Foreign trade • In the next two lectures we will develop versions of the IS-LM and AD-AS models for an open economy. • An open economy can have several meanings: – Goods market: trades goods and services – Financial market: allow the flow of investment capital – Factor market: allows the free movement of companies and people • In this class we will focus on the first two: openness in goods and financial markets. How open is the Australian economy? 120000 100000 80000 60000 40000 20000 0 19 4 19 9 5 19 2 5 19 5 5 19 8 6 19 1 6 19 4 6 19 7 7 19 0 7 19 3 7 19 6 7 19 9 8 19 2 8 19 5 8 19 8 9 19 1 94 Million A$ • You could measure the size of imports or exports (why not both?) in the Australian economy. • But this would lead to the same problems as measuring GDP in nominal terms. Exports Imports Importance of external trade 40 Ratio to GDP (percent) 35 Imports/GDP 30 25 20 15 10 Exports/GDP 5 0 1901 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 Globalization? • Much is made of the “new” impact of globalization in the world economy. • But from the previous graph, the Australian economy is as dependent (even less) on the rest of the world as it was one century ago. • “Globalization” must be referring to something else instead- the free flow of people and ideas across the world- rather than goods and services. Trade balance • We define a term “net exports”, which is just exports minus imports, X – M. • If X>M, we say we are in a “trade surplus” and if X<M, we say we are in a “trade deficit”. • The trade deficit in Australia has grown large in nominal terms in the last twenty years, but as a percentage of GDP, it has stayed constant (or even fallen). • Later, we will explore what an Australian trade deficit means. Millions A$ 0 -6 -4000 -9 -6000 -12000 -12 -8000 -15 -18 -10000 -21 -24 % of GDP 19 49 19 51 19 53 19 55 19 57 19 59 19 61 19 63 19 65 19 67 19 69 19 71 19 73 19 75 19 77 19 79 19 81 19 83 19 85 19 87 19 89 19 91 19 93 19 95 Australian trade deficit 4000 6 2000 3 0 -2000 -3 Nominal exchange rates • When we talk of “exchange rates”, we have to be cautious, as there are many types of “exchange rates” that are used. • The “nominal exchange rate” is the rate at which the Australian dollar (A$) trades for other currencies- the “price of the Australian dollar”. • Example: If the Australian dollar trades for $0.80, we mean that A$1 is worth US$0.80. • Note that there will be as many nominal exchange rates as there are other currencies. • For Australia, the reference currencies are usually US$ and the Japanese Yen. Price of the A$ 1.60 US$ per A$ 1.40 US$/A$ 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Appreciation and depreciation • When we talk of an “appreciation of the A$”, we mean that the price of the A$ in terms of another currency has increased, so the A$ was appreciating in 1973. • When we talk of a “depreciation of the A$”, we mean that the price of the A$ in terms of another currency has decreased, so the A$ has generally depreciated against the US$ since the mid 1970s. • But these are nominal terms, and don’t signify much in reality. Real exchange rate • We would like to have an exchange rate that got rid of the effects of prices and concentrated on “real” effects, just as we do with real GDP. • We would like instead to talk simply in terms of how Australian goods trade for American goods. • Example: Harry Potter and the Half-Blood Prince sells for US$17.99 at www.amazon.com, while at www.dymocks.com.au it sells for A$29.95. • What is the real exchange rate between Potter in Australia and Potter in the US? Real exchange rate • We need to translate the prices into a common currency, so we will use the Australian $. The nominal exchange rate, E, is US$0.78/$A1. • One US Potter goes for US$17.99, which is US$17.99/E US$17.99/(US$0.78/A$1) = A$23.06 • The real exchange rate is A$29.95/A$23.06 = 1.30. • But let’s say we want a real exchange rate for the whole economy, not just for copies of Potter. • We use the general price levels (or GDP deflators) in the two countries. Let P be the Australian price level, and P* be the US price level. • Real exchange rate e = P / (P*/E) e = EP/P* Australian goods in terms of US goods Real exchange rate 1.60 Nominal exchange rate, 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 Real exchange rate, e 0.40 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Real exchange rate • The real exchange rate then expresses how average prices are moving in Australia with respect to other countries, such as the US. • The nominal exchange rate of the A$, E, fell against the US$, but the real exchange rate did not fall as much. Why? • Answer: Average inflation in Australia was higher than in the US, so P grew faster than P* balancing out the drop in E. Multilateral exchange rates • The