Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission April 2014 The Secretary Department of Treasury and Finance 1 Treasury Place Melbourne Victoria 3002 Australia Telephone: +61 3 9651 5111 Facsimile: +61 3 9651 5298 www.dtf.vic.gov.au Authorised by the Victorian Government 1 Treasury Place, Melbourne, 3002 © State of Victoria 2014 This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Australia licence. You are free to re-use the work under that licence, on the condition that you credit the State of Victoria as author. The licence does not apply to any images, photographs or branding, including the Victorian Coat of Arms, the Victorian Government logo and the Department of Treasury and Finance logo. Copyright queries may be directed to IPpolicy@dtf.vic.gov.au ISBN 978-1-92222-219-0 (pdf) Published April 2014 If you would like to receive this publication in an accessible format please email information@dtf.vic.gov.au This document is also available in PDF format at www.dtf.vic.gov.au Contents 1. Introduction .................................................................................................... 1 2. Provision, funding and financing ..................................................................... 7 2.1 Various public and private financing models may have a role to play ........................................7 2.1.1 Information Request 3.1.................................................................................................8 2.1.2 Information Request 5.1...............................................................................................10 2.1.3 Information Request 6.1...............................................................................................12 2.1.4 Information Request 6.2...............................................................................................13 2.1.5 Information Request 6.3...............................................................................................15 3. Better institutional and governance arrangements are crucial...................... 18 3.1 Background ................................................................................................................................18 3.1.1 Information Request 2.1 ..............................................................................................20 3.1.2 Information Request 7.2 ..............................................................................................20 3.1.3 Draft Recommendation 11.1 ........................................................................................22 3.1.4 Draft Recommendation 11.2 ........................................................................................24 3.1.5 Draft Recommendation 11.3 ........................................................................................24 3.1.6 Draft Recommendation 11.4 ........................................................................................24 3.1.7 Draft Recommendation 11.5 ........................................................................................25 3.1.8 Draft Recommendation 11.7 ........................................................................................25 3.1.9 Information Request 11.1.............................................................................................26 3.1.10 Information Request 11.3.............................................................................................27 3.1.11 Draft Recommendation 11.9 ........................................................................................28 Attachment A – Treasury Corporation of Victoria PPP Modelling scenarios ............. 29 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 i 1. Introduction The Victorian Government is committed to responsibly managing its budget to support a sustained program of infrastructure development and continued high quality services for Victorians while avoiding excessive levels of debt. The Government’s financial strategy aims to ensure that debt and debt servicing costs do not grow faster than Gross State Product and result in a rising relative tax burden. With the Commonwealth’s greater funding capacity, and being the direct financial beneficiary of productivity enhancements through increased taxation revenue, the Commonwealth is a key partner in the delivery of infrastructure. Investing in productivity enhancing infrastructure is a key priority of the Victorian Government. However there is a complex feedback loop between infrastructure investment, productivity growth, tax burden, competitiveness and cost of living pressures. As the Draft Report acknowledges, states are constrained in terms of their ability to use their tax base to service additional debt. Cost-benefit analysis in economic evaluations While cost benefit analysis is the key tool in evaluating projects, it can sometimes represent a relatively narrow measure of economic costs and benefits directly related to an initiative/project. A positive benefit cost ratio (BCR) is generally a good evaluator of respective projects’ economic impacts for the purpose of guiding prioritisation (and indicate that on balance the initiative represents an economic good). However BCRs do have limitations and should not necessarily be the sole indicator to demonstrate the true value of an investment. To address these issues Victoria’s business cases articulate other relevant quantitative and qualitative factors which are not picked up in the standard BCR, for example ‘wider economic benefits’ (WEBs), and any distributional impacts (where this may be a stated/relevant objective). As an economic, not financial analysis tool, a positive BCR gives no indication of financial sustainability, that is a project’s capacity to ‘pay for itself’ over time without the need to raise taxes. Currently, almost all government projects would result in a negative financial return to government, regardless of the economic BCR. From a state perspective the key decision making drivers therefore also include the impact of an investment on the state’s budget sustainability, competiveness, Gross State Product and growth potential. Nevertheless, Victoria acknowledges the importance of BCR analysis as a tool to inform investment prioritisation, and agrees with the Draft Report’s emphasis on the importance of transparent cost benefit analysis to guide decision making around competing priorities. Victoria’s Economic Evaluation Guidelines follow a similar approach to that endorsed in the Draft Report. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 1 Build now or build later? Given the significant upfront expenditure involved in economic infrastructure and usually long periods over which benefits accrue, the question of when to build can be as significant as whether to build. Put simply, if the cost savings from waiting, including time value of money or reduced interest on debt or reduced taxation, exceed the benefits foregone and inflation impacts during a period of wait then build, then the BCR may increase during the period of wait then build. As an example, delivering a transport project with spare capacity earlier than optimal has a higher cost, such that even if the project has strong BCR now, it could have a reduced economic benefit compared to waiting and investing later. Effectively, the Government has a portfolio of "in the money call options" over most positive BCR infrastructure projects and the decision of when and in what order to exercise these options is relevant. Where several projects are in a network any analysis is even more complicated. The potential impact of waiting should also be important in considering the role of BCRs in ranking or prioritising projects. The Productivity Commission may wish to consider whether a simple prioritisation of highest BCR first without considering the ability to wait can result in sub optimal decision making. An alternative construct to any projects in a bottom up identification of an "infrastructure deficit" is to think of them as a portfolio of in the money options on projects which should be assessed for when is the optimal time to exercise and build rather than simply assume they should all be built now. Analysis of cost drivers The Draft Report highlights the broad range of factors that impact construction costs and makes a number of practical recommendations to effectively manage the cost of infrastructure delivery. In considering these factors, there can be a disproportionate focus on ways to reduce the cost of private sector finance or further review contractual risk allocation to the private sector partners in infrastructure delivery. It is relevant to also consider (and as noted in the Draft Report) that public private partnership (PPP) projects, average around 10 – 15 per cent of capital investment program in the Victorian Government’s General Government Sector. The cost of private sector finance is therefore only directly relevant to this 10-15 per cent of the State’s capital spend. Analysis by the Treasury Corporation of Victoria (TCV) demonstrates that even for this 10-15 per cent of capital expenditure, reducing construction costs in relative terms has the greatest impact on reducing the whole of life cost of the infrastructure project to the State. The TCV analysis points to the conclusion that private sector introducing design and service delivery innovation and efficiencies in construction, operation and maintenance and overall whole life costs has greater potential to make material contributions to infrastructure affordability than financial engineering reducing costs of private sector finance. Compared to reducing construction or operating costs, reducing the cost of private sector debt or equity by a an equivalent amount will have a smaller impact on the overall net present value of infrastructure projects. Achieving those same relative reductions has different difficulties and complexities but Victoria considers that efforts in reducing 2 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 construction costs (including bid costs) and time, and achieving design and service delivery innovation should drive resource prioritisation. As well as the service outcomes achieved a relevant metric for judging the effectiveness of our capital program is net present whole of life cost. There are many examples of better design which can have a higher capital cost leading to more effective service outcomes and operational capability and lower operating and maintenance costs. The TCV analysis is at Attachment A and is further discussed below. State’s broad infrastructure investment The Terms of Reference have set the Commission’s focus on economic infrastructure, although the Draft Report (p 48) does state that the report also covers social infrastructure. Victoria reinforces that a significant annual component of the State’s General Government Sector (GGS) capital expenditure is on social infrastructure