The Beginning of the End - Divining the causes of economic stagnation in Renaissance Italy, the Dutch Republic and the United Kingdom. Lewis Evans (3326721) Master-thesis Comparative History August 10th, 2009 Supervisor: Bas van Bavel Acknowledgements Without the help of the following people this thesis would never have been written. First and foremost my thanks to my supervisor Bas van Bavel who encouraged me to ‘think!’, and tirelessly reviewed and commented on all work in progress. Medals of bravery have been awarded for lesser feats. My gratitude also to Maarten Prak without whose help I would still be looking for a thesis topic. Our meetings were essential to keeping doubt and chaos at bay. And where would I be without the e-mails of Paolo Malanima whose urbanization data served as one of the two pillars for my methodology and whose numerous articles provided insight into the rural murkiness of the medieval Tuscan countryside? Ewout Frankema’s consulting services in the early stages were greatly appreciated and are an example for the powers of rigorous academic thought. An exhaustive list of moral, financial, editorial, technical and conceptual supporters would require its own table of contents so I shall mention only the most esteemed ones here. Katie Simanzik, Luise von Flotow, Craig Johnson, Felix Meier zu Selhausen, Arjan Pomp, Lotte van der Vleuten, Pim de Zwart and Bill and Melinda Gates. For all those left unnamed, you know who you are. Lewis Evans August 10th, 2009 2 Table of Contents Acknowledgements ...................................................................................................... 2 Table of Contents ......................................................................................................... 3 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 5 Comparative History .................................................................................................. 7 Case Selection ............................................................................................................ 9 Variable Selection .................................................................................................... 10 Methodology and Evaluation ................................................................................... 11 Chapter 1: Pinpointing economic decline ................................................................ 12 Chapter 2: Northern and Central Renaissance Italy.............................................. 23 Economic Chronology ............................................................................................. 23 The Rise of Renaissance Italy .................................................................................. 23 The Effects of War ................................................................................................... 25 Interfering Measures taken by a Foreign Nation ..................................................... 26 Outdated Technology ............................................................................................... 28 Poor Organization in Sectors Important to the Economy ........................................ 30 Access to the Dominant Form of Energy ................................................................. 34 Climatic Influence .................................................................................................... 36 Rise of a Foreign Nation .......................................................................................... 38 Chapter 3: The Dutch Republic................................................................................ 41 Economic Chronology ............................................................................................. 41 The Rise of the Dutch Republic ............................................................................... 41 The Effects of War ................................................................................................... 43 Interfering Measures taken by a Foreign Nation ..................................................... 46 Outdated Technology ............................................................................................... 48 Poor Organization in Sectors Important to the Economy ........................................ 52 Access to the Dominant Form of Energy ................................................................. 54 Climatic Influence .................................................................................................... 57 Rise of a Foreign Nation .......................................................................................... 58 Chapter 4: The United Kingdom .............................................................................. 62 Economic Chronology ............................................................................................. 62 The Rise of the United Kingdom ............................................................................. 62 The Effects of War ................................................................................................... 64 Interfering Measures taken by a Foreign Nation ..................................................... 66 Outdated Technology ............................................................................................... 69 Poor Organization in Sectors Important to the Economy ........................................ 73 Access to the Dominant Form of Energy ................................................................. 77 Climatic Influence .................................................................................................... 78 Rise of a Foreign Nation .......................................................................................... 79 Chapter 5: Conclusions ............................................................................................. 82 Step-by-Step Chronologies of Decline .................................................................... 83 Italy ...................................................................................................................... 83 The Dutch Republic ............................................................................................. 84 The United Kingdom ........................................................................................... 86 Insignificant Variables ............................................................................................. 88 Outdated Technology ........................................................................................... 88 Access to the Dominant Form of Energy ............................................................. 89 Significant Variables ................................................................................................ 90 The Effects of War ............................................................................................... 90 3 Interfering Measures taken by a Foreign Nation ................................................. 92 Poor Organization in Sectors Important to the Economy .................................... 92 Climatic Influence ................................................................................................ 95 Rise of a Foreign Nation ...................................................................................... 95 Three Final Observations ......................................................................................... 97 Bibliography: ............................................................................................................ 101 4 Introduction Few historical topics can compete with studies of decline in terms of sheer entertainment value. Dark yet alluring images spring to mind. Decadent banquets being celebrated while barbarians pound on splintering city gates, collapsing triumphal arches through which a terrified population attempts to flee, and scenes of wanton destruction as once-great cities are ransacked flash before the mind’s eye. This is the stuff of a good story. Thankfully history has supplied us with no shortage of cases to study. The empires of Persia, Rome, Tang China, the Mongols, the Dutch, and the British are perhaps some of the most widely-known examples of great nations rising and declining, but by no means represent an exhaustive list. The topic of decline has attracted no shortage of scholarly attention. Edward Gibbon, Immanuel Wallerstein, Paul Kennedy, Giovanni Arrighi, Mancur Olson, Amy Chua, and many others - some of whose works will be examined in this thesis have all contributed to the substantial body of historical literature surrounding the rise and demise of national entities.1 It should come as no surprise that a subject matter that has attracted such attention has not failed to stimulate an equal amount of controversy. Attempts at explaining the growth, glory and decay of nations are numerous, varied, and perhaps most importantly as it is the raison d’être for this thesis, often contradictory. Explanations respectively citing the effects and consequences of imperial overstretch, war, outdated technology, institutional sclerosis, climate change, and resource endowment as the causes of decline can be found for each and every past hegemon. The sheer diversity of explanations for decline is due to either the broad definition of decline – a country can decline politically, socially, militarily, economically, artistically, etc… - or to a lack of a clear chronology. Clear definitions of when periods of growth ended and decline set in are strangely absent in the pertinent literature. 1 Gibbon, The History of the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire, Wallerstein, The Modern World System Vol I-III, Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers, Arrighi, The Long Twentieth Century, Olson, The Rise and Decline of Nations, Amy Chua, The Day of Empire. 5 The aim of this thesis is threefold. The first is to discover the actual cause or causes of economic2 stagnation in the case of Central and Northern Renaissance Italy3, the 17th century Dutch Republic, and the United Kingdom in the context of the latter nineteenth and early twentieth century4. The second is to determine whether a general rule regarding the cause or causes of economic stagnation can be formulated. The third and final goal is to draw generally-applicable conclusions regarding the longer process of economic rise and decline. Numerous explanations for economic decline exist for each of the three country cases. The process of arbitrating between them to pinpoint the true causes of economic stagnation, and the search for a universal cause of stagnation will be threefold. First, a clear chronology of growth, stagnation and decline will be established for each of the three country cases. This will be the focus of chapter one. Second, the effects of the seven variables thought to have caused stagnation will be examined in each country case. These variables have been carefully chosen and represent the principal explanations of decline and represent schools of thought that attribute economic decline to either political, social, economic, technological or other reasons. Having established the true causes of economic stagnation in each of the country cases – the relevance of each cause will be determined by the timing of its appearance in the respective country chronologies - the third and final step will involve a comparison of these ‘true causes’ to determine whether a generally-applicable rule regarding the cause, series of causes or conjuncture of causes for economic stagnation can be formulated. The individual country cases are the subject of chapters 2, 3 and 4. The plausibility of a universally-applicable theory for the causes of stagnation and general observations of economic rise and decline will be the subject of the concluding chapter. Only by comparing the causes of economic stagnation of individual historical cases can patterns be revealed that might lead to the formulation of a universally applicable rule. Restricting our study to individual cases would provide greater insight into their individual fates but would exclude the possibility of discovering common To avoid somnolence-inducing repetition, the adjective ‘economic’ will not be mentioned every time growth, stagnation, decline and hegemony are referred to. As this is a thesis in economic history, the descriptor ‘economic’ can be considered implicit. 3 To avoid repetition, the Central and Northern regions of Renaissance Italy will from now on simply be referred to as ‘Italy’. 