PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY RUNNING HEAD: PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Personality, Uncertainty, and Economic Preferences Christopher D. Johnston Department of Political Science Duke University christopher.johnston@duke.edu Acknowledgements: I would like to thank Stanley Feldman, Howard Lavine, Matthew Lebo, Chris Federico, Ben Newman, and James Wilfred Jenkins III for comments and discussions on earlier versions of this manuscript. PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY ABSTRACT Contemporary work on economic preference formation in both political economics and political psychology has emphasized the importance of certainty and security concerns as key factors underlying mass preferences for more or less government intervention in economic matters. The qualitative nature of the relationship between needs for certainty and security and economic preferences, however, is quite distinct across these literatures. The former emphasizes the social protective functions of social welfare, and thus hypothesizes a positive relationship between security and certainty needs and economic liberalism, while the latter emphasizes symbolic factors related to institutional stability and change, and thus implies a positive relationship between needs for certainty and security and economic conservatism. The present paper seeks a synthesis of these literatures through the consideration of heterogeneity in the dispositional foundations of economic preferences and ideology across political engagement. It is theorized that the politically engaged, in their greater exposure to elite discourse, understand economic issues through the more symbolic lens of institutional stability and change, while the unengaged default to a concrete understanding of economic intervention as social protection. Across three datasets it is shown that economic preferences are strongly determined by certainty and security needs, but in exactly opposite ways across levels of citizen engagement with elite politics. The implications of these findings for the political psychology literature on personality and ideology, for integrated approaches to preference formation in political science, and for American politics more broadly, are discussed. 2 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY INTRODUCTION Few theoretical conflicts appear more fundamental than that of self-interest-based and personality-based approaches to understanding economic preference formation. The differences between these literatures echo historical divisions between political economic and political psychological approaches to mass politics more generally (e.g. Sears and Funk 1991). Contemporary manifestations of these literatures, however, share a common focus on the concepts of uncertainty and security. In political economics, recent work suggests the importance of risk aversion and labor market uncertainty to preferences for government-provided social welfare (Iversen 2005; Iversen and Soskice 2001; Moene and Wallerstein 2001; Rhem 2009; Sinn 1995). As Iversen (2005) explains, “workers…do not know with certainty how they will fare in terms of future employment and income. In this situation, risk-averse people will demand insurance against loss of employment and income.” An extension of this basic logic suggests that citizens in labor market positions which entail higher levels of income and employment uncertainty will prefer social welfare at higher rates, and that citizens who are dispositionally risk and uncertainty-averse will prefer social welfare at higher rates than citizens who are less risk-averse (see also Ehrlich and Maestas 2010; Kam and Simas 2010). In political psychology, the role of uncertainty and security for economic preference formation takes on a more ideological character. Recent theorizing argues that the dispositionally risk and uncertainty-averse oppose government redistribution and social welfare in order to protect status quo institutions, values, and socioeconomic arrangements (Gerber et al. 2010; Jost et al. 2003; Jost, Federico and Napier 2009; Mondak 2010). As Thorisdottir and Jost (2011, p. 789) argue, “The status quo, no matter how aversive, is a known condition and is therefore easier to predict and imagine than a potentially different state of affairs that could be either better or 3 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY worse…Thus, status quo conservatism offers more familiarity and certainty than do alternative ideologies that are characterized by preferences for social change and innovation; for this reason, it is likely to be more accessible and attractive when people are seeking stability and security.” Several lines of empirical research suggest that personality indicators related to needs for certainty and security are associated with conservative political orientations (e.g. Amodio et al. 2007; Gerber et al. 2010; Hetherington and Weiler 2009; Jost et al. 2003; Mondak 2010; Oxley et al. 2008). Thus, while sharing a common bond in a focus on the importance of uncertainty and security to economic preference formation, these two literatures come to very different conclusions about the direction of the relationship. The political economics literature sees these needs as driving a preference for government-provided social protection and insurance, while the psychology literature sees uncertainty and security needs as the basis for opposition to changes in status quo institutions and hierarchies. The present paper seeks a reconciliation of these perspectives by positing heterogeneity in the association of psychological needs for certainty and security to economic preferences. I argue that the two theoretical paradigms can be distinguished by the level of abstraction upon which economic issues are represented, and that citizens will vary with respect to representational abstraction as a function of political engagement. I thus hypothesize that the relationship between personality and economic preferences will vary in qualitative form across levels of political engagement. More specifically, I hypothesize that the politically unengaged, viewing economic issues through the lens of social protection, will show a positive relationship between needs for certainty and security and economic liberalism. The politically engaged, by contrast, viewing economic issues through the more abstract and symbolic lens of institutional stability and change, will show a positive relationship between 4 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY needs for certainty and security and economic conservatism. I test these claims across three distinct datasets in the realm of American politics, utilizing two distinct measures of needs for certainty and security, and two distinct measures of preferences for government-provided social welfare, finding very strong support for theoretical expectations in all cases. The present paper thus represents a reconciliation of two seemingly competing literatures in a way which maintains the importance of each. Moreover, the theoretical logic which underpins these expectations suggests avenues for future integration and, perhaps, a more unified science of mass preference formation. PERSONALITY, UNCERTAINTY, AND CONSERVATISM Recent research on personality and mass politics, despite diversity of theoretical paradigm and language, converges on the importance of certainty and security as key concepts underlying stable differences in political orientations. This conceptual convergence is made explicit by John Jost and his colleagues within their theory of political ideology as motivated social cognition (Jost et al. 2003; Jost, Federico and Napier 2009). They argue that political conservatism (as opposed to liberalism), in its emphasis on institutional stability, and in its provision of a justification for the socioeconomic status quo, is palliative for citizens with psychological needs for epistemic certainty and existential security. As Jost and Hunyady (2005) argue, “There is a good match between needs to reduce uncertainty and threat and system justification, because preserving the status quo allows one to maintain what is familiar while rejecting the uncertain prospect of social change. For many people, the devil they know seems less threatening and more legitimate than the devil they don’t” (p. 262). 5 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY This general hypothesis finds empirical support in a number of studies. Jost et al. (2003), in a meta-analysis of over eighty studies on the topic, find that psychological indicators related to these needs (e.g. intolerance of ambiguity, mortality salience, dogmatism) are associated with several indicators of general political conservatism (e.g. authoritarianism, ideological selfplacement). More recent work also shows converging evidence. Hetherington and Weiler (2009) find that needs for security and certainty are strongly related to preferences over social and foreign policy, and have become an increasingly important predictor of partisan orientations in the American mass public since 2000. Van Hiel, Pandelaere and Duriez (2004) find strong associations between the need for nonspecific epistemic closure and cultural conservatism (see also Chirumbolo et al. 2004; Van Hiel and Mervielde 2004), and Federico and Goren (2009) find that the need for closure predicts conservative ideological self-placements. Converging evidence can be found within recent work on personality within political science. Mondak (2010) finds strong associations between the “Big Five” personality traits of openness to experience and conscientiousness and political liberalism and conservatism, respectively. It is notable that these two traits are the strongest predictors of political ideology and identification, as they represent the “Big Five” analogues of the more basic needs for