union: Review of the Progress toward Liberalization and Integration, p. 15 Available at: http://mit.edu/ceepr/www/2005-003.pdf 9 efficiency gains by increasing the scope of the products and/or their geographical markets14. The issue of collective market dominance should also be carefully considered. Concentrated or not, wholesale markets can tend to yield towards collective dominance as it briefly occurred in the English wholesale electricity market after 199815. 3.2 The Network As has been mentioned above, transmission and distribution networks are considered to be natural monopolies. Restructuring the markets to allow wholesale and retail competition would be pointless without a competitive minded operation of the network. No matter how many undertakings are competing between each other in the wholesale market, as long as they cannot access the network on nondiscriminatory and transparent basis, trade will be restricted. Therefore electricity and NG trade depends on the access undertakings have to their corresponding networks. If a producer owns and operates the network it would be inclined to favour its retail interest by providing its production unit access to available capacity rather than granting it to its competitors. The unbundling of ownership and operation of the network infrastructure is desirable to avoid situations like the one just mentioned. Prohibiting ownership by generators/producers of network assets or not allowing the owners of transport infrastructure to engage in competitive activities of electricity and NG markets are other alternatives. For cross-border trade of electricity and NG to take place, bordering markets need to be interconnected. Interconnection may well be the most important 14 Cameron, P., Competition in Energy Markets 324 (Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2002) Newberry, D., The Relationship between Regulation and Competition Policy for Network Utilities p. 22 Available at: http://www.dspace.cam.ac.uk/bitstream/1810/137385/1/eprg0611.pdf 15 10 barrier for electricity and NG cross-border trade competition16. Ownership of production facilities and ownership/operation of interconnection infrastructure can also provide incentives to restrict access to third parties from both exporting and/or importing markets. Notwithstanding the measures introduced in order to enhance competition in electricity and NG markets (i.e. unbundling of ownership/operation), the firm responsible for the network operation will sustain a dominant position which could be easily abused without adequate regulation establishing nondiscriminatory third party access (TPA), cost reflective prices, equivalent prices for similar services to different consumers, etc. Moreover there is also a need to address the way in which capacity will be managed in highly congested areas of the network. Additionally, a harmonized approach for cost based transmission pricing will be needed to avoid disruptions to potential trade between interconnected markets. It is clear that the main issue regarding the network is the granting of TPA on a non-discriminatory and transparent basis. Without this access competitors will have no market to trade. Therefore it is possible to affirm that TPA to the network is “an essential condition for creating competitive cross-border energy markets.”17 3.3 Long Term Contracts Upstream and downstream electricity and NG infrastructure projects are capital intensive. Financing electricity generation plants and NG production facilities usually require long-term purchase agreements to guarantee the project sponsor’s lenders certain amount of revenue flows to repay dept. 16 Celli, R., and Riis-Madsen, C., New developments in EU legislation and Application of Competition Rules to Interconnectors 177 I.E.L.T.R. (2002) 17 Walde, T., and Gunst, A., International Energy Trade and Access to Networks: The Case of Electricity in Electricity Trade in Europe: Review of the Economic and Regulatory Challenges 183 (Desta, M., and Bielecki, J., eds., The Hague: Kluwer Law International, 2004) 11 In electricity generation and NG production projects these contracts are called power purchase agreements (PPA) and gas sales agreements (GSA) respectively. The long-term nature of these contracts is linked to the financing period which depends on the repayment of also long-term loans. Both PPA and GSA contain take or pay clauses. Through these clauses the purchaser of electricity or NG will assume the obligation to “take” a specific volume of the product. This means that no matter if the purchaser “takes” or not “takes” such volume it will have to pay the price agreed for it. These clauses mitigate the supply risk of the producer by guaranteeing the purchase of volume from the project. On the other hand, the purchaser will thus assume the market risk of the purchased product. Another type of clauses used, are destination clauses. These clauses have been used in contracts for the supply of Russian Federation NG to the EU. Destination clauses basically exclude the possibility of the purchaser of NG of reselling the purchased product and restrict its use to specific areas. The project financing of network infrastructure utilizes similar contracts to guarantee revenue as those used in electricity generation and NG production projects. The way in which this type of projects’ revenue is guaranteed is through long-term capacity contracts (LTCC). These LTCC reserve the capacity of new built network infrastructure to a particular market undertaking, usually a producer. The logic consequence of this is that TPA to the network will be limited or inexistent during the duration of the contract. PPA and GSA (with take or pay and destination clauses) and LTCC can act as market access barriers that would significantly reduce competition and trade. In the case of the former two, these would have the effect of discouraging new market entrants. Regarding the latter, available capacity will be scarce or even inexistent and therefore there would not even be a market to trade in. NG storage infrastructure finance would likely have in place LTCC contracts. 