4 To avoid repetition the United Kingdom will henceforth be referred to as the ‘UK’. The adjective ‘British’ shall be understood as being synonymous with the UK. 2 6 trends. This brings us to the core issues of the comparative method. Before explaining why the country cases and variables were chosen, first a few words on comparative history. Comparative History The goal of comparative history is to formulate new explanatory interpretations of historical phenomena. Whereas traditional historians tend to describe historical events, a comparative historian will try to explain why historical events happened the way they did. Ideally, a comparative historical analysis of past experiences might even provide insight into present day concerns.5 Furthermore comparative historians hope that the comparison of similar historical phenomena will lead to the formulation of universally-valid explanations regarding the causes and outcomes of analogous historical events.6 Some examples of favored topics for such comparisons have been the causes of revolutions, the origins of different typologies of political regimes, the varying developments of social movements and the processes behind the formation of national states.7 In these comparisons that often fall under the category ‘big history’, historical eras and geographical location are not an immediate concern. As long as the object of comparison is considered and can be proven to be sufficiently analogous as to warrant a comparison, the primary restrictions to a fruitful historical comparative analysis are the age-old curse of comparable data for all of the to-be-compared cases, and the historian’s creativity. A Chinese and the Roman empire might be compared, both ends of the Eurasian continent might be treated as peers around 1750, and something as delicate as silk might be found to be at the root of the divergent development of two once-similar nations.8 In comparative history a stimulating conclusion is often the result of an audacious question. It helps to have chutzpah. Two principal methodological approaches serve as the basis of these comparisons: the case-oriented and the variable-oriented approach. In the case5 Mahoney, Rueschmeyer, Comparative Historical Analysis, 9. Kolchin, “Comparing American History,” 64-65. 7 For ‘causes of revolutions’ see Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions, for the ‘origins of political regimes’ see Moore, Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, for ‘development of social institutions’ see Skocpol, Protecting Soldiers and Mothers, for the ‘formation of national states’ see Tilly, Ardant The Formation of National States in Western Europe. 8 For a comparison of the Han Empire and Roman Empire during the Principate see Custers, Balancing Acts, for ‘both ends of the Eurasian continent’ see Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, for ‘silk’ see Ma, “Why Japan, Not China”. 6 7 oriented approach a limited number of historical cases are studied within their specific historical contexts in the hopes of reaching limited generalizations.9 Case-oriented work tends to be qualitative, interpretive, and holistic and is characterized by a dialogue between theory and data. A drawback of the case-oriented approach is that the small number of cases that due to their required similarities can only be added to with difficultly can lead to a possibly vague and impressionist conclusion. Whereas the case-oriented approach works from historical evidence towards establishing a generalizing theory, the variable-oriented approach works in the opposite direction. Theories are proven or falsified based on checking them against large amounts of cases and data.10 Abstraction is given precedence over specificity.11 Compared to the case-oriented approach, the variable-oriented approach tends to be quantitative (i.e. statistical), theory-based, reductionist, and with the ultimate goal of proving or falsifying a hypothesis. The variable-oriented approach is best suited for the comparison of a large number of cases that can be chosen with much less stringent selection criteria. For this very reason the variable-oriented approach is less suited for historical comparisons whose intrinsic specificity encourages comparing only a small number of cases. The variable-oriented approach tends not to explain the ‘why’ and ‘how’ of historical phenomena. Interestingly, the most commonly-quoted advantages and disadvantages of the comparative method revolve around the same basic concept: simplicity. Its critics accuse it of oversimplification while its advocates applaud precisely this ability to create clarity in contexts long obfuscated by academic hairsplitting. An example that will serve both to illustrate the comparative method being used to arbitrate among competing explanations until all but one have been discarded, as well as to illustrate the controversy that it is capable of arousing is Daron Acemoglu’s study of the colonial origins of comparative development.12 In it geography and resource endowment, religion and culture, institutions and even history itself are declared extraneous to the true explanation of why some former colonies are rich and others poor. Once the regressions have been run, the factor that best explains their radically different stages of development is early settler mortality. If the white man lived 9 Ragin, The Comparative Method, 35. Ibid., 53. 11 Ibid., 54. 12 Acemoglu, Johnson, Robinson. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution.” 10 8 colonies prospered, if he died they grew impoverished. Although undoubtedly a novel conclusion that has sparked much inherently-valuable discussion, it can only be hoped that such extreme, mono-causal reductionism will awake suspicion, not only among historians but in the mind of any critical human being. Examples of good comparative history, those in which cases and variables have been carefully chosen and defined, in which the balance between generality and complexity has been painstakingly maintained, might, after much interpretation of the results, cautiously indicate a general causality itself deserving further research. Any comparative study alleging to do more should be treated with skepticism. This thesis will make use of the case-oriented approach. It is ideally suited for the comparison of three historically-relevant cases that become comparable through the shared experience of economic growth, stagnation and decline. The comparison of the effects that a small number of variables (7) had in each of the three cases will suffice for the eventual formulation of a general rule regarding the causes of economic decline. Answering the question of why to use the comparative method in the specific case of this thesis instead of the more traditional narrative approach brings us back to the primary goal of the comparative method. Only a systematic comparison of the yetto-be-determined true cause or causes of economic stagnation in the three country cases will permit the formulation of a generally-valid explanation of economic stagnation. Only by comparing the individual fate of the three former economic hegemons by the same standards can a reduction among the plethora of explanations for economic decline be achieved. Parsimony and Ocham’s razor at work! Without wanting to prematurely give away the details of the findings at this point, it will be said that some astonishing surprises await the diligent reader. The validity of timetried explanations will be undermined and factors that have hereto been largely ignored will be cast in a new light. But why these three countries? Case Selection The three country cases to be examined are the Central and Northern regions of Renaissance Italy, the Dutch Republic in the period surrounding its Golden Age, and the United Kingdom in the nineteenth and twentieth century. These three cases were not chosen at random. From roughly the fifteenth to the twentieth century, they 9 represented the geographically shifting, yet uninterrupted epicenter of economic activity in Europe.13 In each case the country first rose until becoming the economic hegemon of its era, for a shorter or longer period of time conserved this position, and then experienced first economic stagnation and then economic decline. Both economic stagnation and decline can be either ‘relative’ or ‘absolute’. This difference will be explained in chapter 1. Despite the differences in their respective geographical dimensions, the size of their populations, and the manifold differences in political, economic and social frameworks inherent to the three diverse eras in which they rose, reigned, stagnated and declined, the three countries become comparable due to their shared experience as once-great then stagnating and declining economic powers. Extending the scope of such a timeline of economic hegemons both backwards and forwards in time would locate modern-day Iraq as the economic forerunner of the city states of Northern and Central Italy in the early Middle Ages, and the United States as the UK’s economic successor of the twentieth century. Hence the three selected cases could easily have been added to. Limited knowledge, time, an already badly strained maximum number of words and my personal interest in the early modern and modern period, are the main reason, why only these three cases and not more shall be examined. Variable Selection Seven variables will be examined regarding their possible roles in causing economic stagnation. They are ‘the effects of war’, ‘interfering measures taken by a foreign nation’, ‘outdated technology’, ‘poor organization in sectors important to the economy’, ‘access to the dominant form of energy’, ‘climatic influence’, and ‘the rise of a foreign nation’. These variables were drawn from the principal theories that have been put forward to explain decline in the three country cases by the most relevant authors. Each variable was carefully formulated in such a way as to remain pertinent in all three country cases despite the nearly 1700 year time span that separates the onset of economic stagnation in Renaissance Italy from end of UK economic hegemony at the end of the Victorian Era. Each variable represents one facet of the basic make-up shared by all societies regardless of their appearance in history. As listed in the paragraph above, these 13 Maddison, Explaining the Economic Performance of Nations, 102. 10 variables represent the larger categories of politics, economy, technology, society, geography and climate. The variable of a ‘rising foreign nation’ was added last and after much of the research had already been done. Although ultimately not as significant as initially anticipated, it was not removed. Its importance is discussed in the conclusion. Cultural explanations have been consciously omitted from this thesis due to their difficult quantifiability. Methodology and Evaluation The proposed methodology with which those variables that caused economic stagnation will be separated from those that didn’t is simple. First, a chronology of periods of growth, stagnation and decline will be established in each of the three cases. How this chronology is established, without which any proposed arbitrage between competing theories of economic stagnation and decline would simply be a further voice in the cacophony of competing hypothesis, is the subject of chapter 1. Second, manifestations of each of the seven variables will be identified in the respective country cases. Here the word ‘manifestations’ is used due to the evolving nature of the variables over the nearly 700 year span of time in question. Although looking for ‘manifestations’ of specific variables in evolving historical contexts might sound like a difficult task, it will soon become clear that the bulk of this work has already been done by the individual authors between whose theories we propose to arbiter. Third, is the question of inserting the manifestations of each variable into the clearly-delineated chronologies of growth, stagnation and decline in each country case and seeing where they fall. Assigning a positive or negative value to each variable in the respective country cases then becomes simple. Only those variables that appeared prior to the onset of economic stagnation will be considered as possible causes of economic stagnation and will be assigned a positive value. All variables that occurred after the onset of economic stagnation can logically not be considered a cause of stagnation and will be assigned a negative value. The evaluation of the variables based almost solely on their chronological appearance – any conclusion must contain room for interpretation – will allow cause to be differentiated from consequence. 