certainty and security. As Mondak argues, “the openness and conscientiousness hypotheses are best understood in terms of traditional views in which liberalism corresponds with a willingness to see government tackle new and varied problems, while conservatism implies a more cautious approach in in which presumption favors the status quo” (p. 127). This logic is echoed by Gerber et al. (2010) in their examination of ideology across the social and economic domains. They argue that openness to experience implies a positive response to “unconventional and complex stimuli,” and thus, “It follows that this attraction to novelty and tolerance for complexity 6 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY encourage not only overall liberalism, but also support for liberal social and economic policies, which typically involve new programs or interventions that overturn existing practices” (p. 116). Similarly, with respect to conscientiousness, which involves “socially prescribed impulse control,” there should be a connection with conservatism as “identifying as conservative involves supporting traditional norms in both the economic and social policy domains” (p. 115). The biology and politics paradigm also finds supporting evidence. Amodio et al. (2007), for example, find that conservatism is associated with lower levels of conflict monitoring, as evidenced by less activation in the anterior cingulate cortex (ACC) among conservatives relative to liberals. The ACC is implicated in the detection of situations that require a shift from habitual responses, and thus attention to uncertainty in the environment (e.g. Botvinick, Cohen and Carter 2004; Cunningham et al. 2003; Kerns et al. 2004). Oxley et al. (2008) find that several indicators of sociocultural conservatism are associated with both galvanic skin responses and startle blink responses to threatening stimuli, which indicates greater threat sensitivity among conservative individuals. Settle et al. (2010) additionally find that a specific gene variant known to be associated with novelty-seeking predicts political liberalism. LIMITATIONS Taken as a whole, this literature provides robust empirical support for the statistical association of a wide variety of indicators of uncertainty aversion and security-seeking with several measures of conservative political orientations. The literature is nonetheless limited in breadth of application. More specifically, empirical support for the association of personality indicators related to uncertainty aversion and security-seeking is much stronger for cultural 7 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY conservatism than economic conservatism. Several studies which distinguish between social and economic manifestations of conservatism fail to find support in the latter domain. Van Hiel, Pandelaere and Duriez (2004) find that uncertainty aversion is strongly related to cultural conservatism, but is minimally and insignificantly related to economic conservatism. Chirumbolo et al. (2004) examined the (bivariate) associations between the need for nonspecific cognitive closure and a variety of political and social attitudes, and found significant associations of this indicator with anti-immigration, nationalism, support for autocratic leadership, pluralism, and multiculturalism, but no associations with either support for free enterprise or the welfare state. Feldman and Johnston (2009) examined the relationship of authoritarianism, need for nonspecific cognitive closure, and the need for cognition on social and economic conservatism in the 2000 and 2004 American National Elections Studies. While all three predictors were significantly related to social preferences (e.g. gay marriage, abortion), none significantly predicted economic preferences (e.g. health insurance, government spending). Carney et al. (2008) found associations of openness to experience, extraversion and conscientiousness with self-identification as a social conservative, but not self-identification as an economic conservative. Similarly, Van Hiel and Mervielde (2004) found associations of openness and conscientiousness with social but not economic conservatism. Thorisdottir et al. (2007), in a study of Western Europe, found that “rule-following” strongly and significantly predicted both general left-right orientations and value traditionalism, but only weakly, though significantly, predicted acceptance of inequality. Similarly, the need for security significantly predicted leftright orientations and value traditionalism, but, contrary to expectations, substantially and significantly predicted economic liberalism. In other words, citizens with dispositional security needs were less accepting of inequality, not more. 8 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY A smaller number of empirical studies, however, do find theoretically expected associations, but the nature of the data and models suggest a more complex model underlies the personality-based origins of economic preferences. Gerber et al. (2010) find that openness to experience and conscientiousness predict economic liberalism and conservatism, respectively, but utilize a sample consisting of registered voters, and thus citizens who are likely more engaged with elite politics. Federico, Fisher and Deason (2011) find that authoritarianism predicts (anti-) egalitarianism among the politically sophisticated. Golec (2001; as reported in Jost et al. 2003) finds that uncertainty aversion predicts economic liberalism among Polish adults, but finds the expected relationship with economic conservatism among student political activists. This research suggests that political engagement moderates the relationship of personality with preferences in the economic domain. I return to this issue of moderation below. PERSONALITY, UNCERTAINTY, AND SOCIAL PROTECTION The political economics literature takes a very different approach than the recent work on personality, arguing that concerns with economic uncertainty and security provide a key foundation of public support for social welfare. From this view, redistribution, income, and employment protection serve as forms of publically-provided insurance against the vagaries of free market capitalism (Moene and Wallerstein 2001; Sinn 1995; Varian 1980). Iversen (2005; Iversen and Soskice 2001), for example, shows that citizens with skills specific to industries, occupations, or firms support social welfare to a larger extent than citizens with more general skills. The former are more likely to suffer a loss in the value of their labor due to, say, technological change or changes in the structure of the labor market, and thus support social welfare as a means of insuring against future income loss. In a similar vein, Rhem (2009) finds 9 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY that citizens within occupations with relatively high unemployment rates prefer social welfare more than citizens in low unemployment arenas. Again, this suggests that they are hedging against risks associated with their personal labor market position. This theoretical framework suggests that stable differences in citizens’ levels of risk and uncertainty aversion should, all else equal, be associated with their support for social welfare. More specifically, at any given position in the labor market, citizens high in needs for security and certainty should prefer government-provided social welfare more than those low in such needs, all else equal. Social welfare, in this sense, constitutes a “functional match” to personality profiles characterized by uncertainty aversion and security-seeking (Jost, Federico and Napier 2009). Recent research provides some support for this general hypothesis. Kam and Simas (2010) find that dispositional risk aversion is associated with stronger preferences for certain over probabilistic outcomes in Prospect Theory games (Kahneman and Tversky 1979; Quattrone and Tversky 1988). While they limit their conceptualization of this personality trait to risk aversion, the items utilized to measure the trait bear striking resemblance to those used by psychologists to measure more general constructs such as the need for epistemic closure (e.g. Kruglanski, Webster and Klem 1993) or openness to experience (Gerber et al. 2010). For example, one item reads, “I prefer friends who are exciting and unpredictable,” while another reads, “I would like to explore strange places.” Ehrlich and Maestas (2010) find that dispositional risk aversion predicts support for trade protectionism among low-skilled workers, and predicts opposition to immigration among citizens in occupations exposed to potential displacement by immigrant workers. Thus, citizens high in risk aversion preferred government intervention for reasons of income and employment protection. Finally, recall that Thorisdottir et al. (2007) find that dispositional needs for security predict economic liberalism in Western 10 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Europe. They suggest that “a preference for inequality seems motivated more by acceptance of risk than by needs for security” (p. 196). SYNTHESIS The implications of this review suggest exactly opposite theoretical expectations for the relationship of personality traits related to needs for certainty and security to economic preferences. While recent work in political psychology suggests that such needs should be associated with economic conservatism qua opposition to government intervention, the political economics literature suggests that such needs should be associated with economic liberalism and support for social welfare as social protection. Furthermore, the former literature has found minimal support for this hypothesis except among politically engaged citizens. The latter literature, by contrast, has found some support for expectations, but empirical tests are fewer in number and the