which, by its nature is usually unsuitable for user pays regimes and which has a less direct impact on productivity. The large quantum of investment required in social infrastructure, and the resultant call on recurrent operating expenditure is an important consideration when assessing budget capacity and sustainability of budgets and borrowings. Apart from roads much of the State’s investment in economic infrastructure is through Public Non-Financial Corporations (PNFCs), such as water authorities. The majority of Government Trading Entities (GTEs) discussed in the Draft Report in Victoria are either PNFC or Public Financial Corporations (PFCs) such as TCV, VFMC, VMIA or VWA that do not directly deliver infrastructure. While many of the themes of the Draft Report also apply to GGS social infrastructure, some draft findings and draft recommendations will have limited direct applicability particularly as noted given the limited ability to apply user pays models to social infrastructure. Table 1 below published in the 2013-14 Victorian Budget shows the large investment in the GGS in non-economic infrastructure. Broadly, the State’s capital expenditure can be grouped into four categories: 1) the vast majority of Victoria’s infrastructure investment is financed and funded through general revenue and borrowings in the GGS (most social and transport infrastructure, much of which is not suited to user charges); 2) availability payment PPP projects are financed by the private sector, and funded through general government revenue (some social and transport projects in GGS); 3) a small proportion of demand risk transfer PPP projects that are financed by the private sector and either funded wholly or partly from third party revenue streams (some toll roads in GGS); and 4) infrastructure financed by PNFC borrowings and funded from the user charges they collect. In accordance with international accounting standards availability PPP project assets and liabilities are on balance sheet and impact net debt, and are therefore also highly relevant in the context of budget capacity and sustainability. Full demand risk transfer toll roads are currently off balance sheet. The State presents two balance sheets, that of the general government sector and a whole of State balance sheet which consolidates our Government Trading Entities (GTEs), our PFCs and our PNFCs. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 3 In respect of availability based PPPs in Victoria, it is incorrect to say "long-term funding by governments via payments to the private party do not show up on the government’s balance sheet as debt" (Draft Report p 97 seems inconsistent with other sections including p 14). Similarly, the long term availability payments are not "hidden contingent liabilities" (Draft Report p 174). The research referred to was relevant to earlier PFI deals in the UK and Europe. We would also like to clarify comments about GTEs (Draft Report p 159 and 160) in case the terms "off budget" might be confused by the reader with "off balance sheet". The full liabilities of GTEs are consolidated and fully shown in the whole of government balance sheet. They may or may not have implicit or explicit guarantees from the State. The term "budget sector" is often used to describe the GGS. Generally GTEs are "off budget" to the extent they do not appropriate from budget sources and are not in the GGS balance sheet. However some GTEs receive budget funding. We note that one rating agency classifies some, but not all, GTE debt as "self sustaining" where it is fully serviced from third party charges when considering credit ratings. It is not strictly accurate to say "but the [GTE] debt will generally not be reflected in the government’s overall credit rating" (Draft Report p 160). Table 1: Purchase of non-financial assets by government purpose classification (a) ($millions) General public services Public order and safety Education Health Social security and welfare Housing and community amenities Recreation and culture Fuel and energy Agriculture, forestry, fishing and hunting Mining, manufacturing and construction Transport and communications Other economic affairs Other purposes Not allocated by purpose (b) Total purchases of non-financial assets 2013-14 2014-15 2015-16 2016-17 Budget Estimate Estimate Estimate 197.0 120.3 106.7 105.3 847.5 566.0 245.5 246.3 518.9 365.2 244.8 242.0 1 147.9 842.0 756.3 554.2 154.5 108.4 97.6 31.6 173.7 116.8 76.9 72.9 157.1 87.4 72.1 40.6 4.3 2.7 2.4 .. 61.5 22.7 10.9 6.3 0.1 0.1 0.1 .. 2 047.8 1 584.9 894.3 525.8 58.3 18.8 17.6 4.2 0.7 0.4 0.4 .. ( 500.3) 301.0 819.1 2 022.7 4 868.9 4 136.7 3 344.7 3 851.9 Notes: 4 (a) Classifications have been determined using ratios based on historical data and the impact of policy and non-policy estimate variations. (b) Estimated amount available to be allocated to departments and projects in future budgets. This includes departmental underspending, which may be subject to carryover. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 By way of comparison the following table, extracted from data published in the 2013-14 Victorian Budget, summarises the scale of Victoria’s PNFC sector capital investment program. Table 2: Public non-financial corporations capital program 2013-14 – summary (excluding Vic Track) ($millions) Entities (by sector) Metropolitan Water Entities New & existing projects Total Estimated Estimated Expenditure Investment to 30.06.13 Estimated Expenditure Remaining 2013-14 Expenditure 5 187 1 403 955 2 829 Non-Metropolitan Water Entities New & existing projects 7 399 2 504 756 4 139 Director of Housing New & existing projects 1 152 322 237 593 Other Entities New & existing projects 774 294 218 262 14 511 4 522 2 165 7 823 Total Notes:(a) Data extracted from the 2013-3014 Victorian Budget, State Capital Program, Budget Paper No.4. Accountability framework Victoria continues to look for opportunities for efficient and effective decision making and timely project delivery. As an investor, it is critical that governments clearly scope and define projects, put in place effective governance structures and ensure that project teams have the necessary skills and capabilities. The Government has taken action to introduce policy and process requirements to reinforce and improve infrastructure delivery practices and accountability in Victoria both in the GGS and the PNFC sector. These actions build on and have strengthened Victoria’s devolved accountability and risk based governance arrangements. This includes processes focused on holding departments and agencies more accountable for effective infrastructure delivery, including through increased scrutiny of major projects by central agencies and the Government. Infrastructure is about facilitating service delivery to the community and is not just about building things. There is significant alignment in ensuring those responsible for the ultimate service delivery also are accountable for the scope definition, cost and quality of the asset. The Government, in its investor capacity within the GGS, receives information and advice from departments, central agencies and other relevant experts to help it make informed GGS investment decisions. Ultimately it is the responsibility of executive Government to determine investment priorities and ensure effective planning processes are in place. Victoria does not consider it necessary to have independent institutional structures in place to prioritise or veto decisions on GGS infrastructure investment. While an independent body may help provide investment advice, it does not have a democratic mandate to make final investment decisions. Elected governments are best placed to prioritise scarce taxpayer resources. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 5 The accountability framework within the PNFC sector is different. Here the Government sets the objectives and functions of the state owned enterprises through its enabling legislation, statement of expectations or corporate planning process. Day to day oversight of the PNFC is through an independent board, whose appointment is skills/experience based. The Government, as shareholder, ensures accountability through the corporate planning process. In utilities, such as the water authorities, the Essential Services Commission has a regulatory function which includes regulatory decisions around the utilities’ infrastructure investment. Construction industry productivity The Victorian Government continues to implement a range of measures to address productivity in the construction industry including the Implementation Guidelines to the Victorian Code of Practice for the Building and Construction Industry. The Victorian Government is supportive of the two draft recommendations on this issue: • 12.1 - All Australian governments should adopt the Victorian building and code guidelines for their own major infrastructure purchases; and • 12.2 - The Australian Government should increase the ceiling of penalties for unlawful industrial relations conduct in the construction industry. This supplementary submission responds to some of the information requests, where the Victorian Government considers it can usefully contribute to the public debate, further to the information provided in the initial Victorian Government submission dated January 2014. Responses are grouped under the headings identified in the Draft Report. 