11 Chapter 1: Pinpointing economic decline The first step in delineating periods of economic growth, stagnation and decline is defining indicators that accurately reflect economic activity. The period in which our first two country cases – Italy and the Dutch Republic – rose, stagnated and declined present a first problem. Any attempt to document economic activity in pre-industrial economies will be bedeviled by a lack of modern statistical data that is the basis for contemporary economics. GDP per capita, industrial output, productivity increases, and capital accumulation are but some modern economic indicators that are the result of statistical science that are at best available as estimates for historical case studies.14 The proposed categorization of economic periods in the case of Italy and the Dutch Republic must therefore rely on proxy indicators of economic activity. Such proxy indicators are manifold. Agricultural labor productivity, tax registers, population numbers, and the construction of city walls are only some of the indicators that have been used to deduce and document a society’s economic vitality, lack thereof, or transition from a stage of growth to one of stagnation or decline.15 Inevitably, and as the word ‘proxy’ itself implies, these indicators are subjected to the vagaries of approximation, missing data, inferences and outright guesswork. The risk of using such proxy indicators is that any further argument based on such tentative assumptions will itself suffer from a lack of credibility. The proxy indicator for pre-industrial economic activity least prone to such irregularities and most widely used is data on urbanization rates. Kuznets, Bairoch, DeVries, Acemoglu and Pamuk argue than increased urbanization rates reflect an increase in agricultural productivity, the mainstay of pre-modern economies, and foretell the shift of employment structure from the primary to the secondary and tertiary sectors.16 As a rule of thumb, the fewer people employed in agriculture in preindustrial societies, the greater the society’s agricultural productivity and the greater the wealth that was accumulated through manufacturing and services. Although 14 Fei, Growth and Development, 7, 8. Lopez, Miskimin, “Economic Depression of the Renaissance”, 408-426. 16 For urbanization rates as indicators of economic activity see Acemoglu, Johnson, Robinson, “Reversal of Fortune”, 1232, Bairoch, Cities and Economic Development, chapter 1, DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 164, Kuznets, Modern Economic Growth, Van Zanden, The Rise and Fall of Holland’s economy, 20, Pamuk, “The Black Death:, 289-291. 15 12 urbanization rates themselves are subject to estimates before 1300 they become reliable in the European context from the mid-fourteenth century onward.17 In the case of the UK and the United States that became the world’s economic hegemon at the beginning of the twentieth century, readily available data on GDP per capita will be used to establish a similar economic periodization. As with urbanization rates, GDP per capita is a reflection of the productivity of an economy. It represents the total national income divided by the number of citizens of a country. Hence a higher GDP per capita reflects a greater productivity of the economy. For the purpose for which GDP per capita as an indicator of economic activity will be used in this thesis, its possible shortcomings as an economic indicator of real per capita income are acknowledged but will be ignored. The principal criticism is that an unequal distribution of wages across any given population would undermine its per-capita validity. Let us recall, however, that this is not a paper on economic wellbeing or social equality, but on economic stagnation. Why not simply use urbanization rates in all three cases? In the context of the latter half of the nineteenth and early twentieth century, urbanization rates are no longer sufficient as a proxy indicator for economic activity. Sustained, long-term population growth during the nineteenth century across Europe led to a burgeoning of European cities in what should be understood more as an outlet for Malthusian pressure from the countryside than a reflection of the levels of industrialization or economic activity of these urban death traps. Surely the sprawling slums of the developing world are not an indicator of economic prowess. With the beginnings of reliable data collection on industrial output and the advent of modern economic statistics that began in the closing decades of the nineteenth century, GDP per capita estimates will help us pinpoint the moment in which the UK fell behind its American successor. The economic trajectory of each of the three countries will be divided into three phases. The first phase will be one of growth. This is when the urbanization rates or GDP per capita grew from one time increment to the next. As economic rise and decline is a lengthy process, small reversals of general trends that upon closer scrutiny can be found for each of the three cases will be overlooked. The second phase is one of stagnation. This can be either ‘relative’ when compared to a preceding 17 Maddison, The World Economy, 248, Federico, Malanima, “Progress, Decline, Growth”, 439. 13 period of substantially larger growth, or ‘absolute’ when no growth whatsoever occurred. The final phase is one of decline. Decline too can be relative or absolute. Relative decline is when an economy continued to grow but at a lesser rate than another economy. Absolute decline is when in absolute numbers economic activity decreased. Of the three phases and their relative or absolute variations, the only one that will not be encountered in this paper is absolute stagnation. The point of this periodization is to determine the true causes of economic stagnation in the three country cases. In order to create clarity among the potpourri of existing explanations of economic decline a certain discipline is called for. The logic behind the proposed chronology-based elimination of variables is simple. If for example country A is determined to have begun to stagnate in 1400, and variables 1, 2 and 3 all occurred between 1450 and 1550, then clearly they can be discarded as possible causes of stagnation in the case of country A. Little is to be gained by making exceptions of 50 or 100 years regardless of how important a certain variable that has just missed the cut-off date might appear. It is only by rigorously adhering to the established chronological yardsticks that any meaningful conclusions can hope to be reached. A compilation of European urbanization data from 1300 to 1870 results in the following graph. Figure 1: Urbanization Rates in Western Europe from 1000 – 1870 AD 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Italy Dutch Republic Dutch Republic DeVries UK Germany Europe with UK 1870 1800 1750 1700 1650 1600 1550 1500 1400 1300 1200 1100 Europe without UK 1000 Percent (%) Urbanization Rates in Western Europe from 1000 – 1870 AD Source: All statistics from Malanima, unpublished manuscript with the exception of ‘Dutch Republic DeVries’ from DeVries, European Urbanization, p. 39. 14 In the case of Italy, Malanima has estimated the urbanization rate for 1000 and 1100 to be between 5 and 12%, to be 12% for 1200 and 15% for 1250.18 The lowest of these estimates were used in the graph for Italy until 1250. Regardless of the exact numbers the trend is clearly one of one rapid growth from 1000 to 1300. This period of growth was followed by one of decline between 1300 and 1500, after which a slight recovery occurred between 1400 and 1500. Despite the fifteenth century recovery the entire period between 1300 and 1500 will be considered one of stagnation. This is due to the marginal difference of only 1.6% in urbanization rates in 1300 and 1500 respectively. It will be recalled that phases of economic growth, stagnation and decline are extremely long, and that in the context of this thesis longterm developments and not short-term reversals of general trends are of interest. Finally from 1500 until 1870 Italy entered a period of absolute decline, when in the final decades of the nineteenth century the urbanization rates were just slightly higher than they had been in 1200. The roots of economic stagnation in Italy should therefore logically be looked for prior to 1300. Compared to Renaissance Italy, reliable urbanization data for the Dutch Republic is more readily available. Jan DeVries’ continuation of Slicher van Bath’s seminal work on pre-industrial Dutch population patterns allows the one hundred year measurement increments to be shortened to fifty years for the period between 1500 and 1800.19 Although there are slight discrepancies between the estimates of Malanima and DeVries for the period of the high Middle Ages – Malanima estimates urbanization rates in 1500 to have reached 18.9% while DeVries places them at only 15.8% - several common trends for the period between 1300 and 1500 can be established. First, that already in the high Middle Ages the Dutch Republic was highly urbanized – between 1300 and 1500 it lay ca. 10% above the western European average - and second, that there was a slow but steady increase of urbanization in the two centuries preceding 1500.20 Then between 1550 and 1650, urbanization rates soared from 15.3% to 31.7%.21 The 350 year period between 1300 and 1650 will be considered one of growth. Malanima, “Urbanization and the Italian economy”, 108. For the Dutch Republic urbanization estimates of DeVries will be used to supplement those of Malanima. For the original article on Dutch population estimates see Van Bath, Faber, Roessingh, Van der Woude, Van Xanten, "Population Changes and Economic Developments in the Netherlands”. 20 Malanima, unpublished manuscript, DeVries, European Urbanization, 39. 21 DeVries, European Urbanization, 39. 18 19 15 Beginning in 1650 urban growth slowed considerably, especially when compared to its earlier precociousness. Although the rate of urbanization increased by 1.9% between 1650 and 1700, compared to the increase of 9% between 1550 and 1600, or 7.4% between 1600 and 1650 the increase in the second half of the seventeenth century was paltry.22 Contrary to the lore surrounding the Dutch Golden Age, the second half of the seventeenth century will be considered one of stagnation. In 1700 absolute decline set in and reached its nadir in 1800 with the urbanization rate falling to 28.8%. Beginning in 1800 a slight reversal of the declining trend began and by 1870 urbanization rates had climbed to 29.1%. What is important to emphasize in the case of Dutch decline is that although urbanization rates did decline in absolute terms, the decline was both very slight, varying between a high of 33.6% in 1700 and a low of 28.8% in 1800, and that even at their nadir were still much higher than the European average. Given the above the causes of Dutch economic stagnation must be sought before 1650. For a similar periodization in the case of the United Kingdom we will switch from the use of urbanization rates as a proxy indicator of economic activity to that of GDP per capita. As has been mentioned above, by the nineteenth century urbanization rates lose some of their significance as indicators of economic activity due to the sustained population growth that occurred across Europe in the eighteenth century.23 When the United States surpassed the UK as the global economic hegemon at the beginning of the twentieth century, industrial and manufacturing data was both readily available and regularly recorded. In a heavily-industrialized age when the manufacturing sector of a nation’s economy figured largest in its bid for economic hegemony and increasing statistical data was turning GDP per capita estimates into meaningful and useable numbers, using urbanization rates alone as economic indicators would be insufficient.24 22 Ibid., 39. DeVries, The economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 243, Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 18. 24 Chandler, Scale and Scope, 3-4. 23 16 The compilation of GDP per capita data for Italy, the Netherlands, the United Kingdom, Germany, Western Europe and the United States between 1820 and 1998 results in the following graph. Figure 2 GDP per Capita for selected countries in Western Europe and the United States GDP per Capita 1990 International Dollars 30000 25000 Italy 20000 Netherlands UK 15000 Germany 10000 West Europe USA 5000 0 1820 1870 1913 1950 1973 1990 1998 Source: Maddison, The World Economy, p. 264 Before discussing the UK’s economic performance in the nineteenth and twentieth century which will be the period of focus of this thesis, first a few words on the British economy in the early modern period. Already in the sixteenth century innovations in agriculture increased the reliability of the food supply, mitigating famine and increasing life expectancy.25 Based on a comparison of real wages between 1300 and 1800, Allen argues that from 1600 onwards England was the most successful economy in Europe.26 By 1700 only 56% of the labor force was employed in agriculture, and by 1750 British agricultural labor had the highest per capita output of Europe.27 Maddison estimates that British per capita income doubled between 1500 and 1700.28 Between 1700 and 1820, British population and per capita income grew at twice the speed of the European average.29 25 Maddison, The World Economy, 91. Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 3. 27 Ibid., 22. 28 Maddison, The World Economy, 91. 29 Ibid., 94. 