focus has not been on domestic economic preferences or ideology. A potential resolution of these literatures is suggested by a consideration of differences in how each “understands” the economic domain, more specifically, with respect to the level of abstraction each assumes for citizen representations of economic issues. The hypotheses of the political psychology literature assume that citizens understand economic policy in a highly symbolic fashion. From this perspective, economic conservatism represents adherence to status quo norms, institutions, and socioeconomic hierarchies, and thus certainty and security needs are best served by opposition to liberal interventionism. The traditional view in political science, however, suggests that only a subset of citizens achieve such ideological understandings of political issues (Converse 1964), especially ones as difficult as those in the economic domain (Carmines and Stimson 1980; Pollock, Lilie and Vittes 1993). From this view, elites construct the symbolic content of difficult issues, and it is through exposure to elite discourse that citizens 11 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY come to understand the broader symbolic implications of such issues. As Pollock, Lilie and Vittes (1993) explain, the extent to which citizens utilize abstract and symbolic representations of policy conflict to form their preferences, as well as the nature of the abstract content applied, “will depend on whether opportunistic ‘cultural entrepreneurs’ can successfully frame the issue as a battle over core values and whether individuals are alert to what these social agents are saying” (p. 31). In the absence of such exposure, we should expect citizens engaged in preference formation to rely on considerations which are available to them (Zaller 1992), which are more likely to concern personal or familial interests. As Converse (1964) argued in his seminal work, “moving from top to bottom of this information dimension, the character of objects that are central in a belief system undergoes systematic change. These objects shift from the remote, generic, and abstract to the increasingly simple, concrete, or ‘close to home.’ Where potential political objects are concerned, this progression tends to be from abstract, ‘ideological’ principles…to such objects of immediate experience as family, job, and immediate associates” (p. 213). These considerations suggest that the question raised by a review of this literature is not of an “either/or” form, but rather “for whom?” I posit that each model applies to mass preference formation, but for distinct subsets of the citizenry defined by levels of political engagement. I thus offer the following two hypotheses to be tested in the empirical sections of the paper: (1) For politically unengaged citizens, increases in needs for certainty and security will be associated with increases in economic liberalism. (2) For politically engaged citizens, increases in needs for certainty and security will be associated with increases in economic conservatism. 12 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY One of the most interesting aspects of these two hypotheses is that they offer a potential explanation for the weak to null findings of recent research in political psychology which has explicitly examined the economic domain in the context of dispositional influences. Specifically, a failure to account for heterogeneity across levels of political engagement, to the extent that the effects are of opposite sign for the engaged and unengaged, would result in marginal effects of zero as a result of such aggregation. This hypothesis thus offers an elegant solution to the problem of null and minimal findings in recent work within the economic domain: needs for certainty and security are actually highly influential factors influencing the economic preferences of citizens, but in unique ways conditional on how these issues are understood, and thus on political engagement. Moreover, the present perspective suggests that these two seemingly disparate literatures share a common perspective, and do not differ at a fundamental level. In both cases citizens may meaningfully pursue goals which are personally relevant (e.g. security), but the ways in which such pursuit manifests at the level of economic preferences is conditional on how citizens actually understand the issues at hand. DATA AND METHODS To test my hypotheses I rely on data from the 2000, 2004 and 2008 American National Elections Studies. In 2000, the ANES utilized both face-to-face and telephone interviews, the former via a national probability sample, and the latter via random digit dialing. In 2004 and 2008, all interviews were conducted face-to-face. The 2008 ANES included an oversample of Black and Latino Americans. Information regarding all aspects of these studies can be accessed at the ANES public website. In the analyses to follow I rely only on self-identified White Americans. Recent work suggests that personality may operate differently in the economic 13 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY domain across racial and ethnic groups (Gerber et al. 2010), and thus analyses should examine such groups separately rather than make general inferences that do not hold across all subsamples. In 2000 and 2004 the sample sizes for minority group members are simply too small to accurately assess these hypotheses. In 2008, however, the ANES conducted an oversample of Black and Latino Americans. I estimated identical models for these subsamples and found no evidence of an influence of personality on preferences. This is consistent with the findings of Gerber et al. (2010). These results are reported in Appendix A. I also estimated the full sample models for both 2000 and 2004, and the results are included in Appendix A. The pattern of results is similar but the effect sizes are weaker. This is consistent with a “dilution” of the influence of personality when including minority groups in the analysis. Needless to say, all inferences throughout the remainder of the paper apply to White Americans only. At this time, little theoretical or empirical work has sought to address racial and ethnic heterogeneity in the influence of personality on political attitudes and behavior. This is clearly an important topic for future research, but beyond the theoretical scope of the present paper. Dependent Variables I test the two hypotheses of the present study utilizing two distinct measures of economic conservatism, one concerning broad preferences over government intervention in economic matters, and one more policy-oriented. Preferences for Limited Government. I draw on three items in each survey to measure general orientations toward government intervention in economic matters. Each survey contained an identical set of items. For each, respondents were asked to choose from two statements. The first item contrasted the statement, “The main reason government has become 14 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY bigger over the years is because it has gotten involved in things that people should do for themselves,” with, “government has become bigger because the problems we face have become bigger.” The second contrasted, “We need a strong government to handle today’s complex economic problems,” with, “The free market can handle these problems without government being involved.” Finally, the third contrasted, “The less government, the better,” with, “there are more things the government should be doing.” I recoded these items so that each takes on a value of one for the limited government response. I then created a summative index with higher values indicating greater preferences for limited government. Economic Policy Conservatism. I measure economic policy conservatism in each study as a scale constructed from responses to specific policy items. In 2000 and 2004, I rely on three items: preferences for more or less government spending and services, preferences for government guaranteed jobs and income, and preferences over the government provision of health insurance. In 2000, the respondents were randomly assigned to receive one of two item formats. The first utilized the typical ANES seven-point scale format, while the second utilized a branching format resulting in a five-point scale. The three middle options of the former were combined to form a five-point scale, and the two samples were combined to maximize sample size. In 2004, all respondents received the seven-point branching format. In 2008, I rely on only two items: preferences over government spending and services and over the government provision of health insurance. In this study only half of the sample received the government guaranteed jobs and income item. In addition, half of the sample was randomly assigned to receive new versions of the health insurance and spending items. Both of the new versions of these items utilized slightly different wordings and a branching format. I again combine the two subsamples to maximize sample size. The exact wordings for all items from all three studies are 15 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY contained in Appendix B. The reliability of the scales in 2000 and 2004 were .59 and .71, respectively. In 2008, the correlation between the spending and insurance items was .42. Each scale was recoded to range from zero to one prior to analysis. Independent Variables Needs for Certainty and Security. I operationalize dispositional needs for certainty and security in two ways. In all three studies I rely on four items utilized by recent work to measure the construct of “authoritarianism.” The scale was constructed equivalently in each study. Each item asked respondents to choose which of two values is more important for a child to possess. The pairwise comparisons include: “Independent or Respect for Elders,” “Curiosity