6 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 2. Provision, funding and financing 2.1 Various public and private financing models may have a role to play PPP projects in Victoria have continued to demonstrate there is an active and competitive private finance market for GGS infrastructure. The PNFC sector is also able to easily tap private sector finance, however Victoria provides capital to our PNFC sector through centralised borrowings via Treasury Corporation of Victoria (TCV), usually at competitively neutral rates. The Victorian Government agrees with draft finding 5.1 that there is no shortage of private sector capital. There is much public discussion around the merits and costs associated with private finance in public infrastructure. Where applicable to specific projects, introducing private finance can be critical to driving competitive efficiencies and also has the benefit of fostering innovation by the private sector. In looking for further improvements to the PPP model, it remains useful context to reinforce that reducing core infrastructure costs has the greatest impact on lowering total whole of life costs compared to reducing the cost of the private debt finance or equity, as shown in Figure 1 below. In demonstrating this point, TCV has completed some modeling based on a standard availability PPP project. The full TCV report is at Attachment A to the submission. The key finding is that for the ten to fifteen per cent of infrastructure typically financed by PPPs reducing a hypothetical project’s construction cost (including bid and design costs) has the greatest net present cost (NPC) sensitivity. The same relative changes in financing fees and margins and Facilities Management (FM)/consortium costs have a lesser impact. This is driven by the fact that the project’s construction cost is directly correlated with the amount of capital required (both debt and equity). This in turn drives the required amounts to be serviced in the PPP structure and therefore reducing construction costs reduces the quantum of both debt and equity outstanding and the associated interest costs and equity distributions. A range of baseline profiles were tested against five, ten and twenty per cent reductions in the key cost drivers. The figure below demonstrates the impact on a typical project’s NPC from a five per cent reduction in the key inputs. Notwithstanding that achieving a five per cent reduction in construction costs has different complexities and difficulties to achieving a the same reduction in financing costs, the analysis suggests that efforts in reducing construction costs (including bid costs) and time can result in much larger impacts on infrastructure affordability than financial engineering merely improving financing costs, and hence this should drive resource prioritisation. One outcome from introducing private finance in PPPs is that the active role of the private sector is expected to introduce design and service delivery innovation and efficiencies in construction, operation and maintenance and overall whole life costs compared to non PPPs. The TCV analysis is relevant in directing efforts for where to improve PPPs further. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 7 Figure 1 – Project cost sensitivities at 5% These results demonstrate that a priority for reform should be to focus efforts on reducing the overall construction cost of infrastructure projects. 2.1.1 Information Request 3.1 The Commission seeks examples of where privately delivered public infrastructure project tender processes at the Australian Government or state or territory level have failed to meet the public sector comparator. PPPs are one of many procurement options used to deliver infrastructure in Victoria, including design and construct, alliancing and managing contractor. PPPs have typically made up around ten per cent of the annual capital investment. The Public Sector Comparator (PSC) is a key cost benchmarking tool to assess value for money in PPP projects. Different types of cost benchmarking is used for other procurement methodologies. In design and construct and alliance contracting it is a competitive market response that determines affordability to ensure value for money. The PSC methodology started with the early PPPs when governments were looking to satisfy themselves that in the absence of a deep and competitive market for PPPs at the time that the outcomes were providing taxpayers with value for money. Until recently, the PSC has been used as a pass/fail benchmark to determine whether or not PPP delivery will result in a value for money outcome, when compared to traditional State project delivery. This approach assumes that where a PPP tender process fails the PSC value for money benchmark, PPP delivery is deemed not to deliver value and the Government then has the option of reverting back to traditional delivery with the PSC forming the basis of the project's budget and scope. In practice, there is now a deep and competitive market for PPPs and it has been extremely rare that a tender process would be discontinued in situations where tenderers failed to meet the PSC for a PPP project in Victoria. 8 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 The PSC is an important tool to ensure that government is an informed buyer and has the knowledge to drive competitive outcomes during the tender process. Partnerships Victoria projects have delivered over $1 billion of savings (using September 2011 dollars) when compared with the PSC. However, there are limitations and the PSC as an absolute value for money benchmark has attracted significant criticism at times, including: • the PSC necessarily is a point-in-time estimate that can become dated when used to benchmark live/evolving tender processes; • the PSC is generally built up using desk top quantity surveying methodology and is therefore more theoretical compared to actual tenders, because it is not market tested; and • the PSC can be significantly impacted by underlying assumptions that can vary significantly during the bid period, such as cost escalations, fluctuations in interest rates including exchange rates (through the discount rates) and risk adjustments. Value for money is a broader concept that encompasses the quantitative PSC analysis and qualitative factors. It is important to note that where market testing of the PSC in a competitive PPP tender environment suggests an underpricing/over-scoping problem with the PSC (i.e. ‘failure’ to beat the PSC), this is not necessarily an indication that merely changing procurement methodology would lead to a different outcome. Changing approach could also result in delays to the process. In May 2013, the Victorian Government announced various enhancements to Victoria’s existing PPP policy, via the release of the revised Partnerships Victoria Requirements document. Importantly, these enhancements included the following reforms to the application of the PSC in PPP tender processes: i. the PSC will no longer represent a pass/fail test, however will still be applied as a cost benchmark for tenderers to beat (in a competitive environment). Therefore there will no longer be an assumption that if the PSC is not met through the tender process that the Government will revert to traditional State delivery; ii. the Department of Treasury and Finance will engage an independent external advisor to review the PSC and ensure its robustness, prior to Government approval of the RFP (in addition to the quality assurance workshop required to be conducted by procuring agencies); iii. procuring agencies will be required to develop a scope ladder for approval alongside the PSC, in order to identify a priority of scope items which tenderers may remove or add depending on where their pricing sits in relation to the PSC (essentially allowing tenderers to compete on scope as well as price); and iv. the current practice of disclosing the raw PSC to tenderers will continue, but consideration may be given to disclosing the full PSC, where particularly complex projects could benefit from this. The information request 3.1 specifically relates to the Public Sector Comparator and PPP projects. In reviewing projects since 2000, no Victorian PPP project has seen private bids fail the PSC test and the project revert to an alternative procurement methodology. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 9 Project example – The Victorian Comprehensive Cancer Centre The Victorian Comprehensive Cancer Centre (VCCC) is a recent example of the complexities inherent in establishing a PSC and associated reference design at a point in time well in advance of proposal submission by tenderers. Victoria took the lessons learnt from this and other experiences, as well as market feedback, in developing Victoria’s reforms in relation to the application of the PSC. The VCCC project tender process commenced in September 2009 with the release of an Expression of Interest to the market. Divergences between the market’s interpretation of the tender documentation and the State’s PSC/reference design emerged during the Request for Proposal phase. This led to clarification being sought by both tenderers and the State and eventually resulted in an additional procurement stage. A joint Department of Treasury and Finance and Department of Health review of the process highlighted areas for improvement in PSC/reference design development practices. One of the key findings was that reverting to traditional delivery was not likely to resolve the discrepancies, which were due to a number of different factors. Instead, the State successfully negotiated a contract with the preferred tenderer by implementing a combination of measures, predominantly around better defining project requirements to eliminate possible premium risk pricing by tenderers, sharper alignment of project requirements with PSC cost and risk estimates and introducing an alternative financing structure (as the project financing requirement was considered above the efficient threshold in the project financing market at the time). 2.1.2 Information Request 5.1 The Commission seeks feedback on the availability of bond finance for public infrastructure projects in Australia. • To what extent are there impediments to the development of the Australian bond market to support investment in infrastructure? • To what extent are there barriers to Australian infrastructure firms accessing international bond markets? It is generally acknowledged that following the collapse of monoline insurers during the Global Financial Crisis (GFC), bond finance became unavailable or unaffordable for PPP projects. However, there has been a gradual return of bond market appetite for PPP project risk in the last two years or so, mainly for brownfields refinancings. The refinancing of the Victorian Desalination Plant project in October 2013 provides a recent example of effective utilisation of bond financing for an Australian PPP. The refinancing included a combination of bank debt tranches (with varying tenors), domestic bonds (issued in the Australian Medium Term Note (AMTN) market) and US and Australian dollar denominated bonds issued in the US Private Placement (USPP) market. As part of the US bond issuance, Project Co (the concessionaire under the Project Deed) put in place cross currency swaps to mitigate exposure to foreign exchange risk associated with the US dollar denominated bonds. The diversified sources and tenors of the refinanced senior debts contributed to the favourable pricing achieved for each debt tranche, and have significantly reduced future refinancing risk for the project. This is the first time that an Australian PPP has utilised the USPP market as a funding source. The introduction of USPP 10 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 bonds into the Australian PPP market is a positive step for the Australian PPP financing market, which will likely enhance competition for future PPP transactions in Australia, providing greater depth for capacity and pricing. Bond investors are typically long-term investors and require payment of interest unearned in the event of early termination. In the desalination project refinancing, Victoria, in conjunction with Project Co, was successful in negotiating out this "make whole" provision that is standard in all bond issues domestically and internationally. This provision would have exposed the State to a considerably higher termination liability. In addition, Victoria