26 17 The simultaneous growth of the population and of per capita income made the UK a unique economic success story in eighteenth century Europe. The eighteenth century was characterized by a substantial decline in the agricultural labor force, and the rise of industry and services. If in 1700 British GDP was at twice the Dutch level, in 1820 it was seven times as high.30 The UK’s productive primary and well-supplied and innovative secondary sector guaranteed that British per capita income in the nineteenth century increased three times as fast as it had between 1700 and 1820.31 Suffice it to say that the UK’s lead in GDP per capita at the beginning of the nineteenth century had not developed overnight. For the period that coincides almost perfectly with the Victorian Era (18371901) the UK enjoyed a higher GDP per capita than all other European countries as well as the United States. Nineteenth century growth rates of GDP per capita, however, foreshadowed the end of British economic hegemony. Already between 1820 and 1870, American GDP per capita grew faster than that of the UK.32 It might only have been by a marginal 0.08%, but it indicated a trend that by the turn of the century would mark the end of British hegemony. Despite the slightly higher growth rates of American GDP per capita the period between 1820 and 1870 will be considered one of growth. In what might be considered the tail end of the growth period that began in the sixteenth century, the UK managed to conserve its lead in terms of absolute GDP per capita over its closest competitors. Around 1870, both the United States and Germany began to experience a marked quickening of their GDP per capita growth rates. In absolute values and per annum these are of 1.82% and 1.63%.33 The UK lagged behind its two closest economic competitors in this period with a GDP per capita growth rate of only 1.01%. Although the UK was able to conserve its lead in total GDP per capita until the beginning of the twentieth century, its days of economic hegemony were clearly numbered. In 1900, the United States overtook the UK in absolute GDP per capita numbers, and in the next decades was to leave Europe’s GDP per capita average far behind. Although the UK still claimed the highest GDP per capita of all remaining western European countries until 1950, its growth rate between 1913 and 1950 Ibid. It is important to note that this is ‘total’ and not ‘per capita’ GDP. Despite the growth of the British economy, the Dutch Republic conserved its lead in GDP per capita until the beginning of the nineteenth century. 31 Ibid., 97. 32 Ibid., 186. 33 Ibid., 186. 30 18 remained above the western European average by only 0.09%. Because of the comparatively poor performance of GDP per capita growth between 1870 and 1913 and its convergence with the European average between 1913 and 1950, the period between 1870 and 1950 will be considered as one of stagnation. Between 1950 and 1973, the growth of British GDP per capita dropped considerably below that of its European competitors, remaining 1.49% below the western European growth average for the entire period. Around 1960, Dutch GDP per capita rose to a higher absolute level, and both Germany and Italy experienced GDP per capita growth rates that were higher by 2.58% and 2.51% respectively. By 1973 British GDP per capita had fallen just below the average of Western Europe in absolute numbers. In the final decades of the twentieth century there was a convergence of GDP per capita across all western European countries with the UK occupying a middle position. The United States, as already in the first decades of the twentieth century, had conserved its substantial lead. Given the above, the period between 1950 and 1973 will be considered as one of relative economic decline. The scope of inquiry in the case of the UK will end in the decades after the Second World War. The causes for British stagnation must be sought before 1870. Although urbanization rates and GDP per capita are the two proxy indicators for economic activity that will be used to delineate economic periods there are other proxy indicators of economic activity that tell a complementary story. In the case of Italy for instance, per capita agricultural productivity grew in the period between 1000 and 1300 when it reached its highest point, stagnated at a high level until 1500, and then declined gradually but inexorably until 1861.34 Although it is not surprising that something as fundamental to economic activity as agricultural productivity would mirror the same up and downward movements as rates of urbanization, the identical trajectory of agricultural productivity reinforces the periodization suggested by urbanization rates as well as hints at the importance of agricultural developments in solving the puzzle of Italian economic decline. In the case of the Dutch Republic per capita income is estimated to have grown rapidly between 1580 and 1700, when a “significant” fall of per capita GDP 34 Federico, Malanima, “Progress, decline, growth”, 439. 19 began and lasted until 1820.35 The nadir was reached at the end of the Napoleonic Wars.36 These numbers confirm the general economic trend outlined by the urbanization rates. In the case of the UK ample signs of a loss of momentum can be found in its manufacturing sector in the last decades of the nineteenth century. From 1875 to 1900, output per capita growth slowed then fell behind latter-day industrializing economies.37 The serious loss of competitiveness linked to the failure of British industry to match the productivity advances of other countries (i.e. the application of science to the industrial process) was apparent between 1899 and 1913, and helped transform the period of growth from 1820 to 1870 into one of relative stagnation that lasted until 1950.38 Britain’s enduring failure to effectively modernize its staple industries until after the Second World War undoubtedly contributed to making the period between 1950 and 1973 one of relative economic decline.39 Again this industrial data ratifies the story told by the GDP per capita comparison. Here a few preemptive words to mollify the critics. As with any methodology claiming to provide clarity by arbitrating between theories of acclaimed economic historians with an ingenious, hereto undiscovered methodological artifice there are bound to be shortcomings. The methodology proposed here is no exception. Critics will belittle the delineation of economic periods as being chronological approximations, and claim that the process of elimination require too rigid an adherence to the established economic phases. Are there not grey areas? Did Italian economic stagnation not begin in 1348 after all? Is it not presumptuous to define half of the Dutch Golden Age as ‘stagnant’? What would Queen Victoria have said about half her reign amounting to little more than maintaining the status quo? Hoping to appease, these two possible inadequacies will be addressed here. First to the accusation of arbitrarily delineating the economic periods. Given the available data on the already discussed primary and secondary proxy indicators, the delineation of periods was done as conscientiously as possible. Given the care taken in the compilation and interpretation of the data, any accusation of arbitrariness 35 Maddison, The World Economy, 245. Ibid. 37 Elbaum, Lazonick, Decline of the British Economy, 9. 38 Ibid. 39 Ibid., 10. 36 20 is unwarranted. A lack of chronological precision or using increments of time that are too large to be meaningful are perhaps more justified as criticism. Given the nature of the proxy indicators, however, these ills are only difficultly addressed. Urbanization rates in the late Middle Ages were simply not recorded once every few years. It can only be hoped that when placed in the broader context of economic rise and decline, a process that lasts not decades but centuries, that the ability to delineate economic trends will be sufficient an achievement to warrant forgiving potential shortcomings that come from a too literal reading of the available data. Second, to the point of adhering to the economic phases with excessive rigidity. Admittedly cut-off dates are seldom a cause for joy. They figure among other necessary evils such as punch clocks, alarm clocks and deadlines. And yet nobody claimed that creating order was going to be a gentle affair. I am fully aware that such strict, black and white categorization, especially in the field of the humanities, can quickly resemble a rigid thought process that is foreign to the spirit of academic inquiry itself. Thus is the burden of the comparative historian. In return for such an intransigent treatment of complex contexts that over time have filled tomes that in turn have come to occupy entire floors of libraries, this chronology based methodology offers the luxury of clarity that comes from being able to separate the relevant from the immaterial. It can only be hoped that the originality of the findings and the boldness of the final conclusions will make up for the methodological imperfections. Having addressed these here, we will move on, rigorously and without further apology. Based on the available urbanization and GDP per capita data the periodization in each of the three country cases which will be used to determine the relevance of the competing variables for the remainder of this paper is as follows. Italy’s phase of economic growth lasted from 1000 to 1300. Economic stagnation set in in 1300, and lasted until 1500. Absolute economic decline began in 1500 and lasted until 1870. In the case of the Dutch Republic the phase of economic growth lasted from 1300 to 1700, although due to the comparative sluggishness of growth between 1650 and 1700, and in order to stick to the three-phase delineation, the period between 1650 and 1700 will be considered one of stagnation. Economic decline set in in 1700, and lasted until 1800. The period after 1800 is of no interest in the context of the search for the causes of Dutch economic stagnation. 21 In the case of the United Kingdom the economic phases need to be defined somewhat differently. At no time in the period in question – the nineteenth and twentieth century – did absolute economic stagnation or decline occur. In comparison with the United States, its economic successor, and Germany its closest economic rival in Continental Europe, it will be a question of relative economic performance. In order to stay within our previous definitions of growth, stagnation and decline, and basing the delineation on the available GDP per capita data, we will treat the period between 1820 and 1870 as one of growth, the period between 1870 and 1950 as one of relative stagnation, and the period between 1950 and 1973 as one of relative decline. Now that the respective periods of economic growth, stagnation and decline that will allow us to distinguish between cause and consequence have been defined, it is time to examine the seven variables suspected of causing economic stagnation in the respective historical and national settings. 22 Chapter 2: Northern and Central Renaissance Italy Economic Chronology Based on urbanization data it has been established that the northern and central regions of Renaissance Italy experienced prodigious economic growth from 1000 to 1300, economic stagnation from 1300 to 1500 and absolute economic decline from 1500 to 1870. Further proxy indicators such as agricultural productivity and GDP per capita estimates mirror the basic upwards and downwards movement described by the urbanization rates, thereby seconding the above delineation of the respective economic phases.40 Of particular interest to the investigation of the causes of economic stagnation are the historical manifestations of the seven variables that can be found prior to 1300. Only the variables that pre-date the onset of stagnation will be assigned a positive value at the end of the chapter. This chapter and the two following country chapters will be structured as follows. First a brief outline of the economic rise of the country will be given. This outline will help understand the economic context in which the seven decline-causing variables were at work. Then each of the seven variables and their respective historical manifestations will be discussed and chronologically situated in one of the established economic phases. Each country chapter will end with a table summarizing the positive or negative values assigned to each variable. The Rise of Renaissance Italy Maddison argues that especially the regions in Northern and Central Italy benefited from the general economic re-awakening of Europe that began in the eleventh century.41 Common trends for Europe’s most prosperous regions from the eleventh to the sixteenth century included the gradual incorporation of technological advances that raised agricultural productivity, an increase in the area of rural settlement and cultivation, the beginnings of the nation state, an increased regional specialization in food production and services that reflected expanding trade, and important advances For ‘agricultural productivity’ see Federico, Malanima, “Progress, Decline, Growth”, 444, for ‘GDP per capita estimates’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 245. 41 Ibid., 53. 