or Good Manners,” “Obedience or Self-Reliance,” and “Considerate or Well-Behaved.” Some respondents volunteer “Both,” and these are coded at an intermediate point. The four items were then summed to create a single measure. Much work in political psychology suggests that “authoritarianism” is derivative of more basic needs for certainty and security (see Jost et al. 2003 for much evidence in this regard; see also Duckitt 2001; Feldman 2003; Lavine et al. 1999; Lavine et al. 2002; Stenner 2005). More recently, Hetherington and Weiler (2009) demonstrated the convergent validity of this operationalization. Moreover, the items themselves have face validity with respect to their ability to distinguish respondents on the basis of epistemic and existential needs. Each item considers potential solutions to dealing with a dangerous or uncertain world, more specifically, by adhering to established norms, rules and institutions, and respecting legitimate authorities. As Duckitt (2001) argues, “A view of the world as dangerous, unpredictable, and threatening…would activate the motivational goal of social control and security. This motivational goal would be expressed in the collectivist sociocultural values of conformity and traditionalism and in…authoritarian social attitudes” (p. 50). Personally, I 16 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY believe the term “authoritarianism” is unnecessarily pejorative, and should be reserved for certain forms of overt, anti-social behavior and attitudes, not underlying dispositions and traits, and thus continue to refer to this scale as needs for certainty and security despite its recent usage. In 2008 I rely on a second measure for replication purposes which tap the need for nonspecific cognitive closure (Kruglanski 1989; Kruglanski and Webster1996). The need for closure is defined by citizens’ relative comfort with, or aversion to, uncertainty generally, and thus to substantial changes in their social environment. As Jost et al. (2003) explain, “contents that promise or support epistemic stability, clarity, order, and uniformity should be preferred by high-need-for-closure persons over contents that promise their epistemic opposites (i.e. instability, ambiguity, chaos, and diversity)” (p. 348). One item included in the 2008 ANES was modeled after related items from the dispositional need for closure scale (Kruglanski, Webster and Klem 1993). This item read, “Of the situations when you see two people disagreeing with one another, in how many of them can you see how both people could be right?” Response options ranged from zero (“All of them”) to four (“None of them”).1 Higher values imply a greater need for closure. Political Engagement. I operationalize political engagement with two variables: political sophistication and partisan strength. Political sophistication has commonly been utilized to proxy for attention to elite discourse, and the propensity of citizens to seek out and assimilate information from the elite space (e.g. Berinsky 2007; Zaller 1992). Partisan strength taps the extent to which citizens have a developed political identity, and thus the extent to which they are personally invested in elite level partisan politics. In this sense, partisan strength can be seen in Related items from Kruglanski et al.’s (1993) need for nonspecific cognitive closure scale include: “When considering most conflict situations, I can usually see how both sides could be right,” and, “In most social conflicts, I can easily see which side is right and which is wrong.” 1 17 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY terms of the extent to which a given citizen feels a part of their political “team” (Green, Palmquist and Schickler 2002), and should thus be related to political information seeking, and the tendency to assimilate rhetoric from in-partisans. Thus, both political sophistication and partisan strength are intended to tap citizens’ exposure to elite rhetoric.2 In 2000 and 2004, political sophistication was operationalized with six knowledge items. At the time of this writing, the knowledge items for 2008 had yet to be released by the ANES. I thus rely on two items: the citizen’s self-reported interest in politics, and the interviewer’s subjective rating of the respondent’s knowledge of politics. These two items were highly correlated (r=.42) and were combined to form a single scale. To check the validity of this operationalization, I generated an identical variable in the 2004 ANES, and correlated this scale with the political sophistication operationalization constructed from the six knowledge items in that study. The correlation was large, indicating that the former provides a reasonable proxy for this indicator (r=.57). Partisan strength was operationalized by folding the traditional ANES seven-point partisan identification measure about its midpoint, resulting in a four-point scale ranging from “pure” independent to strong partisan. The exact items used to construct the sophistication scales can be found in Appendix B. Controls. I additionally control for several variables which are exogenous to needs for certainty and security, but which may be correlated with both the latter and the dependent variable. These include age, gender (1=male), education (six categories, entered as dummy variables to allow for non-linearity), income, and employment status (1=unemployed). All variables were recoded to range from zero to one prior to analysis. With respect to partisan strength, the “sports analogy” is a good one. Someone with a strong attachment to a sports team (i.e. a highly developed identity) is more likely to seek out information about their team, and about sports generally, than someone with little attachment to, and thus investment in, a team. 2 18 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY ANALYSIS AND RESULTS Results for Preferences over Limited Government I first consider the results for preferences over limited government for all three years, and then turn to the estimates for economic policy conservatism. In each year, I regressed preferences for limited government on needs for certainty and security (hereafter NCS), the two measures of political engagement, the interactions of these with NCS, and all controls. As limited government is ordinal, I estimated the model with maximum likelihood using an ordered probit link function. The results for these first analyses are shown in Table 1. As the dependent variable is coded in the conservative direction, hypotheses (1) and (2) imply negative coefficients on the NCS constituent terms (i.e. NCS increases support for a government role when engagement is low) and large and positive coefficients for the NCS interactions with political engagement (indicating a reversal at high levels of engagement). Across the three models, I find strong support for both hypotheses. In all three cases the constituent term on NCS is substantively large, in the expected negative direction, and statistically significant, implying an increase in support for government intervention across NCS when political engagement is at a minimum. Moreover, and in support of hypothesis (2), the interaction term of NCS and political sophistication is positive, large and statistically significant in all three cases. While all three coefficients for the interaction of NCS with partisan strength are in the expected positive direction, none attain conventional levels of statistical significance. Knowledge thus seems to be the better indicator of exposure to, and assimilation of, symbolic elite discourse and the resulting abstract representation of the economic domain which drives the reversal. 19 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Table 1. Regressions of Preferences for Limited Government on Needs for Certainty and Security (NCS) and Controls ______________________________________________________________________________ Variable 2000 ANES 2004 ANES 2008 ANES ______________________________________________________________________________ NCS -.76 (.34)* -1.03 (.42)* -1.94 (.41)* NCS X Soph 1.51 (.51)* 1.22 (.55)* 2.49 (.54)* NCS X Strength .69 (.46) .61 (.47) .54 (.40) Sophistication Partisan Strength Age Male HS Degree Some College Associate Degree BA Degree Professional Degree Income Unemployed -.48 (.35) -.49 (.32) .08 (.17) .39 (.07)* .18 (.15) .35 (.15)* .18 (.17) .25 (.16) .10 (.18) .85 (.27)* -.14 (.20) .24 (.36) -.48 (.29)^ .45 (.19)* .24 (.09)* .00 (.19) .14 (.20) -.16 (.23) .19 (.21) -.36 (.23) .38 (.19)* -.16 (.24) -.97 (.38)* -.17 (.26) .68 (.16)* .27 (.07)* .14 (.15) .31 (.17)^ .29 (.17)^ .40 (.17)* .37 (.20)^ .45 (.16)* -.06 (.16) Cut 1 Cut 2 Cut 3 -.15 (.27) .38 (.27) .89 (.27) -.09 (.34) .52 (.34) 1.09 (.35) -.31 (.32) .29 (.32) .93 (.32) Pseudo R^2 .04 .05 .05 N 1127 699 975 ______________________________________________________________________________ Notes: Entries are maximum likelihood ordered probit estimates and standard errors (in parentheses). Estimates are for self-identified Whites only. *p<.05; ^p<.10. Ordered probit coefficients are not easily interpretable. I thus converted these estimates into predicted probabilities of support for limited government, across levels of NCS, for low and high levels of political engagement. I graph these estimates for each of the three models in Panels A-C of Figure 1. 20 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Figure 1. The Influence of Needs for Certainty and Security on Preferences for Limited Government Panel A. 2000 ANES Low Engagement High Engagement High Engagement .6 .5 .4 .3 .1 .1 .2 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 Pr(Restrict Government) .7 .7 .8 .8 Low Engagement Panel B. 2004 ANES 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 Needs for Certainty and Security .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Needs for Certainty and Security Panel C. 2008 ANES Low Engagement High Engagement .