The Density Debate – A Personal View Christine Whitehead London School of Economics and Cambridge Centre for Housing and Planning Research East Thames Housing Group The Building Centre London 24 January 2008 How Do We Define Density? Density is defined very differently by planners and economists • Planning densities are defined in terms of physical attributes – numbers of dwellings or habitable rooms per hectare; • Economists are interested in outcomes in terms of population per hectare and densities of occupation; • The two are usually related to one another but not always; the relationship is changing; and sometimes inconsistent Why Are We Interested? • Important element in the debate about whether planning policy is too constraining and whether the emphasis on density is helping to increase prices; • Regarded as a core element in the sustainability and regeneration agenda; • Strongly related to other policies notably on brownfield development; Section 106; and mixed communities – but the linkages often not understood Government Policy on Densities • Requirement to increase residential planning densities placed on regions and local authorities; • Formal requirements in PPS3 (2006) actually no tougher than those in PPG 3 introduced in 2000. But the rhetoric and the pressures put on authorities much stronger; • Interpreted differently in different areas but generally the pattern is based on location in relation to the centre and on transportation. Little emphasis on other aspects of sustainability (assumed able to respond); • London’s policy in the London Plan very much stronger than anywhere else in the country – with major implications for the size of dwellings and built form Actual Densities • Outside London, densities have been falling – in suburban as well as central areas; • In London immigration and population growth have necessarily increased densities; • Densities of occupation vary greatly between different groups of households; between tenures; and most importantly by income; • Location and space per dwelling are highly correlated with one another, in part because of their relationship to income distribution Fundamental Tensions • In a growing economy demand for housing increases roughly in proportion to income growth – so if incomes rise by 2% p.a. for twenty years we want about 50% more housing overall; • As supply is constrained this pressure increases house prices; differentially increases the price of larger units; and increases problems of affordability at the bottom end of the market; • Role of planners impossible? Must aim to use less land; build on more brownfield; achieve mixed communities; provide more space per person; provide more units; ensure better design; and improve quality and services for both additional and established households Economic Principles of Planning • Economic rationale for planning is to overcome market failures – encourage positive externalities and discourage negative; improve information; assist adjustment; and ensure adequate provision of public open space and services; • Higher densities address issues of urban sprawl and the need for diverse and productive economy – but also costs of too high densities in terms of pollution, congestion and the loss of value to individuals; • Fundamental objective to maximise social value of development – but while general objectives are clear, relationships are complex and target based approaches may produce perverse results Market Pressures • Demand for separate units increases with demographic growth but equally with incomes across established as well as additional households; • Income elasticities similar for internal and external space – and stronger for houses than flats; • Also evidence of pressures to live closer to the countryside – but value of local open space particularly high; • Some types of household value central locations and newer migrants generally demand less housing per household; • Given a growing economy one would expect to build at high standards suitable for the future and to allow older/less appropriate housing filtering down the system The Evidence in Densities • Population densities fell significantly from 1945 up to the 1980s. They stabilised in the 1990s (1% decline) while densities in London actually rose by 8%; • This is partly the outcome of constrained supply and rising prices; • England’s urban areas are relatively dense as compared to other high income countries – except for central London; • On wider definitions of London, densities are high by international standards The Evidence on Sustainability • The most quoted estimates that doubling density halves energy use is based on a simple correlation and reflects stage of development rather than a direct relationship; • Corrected estimates show an impact of well below 10% and would involve quite unrealistic policy constraints; • Higher densities support better public transport – but the critical figures for this are between 25dph and 60dph ; • The position with respect to local services – and healthy living – is even less clear – but again 50-60dph appears to be the relevant benchmark Do Higher Densities Deliver? • Higher densities traditionally generate more but shorter trips, using more public transport • Evidence from the “revived” central urban areas such as Leeds suggests that as individual networks expand these trips are getting longer • The growth of second and weekend homes is also relevant here as, if people have less space in the urban area, they substitute other (less sustainable?) lifestyles • The most important issues are how the demand for space can be satisfied and the ways in which the construction industry is responding to market and policy pressures Table 1: Housing Densities in Europe Useful floor area per dwelling (M2) Year Total Year Dwellings dwelling completed stock Austria 2003 93.9 2002 101.0 Belgium 1991 86.3 2001 119.0 