40 23 in mining, metallurgy, shipping and navigation.42 Maddison estimates that European GDP per capita doubled between 1000 and 1500.43 The Italian city states of Florence, Genoa, Pisa, Milan and Venice were on the forefront of this development and only Flanders with its cloth production, banking and commerce oriented towards the north of Europe could boast similar rates of urbanization and economic activity.44 Although undoubtedly there were important differences between the city states compared to the rest of Europe they were united by common characteristics. Venice will serve as an example. It is accredited with reopening the Mediterranean economy to western European commerce as well as developing trade links with northern Europe, both by sea and over the Brenner Pass.45 It successfully defended its status as a republic which was dominated by a capitalist merchant elite and had political and legal institutions that guaranteed both private property and the enforceability of contracts. Protectionist measures were instated to shield local industries from foreign competition and a pragmatic and opportunistic foreign policy actively intervened in matters of commercial interests with political pressure or military action.46 The city also played a pivotal role in transferring Asian and Egyptian technologies (cane sugar and silk production and glass blowing) to Europe and was a pioneer in the emerging markets of foreign exchange, international credit, banking, accountancy, and government bonds.47 Its fiscal system was efficient and favorable to merchant profit and accumulation of capital, and as a state it was both relatively tolerant and secular compared to the majority of its European contemporaries.48 These technological and organizational achievements resulted in thriving cities, a reputable manufacturing sector and a merchant class that had far-reaching influence in both foreign markets and the international carrying trade. By the beginning of the fourteenth century at least Northern and Central Italy appeared to be on the verge of regaining the former glory of Imperial Rome. History, however, is unpredictable. Only three hundred years later Italy had sunk into “insignificance”: 42 For an abbreviated overview of Europe-wide trends see Ibid., 53. Maddison summarizes the work of Lynn White’s Medieval Technology and Social Change. Oxford Press, 1964. 43 For the ‘GDP estimate’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 51. 44 Ibid., 52. 45 Ibid. 46 Ibid. 47 Ibid. 48 Ibid. 24 poor, predominantly agricultural, over-populated and an importer of foreign manufactures.49 What had happened? The Effects of War The fifteenth century, the second and final century of economic stagnation before Italy embarked on its inexorable retreat into economic insignificance, was characterized by a series of wars that ravaged the north of the country. First the Wars of Lombardy (1425-1454) between the Republic of Venice and the Duchy of Milan wreaked havoc on the economy of Lombardy, then beginning in 1494, northern Italy would bear the brunt of being the show place of the struggle for power between France and Habsburg Spain. The Italian Wars devastated northern Italy without a mention worthy pause until 1559. By the end, Habsburg Spain had prevailed over France and the states of Italy had been either destroyed or reduced to second-rate powers.50 This long series of armed conflicts had far-reaching consequences for the economies of the city states of Renaissance Italy. Farmland reverted to wasteland, agricultural production was disrupted by marauding troops, the population was decimated by famines and epidemics and declined by 20%, and urban manufacturing and the ‘invisible exports’ of banking and shipping suffered from the disruption of trade.51 Italy’s early-sixteenth century economy suffered grievously during the sixty five years of uninterrupted warfare that began in 1494.52 Despite the wars’ devastating effects on all three sectors of the economy, its chronological appearance only in the middle and then again at the end of the fifteenth century excludes it as a possible cause for economic stagnation. This does not mean that the wars’ prolonged duration during the first fifty years of decline as well as its recurrence and devastating effects on the population and agriculture did not make war a factor that cemented decline. Due, however, to where it falls in the chronology – 125 years after the onset of economic stagnation – the variable will be assigned a negative value. For “insignificance” see DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 17, for other characteristics see Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 196. 50 Duggan, A concise history of Italy, 47, 52, 59, 61. 51 Sella, “Two faces of the Lombard Economy”, 11, Black, Early Modern Italy, 35. 52 Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 202. 49 25 Interfering Measures taken by a Foreign Nation Mercantilist policies that first spring to mind as a common method with which nations interfered with foreign economies did not figure prominently in the inter-European trade of the eleventh through fourteenth century and indeed did not play a role in the Italian context until the mid-seventeenth century.53 When they did, French and English mercantilist policies consisted of high import duties, tax cuts and royal subsidies for national manufactures, as well as instances of price dumping.54 The combined effects of these policies lowered the cost of foreign made goods and pushed Italian manufactures out of domestic and foreign markets.55 In the established chronology of decline, however, the appearance of French and British mercantilism is of little interest. By the mid-seventeenth century the Italian economy had been stagnating and declining for a total of 300 years. There are, however, two other historical manifestations of this variable worth considering. The first is the expansion of the Ottoman Empire in the second half of the fifteenth century, and the economic consequences this had for Italy.56 In 1479, the Ottomans shut Italian traders and merchants out of the Black Sea. In 1517, the Ottoman’s conquest of Egypt virtually terminated the spice trade for European traders.57 The increasing loss of control of trade and shipping in the Mediterranean due to both Ottoman expansion and increased competition by England and Flanders contributed to undermining Italy’s role as a Mediterranean power.58 By 1600, centuryold Venetian seaborne dominance had vanished.59 The second manifestation is related to the decline of Spain. Cipolla argues that the secular decline of Spain in the seventeenth century led to the formation of monopolies of primary materials such as wool, oil and dyes.60 The monopolization of these basic commodities on which Italian manufactures depended further raised the price of Italian finished products. DeVries argues that the decline of the Iberian 53 Ibid., 209. Ibid. 55 Ibid., 202, Sella, “The Two Faces of the Lombard economy”, 11. 56 Andrew Hess describes the resources that became available to the Ottomans through their seizure of Syria, Egypt and Arabia as necessary to project their power to the gates of Vienna. The victory of Selim the Grim over the Mamluk empire are in his words “a major event in both European and Middles Eastern history.” Hess, The Ottoman Conquest of Egypt, 55. 57 Maddison, The World Economy, 53. 58 Ibid. 59 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 26. 60 Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 210. 54 26 Empire had a “severe” impact on Italy, in particular on its “client centers” in Northern Italy that suffered from the contraction of trade with its main trading partner.61 For Venice the loss of the spice trade as well as the loss of market leverage in the Levant that was a further consequence of Ottoman expansion in the eastern Mediterranean had immediate negative economic consequences. Maddison argues that the waning trade led to a sharp decline in demand for the product of the Arsenal shipyard; Venice’s largest employer.62 Another consequence of the declining profitability of the Levant trade was the reorientation of a “significant portion” of Venetian capital towards agriculture and the development of Palladian Villas from 1500 onwards.63 The shift from manufacturing and trade to agriculture is highly significant. Lopez is quick to point out that there are fundamental qualitative differences between these economic activities. In the context of the mid-fourteenth century Europe-wide economic crisis that lasted until the last decades of the fifteenth century, he questions how valuable the expansion of the North Sea herring fishing grounds really were, when compared to the failing yet vastly more lucrative pepper trade of the Levant.64 If trade and the ‘invisible services’ of shipping and banking were the second and third pillars of the late Medieval Italian economy, then surely being shut out of once-lucrative spice markets and Eastern Mediterranean commerce could only cement Italy’s long-term path into decline.65 It seems only human that Italian investors amidst declining demand for urban manufactures and rising prices for agricultural products would have been enticed by the comparatively greater profitability of agricultural, and were only too happy to ignore the long-term consequences of abandoning the secondary and tertiary sectors of the economy to what in hindsight would be a clear case of ‘long-term deflation’.66 For chronological reasons seventeenth century French and English mercantilist measures have been discounted as possible causes of stagnation. A similar conclusion must be reached for the economic consequences of a declining Iberian Empire. In the seventeenth century Italy was already irremediably declining. Although Ottoman expansion and the subsequent contraction of Italian trade in the eastern Mediterranean 61 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 250. Maddison, The World Economy, 58. 63 Ibid., 53, 57. 64 Lopez, Miskimin, “Economic Depression of the Renaissance”, 412-413. 65 Ibid., 413. 66 Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 212, 214. 62 27 undoubtedly had the greatest negative consequences for those cities most involved in the spice trade, the fact that it too falls so late in the period of stagnation, only making its appearance on the brink of decline, warrants that the variable of ‘interfering measures taken by a foreign nation’ will be assigned a negative value. Outdated Technology By the mid-sixteenth century, the once sought after Italian manufactures that for centuries had enjoyed a reputation becoming of their high standards and quality were no longer selling.67 The explanation for the drying up of demand is simple; English, Dutch and French goods were cheaper.68 Cipolla argues that excessive guild control, poorly conceived taxation and high labor costs were the main factors that contributed to raising the price of Italian urban manufactures.69 Further he argues that guilds obliged manufacturers to use outdated methods of production and organization, prevented competition between associates, and were all-around “formidable obstacles to innovation”.70 All of these reasons are organizational in nature, and yet resulted in the continued use of outdated methods of production. They will be addressed in detail when organizational shortcomings are examined below. The more fundamental link between organizational shortcomings and outdated technology will be returned to in the concluding chapter. The imported English, French and Dutch goods that began to erode the market share of Italian manufactures in the sixteenth century were not only cheaper but also in higher demand. Foreign made fabrics for example were lighter and came in a greater array of colors.71 Renowned Italian manufacturers haughtily held these ‘new fashions’ in contempt and believed that quality and tradition would eventually overcome a mere passing fad.72 Although the important textile industry was first to feel the pressure of imported English worsteds, French silks and German linen and fustions, other manufactures were similarly affected. Dutch firearms are another example of foreign goods outpricing Italian manufactures both in Italy and in foreign 67 Ibid., 202. Ibid., 203. 69 Ibid., 205-208. 70 Ibid., 205. 71 Ibid., 204. 72 Ibid., 207. 