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 Notes: Plots represent predicted probabilities of giving two or three (out of three) limited government responses. Estimates were generated holding all controls at their central tendencies. “Low Engagement” represents independent citizens at the 5th percentile of political sophistication, while “High Engagement” represents strong partisans at the 95th percentile of political sophistication. 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Needs for Certainty and Security 21 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY The points represent the predicted probabilities of giving two or three conservative responses to the three limited government items. Low engagement corresponds with an independent citizen at the 5th percentile of sophistication (zero correct responses for 2000 and 2004), while high engagement represents a strong partisan at the 95th percentile of sophistication (five correct responses in 2000 and six in 2004). These estimates can thus be interpreted as the effective bounds on the influence of NCS in terms of absolute magnitude. All controls were held at their central tendencies. Looking first at the estimates for the 2000 ANES, a change from low to high on NCS for unengaged citizens corresponds with an expected decrease in the probability of giving two limited government responses of about .29 (95% CI = [-.53, -.04]), while for engaged citizens this same change in NCS corresponds with an increase in the probability of .44 (95% CI = [.24, .62]). These are both substantial effects with respect to magnitude, but as expected by the theorizing above, are in exactly opposite directions substantively. The results for 2004 are highly similar. For low engaged citizens the marginal effect of NCS is -.34 (95% CI = [-.60, .07]), while for the highly engaged it is .30 (95% CI = [.09, .51]). Finally, turning to the 2008 study, a change from low to high on NCS for low engaged citizens corresponds with a decrease in limited government of 56 percentage points (95% CI = [-.74, -.33]), while the same change for the highly engaged corresponds with an increase of 41 percentage points (95% CI = [.24, 57]). Overall, these results strongly support theoretical expectations. There is, however, an interesting nuance to the findings which is worth mentioning, and which reinforces the basic theoretical mechanism thought to underlie the patterns observed. Specifically, consider the asymmetry in the magnitude of the absolute marginal effect of NCS across engagement across the different years. While only so much can be gleaned from this small number of (yearly) 22 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY observations, the patterns across the years with respect to this asymmetry make good sense in light of theory. In 2000, a culmination of the late-1990s economic boom, the marginal impact of NCS on liberalism for the unengaged is 15 percentage points lower (in absolute terms) than its impact on conservatism for the engaged. In contrast, in 2008 in the midst of the recent economic crisis, this pattern reverses, with the absolute effect for low engaged citizens 15 percentage points larger than that of the highly engaged. If citizens at low levels of engagement are indeed more likely to view the economic domain through the personal lens of economic certainty and security, then this pattern is exactly what we should expect to see, namely, an increase in the importance of basic needs for certainty and security on preferences for government intervention when the economy itself suggests objective reasons to be uncertain and insecure. Results for Economic Policy Conservatism I turn now to the results for economic policy conservatism, which are shown in in Table 2. For each year, I estimated identical models to those for limited government, except that I utilized ordinary least squares regression with robust standard errors to correspond with the pseudo-continuous dependent variable. When interpreting coefficients, recall that all variables are coded from zero to one. The patterns in Table 2 once again strongly support theoretical expectations, and largely replicate the findings above with a distinct measure of economic preferences. In 2004 and 2008 the constituent term for NCS is negative, large, and statistically significant, while in 2000 it is marginally significant (p<.10). Moreover, the interaction term of NCS and political sophistication is once again strong, positive, and significant in all three models. As with the analyses for limited government above, despite being in the correct direction, I find no significant moderating effect of partisan strength in 2000. I do, however, find a large moderating effect in both 2004 and 2008 which is consistent with my more general 23 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY expectations regarding political engagement. Overall, looking across all six models, it appears that political sophistication matters more than strength of political identity, although there is some evidence that such strength matters given the consistently positive moderating influence of the variable, and its significance in two of the models. Table 2. Regressions of Economic Policy Conservatism on Needs for Certainty and Security (NCS) and Controls ___________________________________________________________________________ Variable 2000 ANES 2004 ANES 2008 ANES ___________________________________________________________________________ NCS -.11 (.07)^ -.27 (.08)* -.34 (.10)* NCS X Soph .23 (.11)* .26 (.11)* .39 (.13)* NCS X Strength .09 (.09) .34 (.10)* .22 (.10)* Sophistication Partisan Strength Age Male HS Degree Some College Associate Degree BA Degree Professional Degree Income Unemployed Constant -.09 (.07) -.02 (.06) .05 (.03) .03 (.02)^ .05 (.03) .11 (.03)* .07 (.04)* .08 (.03)* .07 (.04)* .19 (.05)* -.06 (.04) .43 (.06)* -.06 (.07) -.11 (.06)* .08 (.04)* .03 (.02)^ .02 (.04) .03 (.04) .04 (.05) .04 (.04) .00 (.05) .21 (.04)* -.03 (.04) .35 (.07)* -.16 (.09)^ -.08 (.07) .18 (.04)* .09 (.02)* .05 (.04) .08 (.04)* .07 (.04)^ .07 (.04)^ .02 (.05) .24 (.04)* .03 (.04) .29 (.08)* R^2 .07 .15 .14 N 1182 729 1005 ___________________________________________________________________________ Notes: Entries are ordinary least squares estimates and robust standard errors (in parentheses). Estimates are for self-identified Whites only. *p<.05; ^p<.10. 24 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Once again, I facilitate interpretation of these dynamics by translating model estimates into predicted values of the dependent variable. These are graphed in Panels A-C of Figure 2. Looking first at 2000, the marginal effect of NCS for low engaged citizens is -.11 (95% CI = [.25, .03]), while for the highly engaged it is .17 (95% CI = [.05, .29]). Thus, NCS decreases conservatism (albeit insignificantly) by about 11 percentage points for low engaged citizens, and increases policy conservatism by about 17 percentage points for highly engaged citizens. The results for 2004 are quite a bit stronger in terms of magnitude. At low levels of engagement, a change from low to high on NCS corresponds with a decrease in policy conservatism of about 27 percentage points (95% CI = [-.42, -.10]). For the highly engaged, the effect of NCS is an increase in conservatism of about 33 points (95% CI = [.21, .45]). Finally, in 2008 the estimates for low and high engaged citizens were -.29 (95% CI = [-.47, -.10]) and .28 (95% CI = [.17, .40]), respectively. Taken as a whole, this second set of analyses provides converging evidence for hypotheses (1) and (2). In contrast to the limited government analyses, however, the strong asymmetry between 2000 and 2008 is not full replicated. While the marginal effect of authoritarianism for low engaged citizens is indeed lower in 2000, the effects in 2004 and 2008 were comparable. 25 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Figure 2. The Influence of Needs for Certainty and Security on Economic Policy Conservatism Panel A. 2000 ANES Low Engagement High Engagement High Engagement .7 .6 .5 .4 .3 .2 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 Predicted Economic Conservatism .8 .8 Low Engagement Panel B. 2004 ANES 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 0 1 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Needs for Certainty and Security Needs for Certainty and Security Panel C. 2008 ANES Low Engagement High Engagement .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 Notes: Plots represent predicted values of economic policy conservatism. Estimates were generated holding all controls at their central tendencies. “Low Engagement” represents independent citizens at the 5th percentile of political sophistication, while “High Engagement” represents strong partisans at the 95th percentile of political sophistication. 