12 4. Explicit Regulation or Competition? As this paper has identified above, there are a few competition issues that can arise from electricity and NG market structures, the degree of market share private undertakings possess in these markets, the contracts usually entered in order to project finance new infrastructure and the ownership and operation of the network that could affect, distort and/or restrict cross-border trade of electricity and NG. As electricity and NG networks are considered to be natural monopolies there is a common understanding that these should be subject to explicit regulation. However nothing suggests that competition law should not be also applied in parallel to such explicit network regulation18. This raises two issues that need to be dealt with. The first refers to what issues should this network specific regulation be applicable to. It seems likely that this specific regulation should address the way in which TPA is granted, congestion is managed and transmission and capacity charges are determined. This has been the approach undertaken by the EU through Regulation 1228/2003 on conditions for access to the network for cross-border exchanges in electricity. Access to NG networks is subject to Regulation 1775/2005 on conditions for the access to the NG transmission networks. The second issue relates to what should be left to competition. Competition law could be applicable to any abuse of the network operator’s dominant position by treating competitors discriminatorily, charging unfair prices for capacity and/or transmission services that restrict or distort cross-border electricity and NG trade. 18 Van Der Woude M.H., Competing Gas Pipeline Infrastructure: Some Comments from a Dutch Perspective in International Energy Law and Taxation Review 296 (December 2005) 13 The way to deal with anticompetitive practices at both ends of the network is pretty strait forward. As in any other market where competition is feasible, no explicit regulation should be required. All anticompetitive practices carried out by undertakings taking part in the wholesale and retail electricity and NG markets should be subject to competition law. In the EU, for example, the electricity and NG sector specific regulations have been applied in parallel with the general competition law provisions contained in articles 81, 82 and 86 of the EC Treaty. 5. Competition Provisions in Regional Trade Agreements applicable to Cross-border Trade of Electricity and Natural Gas: The Way Forward? In the previous chapter, this paper has examined the possibilities of applying competition law to the network and to the activities currently considered competitive at both ends of the network. In an interconnected market where cross-border trade of electricity and NG is taking place, anticompetitive effects originating in one domestic market can be felt in another. These anticompetitive effects may be difficult to be addressed by the latter market competition authorities. Furthermore, addressing cross-border anticompetitive practices, from a national platform, may be difficult where countries do not apply competition law to their markets or where there are differences in the chosen competition law approach to address anticompetitive practices. These situations could lead to differences in the way these laws would be enforced. Moreover, issues of jurisdiction and nationalism19 could increase the possibilities of conflict between competition law enforcement by national competition authorities. 19 Tarullo, D., Norms and Institutions in Global Competition Policy in The American Journal of International Law 481 Vol. 94, No. 3., (July 2000) 14 Private market access barriers that could foreclose the entrance of new competitions could arise from the abuse of the dominant position that an undertaking has in one or more interconnected markets due to the structure of the markets or by way M&A. However the abuse of network operators’ de facto dominant position can pose a fundamental market access barrier in electricity and NG markets. Long-term contracts used in the electricity and NG industries to finance upstream and downstream infrastructure projects can also have a market foreclosure effect. These market access barriers will also be difficult to tackle by national competition authorities. Furthermore the liberalization process has suggested the need to create and independent energy regulator to supervise the overall functioning of the market. Coordination between competition authorities and independent energy regulators could be beneficial in order to facilitate the identification of anticompetitive behaviour in an interconnected market. 6. Conclusions This paper has examined the liberalization process that has been undertaken in electricity and NG markets, the measures that have been used to achieve this, the existing dominant positions pre-liberalization and the markets reconcentration tendency post-liberalization. It has also assessed the pivotal role that the network plays in enabling competition in interconnected electricity and NG markets. The contractual instruments to finance infrastructure projects in upstream and downstream electricity and NG markets and their potential to foreclose entrants to new undertakings has also been reviewed. 15 Furthermore the previous chapter has provided strong reasons to consider the need to address cross-border competition related issues on a supranational level. Therefore these anticompetitive practices could be addressed by the application of competition provisions contained in Regional Trade Agreements. If this were the way forward, one question remains answered. What should these provisions look like? 16