was able to secure a non-standard clause in the USPP issuance to allow the State to elect to either pay or take novation of the bonds and associated cross currency swaps in the event of early termination. This provides greater flexibility for the State to consider the most appropriate method of payment at the time of an early termination, given there may be budget and/or other constraints at the time. Bond markets are attractive when compared to bank debt as they provide an opportunity for longer term funding, limiting a project’s exposure to future refinancing risk. Prior to the Victorian Desalination Plant refinancing there had been a number of other PPP projects utilising the local AMTN bond market such as the EastLink toll road. There had also been several private placements in the US market (for non-PPP projects). Other infrastructure firms (eg Transurban) regularly access both domestic and international bond markets, however these debts are predominantly raised at the corporate level rather than at the specific asset level. Since the GFC there has been limited appetite amongst PPP investors in Australia for PPP project bonds, particularly there is a marked absence of investors taking bid cost as well as construction risks. The gradual ‘come back’ of the bond market to PPPs has been limited to refinancing transactions, where projects have been significantly ‘derisked’ by the completion of the construction phase, once steady state operations have commenced. While overseas bond markets provide better prospects, accessing these markets has currency risk implications; i.e. repayments may vary according to fluctuations in the exchange rate. As per the Victorian Desalination Plant refinancing, cross-currency swaps would be required to give the State and private parties certainty regarding interest rate and principal exposure. For this reason at an individual project level international bond issuances are still relatively expensive compared to domestic bank debt or bond markets. In Victoria entities in the PNFC sector generally borrow at market neutral rates from TCV. These PNFCs, particularly the regulated ones, could be expected to be able to access bond financing, as comparable private sector companies, should the shareholder wish to. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 11 2.1.3 Information Request 6.1 The Commission seeks views on the costs and benefits of governments issuing project specific infrastructure bonds, with the interest rates reflecting the risks of the project and which explicitly do not have a government guarantee. The proposition of project specific infrastructure bonds is probably more relevant for projects with third party / user charges type revenue streams, which typically represents a very small percentage of the Victorian Government’s GGS infrastructure spend but is more relevant for our PNFCs. Victoria supports transparent cost recovery, including the true cost of finance, from users as an efficient use of capital. As noted above in Victoria the PNFC sector invests in economic infrastructure and generally recovers the cost of the investments via user charges. These entities are assigned a rating equivalent by the State or can obtain shadow ratings from a ratings agency. Based on this, funding is made available to them on market neutral rates. For a regulated water company the costs ultimately borne by the water users will reflect interest rates representative of the risks of that entity including their projects. We note that internationally regulated private sector utilities appear to finance much of their capital programmes through borrowings at the corporate level rather than through extensive use of project financing for specific programmes. The private sector analogy to the GGS or a PNFC issuing project specific infrastructure bonds would be a private sector entity choosing to project finance rather than corporate finance a project with similar pros and cons. In the context of economic infrastructure investments with third party revenue streams within the GGS, there appears to be little benefit to the State issuing project specific bonds to fund construction compared with the State funding construction and then selling a constructed asset with a proven revenue stream. If the driver is ensuring a transparent cost of funds for the risks, States could achieve the same result through a PPP structure where the PPP concessionaire issues project specific financing and assumes additional construction and operating risks. Where third party revenues ultimately fully repay the upfront financing costs, if structured as PPPs, these projects generally sit off balance sheet, for example selffunded projects like toll roads. There may be some advantages to a Government issued GGS project specific infrastructure bond if this funding form is considered self-sustaining debt for rating agency purposes. This could be a minor advantage during the construction period compared with a counter factual of the State funding construction and then selling a constructed asset with a proven revenue stream and recycling the proceeds for debt reduction or further infrastructure investment. There may also be investor appetite for Consumer Price Index (CPI) or Gross State Product linked instruments (such as a GGS issued specific infrastructure bond) or potentially where investors are reaching exposure limits for individual State debt instruments. The question raised is whether this is an efficient pricing model for funding where investors will be exposed to a single project rather than say a portfolio of assets through government bonds or bonds issued in a broader government infrastructure fund or through PNFCs directly accessing private sector capital. The other question is whether this type of revenue stream will attract a different asset allocation and/or new class of investors, which might occur in a retail offering of bonds. 12 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 However, some of the inflexibilities and costs associated with such bonds, as identified in the Productivity Commission’s Draft Report, may increase costs to manage and issue this class of financing instrument compared to straight government debt. Victoria considers that the merits of issuing project specific revenue (as opposed to debt) instruments or quasi equity instruments could be investigated further. The illiquid and long term nature of investing in PPP equity together with the size of the investment required and the bid costs can make investing in PPP equity relatively unattractive to small to medium sized super funds. Alternative structures may offer better value, depending on specific project characteristics and market conditions. For example, where the State builds a toll road and retains toll revenues until a proven revenue stream is established, revenue sharing units of varying maturities (e.g. 1 year, 3 years or 5 years) can then be divested, in denominations suitable for small, medium and large sized institutional investors. This approach could potentially broaden and deepen the available pool of finance which is likely to result in a competitive effective cost of capital. This potentially offers the market an attractive infrastructure equity product not otherwise available unless made available for the State. Victoria believes that alternative structures should continue to be assessed against existing alternatives. There is deep and wide demand for project specific infrastructure debt issued by PPP companies which would appear to be very similar to project specific debt if issued by Government. As noted above, the TCV analysis points to the conclusion that private sector introducing design and service delivery innovation and efficiencies in construction, operation and maintenance and overall whole life costs has greater potential to make material contributions to infrastructure affordability than financial engineering reducing costs of private sector finance. 2.1.4 Information Request 6.2 The Commission seeks views on the costs and benefits of governments issuing converting infrastructure bonds to finance greenfields infrastructure investments. The potential benefits of converting infrastructure bonds are described as in effect a forward sale of the asset, while issuing low cost debt and then transferring the asset and borrowings off balance sheet at completion. The suggestion is that the end result would be identical to a conventional PPP, but that the risks would be better matched. This proposition is relevant for projects with third party / user charges type revenue streams, which typically represents a very small percentage of the Victorian Government’s GGS infrastructure spend. However, all other types of projects including availability based PPP arrangements remain on balance sheet for government either through debt to fund capital or service provision or recorded as finance lease liabilities. Since the service payments are government obligations for government directed services, subject to performance measures such as abatements, such payments are unlikely to be off balance sheet. It is not clear how a converting debt could extinguish the State’s obligations for service payments to be recorded as a balance sheet liability. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 13 Furthermore, given the materially different capital structure, i.e. 100% equity for operations period, this may not necessarily lead to better value for money outcomes compared to a typically geared private financed arrangement, which gives rise to tax deductions for the special purpose vehicle. During the construction period, if the commercial drivers are similar to other privately financed projects, then the government may not wish to provide interest during construction, and this is likely to be attractive to a smaller pool of investors. If, as proposed, a fixed coupon were to be paid during the construction period, this potentially cuts across the financial discipline of reaching practical completion by paying out on debt during construction. Bondholders in PPP structures provide a stable funding structure, potentially for the full term of a project. However, when it comes to negotiating changes or responding to commercial outcomes, the bond trustee’s mandate is generally not as flexible as the privately financed sponsor vehicle model with institutional lending arrangements. Overall, the proposed benefits of the converting infrastructure bonds do not appear to have any advantages over traditional government financing and asset disposal post completion. Furthermore, the deepest and most competitive pool of investors is arguably available where government funds construction and bears that risk and then disposes of an asset with known and proven cash flows. Notwithstanding the above, the instrument could achieve some of the robust features of PPPs including transferring construction risks, innovation and whole of life costing. However, the Victorian Government generally agrees with the Productivity Commission’s reservations about the design and operation of converting infrastructure bonds. As noted above, the TCV analysis points to the conclusion that private sector introducing design and service delivery innovation and efficiencies in construction, operation and maintenance and overall whole life costs has greater potential to make material contributions to infrastructure affordability than financial engineering reducing costs of private sector finance. 