Lecture 14: Problems/Applications of discretionary policymaking • Targets & instruments revisited • Practical difficulties of policymaking • Managing emerging market inflows • Appreciate or add to reserves? • If add to reserves, then sterilize? • Example of China 2003-2012 Targets & instruments revisited • When we first showed the need to have as many independent policy instruments as goals, monetary & fiscal policy were not independent. • Now, with capital mobility, they have somewhat independent effects on external balance, provided that is defined as BP=0 (rather than TB=0). • The reason: they have opposite effect on capital flows, because they have opposite effects on interest rates. • => Even with a fixed exchange rate, the proper combination of monetary and fiscal policy can attain internal & external balance at the same time. ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell ● TD balanced by KA surplus ● In theory, there exists a precise mix of monetary & fiscal policy that will hit both internal balance and BP=0. Practical difficulties of policymaking Lags: between the change in a policy instrument and the response in the economy Uncertainty with regard to: • the current position of the economy (“baseline”); • future disturbances (“shocks”); • the correct model (e.g., multipliers). Expectations on the part of the public Political Constraints Capital inflows to Emerging Markets rose rapidly 2003-07, were set back temporarily in global financial crisis of 2008-09 ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell EmergingMarkets.org Alternative Ways of Managing Capital Inflows A. B. Allow money to flow in Sterilized intervention (can be inflationary) (can be difficult) C. D. Allow currency to appreciate (lose competitiveness) Reimpose capital controls (can impede efficiency) ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell EM Exchange Market Pressure resumed in 2010 In Latin America, renewed inflows were reflected mostly as reserve accumulation in Peru, but as appreciation in Chile & Colombia. more-managed floating less-managed floating Source: GS Global ECS Research In Asia, Korea & Singapore in 2010 took inflows mostly in the form of reserves, while India & Malaysia took them mostly in the form of currency appreciation. more-managed floating less-managed floating GS Global ECS Research When EM countries intervene to prevent appreciation, do they sterilize? Attempts at sterilization where emerging markets have faced large inflows: • In early 1990s, Colombia, Korea, Indonesia and others tried for a year or two and then gave it up. • In the past decade, China successfully sterilized for quite awhile, starting in 2003. ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell Recall recent example of sterilization against money inflows: China, 2003-2010 ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell China has mostly taken the BoP surplus as fx reserves. But it also allowed RMB appreciation (2005-08 & 2011-12). ITF220 - Professor J.Frankel Sterilization foreignreserves reserves: Sterilization ofofforeign Decreases in PBoC’s domestic assets offset increases in foreign assets Source: Zhang, 2011, Fig.7, p.47. Also China raised required reserve ratio for banks Source: Zhang, 2011, Fig.6, p.46. ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell In 2007-08 China had more trouble sterilizing the reserve inflow • PBoC began to have to pay higher domestic interest rates – and to receive lower interest rate on US T bills – => “quasi-fiscal deficit” or “negative carry” for central bank. • Inflation became a serious problem in 2007-08. – True, global increases in food & energy prices were much of the explanation. – But • Appreciation is a good way to put immediate downward pressure on local prices of agricultural & mineral commodities. • Price controls are inefficient and ultimately ineffective. ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell China tightened banks’ reserve requirements & lending rates. By 2007, no longer could hold off overheating. But the 2008-09 recession did it instead. By 2010-11, inflation was again accelerating. Fxtimes.com China’s housing prices took off again in 2013. Rate of increase of housing prices in 4 major Chinese cities (year-on-year) Source: Gwynn Guilford — Sept. 6, 2013 16 End of Lecture 15: Problems/Applications of discretionary policymaking Appendix 1: Examples of sterilization of inflows, from the early-1990s (1) Central bank sells sterilization bonds during period of sterilization ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell Examples of sterilization of inflows, early-1990s (2) Interest rates are high during period of sterilization, fall thereafter. ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell Examples of sterilization of inflows, early-1990s (3) Reserves rise rapidly during sterilization period; slow down thereafter ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell Appendix 2: Five reasons China warranted a more flexible exchange rate regime, in its own interest • Overheating of economy in 2007-08: …=> appreciation – Wasn’t relevant in 2009 slowdown. But was again in 2010-12. • Excessive reserves ($3 ½ trillion as of 2014) – Though a useful shield against currency crises, by now China has enough reserves – Harder to sterilize the inflow over time. • Attaining internal and external balance. – To attain both, need 2 policy instruments. – In a large country like China, the expenditure-switching policy should be the exchange rate. – Along with expenditure-increasing policies (2009). • Avoiding crash: – Experience suggests it is better to exit from a peg in good times, when the BoP is strong, than to wait until the currency is under attack. • RMB undervalued, judged by Balassa-Samuelson relationship. ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell Longer-run perspective: Balassa-Samuelson relationship • Prices of goods & services in China are low – not just low judged by Absolute PPP (.23 relative to the US), – but also low by standards of Balassa-Samuelson relationship estimated across countries (which predicts .36). • The RMB is undervalued in this specific sense. – 2000 estimate was 35% • before 2007 statistical revisions by IPC project. – Now undervaluation estimate more like 15%. ITF-220 - Prof.J.Frankell Estimation of B-S relationship for 2000 • For every 1% increase in real income/capita (relative to US), prices increase .4% (relative). • China’s estimated residual is .15 – Using revised ICP stats. – Subramanian (2008). Fitted values CHN logRER00 .370385 CHN Frankel (2006) 118 countries, PWT -2.15096 6.17768 10.6917 ITF-220 loginc00 - Prof.J.Frankell Real appreciation • The RMB’s real appreciation against the $ from 2009 to 2012 amounted to 12%, • reducing the degree of undervaluation by roughly half, • depending on whether one measures it against the $ or against all currencies. • More is expected, as China’s relative wages continue to rise. • In any case, China’s real exchange rate is already closer to this measure of equilibrium than are most countries’ exchange rates (Cheung, Chinn & Fuji, 2010). China Adjusts, 2009-12 • Various measures suggest that China has achieved a major share of the needed trade adjustment since 2009: • Its trade surplus peaked at $300 billion in 2008, and declined thereafter. • Substantial real appreciation of the RMB has brought it closer to equilibrium. – Some nominal appreciation + – Some price inflation and, especially, wage increases. Adjustment of relative prices • The famous “China price”: – Ever since China rejoined the world economy 3 decades ago, its trading partners have been snapping up exports of manufacturing goods, – because low Chinese wages made them super-competitive on world markets. • But in recent years, relative prices have adjusted – following the laws of market economics. Adjustment of relative prices, continued • The change in relative prices is reflected as real exchange rate appreciation. – This comprises, in part, nominal appreciation – and, in part, Chinese inflation. – Government officials would have been better advised to let more of the real appreciation take the form of nominal appreciation ($ per RMB). – But since they didn’t, it showed up as inflation instead. – See charts below: • appreciation, against the $ and other currencies. Appreciation versus the US $, 2005-12 1.5 1.4 CNY/USD, 2005M06=1 1.3 real 1.2 nominal 1.1 1.0 The RMB rose against the $ during 2006-08, but temporarily returned to peg in mid-2008. 0.9 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Appreciation vs. index of currencies, 2005-12 1.35 1.30 CNY Index, 2005M06=1 1.25 1.20 Real value of CNY 1.15 Value of CNY 1.10 1.05 1.00 0.95 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 China’s trade balance The surplus peaked in 2007, and then fell. Source: Reserve Bank of Australia (June 2013) China runs a deficit in primary products, offset by a surplus in manufactures. China’s trade balance The bilateral surplus with the United States is as big as ever – which has no economic importance, but is politically sensitive. 31 The natural adjustment process was delayed. • 1st, because the authorities intervened to keep the exchange virtually fixed against the dollar, in the years 1995-2005 and 2008-2010. • 2nd, workers in China’s increasingly productive coastal factories were not paid their full value. – The economy has not completed its transition from Mao to market, after all. • As a result of these two delaying mechanisms, Chinese continued to undersell the world. But then two things happened. • 1st, the yuan was finally allowed to appreciate against the $ during 2005-08 & 2010-11, by 25% cumulatively • =17% + 8%. • Though less against other currencies. • 2nd, labor shortages began to appear => China’s workers at last won rapid wage hikes. – Major cities raised their minimum wages sharply over each of the last 3 years: • 22% on average in 2010 & 2011; • Meanwhile another cost of business, land prices, have risen even more rapidly. Chinese wages have been rising Source: “China’s wage inflation,” Aug. 28, 2013 34 Real appreciation • The RMB’s real appreciation against the $ from 2009 to 2012 amounted to 12%, • reducing the degree of undervaluation by roughly half, • depending on whether one measures it against the $ or against all currencies. • More is expected, as China’s relative wages continue to rise. • In any case, China’s real exchange rate is already closer to this measure of equilibrium than are most countries’ exchange rates (Cheung, Chinn & Fuji, 2010). 5 types of adjustment are gradually taking place in response to the new high level of costs in the factories of China’s coastal provinces: • 1st, some manufacturing is migrating inland, – where wages & land prices are still relatively low. • 2nd, export operations are shifting to Vietnam or Bangla Desh – where wages are lower still. • 3rd, Chinese companies are beginning to automate, – substituting capital for labor. • 4th, they are moving into more sophisticated products, – following the path blazed earlier by Japan, Korea, & other Asian tigers • in the “flying geese” formation. • 5th, multinational companies that had in the past moved some stages of their production process to China, out of the US or out of other high-wage countries, are now moving back. • All five of these ways of reallocating resources represent the economic process operating as it should. • None of this comes as news to most observers of China. • Many Western politicians are unable to let go of the syllogism that seemed so unassailable just a decade ago: – (1) The Chinese have joined the world economy; – (2) their wages are $0.50 an hour; – (3) there are a billion of them, and so – (4) their exports will rise without limit: “Chinese wages will never be bid up in line with the usual textbook laws of economics because the supply labor is infinitely elastic.” • But it turns out that the laws of economics do eventually apply after all -- even in China. Expansion of the services sector. This 6th dimension of adjustment still lags behind, • despite the consensus in favor of it. • China has had great success in manufacturing – especially via exports. • Now it needs to help the other side of the economy catch up: services, via domestic demand – Retail, education, environmental quality, – health care, pensions, social safety net. • Some of this could be done via government spending – especially with the economy in slowdown in 2014, – as China did in 2009; but that was mostly heavy investment.