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Needs for Certainty and Security 26 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Replication with the Need for Nonspecific Cognitive Closure I sought to replicate the findings above with a distinct measure of the key independent variable; specifically, the need for nonspecific cognitive closure. I substituted this variable for the “authoritarianism” operationalization in identical models of limited government preferences and economic policy conservatism. These results are shown in Table 3 and Figures 3 A-C. In both cases, the results are weaker with respect to statistical significance, which is understandable given the single-item operationalization of this construct. Nonetheless, the patterns show support for theoretical expectations and hypotheses (1) and (2). In the model for limited government preferences, the constituent term on the need for closure (NFC) is negative, although fails to attain statistical significance (B=-.57, p<.25). The interaction term with political sophistication is large, positive and marginally significant (B=1.32, p<.06). Thus, the basic pattern of results is identical to the analyses above, although the estimates are rather inefficient. In addition, the interaction of NFC with partisan strength in the limited government model is in the incorrect direction and insignificant. I thus plot the predicted probabilities of giving two limited government responses in a way identical to that above, as well as holding constant partisan strength at its median value. These are panels A and B in Figure 3. Turning to the results for economic policy conservatism, I find stronger support for theoretical expectations, and a cleaner replication. The constituent term for NFC is substantively large, negative, and statistically significant (B=-.25, p<.05). The interaction term with political sophistication is large, positive, and marginally significant (B=.32, p<.06). The interaction term with partisan strength is much smaller and not significant (B=.07, n.s.). The predicted values of economic conservatism, across values of NFC, for low and high engagement are plotted in panel C of Figure 3. The characteristic pattern is again evident. Thus, while weaker overall, I have 27 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY replicated the basic pattern of findings utilizing an entirely distinct measure of needs for certainty. Table 3. Regressions of Preferences for Limited Government (LG) and Economic Policy Conservatism (EPC) on Needs for Nonspecific Cognitive Closure (NFC) and Controls ______________________________________________________________________________ Variable LG EPC ______________________________________________________________________________ NFC -.57 (.49) -.25 (.11)* NFC X Soph 1.32 (.70)^ .32 (.17)^ NFC X Strength -.46 (.52) .07 (.13) Sophistication Partisan Strength Age Male HS Degree Some College Associate Degree BA Degree Professional Degree Income Unemployed Constant -.07 (.38) .37 (.27) .69 (.16)* .26 (.07)* .18 (.15) .35 (.16)* .32 (.17)^ .43 (.17)* .34 (.19)^ .44 (.16)* -.07 (.16) - -.08 (.09) .02 (.07) .19 (.04)* .10 (.02)* .04 (.04) .07 (.04)^ .06 (.04) .06 (.04) .00 (.05) .23 (.04)* .03 (.04) .21 (.07)* Cut 1 Cut 2 Cut 3 .67 (.31) 1.25 (.31) 1.89 (.32) - Pseudo R^2/R^2 .04 .13 N 979 1008 ______________________________________________________________________________ Notes: Entries are maximum likelihood ordered probit estimates and standard errors (in parentheses) for LG, and ordinary least squares estimates and robust standard errors for EPC. Estimates are for self-identified Whites only. *p<.05; ^p<.10. 28 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Figure 3. The Influence of Needs for Nonspecific Closure on Economic Policy Conservatism, 2008 ANES Panel A. Limited Govt. High Engagement Low Soph High Soph .4 .3 .2 .1 .1 .2 .3 Pr(Restrict Government) .4 .5 .5 Low Engagement Panel B. Limited Govt. (Strength Constant) 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 Need for Closure .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Need for Closure Panel C. Economic Policy Conservatism Notes: Plots represent predicted probabilities of limited government and values of economic policy conservatism. Estimates were generated holding all controls at their central tendencies. “Low Engagement” represents independent citizens at the 5th percentile of political sophistication, while “High Engagement” represents strong partisans at the 95th percentile of political sophistication. Panel B holds partisan strength constant at its median value. High Engagement .2 .3 .4 .5 Low Engagement 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Need for Closure 29 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY GENERAL CONCLUSIONS The present paper seeks a synthesis of two research paradigms through a deeper examination of their common focus on the concepts of security and certainty. Both political economics-oriented and political psychology-oriented research in recent years emphasizes the importance of needs for security and certainty as antecedents of economic preferences, but do so in very distinct ways. While the former argues that such needs (whether common to all or in terms of individual differences) should be related to preferences for publically-provided social insurance, and thus economic liberalism (in its contemporary American sense), the latter suggests that such needs should drive opposition to government redistribution and social welfare in order to preserve status quo values, institutions, and socioeconomic arrangements. The present paper suggests that both perspectives identify an important dynamic existing within the mass public, but that there is heterogeneity across citizens defined by different levels of political engagement. The politically engaged, as a function of their attention to elite discourse, view economic conflicts as highly symbolic and ideological, and thus as battles over institutional stability and change. The politically unengaged, lacking exposure to the rhetoric which draws out the symbolic content of such issues, view these in more concrete and personal terms, and thus consider their implications for personal interests qua social protection. The punch line of this theoretical analysis is that the influence of personality qua needs for certainty and security should vary in qualitative form across levels of political engagement, with these needs predicting economic conservatism for the politically engaged, and economic liberalism for the politically unengaged. Across three years of American politics, two distinct measures of economic preferences, and two distinct measures of needs for certainty and security, I find very strong support for these expectations. In all cases, the “crossed” interactive pattern of 30 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY marginal effects is evident and of a substantial magnitude. Indeed, the effect sizes for needs for certainty and security rival, and in several cases exceed those of income. Simply put, the role of personality traits related to these dispositions is critical for understanding economic preference formation in U.S. politics among White Americans. The replications utilizing the oversamples of Black and Latino Americans yielded no meaningful influence of such needs, but given the small sample sizes, and limited number of tests, additional work is clearly needed to understand racial and ethnic heterogeneity in personality processes at a deeper level. The theory and findings of the present paper are important for a few reasons. First, scholars in political psychology, with few exceptions (e.g. Gerber et al. 2010), have struggled to find empirical support for the role of dispositions to preference formation in the economic domain. The present paper provides the strongest evidence to date of the importance of needs for certainty and security in the economic domain. Critically, however, the way in which such needs translate into economic preferences is distinct relative to other ideological domains. Lack of attention to this heterogeneity has likely hampered previous work, generating null results as a function of aggregation over political engagement (see also Feldman and Johnston 2009). The present theory offers an elegant solution to this problem, and suggests future lines of research. One potential avenue involves direct examination of citizens’ cognitive representations of economic issues, and how these moderate the translation of dispositions into preferences. This approach would be more in line with the social cognitive approach to personality in psychology (e.g. Cervone and Shoda; Mischel and Shoda 1995), and thus offers integrative potential with a literature focused on general psychological principles. Second, the present theory transcends debates over self-interest versus symbolic politics (e.g. Sears and Funk 1991), showing that both forms of political preference formation can be 31 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY rooted in identical antecedents, and that both are operative within the mass public. This implies less of a division between political economics and political psychology than is traditionally thought. It is my feeling that these literatures can be further integrated through theorizing which utilizes the common language of motivated social cognition (Jost et al. 2003; Kruglanski 1996; Kruglanski and Kopetz 2009; Sorrentino and Higgins 1986). This approach focuses on general cognitive principles of knowledge representation and accessibility in concert with the concepts of motivation and goal-directed behavior; the so-called “warm look” on social judgment (see Kruglanski and Kopetz 2009). In the present context, I have identified a basic set of psychological motives (i.e. needs for certainty and security), and argued that these interact with citizens’ representations of issues to predict preferences. By viewing such dispositions as goals or motives rather than “traits,” a junction point is created with more classical treatments of preference formation emphasizing rational choice and self-interest. Third, the critical role of political engagement to this dynamic suggests that future theorizing and research needs to reexamine the construct of engagement more generally. Historically, political science has focused on the political knowledge, or “sophistication,” aspects of this construct. From this view, lack of sophistication is akin to political ignorance, and preferences for such individuals are often considered rather meaningless, as “non-attitudes” in the classic words of Converse (1970). As shown above, however, lack of “sophistication” may simply imply a distinct way of viewing politics rather than a lack of systematic thought about politics. Far too little theorizing and empirical work has taken seriously the potential systematic nature of preferences among those who pay little attention to politics. The present paper suggests that there may be much “baby” in this supposed “bathwater.” 