14 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 2.1.5 Information Request 6.3 The Commission seeks feedback on the advantages and disadvantages of alternative procurement processes focused on long-term equity, such as an ‘inverted bid’ model. In particular, the Commission is interested in how an alternative procurement process should be designed to maximise efficiency gains and the likely benefits and costs of such an approach. Inverted bid model Victoria’s view is that the current PPP model will usually be preferable because the State receives a complete bid, with all aspects of the transaction competitively tendered concurrently and risk positions agreed. This approach enhances the chances of a bid being kept whole and not re-opened and allows the State to evaluate the net present cost of the whole of life cost to the State. A primary advantage of the current PPP model is the competitive tension that is integrated and internalised in the bidding vehicle to produce an tightly priced mix of service, construction and financing during tendering. In considering different bid structures, the State is mindful of service and design outcomes, risks to the State, complexity and value for money. As indicated in the original submission, Victoria analyses alternative financing structures against a framework of criteria, to guide project specific decisions on these issues. Victoria considers the disadvantages of the inverted bid model include: the disproportional emphasis on the equity and its returns, relative to the benefits of a complete package; the cost of equity, rather than the potential to value add, is the determinant of selecting the equity partner; the loss of the complex risk allocation negotiation and integration between construction, operations delivery and financing, which increase the chances of risk allocations and pricing changing post equity bid; and it potentially creates a mismatch for equity between what equity is willing to absorb and what downstream contractors can absorb or price. Equity may seek to address uncertainty by either gold-plating or de-risking, resulting in higher overall costs in areas such as construction costs, security packages and liquidated damages compared to the lower cost of equity. While there is alignment of long term equity holders’ interests and infrastructure assets, the disproportional emphasis on equity returns upfront does not suit most transactions and is reflected by the TCV modelling, discussed earlier, which highlights that reducing the cost of equity in a PPP transaction has a relatively minor impact on the overall NPV. Breaking up an infrastructure tender into different components and competing each component separately introduces additional risk to the bid process particularly the risks around re-opening of price or risk allocation in later stages. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 15 Victoria’s view is the likely commercial, risk and return requirements of debt and equity are more ‘commodity like’ and capable of benchmarking than the risk positions of subcontractors. Consequently, there is likely to be more risk and potential ultimate cost to the State in using and responding to an inverted bid model leading to an initial ‘unsubcontractable’ position than using a debt and equity competition model resulting in an initial ‘unbankable’ position. Either position is usually fixed through the State assuming more risk or a higher price, but it is considered that there is a higher prospect of arriving at the “un-subcontractable” position. The UK considers that funding competitions can be appropriate where: analogous projects in the same sector have already been successfully delivered by a range of bidders; the likelihood of procuring finance is not in question; the project is not novel, complex, large or likely to involve non-traditional funding sources; experience on successive projects has shown that the terms of finance are reasonably predictable and therefore the Government’s advisors should be able to anticipate the terms; and innovation in financial structuring is unlikely. If the Productivity Commission were considering recommendations on an alternative bid model process, Victoria is of the view that a UK style ‘debt and equity finance competition’ post preferred bidder, where projects are not novel, complex or large, may result in superior outcomes than an inverted bid model because: • the design and service outcomes are the most important results to the State so we would prefer to lock in the most complex and important elements first; • the design and construction and operating costs are the key contributors to whole of life net present cost compared to differences in equity returns; competitively locking in the biggest cost contributor first is more likely to drive value for money; and • in our view there is less chance of a debt and equity competition model leading to an ‘unbankable’ position and the State having to take on more cost or risk as a result, than an inverted model leading to an ‘un-subcontractable’ position and the State having to take on more cost or risk as a result. Victoria acknowledges that for a project with the right characteristics, the ‘inverted bid’ model may offer value over and above the traditional/complete bid model and facilitate a ‘best in breed’ concept where components are competitively tendered. This potential benefit may not outweigh the advantages of an integrated package, where consortium partners exert considerable influence and accept interface risk to offer a competitive package. However, one potential example where an equity/operator may provide value is in proposals brought forward under the Victorian Government’s newly released Unsolicited Guidelines. In these prospective projects, the operator could be presumed to be well placed to manage all of the interface risks, including procurement and management of key subcontracts, network integration, disruption risk, etc. over the life of the contract, thereby offering much greater value to the State than just lower priced equity. On balance therefore, such a long term equity position could provide significant value for money to the State, as well as superior design and service outcomes. 16 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 Government grants and loans The Draft Report notes that further investigation of alternative financing mechanisms will occur and be reported on as part of the final report. Page 190 of the Draft Report notes ‘There was limited discussion of the relative merits of direct capital grants and government loans. In particular, some participants argued that government lending could be a more direct response to current impediments to private sector involvement.’ Victorian considers, as referred to above, that government loans would only appear sensible for projects with third party revenue streams. For availability based PPP projects, providing a government loan instead of a grant structure simply increases the availability payment from the state to effectively repay the loan (to itself). An Australian Government loan, as opposed to simple Commonwealth grants, to an availability based project would have the perverse outcome of the state's availability charge increasing to repay the Australian Government loan, assuming a consistent credit rating between the jurisdictions. The Draft Report notes on page 192 “Targeted capital grants, particularly when administered for projects that would have been undertaken without government assistance, equate to an explicit subsidy. This could encourage unproductive rent-seeking behaviour by private finance providers, as well as place pressure on the government to support projects that would otherwise fail the cost–benefit test. In other words, the mechanism risks creating expectations that any project will be supported, as long as some private finance is available.” Victoria considers the investment decision is separate to the procurement or financing decision. A project investment is considered against a BCR to guide the investment decision and it is only after this decision that financing sources are considered. A capital grant does not reduce the cost, apart from a relatively minor impact on interest during construction. Victoria is unaware of any project where the financing structure has increased a BCR from below one to one or above, or from a ‘do not proceed’ to a ‘proceed’ discussion. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 17 3. Better institutional and governance arrangements are crucial 3.1 Background Investment in productivity enhancing infrastructure is a key priority. A positive BCR is generally a good evaluator of economic impact to guide prioritisation, however it does have limitations and should not be used as the sole indicator to demonstrate to the public the true value of an investment. While BCRs are a useful metric, Victoria considers that simplistic application and over-reliance on this single metric without understanding its limitations creates a misconception that only values included in standard BCRs are important. The difference between economic and financial assessments (relative weak linkages to State revenues) As an economic, not financial analysis tool, positive BCR projects indicate that the economic benefits outweigh the economic costs, albeit ignoring financial sustainability, that is a project’s capacity to ‘pay for itself’ over time without the need to raise taxes. Project benefits and costs largely accrue to a number of specific economic actors, for example; individuals (reduced congestion and travel time savings, reduced accidents, productivity), firms (productivity and profitability), and the environment. On the other hand, currently most infrastructure projects’ financial analyses (the assessment of the overall financial return to government) are negative, usually measured in financial net present value (NPV) terms. Part of this is that generally projects have a very limited positive impact on state revenues (most likely through indirect boosts to GST and payroll tax). From a state perspective, in addition to BCRs, the key decision making drivers for economic infrastructure also include the impact of an investment on the state’s financial sustainability, competiveness, Gross State Product and growth potential. BCRs are not a measure of impact on economic activity or productivity The economic impacts directly related to an initiative/project represented in a BCR can be somewhat narrow. While cost-benefit analysis generally provides a good evaluator of respective projects’ economic impacts for the purpose of guiding prioritisation, focusing solely on BCRs can lead to sub-optimal decision making, due to a range of limitations: 18 • BCRs alone are not a complete measure of a project’s likely impacts on improving productivity or economic growth; • benefits and costs captured within a BCR can vary widely and some impacts are not captured at all or measurement is difficult. An example is ‘wider economic benefits’ or WEBs (such as the benefits generated from transformational infrastructure which serves to increase productivity by encouraging agglomeration of businesses and greater access to labour); and • not all BCRs of the same value have the same impact on productivity and competitiveness, e.g. commuter travel time savings differ from community health benefits. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 Victoria therefore supplements BCR information with: • equity considerations and broader qualitative considerations; • WEB’s where appropriate (consistent with the approach adopted by Infrastructure Australia); • strategic network impacts; and • budget sustainability considerations. Even for measures purporting to capture all of the economic impacts, the methodologies for identifying and quantifying the benefits are subject to a number of simplifying assumptions which need to be understood to properly assess the merits of an investment. Decisions around public disclosure of cost-benefit analysis are informed by project specific circumstances. Victoria is keen to ensure that public disclosure of cost information prior to commencing tender processes does not jeopardise the Government’s ability to optimise value for money through competitive tender processes. This assessment is most usefully made taking into account project specific circumstances and market conditions. Victoria’s original submission to this inquiry encouraged further consideration of how best to collect data for, estimate and include wider economic benefits, and productivity metrics more broadly, to support investment decisions. The potential for productivity based payments for infrastructure investment from the Commonwealth to the States is also an issue that could be further considered. The basic concept of these payments involves further Commonwealth funding to the States for productivity boosting infrastructure investment, where the financial benefits flow to the Commonwealth through increased taxation. Payment by results mechanisms have been put in place in the United Kingdom and examples, such as National Competition Policy reward payments, also exist in Australia. The Grattan Institute’s ‘Game-changers: Economic reform priorities for Australia’ notes that ‘Of course, much infrastructure has non-economic benefits, including public amenity, social cohesion, and environmental impacts. On these grounds alone, individual projects may well be worth pursuing.’ Table 3 below provides one potential lens through which BCRs can be considered. Table 3: Comparative BCRs Low productivity related benefits Low non-economic or non-productivity related benefits High non-economic or non-productivity related benefits “Weak” “Amenity” Likely low BCRs Many will have strong BCRs Do not proceed High productivity related benefits “Often misunderstood” “Stars” May have low traditional BCR Likely high BCR Likely to proceed Likely to have high WEBs Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 19 The ‘weak’ and ‘stars’ boxes are relatively uncontroversial. The amenity box could include investment in cultural assets. Where these are “one off” there are intergeneration equity arguments for spreading the burden of repaying these. However for the majority of the State’s investment in this class of infrastructure the need or desire to invest is recurrent. However the recurrent investment pattern if debt funded is not met by a rise in the ability to repay the debt through increased economic activity, potentially leading to rising tax rates as a proportion of economic activity and ultimately reduced competitiveness. To re-use a common analogy in the infrastructure debate while increasing borrowing to finance a “one off” amenity asset might be a bit like a mortgage, the recurrent nature of a State’s investments in amenity type infrastructure is more akin to buying a new house for your family every year but without any rise in income to pay for the increased mortgage repayments. Projects can fall into the ‘misunderstood’ box when BCRs are simplistically and wrongly applied as a single and comprehensive measure of a project’s worth. 3.1.1 Information Request 2.1 The Commission seeks views on other prospective infrastructure assets that the Commonwealth, States and Territories should consider for privatisation. The Victorian Government notes recommendation 2.1 and is currently investigating the strategic and commercial options for the future of Victoria’s state-owned ports. The scoping study will consider the future ownership options of the ports including the timing, economic and commercial value of each option. The Victorian Government will continue to review its asset base as part of its regular budgetary and strategic processes. In March 2014, the Victorian Government endorsed in-principle an asset recycling partnership between the Commonwealth and States. 3.1.2 Information Request 7.2 The Commission seeks further information from participants on the costs and benefits of land corridor and site preservation strategies. In particular, it seeks evidence on the effectiveness of current jurisdictional strategies and the merits of a national regime. It also seeks views on the optimal ways in which corridors and sites can be used prior to infrastructure developments. Merits of a National Regime States are presently responsible for funding the protection of corridors. The high cost of reservation protection can be a disincentive for State governments to take action to fund long term corridor protection when there are other activities which yield more immediate benefits in terms of service delivery. However, the long term benefits from corridor protection are important to gain, both from a Commonwealth and a State perspective. It is therefore entirely appropriate for the Commonwealth to be a partner with the states in protecting transport corridors of national significance. 20 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 Under current arrangements in Victoria the liability for compensation arises once a planning scheme amendment for a Public Acquisition Overlay is exhibited, at which point there are various triggers for compensation claims, such as when the land owner wishes to sell or develop prior to acquisition. Making budget provisions for future compensation and hardship claims from land owners can be prohibitive where an extensive reservation is required. Recognising the need for corridor protection, the Commonwealth Government could assist with setting the framework and overarching strategy for improving corridor protection, for example acknowledgement of common protection principles and contribute to corridor protection costs for nationally significant infrastructure. This could be managed through the existing Infrastructure Australia project appraisal process with funding drawn from the Commonwealth Government’s infrastructure investment program as part of a project investment decision. Victoria’s approach to corridor and site protection Under current arrangements in Victoria, land is normally reserved by applying a ‘Public Acquisition Overlay’ in Council planning schemes, following a Planning Scheme Amendment process. The Public Acquisition Overlay has two major aspects: it is the statutory mechanism to enable compulsory acquisition of a property for a public purpose; and it is the statutory mechanism to enable control of imminent development that may potentially be in conflict with the longer term public purpose for which the land is reserved. Activities which may potentially be in conflict with the public purpose, such as construction of a new or extended building or land subdivision require the land owner to seek a planning permit from the “Responsible Authority” which involves referral to affected infrastructure agencies seeking views on whether, and under which specific conditions, planning permits should proceed. Existing uses which occur on land subject to a Public Acquisition Overlay are allowed to continue for as long as the Acquisition Authority does not compulsorily acquire the land. Existing land owners whose land is subject to a Public Acquisition Overlay are entitled to ‘loss on sale’ compensation (difference between realised value at sale and full market value of land) and ‘financial loss’ compensation (where an owner is compensated due to the refusal to issue a planning permit). Acquisition Authorities may allow development to occur on land with a Public Acquisition Overlay subject to conditions, which might include allowing development but with no compensation for the additional development. Such agreements are possible when the land is reserved for infrastructure that is not required for some decades and it becomes commercially viable to undertake a development with a defined maximum life before the land is acquired. Affected land owners may also request the Acquisition Authority purchases property on hardship grounds as the result of inability to sell the property due to the existence of a Public Acquisition Overlay on the property. Given the expense of providing for compensation and land acquisition costs, there is a significant opportunity cost in allocating budget funding for a compensation liability that may or may not arise in the short to medium term. A decision to fund corridor protection for a specific project should not be made in isolation based solely on strategic network planning but should also rely on decisions around the likely timeframe of the project proceeding and the impact on the utility of the land in the interim. Ultimately, any government decision to Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 21 fund a project should be based on the merits (and costs) of the specific project under consideration. The Productivity Commission could give consideration to real options and/or opportunity cost approaches in valuing land corridors and sites. If the infrastructure project requiring the land has a negative financial NPV or an economic BCR of less than one, then often the value of the corridor is assessed at nil if reserved for the project compared to alternative uses of the corridor. Valuing the corridor as an “option” over delivering the project in a particular way which is foregone if the corridor is sold and comparing this value to alternative use value might result in better economic decisions. 