68 28 markets.73 Sella argues that the centuries of success that had been enjoyed by the skilled urban craftsmen had “created complacency and blunted inventiveness and the ability to adapt and innovate.”74 The role that outdated technology played in weakening urban economies is highlighted by the greater resilience in times of economic hardship of the low-tech countryside of Lombardy. Rural Lombardy had never enjoyed the “protective shields of superior technology and skills” and specializing in foodstuffs, raw materials and low-grade manufactured goods, was far more successful in adapting to the economic restructuring of the early-seventeenth century.75 With a bit of imagination and goodwill the economic structure in the Lombardy countryside with its wage laborers and nascent cottage industry can be described as ‘flexible’. In comparison the urban centers continued to manufacture old-fashioned products for declining markets with outdated technology and poor organizational structures.76 The outdated technology of urban manufacturing had its equivalent at sea. Lane and Pryor argue that important changes in ship building and naval warfare in the fifteenth century – the rise of multiple mast sailing vessels and the increased use of firearms - first undermined the usefulness of the Venetian style galley in shipping and warfare, and by the sixteenth century had made it obsolete.77 With their sea-power increasingly challenged from the mid-fifteenth century onwards, by the corsairs of the Ottoman Empire who quickly emulated Venetian maritime technology, and finding themselves out-priced and outmuscled by the sailing ships of England, France and the Dutch Republic by the middle of the sixteenth century, it is safe to say that Italy had lost its edge in trade and military control in the Mediterranean by the beginning of the seventeenth century.78 Although Italy’s edge in maritime technology would be continually eroded from the fifteenth century onwards until by the beginning of the seventeenth century Italy had been reduced to a “passive role” in maritime affairs, the timing of the loss of the technological edge in seafaring technology – one hundred years after the onset of Sella, “The Two Faces of the Lombard economy”, 13. Ibid. 75 Ibid., 14. 76 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 27. 77 Lane, Navires et Constructeurs, 15-16, Pryor, Geography, Technology and War, 185-187. 78 For ‘corsairs of the Ottoman Empire’ see Pryor, Geography, Technology and War,186-187,for ‘competition from rising nations’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 53, Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 202. 73 74 29 economic stagnation – excludes it from being a cause of stagnation.79 When the Italian economy began to stagnate Italy was still unchallenged at sea. Similarly, the outdated technology that contributed to making Italian manufactures uncompetitive compared to foreign-made goods by the early-sixteenth century cannot be considered a cause for stagnation. It would have taken ten consecutive generations of urban manufacturers to ward off all technological innovation to span the 200 years that separated the early-sixteenth century from the onset of economic stagnation.80 Due to the above, outdated technology, at land and at sea, will be assigned a negative value. Poor Organization in Sectors Important to the Economy Jan DeVries argues convincingly that it was changes in the organization of production rather than advances in production technology that were required to succeed Early Modern Europe.81 The cost reducing innovations of the Dutch Republic, the most characteristic of which are the closely-linked bulk trade and the central warehouse system, but also an increased division of labor, agricultural specialization and a rural putting-out industry resulted in cost advantages that guaranteed the Dutch vast international markets.82 It will be argued below that the Italian experience differed significantly. Three sectors of the economy will be examined: manufacturing, agriculture and sea-faring trade. In regards to manufacturing, and as was mentioned above in relation with outdated technology, Cipolla argues that the combined effects of guild regulation on urban manufacturing amounted to raising production costs and stifling innovation. The benefits reaped by the urban capital that fled to the countryside from the besieged urban centers of Lombardy will serve as a counterexample to the restrictions and burdens inherent to the sclerotic organization affecting urban manufacturing. Seasonal labor mobility unregulated by guilds allowed for part-time employment of peasant labor during low periods of the agricultural cycle and resulted in low labor costs.83 The immediate and positive effect of increased flexibility of the labor market is telling. In seventeenth century rural Lombardy, a healthy economy developed around 79 80 For Italy being reduced to a ‘passive role’ see Cipolla, 213. I have calculated, likely generously, that the generation length in the late Middle Ages was 20 years. 81 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 245. Ibid., 27. 83 Sella, “The Two Faces of the Lombard economy”, 14. 82 30 commercial farms and a rural handicraft industry that employed a large skilled and semi-skilled workforce.84 Rural merchants and middlemen experimented with the largely-unexplored mechanism of trade which resulted in an upwind for silk production, as well as the mining and metallurgical sectors. An economic structure much closer to the proto-capitalist one that characterized the Dutch Republic allowed the rural areas of Lombardy to flourish at the same times as the urban cities were in their last throes in the 1630s and 40s.85 Berner stresses the link between the excessive power of political organizations and the underdevelopment that was to characterize early modern Italy.86 Although the cost-increasing consequences of poor organizational structures related to urban manufacturing played an undeniable role in making Italian manufactures less competitive by the sixteenth century and contributed to driving urban capital into agriculture, its appearance coincides only with the onset of economic decline. Even if one considers that organizational weaknesses were at work long before their effects actually undercut the competitiveness and profitability of manufacturing, there is still a two hundred year buffer period in the chronology that separates it from being a cause of economic stagnation. Poor organization in manufacturing can therefore not be considered a cause of economic stagnation. In the context of agriculture and the excessive power of political entities we turn to Italian agriculture and Italy’s version of share-cropping: the mezzadria. The mezzadria arose in northern and central Italy in response to the land shortage and population glut that ensued from the demographic recovery after the Black Death in the late-fourteenth and fifteenth century. Although the sheer variety of share-cropping agreements throughout northern and central Italy (let alone the variations across the whole of Italy) make a universally applicable conclusion regarding the impact of share-cropping on the economy difficult, a strong case can be made for its retarding effects on structural change. Black argues that with the flow of urban wealth to the countryside of Umbria and Tuscany that rural properties were consolidated, small landholders dispossessed and share-cropping and leasing contracts introduced that were unfavorable for the 84 Ibid. Ibid., 11-13. 86 Berner, “Italy: Commentary”, 22. 85 31 peasants.87 Further, Black argues that urban centers used the mezzadria system to take control of rural areas.88 Sixteenth century changes in fiscal policies that allowed urban elites to pass the tax burden on to rural communities, and other manifestations of the political monopoly held by the cities vis-à-vis their rural surroundings, guaranteed urban centers an advantage of greater market information and an artificially cheap supply of rural products.89 Although this was not the case everywhere, and in Valpolicella and other regions of the Veronese the share-cropping system appears to have been more balanced and involved greater participation of the land owners, Black insists that “the expropriation and exploitation of peasants was the main characteristic of [this] period through much of Italy.”90 Although an impoverished peasant population might hint at but does not necessarily result in a low-performance agricultural sector, Malanima highlights the structural side effects of share-cropping. It “inhibited the development of manufacturing in the countryside by stimulating the rise of intensive mixed farming which absorbed family labor throughout the year and left no time for seasonal nonagricultural employment.”91 Also addressing the secondary effects of share-cropping, Epstein argues that the “significant redistribution of incomes between land and labor after the Black Death that elsewhere in Europe had favored the peasantry and stimulated demand for cheap textiles produced by domestic rural industry” remained largely absent in Italy.92 Certainly there were exceptions as have been observed in Lombardy, but these tended to prove the rule. Belfanti argues that the beginnings of structural change in the regional economy of Tuscany only occurred at the end of the seventeenth century when a strong demographic recovery after the severe mortality crisis of 1630 created a pool of cheap labor that could be employed in rural manufacturing.93 Only in the eighteenth century did the Tuscan cities lose their grip on the countryside which with more diversified economies and specialized niches (Livorno’s maritime trade, Prato’s woolen industry) challenged the political and industrial hegemony of urban centers.94 87 Black, Early Modern Italy, 32. Ibid., 45. 89 Malanima, ‘Teoria economica regionale e storia”, 145, Belfanti, “Town and country in central and northern Italy”, 296. 90 Black, Early Modern Italy, 34. 91 Malanima, La decadenza di un’economia cittadina, 64. 92 Epstein, ‘Cities, regions and the late medieval crisis: Sicily and Tuscany compared’, 40. 93 Belfanti, “Town and country in central and northern Italy”, 297. 94 Ibid. 88 32 Despite the regional differences within the mezzadria system its direct economic and indirect structural consequences for the Italian economy would prove to be negative and long-lasting. Plagued by low investment, low productivity, and outdated technology share-cropping absorbed labor that elsewhere in Europe was being employed in rural proto-industries. As long as the urban elites were able to conserve their political leverage, the mezzadria remained a reflection of the badly needed yet successfully postponed structural change that characterized Italy’s mature and rigid economy. The dominant form of agricultural organization in Italy from the fifteenth to the eighteenth century was a far cry from the diversified and marketoriented agricultural that was developing in the Dutch Republic and England. Although mezzadria guaranteed that agriculture would be plagued by low productivity until the beginning of the nineteenth century, in the context of our economic chronology the institution of share-cropping as a reflection of poor organization must be assigned a negative value.95 At the time of its introduction Italy’s economy had been stagnating for nearly a century. Poor organization in agriculture and manufacturing had its equivalent at sea. Cipolla argues that seventeenth century Italian shipping was characterized by “conservatism and excessive labor costs.” 96 The resulting waning competitiveness contributed to the expansion of foreign shipping as can be seen in the rapid rise of the free port of Livorno. English sailors who were paid by the voyage and not by the day as were their Italian counterparts regularly made twice the number of voyages in the same amount of time.97 The economy-wide lack of technological and organizational innovation is a clear indication of the ‘internal rigidities’ that plagued Italy’s economy. Its persistent and prolonged absence made Italy a prime victim for the destructive effects of the European-wide economic readjustment of the early modern period.98 Whereas the countries of northwestern Europe invested in new technologies and sought out new markets, Italy’s cities were “abandoned to long-term deflation.”99 Regarding the search for the variables that caused economic stagnation, however, the variable of For ‘low productivity in Italian agriculture’ see Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 4, 12, Federico, Malanima, “Progress, Decline, Growth”, 444, 448, 449. 96 Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 213. 97 Ibid. 98 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 250. 99 Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 214. 