Governors’ Dillemas: Economic and Social Policy Trade-Offs in the Russian Regions (Evidence from Four Case Studies)1 Thomas F. Remington Irina Soboleva Anton Sobolev Mark Urnov Through case studies of four regions, we examine the trade-offs between social and economic policy at the regional level in Russia. All four regions studied seek to stimulate entrepreneurship while preserving or expanding social welfare coverage. Regions differ in development strategies, some placing greater emphasis on indigenous business development and others seeking to attract outside investment. Variation in levels of democracy are unrelated to policy choices. All four regional governments consult actively with local business associations while organized labor is weak. The absence of effective institutions to enforce commitments undermines regional capacity to make social policy an instrument for long-term development. The regime transition from communism to capitalism in Russia and elsewhere challenges policy makers to devise new structures for social provision and economic management consistent with the transition to a market economy. The conflict between those who seek to maintain some or all of the comprehensive guarantees of employment, housing, education, health care, pension security and poverty relief, and those who aim to reduce the socialist welfare state to a minimum set of fiscal commitments has shaped politics both at the central level in Russia and at the regional level (Frye 2010; Cook 2007; Haggard and Kaufman 2008; Gel'man, Ryzhenkov and Brie 2003; Zubarevich 2009). In Russia, regional governors confront the challenge of stimulating growth by providing an attractive environment for capital investment while at the same time ensuring social stability. Accordingly, they must resolve the trade-off between reducing taxes and other burdens on the productive sector and maintaining the social benefits expected by the population. In this paper, we examine the strategies adopted by regional governments in Russia in the face of this redistributive dilemma. Specifically, how do governors balance their social and economic policies? For example, how do they reconcile their obligations in the spheres of education, health care, unemployment benefits, housing and utilities rates, poverty relief, and support for vulnerable and dependent strata, with their desire to stimulate economic development? Do governors have a long-term 1 This research is part of a project entitled, "Silent Heroes: State and Middle Class in Contemporary Russia," which is funded by the National Council for Eurasian and East European Research and the Higher School of Economics in Moscow. We are grateful for their support. 2 strategy for regional development using measures of social policy to contribute to long-term growth? Finally, what leads governors to give priority to one set of social and economic policies over another? An extensive literature exists detailing economic, social and other policy demands on regional governments in Russia (see, inter alia, Hanson and Bradshaw 2000; Hanson 2003; Ross 2002a, 2002b; Remington 2011; Petrov and Titkov 2010). Comparatively few, however, address the way regional decision-makers themselves view the trade-offs these challenges impose and the way they resolve them. In this paper, we use case studies of four Russian regions to understand the strategies ruling elites pursue as they manage the competing objectives of economic development and social protection. Our findings suggest that regional governments regard social and economic policy measures as being in tension rather than as reconcilable elements of a long-term plan for regional development. Studies of the varieties of capitalism demonstrate that there is a tendency for political and economic institutions in advanced industrial democracies to be complementary. Scholars distinguish the "liberal market economy" model--characterized by highly competitive markets for labor and capital, limited public provision of welfare and training, and competitive, majoritarian political institutions--from the "coordinated market economy" with its emphasis on bargaining and coordination among business, labor and government, reliance on consensual decision-making, and high level of income security (Hall and Soskice 2001; Iversen 2005; Iversen and Soskice 2006, 2009; Iversen and Stephens 2008). Our case studies suggest that, despite some differences in emphasis, all four regional governments are pursuing hybrid strategies of regional development. These combine some features of the old socialist statism (such as the administratively determined rates for services by state utilities providers, the authoritarian patterns of decision-making, and the universalistic and regressive nature of social entitlements) with elements of a somewhat skewed corporatism by which business interests are given access to policy making. There are elements as well of a liberal market-oriented economic policy of low taxes and low redistribution (as seen in the push to commercialize and privatize public services). This hybrid model of politics and economics allows regions to avoid radical and potentially destabilizing shifts away from the universal social welfare system of the Soviet regime while slowly introducing elements of market competition for labor and social services. At the same time such a strategy is costly and preserves ample opportunities for rent-extraction 3 and corruption. It also perpetuates tendencies toward paternalism and dependency on the part of the public, including business. Regional governments in Russia, like the national government, face fundamental choices in their strategies for regional development. Creating a climate favorable for business investment comes at the expense of resources needed for other purposes, particularly for redistribution in favor of dependent strata of the population or for the subsidies and credit guarantees that enable local firms to weather difficult economic conditions. The redistributive dilemma is therefore not just between support for the productive sector and support for the dependent strata, it imposes choices over the relative priority of different sectors of the society--the poor and vulnerable; the business sector; and the public sector. The fact that regions have managed to improve compensation for public sector employees indicates that the redistributive choices faced by governors are often resolved in favor not of the poor nor of business, but of the public sector. Low tax collections, inefficient public utilities companies, and weak financial markets all make these redistributive conflicts more acute than would be the case if tax receipts were more robust (as would occur if employers reported and paid taxes on a higher proportion of their actual earnings), if utilities providers were more efficient, and if financial markets could handle bond issues for infrastructure development bringing long-term returns. The short time horizons of economic agents reinforce these redistributive dilemmas. Alleviating the redistributive dilemma between social and economic policy goals by inducing faster economic growth might be possible if institutions for coordination within the business and labor sectors were more effective and both could reach enforceable agreements with government. Then actors might be willing to pool the costs and gains from joint efforts to invest in infrastructure development, improved labor market regulation, training programs that would match the skills of workers to the demands of new productive technologies, and financing for region-wide development plans. At present, however, at least on the strength of these four case studies, regional governments do not see such long-term institutional reform as a high priority.