3.1.3 Draft Recommendation 11.1 Governments should invest more in the initial concept design specifications to help reduce bid costs, but in doing so, provide opportunities for tenderers to contest the specifications of the design. This recommendation is addressed in the National Framework For Traditional Contracting of Infrastructure (the National Framework), released as an exposure draft, and in particular in the Technical Specific Guide No 1 – Project Definition (Guide No 1). The National Framework, which documents best practice to promote productivity improvements in the planning and contracting phase of major projects, expands on concept design specifications to preparing a well-developed ‘project definition’ by the procuring agency. The project definition describes the project’s: functional and performance requirements; scope; risks, constraints and opportunities; and standards requirements. The project definition is the foundation to the procuring agency developing a ‘project solution’ that incorporates a reference design. A well-developed project definition contributes to a high degree of understanding between the procuring agency and tenderer regarding what the procuring agency requires and establishes the success for much of the foundation work essential for good outcomes in the tender and construction phases. A welldeveloped project definition is also critical before a project budget can be established. Guide No 1 further states that the project definition should clearly identify those elements that are mandatory, for example design elements that integrate with an existing network and are part of the procuring agency’s established standards and requirements and should ensure that where the reference design is released, tenderers perceive the reference design as one to be improved upon through their innovative efforts rather than perceiving it as a mandatory requirement. (This documentation can be found at: http://www.dtf.vic.gov.au/Infrastructure-Delivery/Alliance-and-traditional-contracting) The Victorian experience with PPP tender outcomes supports the recommendation that more time/money should be invested upfront to ensure consistency between the PSC and the reference design scope (to avoid undertaking additional reviews after tender commencement thereby prolonging the tender phase). However Victoria highlights the 22 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 importance of not confusing additional investment in appropriate project scoping with being more prescriptive in the context of an output specification for a PPP project. Final designs for PPP projects are usually radically different from the State’s reference design. Furthermore, there are various precedents which show that often the private sector’s capital costs are higher than the State’s estimate, however this higher initial capital expenditure results in lower ongoing operation, maintenance and facilities management costs, thereby delivering value for money to the State over the life of the contract. One key tenet of PPP delivery is the ability to consider the infrastructure from a whole-of-life perspective and determine value for money and service delivery outcome for the long term, beyond the initial asset investment and delivery phase. There are various important qualitative benefits which arise from the State not being overly prescriptive in the design specifications provided to tenderers, including: Innovative designs compared to the Reference Project – examples include the Royal Children’s Hospital, Southern Cross Station and the Melbourne Convention Centre (internationally awarded); Future proofing – additional building areas/facilities compared with the scope assumed by the State, including the provision of additional shell space. Examples are the Royal Children’s Hospital, the Partnerships Victoria in Schools project, EastLink, the Biosciences Research Centre and Victorian Comprehensive Cancer Centre projects; Environmentally sustainable development (ESD) - various ESD initiatives are delivered that go significantly beyond the State’s minimum requirements, and reduce the ongoing operating costs for the project (e.g. the Royal Children’s Hospital project); Improved amenities – complementary retail opportunities and more efficient use of assets are often provided (such as the Royal Children’s Hospital and the Melbourne Convention Centre projects); and Complementary development – additional infrastructure may be provided that supports other government objectives. This was achieved on the desalination plant project where a high speed communications cable was laid along the entire length of the transfer pipeline, facilitating broadband access to the region. There may be certain types of PPP projects where a more developed concept design could be appropriate, for example if a jurisdiction is contemplating undertaking a pipeline of less complex, smaller scale projects (such as social housing) where there is less scope for innovation or minimising whole of life costs. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 23 3.1.4 Draft Recommendation 11.2 When tendering for major infrastructure work under design and construct arrangements, governments should consider contributing to the design costs of tenderers on the condition that governments own the design, where a thorough prior assessment has demonstrated that design innovation is both worth seeking and likely to be received Victoria is not supportive of contributing towards the design costs of tenderers, unless special circumstances apply, rather it supports ensuring that projects are appropriately planned and investigated prior to engaging with the market. The National Framework promotes agencies planning projects comprehensively and producing a design brief which has a degree of granularity sufficient to describe the Clients’ requirements to service providers and Tenderers. The depth and maturity of the design brief will depend on the procurement approach selected, however it should be sufficiently developed to allow the bidders to develop a tender response and give the procuring agency a contract price with confidence. Victoria would also support agencies undertaking design work that would be commonly undertaken by all shortlisted bidders in a D&C to avoid duplication of effort for design that does not serve to materially differentiate one bidder from another. 3.1.5 Draft Recommendation 11.3 Government clients should alter the timing of information provision in the tendering process for infrastructure projects so that non design management plans are only required of the preferred tenderer. The obligation to produce documents upon becoming a preferred tenderer should remain a condition of the initial request for tender. The Victorian Government agrees that Health and Safety Management Plans provided in response to the Implementation Guidelines to the Victorian Code of Practice for the Building and Construction Industry (Guidelines) will only be required of the preferred tenderer. Where Workplace Relations Management Plans are a condition of tender for Victorian Government projects, they must be required prior to contract award, as the government needs to be satisfied that the tenderer can produce an appropriate risk mitigation strategy. 3.1.6 Draft Recommendation 11.4 The ‘early contractor involvement model’ should be trialled to test the costs and benefits of applying past contract performance by tenderers as a means of constructor selection, consistent with the practices of some private sector clients. It is unclear as to the rationale behind this recommendation and in particular the reason as to why the ‘early contractor model’ (ECI) was selected to be trialled to test the costs and benefits of applying past contract performance by tenderers as a means of supplier selection. Indeed, ECI is not a standard contracting model and there are many variants across Australia and within any one jurisdiction. Applying past contract performance by tenderers as a means of supplier selection can be done under any procurement methodology and this practice has been promoted in the National Framework. In particular the Technical Specific Guide No 4 – Performance and Continuous Performance (Guide No 4) outlines implementation guidelines for formally using 24 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 past supplier performance as a tender selection criterion in selecting suppliers for future projects. If a procuring agency does not include past performance of suppliers as a selection criterion, suppliers will not perceive their performance as being important to winning future potential projects. This may be a lost opportunity for improving performance (and making productivity gains) on future projects. Guide No 4 also considers that the use of a past performance criterion in a tender selection framework should not be made to disadvantage new market entrants and therefore negatively impact on the level and quality of competition for public projects. (This documentation can be found at: http://www.dtf.vic.gov.au/Infrastructure-Delivery/Alliance-and-traditional-contracting) 3.1.7 Draft Recommendation 11.5 For complex infrastructure projects, government clients should provide concept designs using Building Information Modelling (BIM) to help lower bid costs, and require tender designs to be submitted using BIM to reduce overall costs. Governments should give serious consideration to where in their better practice guides they may specify the use of BIM. Victoria supports giving further consideration to specifying the use of BIM by tenderers on complex building projects from the more detailed design stage through to project end. BIM may reduce tender costs, construction costs and whole of life maintenance costs. However Victoria queries the relevance of applying BIM to the concept design phases of project development. As noted in its first submission, Victoria is part of the APCC working group on BIM. 3.1.8 Draft Recommendation 11.7 Australian, State and Territory Governments should remove the requirement for local content plans, such as the Australian Industry Participation plans, from tenders for all projects. The Victorian Government does not support removal of local content plans from tenders for all projects. The Victorian Industry Participation Policy (VIPP) is an information and awareness policy. It does not include any price preference for local content and provides a mechanism whereby international suppliers and local (Australian and New Zealand) suppliers are able to compete on fair terms. Value for money is a key criterion of VIPP as it is for all of the Victorian Governments procurement policies. The Victorian Government introduced reforms to the Victorian Industry Participation Policy (VIPP) on 1 January 2013 aimed at streamlining processes and reducing the administrative cost of participation in the program. These reforms significantly lowered the cost of participation