Denmark 2002 109.1 2001 112.4 Finland 2002 77.0 2003 90.2 France 2002 89.6 2002 112.6 Germany 2002 89.7 2003 113.9 Italy 1991 90.3 2000 81.5 Netherlands 2000 98.0 2000 115.5 Sweden 2003 91.6 2003 128.0 England 2001 86.9 1981-2001 82.7 The Policy Response • • • • • Rapidly increasing planning densities; Smaller units with less space per room; More flats; Inflexible built form; More shared ownership rather than social rented dwellings Table 2: Density of new dwellings by region: 2000-05 2000 2005 Proportional Increase London 56 112 100 South East 24 41 71 North West 26 41 56 North East 24 40 67 Yorkshire and Humberside 22 39 77 South West 25 39 56 East Midlands 22 38 81 West Midlands 24 36 50 East of England 22 35 59 England 25 41 64 Table 3: The Changing Make Up of Completions in England Completions 2000/1001 2004/2005 Change ( %) England 1 bed 7 10 2 bed 27 38 3 bed 34 29 4 + bed 32 23 20 (25,970) 41 (63,920) +146% 80 (103,890) 59 (91,980) -11% Total 129,866 155,893 +20% Number of bedroom (est) 400,000 430,500 +8% 1 bed 18 24 2 bed 48 58 3 bed 25 12 9 6 Flats 58 (8,400) 19,920) 83 +138% Houses 42 (6,080) (4,090) 17 -33% 14,492 (11%) 24,063 +66% Flats Houses London 4 + bed Total Number of bedroom (est) 33,300 48,700 (av 2.3) (av 2.0) - 0.3 Figure 1: Shared Ownership as a percentage of all S106 completions 40 NE 35 NW 30 Yorks 25 E Mids 20 W Mids 15 Eas t London 10 SE 5 SW 0 England 2001-02 2005-06 Outcomes • Rising planning densities but stable or falling actual densities outside London; • The London phenomenon – densities rising for new construction 50% faster than elsewhere; • A massive change in dwelling composition linked to declining space standards; • Increasing reliance on one and two bedroom flats often with no through ventilation; • Is there a gap in the market provision of small units? • Are we actually adding to the total stock measured by space? • Can the mixed communities agenda operate? What do People Want?: Market Evidence • Declining occupancy rates in owner-occupied sector even in face of rapidly rising prices; relative decline in the prices of small flats (supply v demand/distribution of income) – although new dwelling premium; even initially occupancy lower than planned; • Higher densities in the private rented sector – especially among those relatively new to the country; increasing overcrowding; rents still based on capacity to pay not quality; • Groups who like central/dense living – young; single; students; less established households; older people looking for services? Table 4: Tenure mix of London residents by migration origin and time in the UK Owned outright Owned with a mortgage Social Rented Private Furnished Private Unfurnished Rich Asylum Other Poor UK Total Countries Countries Countries Born Population <3 >3 <3 >3 <3 >3 years years years years years years 1% 24% 2% 6% 3% 16% 21% 19% 13% 32% 6% 23% 11% 32% 43% 38% 6% 64% 21% 15% 35% 48% 46% 16% 21% 56% 37% 8% 26% 7% 27% 8% 16% 8% 8% 8% 9% 5% 4% 6% Survey Evidence People buying in the market want: • Houses rather than flats; • Larger rooms even if fewer; • Quality kitchens/bathrooms; • Flexibility • Privacy, private space and well managed communal space; • Access to shops, transport, and parking; • Energy and environmental efficiency; • Not to live in featureless boxes What do Social Tenants Want? • • • • • • • • More space and larger rooms; Better and more storage – inside and out; Houses rather than flats; To avoid noise pollution and poorly managed/ used communal space; Better design – flexibility; ventilation; kitchens and bathrooms; Good maintenance and rubbish disposal; Access to parking, shops and transport; Adequate security Attitudes to Density • Density as such rarely the issue except for those spending large proportions of time at home; • Those overcrowded in the home notice – and dislike crowding in the area more; • Conflation between density and high rise – in people’s attitudes ; • Concerns about interaction between new high density buildings and the established neighbourhood Three Examples • Vienna 1929 – Luxury Art Deco for the masses (50 sq m per unit and lots of services) – now 80% plus “known to the police” • China in 1990s – 7 sq m per person; 2007 28m2 per permanent resident for new construction; current government aspiration 100 sq m per unit • London 2007: Homes for nurses at St Thomas’ Hospital – 230 flats for 400 plus hospital workers in 5-20 storey apartment blocks mixed with 330 private flats in separate buildings Conclusions (1) • Perceptions of density thoroughly mixed up with overcrowding; built form; location; and attitudes to the neighbourhood • Urban England remains relatively densely populated. Only very central areas have below average densities as compared to other richer countries • The benefits of higher densities are overstated and anyway depend on existing development far more than on new construction – especially if people move away because of higher density development • Only in central London is there a case for much higher densities Conclusions (2) • Higher densities, and especially high rise must be associated with high quality design and better services. Even so they will only be suitable for relatively small groups of mainly better off households; • Within central London a case can be made for iconic; well-managed; high service charged, super density close to good open space, local services and transport; • If these attributes are forgotten the result is likely at best to be extremely poor value for money and at worst the slums of the future Conclusions (3) • The case for increasing planning densities at the lower end of the density scale is strong in order to maintain efficient services. However to be successful this policy must be combined with better designed homes which provide more space per household and greater flexibility – so that people actually want to live there now and in the future