32 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Finally, the present results speak to contemporary debates over the importance of cultural conflict in American politics. Recent empirical work in political science has questioned the importance of the culture war on the basis of demonstrations that economic preferences remain the dominant predictor of voting behavior (e.g. Ansolabehere, Rodden and Snyder 2006; Bartels 2006; 2008; Gelman 2008). The present results, however, suggest that such analyses may not fully account for the importance of “cultural” factors, because they take economic preferences as givens in their models. As I have shown, such preferences are endogenous to psychological dispositions which constitute the dominant foundations for cultural orientations (see Hetherington and Weiler 2009; Jost et al. 2003). Recent work has considered whether the economic domain has been displaced by cultural conflict, but the present theory argues that economic preferences are actually shaped by dispositions related to culture, providing a distinct, and more subtle, mechanism by which cultural conflict impinges on American politics. 33 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY APPENDIX A. SUPPLEMENTAL RESULTS Table A1. Regressions of Preferences for Limited Government on Needs for Certainty and Security (NCS) and Controls for Full Samples (2000 and 2004) and Blacks and Latinos (2008 ANES) ______________________________________________________________________________ Variable 2000 ANES 2004 ANES Blacks Latinos ______________________________________________________________________________ NCS -.78 (.30)* -.86 (.35)* -.92 (.79) -.18 (.70) NCS X Soph 1.48 (.46)* 1.06 (.46)* .26 (1.08) -1.09 (1.06) NCS X Strength .60 (.41) .35 (.39) .69 (.80) 1.41 (.75)^ Sophistication Partisan Strength Age Male HS Degree Some College Associate Degree BA Degree Professional Degree Income Unemployed -.36 (.32) -.58 (.29)* .19 (.15) .31 (.07)* .17 (.12) .31 (.13)* .16 (.15) .24 (.14)^ .10 (.16) .98 (.25)* -.14 (.16) .30 (.32) -.41 (.26) .52 (.16)* .16 (.08)* -.07 (.15) .15 (.16) -.23 (.18) .12 (.17) -.33 (.19)^ .42 (.16)* -.14 (.19) -.22 (.88) -.90 (.66) .53 (.27)* .34 (.11)* .23 (.17) .21 (.19) .05 (.23) .17 (.25) -.59 (.41) -.21 (.26) -.26 (.18) .86 (.83) -1.16 (.57)* .52 (.28)^ .38 (.12)* .36 (.17)* .32 (.19)^ .67 (.25)* .67 (.23)* .50 (.28) .27 (.29) -.19 (.21) Cut 1 Cut 2 Cut 3 -.13 (.24) .42 (.24) .93 (.24) .03 (.29) .66 (.29) 1.22 (.29) -.37 (.67) .76 (.67) 1.60 (.68) .80 (.58) 1.73 (.58) 2.53 (.59) Pseudo R^2 .04 .05 .03 .05 N 1415 971 478 417 ______________________________________________________________________________ Notes: Entries are maximum likelihood ordered probit estimates and standard errors (in parentheses). *p<.05; ^p<.10. 34 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Table A2. Regressions of Economic Policy Conservatism on Needs for Certainty and Security (NCS) and Controls for Full Samples (2000 and 2004) and Blacks and Latinos (2008 ANES) ______________________________________________________________________________ Variable 2000 ANES 2004 ANES Blacks Latinos ______________________________________________________________________________ NCS -.08 (.06) -.15 (.07)* .21 (.17) -.03 (.17) NCS X Soph .22 (.10)* .22 (.09)* -.16 (.23) .09 (.25) NCS X Strength .08 (.09) .15 (.08)^ -.25 (.16)^ .03 (.18) Sophistication Partisan Strength Age Male HS Degree Some College Associate Degree BA Degree Professional Degree Income Unemployed Constant -.03 (.07) -.06 (.06) .06 (.03)* .01 (.01) .05 (.03)^ .09 (.03)* .08 (.03)* .07 (.03)* .07 (.03)* .20 (.05)* -.08 (.03)* .40 (.05)* -.02 (.06) -.07 (.05) .10 (.03)* .02 (.02) .04 (.03) .06 (.03)^ .02 (.04) .05 (.03) .00 (.04) .18 (.03)* -.08 (.04)* .29 (.06)* .10 (.18) .13 (.13) .12 (.06)* .03 (.02) .03 (.04) -.01 (.04) .01 (.05) .04 (.06) .00 (.07) -.04 (.06) -.04 (.03) .15 (.14) -.05 (.20) -.08 (.15) -.02 (.06) .01 (.03) .07 (.03)^ .10 (.04)* .09 (.06) .10 (.06)^ .06 (.07) .16 (.06)* .02 (.05) .23 (.14) R^2 .07 .12 .04 .06 N 1468 1003 476 416 ______________________________________________________________________________ Notes: Entries are ordinary least squares estimates and robust standard errors (in parentheses). *p<.05; ^p<.10. 35 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY APPENDIX B. QUESTION WORDINGS Government Spending and Services 2000 (Face-to-Face; reduced to 5 points), 2004 and 2008 (Old) Some people think the government should provide fewer services even in areas such as health and education in order to reduce spending. Suppose these people are at one end of a scale, at point 1. Other people feel it is important for the government to provide many more services even if it means an increase in spending. Suppose these people are at the other end, at point 7. And, of course, some other people have opinions somewhere in between, at points 2,3,4,5 or 6. 2000 (Phone) Some people think the government should provide fewer services even in areas such as health and education in order to reduce spending. Other people feel it is important for the government to provide many more services even if it means an increase in spending. [Respondents volunteering “stay the same” are coded at the midpoint] [If “Fewer” or “More” services, “should the government reduce/increase services a great deal, or only some?”]. 2008 (New) Do you think the government should provide MORE services than it does now, FEWER services than it does now, or ABOUT THE SAME NUMBER of services as it does now? [If “more” or “fewer,” “do you think the government should provide A LOT more/fewer, SOMEWHAT more/fewer, or SLIGHTLY more/fewer services than it does now?”] Government Health Insurance 2000 (Face-to-Face; reduced to 5 points), 2004 and 2008 (Old) Some people feel there should be a government insurance plan which would cover all medical and hospital expenses for everyone. Suppose these people are at one end of a scale, at point 1. Others feel that all medical expenses should be paid by individuals through private insurance plans like Blue Cross or other company paid plans. Suppose these people are at the other end, at point 7. And, of course, some other people have opinions somewhere in between, at points 2, 3, 4, 5, or 6. 2000 (Phone) Some people feel there should be a government insurance plan which would cover all medical and hospital expenses for everyone. Others feel that all medical expenses should be paid by individuals through private insurance plans like Blue Cross or other company paid plans. Which is closer to the way you feel or haven't you thought much about this? [Respondents could volunteer “Should stay the same”] [If R chooses one of options, “Do you feel strongly or not strongly?”] 36 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY 2008 (New) Do you FAVOR, OPPOSE, or NEITHER FAVOR NOR OPPOSE the U.S. government paying for all necessary medical care for all Americans? [If “Favor” or “Oppose,” do you favor that A GREAT DEAL, MODERATELY, or A LITTLE?”] Government Jobs and Income 2000 (Face-to-Face; reduced to 5 points) and 2004 Some people feel the government in Washington should see to it that every person has a job and a good standard of living. Suppose these people are at one end of a scale, at point 1. Others think the government should just let each person get ahead on their own. Suppose these people are at the other end, at point 7. And, of course, some other people have opinions somewhere in between, at points 2,3,4,5, or 6. 2000 (Phone) Some people feel the government in Washington should see to it that every person has a job and a good standard of living. Others think the government should just let each person get ahead on their own. Which is closer to the way you feel or haven't you thought much about this? [Respondents could volunteer “Should stay the same”] [If R chooses one of options, “Do you feel strongly or not strongly?”] Political Sophistication 2000 and 2004 Do you happen to know which party had the most members in the House of Representatives in Washington BEFORE the election (this/last) month? Do you happen to know which party had the most members in the U.S. Senate BEFORE the election (this/last) month? Now we have a set of questions concerning various public figures. We want to see how much information about them gets out to the public from television, newspapers and the like. 2000 Only 2004 Only JANET RENO TRENT LOTT DENNIS HASTERT DICK CHENEY Both 2000 and 2004 WILLIAM REHNQUIST TONY BLAIR 37 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY 2008 For political interest, respondents were randomly assigned to one of two operationalizations: A. Some people don't pay much attention to political campaigns. How about you? Would you say that you have been VERY MUCH interested, SOMEWHAT interested or NOT MUCH interested in the political campaigns so far this year? B. How interested are you in information about what's going on in government and politics? EXTREMELY INTERESTED, VERY INTERESTED, MODERATELY INTERESTED, SLIGHTLY INTERESTED, or NOT INTERESTED AT ALL? For political knowledge, the interviewer was asked the following: “R's general level of information about politics and public affairs seemed: Very high, Fairly high, Average, Fairly low, or Very low.” Both items were recoded to range from zero to one and averaged to form a single scale. 38 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY REFERENCES Amodio, David M., John T. Jost, Sarah L. Master, and Cindy M. Yee. 2007. “Neurocognitive Correlates of Liberalism and Conservatism.” Nature Neuroscience 10: 1246-1247. Ansolabehere, Stephen, Jonathan Rodden, and James M. Snyder Jr. 2006. “Purple America.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 (2): 97-118. Bartels, Larry M. 2006. “What’s the Matter with What’s the Matter with Kansas?” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 1: 201-226. Bartels, Larry M. 2008. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Berinsky, Adam J. 2007. “Assuming the Costs of War: Events, Elites, and American Public Support for Military Conflict.” The Journal of Politics 69 (4): 975-997. Botvinick, Matthew M., Jonathan D. Cohen, and Cameron S. Carter. 2004. “Conflict Monitoring and Anterior Cingulate Cortex: An Update.” Trends in Cognitive Sciences 8 (12): 539546. Carmines, Edward G., and James A. Stimson. 1980. “The Two Faces of Issue Voting.” American Political Science Review 74 (1): 78-91. Carney, Dana., John T. Jost, Samuel D. Gosling, and Jeff Potter. 2008. “The Secret Lives of Liberals and Conservatives: Personality Profiles, Interaction Styles, and the Things They Leave Behind.” Political Psychology 29 (6): 807-840. Cervone, Daniel, and Yuichi Shoda. 1999. The Coherence of Personality. New York: The Guilford Press. Chirumbolo, Antonio, Alessandra Areni, and Gilda Sensales. “Need for Cognitive Closure and Politics: Voting, Political Attitudes and Attributional Style.” International Journal of Psychology 39 (4): 245-253. Converse, Philip E. 1964. “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics.” In Ideology and Discontent, ed. David Apter. New York: Free Press, pp. 206-261. Converse, Philip E. 1970. “Attitudes and Non-Attitudes: Continuation of a Dialogue.” In The Quantitative Analysis of Social Problems, ed. Edward R. Tufte. Reading, MA: AddisonWesley. Cunningham, William A., Marcia K. Johnson, J. Chris Gatenby, John C. Gore, and Mahzarin R. Banaji. 2003. “Neural Components of Social Evaluation.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 85 (4): 639-649. 39 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Duckitt, John. 2001. “A Dual-Process Cognitive-Motivational Theory of Ideology and Prejudice.” In Advances in Experimental Social Psychology (vol. 33), ed. Mark P. Zanna. San Diego: Academic Press, pp. 41-112. Ehrlich, Sean, and Cherie Maestas. 2010. “Risk Orientation, Risk Exposure, and Policy Opinions: The Case of Free Trade.” Political Psychology 31 (5): 657-684. Federico, Christopher M., Emily L. Fisher, and Grace Deason. 2011. “Expertise and the Ideological Consequences of the Authoritarian Predisposition.” Public Opinion Quarterly 75 (4): 686-708. Federico, Christopher M., and Paul Goren. 2009. “Motivated Social Cognition and Ideology: Is Attention to Elite Discourse a Prerequisite for Epistemically Motivated Political Affinities?” In Social and Psychological Bases of Ideology and System Justification, eds. John T. Jost, Aaron C. Kay, and Hulda Thorisdottir. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Feldman, Stanley. 2003. “Enforcing Social Conformity: A Theory of Authoritarianism.” Political Psychology 24 (1): 41-74. Feldman, Stanley, and Christopher D. Johnston. 2009. “Understanding Political Ideology: The Necessity of a Multidimensional Conceptualization.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association. Gelman, Andrew. 2008. Red State, Blue State, Rich State, Poor State: Why Americans Vote the Way They Do. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Gerber, Alan S., Gregory A. Huber, David Doherty, Conor M. Dowling, and Shang E. Ha. 2010. “Personality and Political Attitudes: Relationships across Issue Domains and Political Contexts.” American Political Science Review 104 (1): 111-133. Golec, Agnieszka. 2001. “Need for Cognitive Closure and Political Conservatism: Studies on the Nature of the Relationship. Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the International Society of Political Psychology, Cuernavaca, Mexico. Green, Donald P., Bradley Palmquist, and Eric Schickler. 2002. Partisan Hearts and Minds: Political Parties and the Social Identities of Voters. New Haven: Yale University Press. Hetherington, Marc J., and Jonathan Weiler. 2009. Authoritarianism and Polarization in American Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press. Iversen, Torben. 2005. Capitalism, Democracy, and Welfare. New York: Cambridge University Press. Iversen, Torben, and David Soskice. 2001. “An Asset Theory of Social Policy Preferences.” American Political Science Review 95 (4): 875-893. 40 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Jost, John T., Christopher M. Federico, and Jaime L. Napier. 2009. “Political Ideology: Its Structure, Functions, and Elective Affinities.” Annual Review of Psychology 60: 307-337. Jost, John T., Jack Glaser, Arie W. Kruglanski, and Frank J. Sulloway. 2003. “Political Conservatism as Motivated Social Cognition.” Psychological Bulletin 129 (3): 339-375. Jost, John T., and Orsolya Hunyady. 2005. “Antecedents and Consequences of System-Justifying Ideologies.” Current Directions in Psychological Science 14 (5): 260-265. Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky. 1979. “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk.” Econometrica 47 (2): 263-292. Kam, Cindy D., and Elizabeth N. Simas. 2010. “Risk Orientations and Policy Frames.” Journal of Politics 72 (2): 381-396. Kerns, John G., Jonathan D. Cohen, Angus W. MacDonald III, Raymond Y. Cho, V. Andrew Stenger, and Cameron S. Carter. 2004. “Anterior Cingulate Conflict Monitoring and Adjustments in Control.” Science 303: 1023-1026. Kruglanski, Arie W. 1989. Lay Epistemics and Human Knowledge: Cognitive and Motivational Bases. New York: Plenum Press. Kruglanski, Arie W. 1996. “Motivated Social Cognition: Principles of the Interface.” In Social Psychology: Handbook of Basic Principles, E. Tory Higgins and Arie W. Kruglanski (Eds.). New York: The Guilford Press. Kruglanski, Arie W., and Donna M. Webster. 1996. “Motivated Closing of the Mind: ‘Seizing’ and ‘Freezing’.” Psychological Review 103 (2): 263-283. Kruglanski, Arie W., Donna M. Webster, and Adena Klem. 1993. “Motivated Resistance and Openness to Persuasion in the Presence or Absence of Prior Information.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 65(5): 861–876. Lavine, Howard, Diana Burgess, Mark Snyder, John Transue, John L. Sullivan, Beth Haney, and Stephen H. Wagner. 1999. “Threat, Authoritarianism, and Voting: An Investigation of Personality and Persuasion.” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 25 (3): 337-347. Lavine, Howard, Milton Lodge, James Polichak, and Charles Taber. 2002. “Explicating the Black Box Through Experimentation: Studies of Authoritarianism and Threat.” Political Analysis 10 (4): 343-361. Meltzer, Allan H., and Scott F. Richard. 1981. “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” The Journal of Political Economy 89 (5): 914-927. Mischel, Walter, and Yuichi Shoda. 1995. “A Cognitive-Affective System Theory of Personality: Reconceptualizing Situations, Dispositions, Dynamics, and Invariance in Personality Structure.” Psychological Review 102 (2): 246-268. 41 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Moene, Karl Ove, and Michael Wallerstein. 2001. “Inequality, Social Insurance, and Redistribution.” American Political Science Review 95 (4): 859-874. Mondak, Jeffery J. 2010. Personality and the Foundations of Political Behavior. New York: Cambridge University Press. Oxley, Douglas R., Kevin B. Smith, John R. Alford, Matthew V. Hibbing, and Jennifer L. Miller, Mario Scalora, Peter K. Hatemi, and John R. Hibbing. 2008. “Political Attitudes Vary with Physiological Traits.” Science 321: 1667-1670. Pollock, Philip H. III, Stuart A. Lilie, and Elliot Vittes. 1993. “Hard Issues, Core Values and Vertical Constraint: The Case of Nuclear Power.” British Journal of Political Science 23 (1): 29-50. Quattrone, George A., and Amos Tversky. 1988. “Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analyses of Political Choice.” American Political Science Review 82 (3): 719-736. Rehm, Philipp. 2009. “Risks and Redistribution: An Individual-Level Analysis.” Comparative Political Studies 42: 855-881. Sears, David O., and Carolyn L. Funk. 1991. “The Role of Self-Interest in Social and Political Attitudes.” In Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, vol. 24, Mark P. Zanna (Ed.). San Diego: Academic Press, Inc. Settle, Jaime E., Christopher T. Dawes, Nicholas A. Christakis, and James H. Fowler. 2010. “Friendships Moderate an Association between a Dopamine Gene Variant and Political Ideology.” Journal of Politics 72 (4): 1189-1198. Sinn, Hans-Werner. 1995. “A Theory of the Welfare State.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97 (4): 495-526. Sorrentino, Richard M., and E. Tory Higgins. 1986. Handbook of Motivation and Cognition: Foundations of Social Behavior. New York: The Guilford Press. Stenner, Karen. 2005. The Authoritarian Dynamic. New York: Cambridge University Press. Thorisdottir, Hulda, and John T. Jost. 2011. “Motivated Closed-Mindedness Mediates the Effect of Threat on Political Conservatism.” Political Psychology 32 (5):785-811. Thorisdottir, Hulda, John T. Jost, Ido Liviatan, and Patrick E. Shrout. 2007. “Psychological Needs and Values Underlying Left-Right Political Orientation: Cross-National Evidence From Eastern and Western Europe.” Public Opinion Quarterly 71 (2): 175-203. Van Hiel, Alain, Mario Pandelaere, and Bart Duriez. 2004. “The Impact of Need for Closure on Conservative Beliefs and Racism: Differential Mediation by Authoritarian Submission and Authoritarian Dominance.” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 30: 824-837. 42 PERSONALITY AND UNCERTAINTY Van Hiel, Alain, and Ivan Mervielde. 2004. “Openness to Experience and Boundaries in the Mind: Relationships with Cultural and Economic Conservative Beliefs.” Journal of Personality 72 (4): 659-686. Varian, Hal R. 1980. “Redistributive Taxation as Social Insurance.” Journal of Public Economics 14 (1): 49-68. Zaller, John R. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. New York: Cambridge University Press. 43