in the program for both business and government agencies and are counted in the Governments red tape reduction efforts. Annual reports on the performance of VIPP are tabled in the Victorian Parliament and are available from www.dsdbi.vic.gov.au/vipp Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 25 3.1.9 Information Request 11.1 The Commission seeks evidence on the skills of public sector clients to manage contracts for major infrastructure projects. Is there evidence that a relative lack of skills has led to systematic cost overruns during the delivery phase? How does this compare to the performance of private sector clients? As referenced in the original Victorian Government submission, in 2012 the Victorian Parliamentary Accounts and Estimates Committee conducted an inquiry into the effective decision making for the successful delivery of significant infrastructure projects. The scope of this inquiry included the skills and capabilities of the public sector in infrastructure delivery. A range of international precedents were reviewed. The report and the Victorian Government’s response can be found at http://www.parliament.vic.gov.au/paec/inquiries/inquiry/304. Resourcing the appropriate skills and capabilities is imperative in effective public sector infrastructure delivery. The Victorian Government’s Investment Lifecycle and High Value High Risk guidelines highlight a range of competencies and skills required by public sector managers and teams involved in infrastructure development and delivery. Effective and representative project governance is essential in ensuring successful project delivery. The project steering committee or control board provides high level oversight of implementation and management of the project and ensures that both the project team and contractors are held accountable for effective delivery of the project. Victoria considers that governance bodies must include individuals who possess the range of capabilities, skills and experience to support sound decision making (covering legal, financial, project management, general management, operational management, construction and subject matter knowledge). Effective contract management is an important focus of the Partnerships Victoria policy framework. This relates to contract management both in the construction phase and the long term operating phase. Victoria is the only jurisdiction to have specific PPP contract management guidance. This material is currently under review to incorporate some recent learnings from live projects. In relation to contract management in the operating phase Victoria has placed a priority on ensuring contract managers have the appropriate skills to manage the contracts. The Department of Treasury and Finance is responsible for ensuring training is available for new contract managers. This training is currently run by the University of Melbourne and is regularly attended by local contract managers and those from other states. In Victoria procuring agencies have dual accountability for developing and delivering infrastructure projects. Central agencies are responsible for developing and communicating guidelines and procurement models, reviewing and providing advice on business cases and monitoring delivery, capability and trends. In Victoria, agencies which have significant project delivery roles, such as the Department of Justice and the Department of Health have established project management offices (PMOs). These offices provide detailed guidance and enhanced oversight of infrastructure delivery to help ensure the appropriate skills and competencies are applied to project delivery. Other departments such as the Department of Education and Early Childhood Development and the Department of Transport Planning and Local Infrastructure have established governance arrangements to help prioritise investment needs across their portfolio and/or their relevant 26 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 delivery agencies, and oversee and monitor the performance of agencies delivering projects. Where appropriate, procuring agencies may be supported by Major Projects Victoria (MPV), established over two decades ago, with the specific objective of working with procuring agencies (where required) on the delivery of complex, large scale and unique projects of State significance. MPV is a division within the Department of State Development, Business and Innovation, and reports to the Minister for Major Projects. The key competencies provided by MPV to agencies comprise: Project Management advice and guidance; Property Development - driving land and property developments which deliver positive social and economic outcomes for Victorians; PPP experience - assisting agencies with the management of complex PPP projects under the Partnerships Victoria framework; and Compliance and Corporate Services - providing business support, including strategic, financial, communications and compliance advice. MPV have supported agencies in successfully delivering such projects as the State Library of Victoria, Southern Cross Station, Federation Square and the Melbourne Convention Centre. The Linking Melbourne Authority (LMA) is a special purpose statutory authority, established by the Victorian Government and responsible for managing complex road projects on behalf of the Government and the wider community. LMA was established on 1 July 2010 under Section 134 of the Transport Integration Act 2010 (the Act) and is the successor in law to the South Eastern Integrated Transport Authority (SEITA). LMA operates under the new regime introduced by the Act which brings together the transport portfolio under one principal Act and seeks to promote the provision of an integrated and sustainable transport system in Victoria. LMA (as SEITA) was responsible for delivering the $2.5 billion EastLink project. The Authority also delivered the $759 million Peninsula Link project, which opened to motorists in January 2013. LMA is currently undertaking the formal planning and consultation for the first stage of the East West Link between the Eastern Freeway and CityLink, and a further connection to the Port of Melbourne area. 3.1.10 Information Request 11.3 The Commission seeks evidence on the appropriateness and effectiveness of the application of incentive payments within infrastructure contracts. During 2009 Victoria led research into the value for money outcomes achieved in past alliancing contracts and how enhancements can be made in future alliances. The resultant report, ‘In Pursuit of additional value: a benchmarking study into alliancing in the Australian Public Sector’, was published in October 2009. One of the findings of the benchmarking study was that there was little evidence that outstanding (game breaking or breakthrough) outcomes were actually being achieved within the definitions in use in the study (‘paradigm shift'/ ‘not been done before’) despite significant investment in ‘high performance teams’ and the use of financial incentives for Non Owner Participants to achieve extraordinary outcomes. Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 27 Consequently both the National Alliance Contracting Policy and Guidelines and the National Framework suggest that generally the contract should not include financial incentives for the supplier to deliver a better service or to a higher standard than specified in the contract. Rather, if a procuring agency wants a specific outcome or heightened level of performance, then these requirements should be defined in the contract and priced accordingly by the market. The National Framework argues that governments are often the dominant (repeat), blue chip, high value strategic procuring agency for infrastructure suppliers. Accordingly, the government procuring agency should expect the supplier to want to perform to the contract in an exemplary manner without any need for positive incentives. The performance required should be clearly specified by the procuring agency and included in the supplier’s proposal. It is expected that a supplier will work smart and as necessary to achieve the requirements of each project, will be paid fully as per the contract and build on its track record and reputation to improve its attractiveness as a future supplier. Financial incentives should only be appropriate for rare and exceptional cases when the procuring agency cannot specify the requirement as a normal deliverable because it is so extraordinary and therefore cannot meaningfully be priced in the tender. (This documentation can be found at: http://www.dtf.vic.gov.au/Infrastructure-Delivery/Alliance-and-traditional-contracting) 3.1.11 Draft Recommendation 11.9 Government clients should invest more in understanding the site risks for infrastructure projects and update the information provided to tenderers during the request for tender stage in consultation with potential contractors. In order to achieve this, government clients should not rush to market. Victoria fully supports this recommendation which is currently addressed in the National Framework. The National Framework clearly states that good project planning and appropriate investigation of risks is essential for good outcomes (including price) in the Tender and Construction Phases. This supports the establishment of a positive collaborative relationship with the Suppliers. Victoria supports bidders during the tender phase being able to freely request procuring agencies to undertake additional investigatory work and to robustly question the client’s tender requirements. This is supported by industry research undertaken by Victoria and reported in Towards agreed expectations: Tender strategies to improve D&C infrastructure outcomes. The National Framework does reinforce that good project planning and appropriate investigation of risks will be compromised when timelines are truncated. Shortened timelines will normally lead to immature project definition and typically see significant scope changes and other surprises during the tender process and/or post-contract award. Whilst it is recognised that from time to time procurement processes may be required to ‘start as early as possible’ to meet an urgent community service need, the client needs to fully dimension the risks and cost premiums associated with such strategies. Moreover, the procuring agency should inform the decision makers about the cost premiums and potentially negative value for money impact arising from planning processes being truncated. (This documentation can be found at: http://www.dtf.vic.gov.au/InfrastructureDelivery/Alliance-and-traditional-contracting) 28 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 Attachment A – Treasury Corporation of Victoria PPP Modelling scenarios Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014 29 www.dtf.vic.gov.au 30 Productivity Commission Public Infrastructure Inquiry Victorian Government Supplementary Submission, April 2014