higher is e, the cheaper US goods are compared to Australian goods. • So far we have been considering only exchange rates between Australia and the US, but Australia trades with many countries. What if the A$ falls against the US$, but rises against the Japanese Yen? • Multilateral exchange rates show the price of the A$ compared to a weighted average of the currencies of our trading partners, where the weight of a currency depends on the percentage of our trade it composes. What determines E? • The nominal exchange rate (say US$/A$) is determined in a market for A$, where you have both supply and demand for A$. E is the price in this market. • Who demands A$? – Exporters who buy Australian goods to sell overseas. – Foreign investors who buy Australian assets. • Who supplies A$? – Importers who want to buy overseas goods. – Australian investors who buy foreign assets. Market for A$ Exchange rate (cost of 1 A$ in terms of US$) Supply of A$ •Domestic investors •Importers Demand for A$ •Foreign investors •Exporters Amount of A$ Market for A$ • The nominal exchange rate is then affected both by changes in the goods market and also the financial markets. • But the volume of A$ traded on the world financial markets was A$75 billion per day in 2001, while the volume of goods trade was A$0.7 per day in 2001. Goods trade was only 1% of financial trading in the A$. • In the short-term, the price of the A$ is determined by changes in financial markets. Financial market openness • Openness in financial markets means that investors are free to put their money where they wish. • Australian investors are free to invest overseas, and foreign investors are free to invest in Australia. • In this case, investors will put their money where they think it will earn the highest returns. • In equilibrium that means that expected asset returns must be the same in Australia as overseas. Domestic and foreign assets • Return on A$1 invested in Australia for a year: 1+ it • Return on A$1 invested in the US: A$1 becomes US$Et US$Et becomes US$(1+ it*)Et US$(1+ it*)Et becomes US$(1+ it*)Et / Et+1e • As you have to buy a US asset, earn the US interest rate, i*, and then turn the US$ back into A$ in a year. Interest parity • For returns on the two assets to be the same, we will have: 1+ it = US$(1+ it*) Et / Et+1e • Manipulating this and taking logs, it becomes the condition: it = it* - [(Et+1e - Et)/ Et] • The domestic interest rate must be equal to the foreign interest rate less the expected rate of appreciation. • Or it - it* = Expected appreciation of A$. Interest parity 16.0 14.0 Australian interest rate 12.0 Per cent • Another way of thinking about this is to remember that you earn money on foreign assets either because of foreign interest rates or because of exchange rate movements. • If I expect my currency to depreciate, I will need a high interest rate to keep my money in the country. 10.0 8.0 6.0 U.S. interest rate 4.0 2.0 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 Imports and exports • We assume that Australian consumers will consume more imports as their income rises and as imports become cheaper (e rises): IM = IM(Y, e) (+ , +) • We assume that foreign consumers will consume more Australian exports as foreign income rises and as exports become cheaper (e falls): X = X(Y*, e) (+, -) The new IS equation • Exports are measured in Australian goods, but imports are foreign goods, so we have to translate into Australian good through the real exchange rate, e, so net exports are: NX = X(Y*, e) – IM(Y, e)/e • This becomes a component of our AD, so equilibrium in the goods market requires: Y = C(Y-T) + I(Y, r) + G + NX Y = C(Y-T) + I(Y, r) + G + X(Y*, e) – IM(Y, e)/e The new IS equation • We have a new IS curve which depends on Y and r, and has G, T, Y* and e as parameters. • An increase in Y* will shift the IS curve to the right, as export demand rises, but what happens when e rises? • When e rises, perhaps because E rises, X falls and IM rises, as Australian goods are now more expensive. But what happens to IM/e- the value of imports? It is ambiguous. • Marshall-Lerner condition: A rise in e will lead to a drop in NX. The J curve • Typically prices move much faster than goods supply and demand- ie. firms order goods in advance. • In this case, X and IM will not move when e falls. But that means that NX will initially fall if e falls, even if the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied. Eventually however the X and IM will react and NX will rise. • We saw this in the early 80s in Australia. Real exchange rate (1995=100) 140 Real exchange rate (scale at left) 130 4 Trade deficit/GDP (scale at right) 3 120 2 110 1 100 0 90 -1 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Ratio of trade deficit to GDP (percent) Paul Keating’s J curve