95 33 ‘poor organization in sectors important to the economy’ must be given a negative value. None of its manifestations appeared prior to the onset of economic stagnation. Access to the Dominant Form of Energy In the case of Renaissance Italy the primary source of energy to be considered is the size of the population in terms of sheer manpower. The population pattern of Italy between 1000 and 2000 can be divided into three phases. Following the Europe-wide decline in population between the fourth and tenth centuries, the first phase is one of growth that coincided with the period of sustained economic growth between the eleventh and early fourteenth century that witnessed late medieval Italy become one of Europe’s economically dominant hubs.100 The second phase is one of decline followed by stability that lasted from the mid-fourteenth until the seventeenth century. The third phase, which is of least interest in context of this thesis, lasted from the middle of the seventeenth century until present and is characterized by sustained population growth. The beginning of the second phase of population development, the ca. 300 to 350 year period of population decline and stagnation between the early-fourteenth and mid-seventeenth century, missed the beginning of economic stagnation by a mere half century. The initial sudden drop in population was caused by the Black Death of 1348-49, when Italy lost circa 1/3 of its population.101 It was not until 1600 that the population regained pre-plague levels. The interim period of 250 years was characterized by recurring wars (First in Lombardy 1425-1454, then the Italian Wars 1494-1559) as well as sporadic outbreaks of the plague.102 Together they undermined a rapid demographic recovery. Although classical economic theory welcomes a sudden loss of population with the good news of an increase in per-capita productivity, and indeed this was the case in Italy where per capita agricultural output rose by more than a third in the decades after the Black Death, it is important not to forget that agricultural output in absolute terms declined by a third by the end of the For ‘population information between the 4 th and 10th century’ see Malanima, “Urbanization and the Italian Economy”, 99, for ‘population growth and economic rise’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 53. 101 Pamuk, “The Black Death and the origins of the Great Divergence”, 294. 102 Federico, Malanima, “Progress, Decline, Growth”, 447. 100 34 fourteenth century.103 It would not be until the beginning of the eighteenth century that gross agricultural output was again at the level of 1300. Although the Central and Northern regions of Italy were economically among the most advanced and diverse in Europe at the beginning of the fourteenth century, it is important to recall that agriculture still employed 60-70% of the population and accounted for 45-60% of the GDP.104 Malanima argues that Italy’s plummeting then stagnating population and the ensuing absolute decline then stagnation of its agricultural production meant that Italy would experience no growth at all in the period of Modern European Growth.105 Although later increases in population would never fail to undermine per capita productivity in Italian agriculture until by the end of the nineteenth century per capita productivity had fallen below the level of 1300, a large population at the beginning of the early modern period was a crucial ingredient for a productive agricultural sector.106 A final verdict on this variable is complicated by the controversy surrounding the relation between population size and economic productivity. In the case of stagnant technology an increasing population will diminish the returns on labor and result in lower productivity.107 As can be seen in the case of Italy every decrease in population led to an increase in per capita productivity.108 This inverse relationship is interrupted only when technological advances or organizational innovations allow a growing population to find productive employment. This was the case in the Dutch Republic and England where the innovations described by the term ‘agricultural revolution’ freed an ever growing percentage of the workforce from the need to work in agriculture, creating a pool of labor available to rural manufacturing or urban industries.109 Unlike northern and western Europe where the mid-fourteenth century plague epidemics ultimately resulted in an increased market orientation of their economies, the success of which can be measured in their rapidly recovering populations, the mezzadria in Italy further undermined both the productivity of agriculture as well as the chance of structural change. By the time Italy’s population 103 Ibid., 444, 448. Ibid., 437. 105 Malanima, “Measuring the Italian Economy”, 280. 106 Federico, Malanima, “Progress, decline, growth”, 444. 107 Capasso, “Economy and Population”, 19. 108 Federico, Malanima, “Progress, decline, growth”, 444. 109 Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 18. For ‘rapid British population growth’ see DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 8. 104 35 had finally recovered from plagues and warfare at the beginning of the seventeenth century, sheer size of population was no longer a required ingredient to economic growth as it had been in the late and high Middle Ages. Far from it. Over-populated and underemployed, by 1600 Italy was well on the way to becoming a backwater of Europe. Although the radically diminished population and ensuing reduction of agricultural output in the mid-fourteenth century happened close to the onset of economic stagnation, a careful observation of per capita productivity and gross agricultural output reveals that both were declining already before the Black Death. The cause of this must be sought elsewhere. For chronological reasons the variable ‘access to the dominant type of energy’ must be given a negative value. Climatic Influence In regards to climate, or more precisely the impact of climate on agricultural productivity, one occurrence of undeniable importance must be recorded. In the final decades of the 1200s, the so-called ‘Medieval Climatic Optimum’, a combination of climatic conditions that were conducive to high agricultural yields that had characterized the period of sustained growth from 800 onward came to an end.110 Malanima estimates that the ensuing ‘Little Ice Age’ reduced the cultivable surface of Italy by ca. 6% and caused a food shortage for 1-2 million people.111 In an economy where agriculture constituted 45-60% of the GDP, such a blow to the foundation of the economy could only have been devastating.112 The pressure on natural resources caused by the reduction of the surface of cultivable land that stemmed from a cooling of the climate was exacerbated as Italy’s population embarked on a long phase of growth from the mid-seventeenth until present. If in 1300, 2.9 hectares arable land were available per worker, and in the period after the Black Death this temporarily rose to 4.5 hectares due to the decreased population, by 1700 available land per worker had shrunk to 2.6 hectares and by 1870 had dwindled to a mere 1.2 hectares.113 The timing of the end of the ‘Medieval Climatic Optimum’ and the onset of the ‘Little Ice Age’ best explain the decline in per Capasso, “Economy and Population”, 24-25. Ibid. 112 Federico, Malanima, “Progress, decline and growth”, 437. 113 Capasso, “Economy and Population”, 19. 110 111 36 capita productivity and gross agricultural output that can already be observed by the beginning of the fourteenth century. Compared to Italy, the more diversified economies of northwestern Europe fared better. In what was to become the Dutch Republic the end of the Medieval Climate Optimum led to an increase in flooding in the beginning of the fourteenth century and prompted the famine of 1314-1317 that killed 5-10% of the population.114 Although hugely destructive and tragic, the catastrophes also prompted a series of preventive measures. Tol argues that the recurring floods and famines of the fourteenth century acted as a catalyst for formalized water control, and that “by 1350 the Dutch river delta had closed dike systems along all major rivers.”115 In a similar vein Van Zanden argues that the ecological degradation and ongoing agricultural crisis of the late Middle Ages was met with concerted communal efforts to stem ecological decline and also closed off the prospects of subsistence farming that with the demographic and agricultural crisis of the fourteenth century was spreading across much of the rest of Europe.116 With the introduction of cattle farming on land no longer suitable for agriculture, a rural population looking elsewhere for work as day laborers, and the prosperous cities of the Southern Provinces looking for luxury livestock products, the economy of what would become the Dutch Republic experienced a jumpstart towards commercialization and by 1500 was already characterized by “proto-capitalistic” economic structure.117 England was not exempt from the climatic downturn. With a growing season shortened by 1-2 months, recurring sheep and cattle epidemics, the spread of malaria, and the general decline in health of the population due to malnutrition that quickly led to flu, the times when English farmers had considered growing vines were definitely over.118 Snook argues that British farmers pursued a number of strategies that allowed them to temper to effects of the climatic downturn. These were crop variation and increased land settlements to extend the arable surface in the fifteenth and sixteenth century, and colonization, trade, industrialization and emigration in the seventeenth Tol, “Concise History”, 360-361. Ibid., 361. 116 Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s economy, 30-31. 117 Ibid., 20, 31. 118 Snook, Ice Age Extinction, 120-122. 114 115 37 and eighteenth centuries.119 By the time the Little Ice Age was over in 1850, England was at the height of its economic and political power. The effects of the end of the ‘Medieval Climate Optimum’ on agricultural output in Italy at the end of the thirteenth century coincides perfectly with the onset of Italian economic stagnation. Due to the importance of agriculture to Italy’s preindustrial economy and the timing of this climatic downturn, this variable will be assigned a positive value.120 Rise of a Foreign Nation Italy had lost its economic leadership in the Mediterranean by 1600, when the spice trade was lost for good to the English and Dutch who had penetrated the Indian Ocean and the carrying trade between the Mediterranean and northern Europe was being lost to English, French and Flemish shippers.121 Cipolla argues that other nations began developing new industrial, banking and maritime methods on a “large scale” between 1550 and 1600.122 This helps explain the appearance of cheaper and more sought after English, French and Dutch products that displaced Italian manufactures from both domestic and foreign markets. As a result of foreign competition the Italian textile industry had withered away by 1650.123 For the economy in general the turning point came quickly. Already by the early-seventeenth century Italy was a net importer of foreign manufactures and an exporter of primary products or partially worked goods. The seventeenth century would see Italy reduced to a passive role in Maritime affairs and its economy left with nothing but the function of regional distribution.124 In regards to the rise of the Ottoman Empire in the eastern Mediterranean from the mid-fifteenth century onwards that impinged on Italy’s Mediterranean shipping, commerce, spice trade, and seaborne supremacy, it has been established that the earliest manifestations of this development occurred at least a century after the onset of economic stagnation and can therefore be discounted as its cause. 119 Ibid. For the ‘importance of agriculture to pre-industrial societies’ see Wrigley, Continuity, Chance and Change, 7 121 For ‘economic leadership’ see DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of crisis, 26, for ‘carrying trade’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 53. 122 Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 202. 123 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of crisis, 26 124 For ‘passive role’ see Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 212, for ‘regional distribution function’ see DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of crisis, 26 120 38 By the seventeenth century Italy had been outpaced by England, France, and the Dutch Republic. In the context of rising foreign nations, or perhaps more fittingly in the case of Italy in the context of a general shift in patterns of trade, the discovery of the Americas played a crucial role in cementing Italy’s decline and buttressing the rise of the Atlantic economies. Columbus’ accidental discovery of the Americas, the first circumnavigation of the globe and the continued lure of oriental riches guaranteed that trade would both become more global and irretrievably move away from the Mediterranean.125 Although it can be argued that Spain’s colonies were as much a curse as a blessing, that France and the Dutch Republic had only limited overseas territories and that England would only really begin to reap the benefits of its colonial ghost acreage in the eighteenth century, Pomeranz argues convincingly that Europe’s new world colonies “primed the pump” of its most advanced economies.126 The growing demand for the ‘luxury’ consumer goods that paved the way for DeVries’ “Industrious Revolution”, the slow amassment of commercial capital, and Europe’s slow acquaintance with the practice of militaristic capitalism are unimaginable without Columbus’ fortuitous discovery.127 And whereas Italy saw its hectare to worker ratio diminish continually from the seventeenth to the nineteenth century, the landintensive imports from the New World in the form of fuel, fiber and food allowed first England and then the rest of Europe to hold open the “ecological window” and experience first sustained proto-industrial growth and later industrialization.128 By the time these New World benefits were revolutionizing northwestern Europe in the late-seventeenth and eighteenth century, Italy had for all intents and purposes disappeared from the radar. Nevertheless, and for the by now well-known reasons of chronological late coming, the variable of the rise of a foreign nation must be assigned a negative value. When Columbus first sighted what he believed was India, Italy had been stagnating for almost 200 years. Maddison, The World Economy, 44, Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 210. Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 192. 127 For ‘militaristic capitalism’ see ibid., 207, for ‘growing European consumer demand’ see ibid., 153, for ‘European overseas coercion’ see ibid., 188, for ‘industrious revolution’ see ibid., 218. 128 Ibid., 241, 264. 125 126 39 The variables that have been discussed in detail above are summarized in the table below. Italy War Interfering Measures Outdated Technology Poor Organization Access to Dominant Energy Climate Rising Foreign Nation 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 40 Chapter 3: The Dutch Republic Economic Chronology The following economic phases will be used as chronological benchmarks in the case of the Dutch Republic. The period from 1300 to 1650 will be considered one of growth, the fifty years between 1650 and 1700 one of relative stagnation, and the century between 1700 and 1800 one of absolute decline. Of particular interest are variables that appear before 1650. The Rise of the Dutch Republic Competing theories explaining the rise of the Dutch economy point to either the rare absence of medieval feudalist structures that did not interfere with the development of a free market economy, or a combination of favorable exogenous factors in the Early Modern Period. These include religious wars in surrounding countries, the resulting influx of highly-skilled human capital from the southern provinces, and the spectacular rise of the Baltic grain trade after 1570.129 As a result of the absent feudal system, the substantial expansion of commerce and industry, and the massive demographic growth of the late Middle Ages, the area that was to become the Dutch Republic was already by 1500 highly urbanized and characterized by a ‘protocapitalistic’ socio-economic structure.130 With this is meant the coexistence of smallscale agriculture and non agricultural wage labor-based employment.131 In regards to its economic structure, the Dutch Republic was 200 years ahead of its economic successor the United Kingdom, and represented an anomaly within the economic realities of early modern Europe.132 The possibility of supplementing agricultural incomes with wage labor freed the Dutch countryside from Malthus’ preventive check of conscious fertility and resulted in an extraordinarily fecund pattern of reproduction. Until the midseventeenth century, and largely exempt from the plague epidemics of the 1620s and Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s Economy, 19, Van Bavel, Van Zanden, “The jump-start of the Holland economy”, 503. 130 Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s Economy, 29-30, Van Bavel, Van Zanden, “The jump-start of the Holland economy”, 504,509. 131 Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s Economy, 20, 29-30, 32. 132 Ibid., 40. 129 41 30s that reduced the populations of Central Europe by 25%, the Dutch countryside was capable of supplying its growing urban centers and their industries with an almost unlimited supply of cheap labor.133 Dutch population growth until the midseventeenth century can be considered the antithesis of the Italian experience where a severe population loss after the plagues of 1348 and 1349 led to a general labor shortage, high wages and a reduction of gross agricultural output. The European economy that emerged in the fifteenth century was very different from the fragmented localized economy of the medieval world and fundamental shifts in economic structures and modes of organization were required to adapt to the new economic parameters.134 The city states of Northern and Central Italy, as was outlined in the previous chapter, had reached their economic maturity by the fourteenth century and were displaying the “internal rigidities of a mature industrial economy” had proven incapable of reinventing themselves.135 Jan DeVries provides a checklist of what was required for economies to succeed in the early modern period. Declining industries and markets had to be abandoned for ones in expansion, livestock was preferable to arable farming, new and lighter draperies and cotton held more promise than linen and heavy cloth, fledgling key industries had to be protected with subsidies and most importantly costs had to be reduced through organizational innovation.136 This meant manufacturing based on putting-out systems, entrepôt commerce and an agriculture of convertible husbandry.137 The Dutch Republic excelled in all of the above. The Dutch Republic’s dominance of international trade was sealed with the sack of Antwerp in 1576 by Spanish troops which marked the decline of the cities of Flanders. The cities and merchants of what was to become the Dutch Republic did not hesitate to fill the resulting void. Van Zanden describes a “natural transition” to the carrying trade (freightage) from the humble beginnings of inland waterway fishing, via North Sea herring fishing to sea-going trade.138 With its own merchant fleet that could buy commodities at the source and cut out intermediaries, the growth of the Ibid, 20, Van Bavel, Van Zanden, “The jump-start of the Holland economy”, 506. For ‘plague epidemics’ see DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 4. 134 Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 405. 135 Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 21, DeVries, Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 250, previous chapter, 33. 136 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 248-249. 137 Ibid. 138 Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s economy, 33. 133 42 Baltic grain trade in the sixteenth century and the escalation of the rich trades in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, the Dutch Republic was to become the center of world commerce and Amsterdam its central warehouse.139 Dutch hegemony in global commerce would last for two centuries, when finally they were forcefully swept from the seas by England at the end of the eighteenth century.140 By 1570 the carrying capacity of the Dutch Merchant fleet was at par with the combined carrying capacity of Germany, England and France, and in 1670 it was still more than twice the size of that of England, its closest rival.141 The Dutch State had few qualms about using naval might when a competitive edge couldn’t be attained by organizational innovation. Blockading the Scheldt estuary after 1585 which sealed the irremediable decline of Antwerp, repeatedly forcing Denmark to keep the Sound open and passage tolls low, and the support of armed commercial operations in Asia, Africa and more sporadically the Caribbean and Brazil are only some examples of the Estates General advancing commerce by all means.142 For the first half of the seventeenth century, its Golden Age, the Dutch Republic enjoyed unprecedented control of international trade, political clout far surpassing that corresponding to its size and population, and Amsterdam an unchallenged position in banking, trade and finance. Only a hundred years later, however, Dutch economic decline was rampant and visible to all. Between 1750-1800 the cost of living rose to dizzying heights, the once-egalitarian society was characterized by a growing rift between rich and poor and contemporary observers told of ravaged and desolate inland towns that had in recent memory still been thriving centers of manufacturing.143 What had happened? The Effects of War The Dutch Republic gained diplomatic recognition in 1609, as part of the 12-year cease fire that marked the halfway point of the Eighty Years’ War. The war that would end with the Peace of Westphalia in 1648, and permanently divide the former Habsburg Netherlands into the seven rebel provinces that became the Dutch Republic 139 Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 405-407. O’Brien, “Mercantilism and Imperialism”, 477, Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 411. 141 Maddison, The World Economy, 77. 142 Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 411. 143 Boxer, “Dutch Economic Decline”, 262. 140 43 and the Spanish-ruled southern provinces of Brabant and Flanders, initially benefited the Dutch Republic. The northern provinces experienced a large-scale migration of capital and skilled workers from the Spanish-ruled provinces to the south and were able to expand their international networks of trade and shipping to the detriment of Portugal and Spain.144 The once-thriving cities of the southern provinces that were already suffering from the disruptions of war and draconian Spanish rule were dealt a final blow when the Dutch blockaded the Scheldt estuary in 1585, sealing the decline of Antwerp and the rise of Amsterdam.145 The cost of maintaining Dutch Independence, however, was high. A chain of fortresses was constructed in the east to defend the heartland of the Province of Holland in response to the pending threat of a French invasion. Rising army and naval expenditures, and a series of wars against England and France in the seventeenth century burdened the Dutch Republic with a growing debt.146 The reputation of the Dutch Government for quickly and regularly repaying loans allowed it to easily borrow money with which to fund military measures, but also saddled it with an enormous debt.147 The debt rose from 960 000 guilders in 1579, to 5.5 million guilders in 1599 and to 10 million guilders in the first decades of the seventeenth century.148 The upward spiral of debt and interest repayment led to an increase in the excise duty, which in turn raised the price levels for daily goods as well as wages to levels that soon became uncompetitive in an international comparison.149 In the laterseventeenth century the repeated land invasions by the French under Louis XIV forced the Dutch Republic to expand its troops to a staggering 93 000 men by 1693.150 Spain by comparison had 70 000 men under arms, down from a maximum of 300 000 in the 1630s, and France 120 000.151 In the eighteenth century, France would have 400 000 men under arms!152 In the Spanish War of Succession (1701-1714) the Dutch Republic experienced heavy losses of human lives for a wartime population of only two 144 Maddison, The World Economy, 79. Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 405, 411. 146 Maddison, The World Economy, 80. 147 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 101. 148 Ibid., 87. 149 DeVries, Economy of Europe in an Age of crisis, 112. 150 Ibid. 151 Maddison, The World Economy, 81. 152 Ibid. 145 44 million.153 In comparison France in the eighteenth century had one fifth of Europe’s total population. During the eighteenth century the steady drain of manpower became apparent. The difference of Dutch military strength between the Nine Year’s War that began in 1689 and the Fourth Anglo-Dutch War in 1780 is telling. Between 1689 and 1697, the Dutch Republic sent out 24 000 men every year on 100 ships. One hundred years later it struggled to staff 17 ships with a total of 3000 men.154 The shortage of manpower was also apparent in the fisheries that in the eighteenth century had increasing difficulties to man deep-sea fishing voyages.155 Between 1688 and 1748 the Dutch Republic was spending three quarters of its defense budget on its land forces.156 This meant that its merchant fleet and navy were underfunded. Whereever they could, the British stepped in to pick up the slack. The massive diversion of money into military expenditure represented an ongoing drain on possibly productive resources.157 Although this was true for all European countries – Kennedy likens Spain and France at the Peace of Westphalia to two “punch drunk boxers” reeling from the efforts of ongoing warfare – the odds were increasingly stacked against the tiny Dutch Republic in the run of the seventeenth century.158 Although only the second half of the seventeenth century would become synonymous with ongoing warfare for the Dutch Republic against both England and France, the precipitous increase of expenses linked to war already in the closing decades of the sixteenth century is an early indicator of the trend. The long-term and devastating effects of war on the Dutch Republic would increase in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries until it had effectively been ground to a pulp between the rising powers of England and France.159 As Maddison is eager to stress, when at war with either Britain or France in the seventeenth and eighteenth century, the Dutch Republic felt “the concentrated energy of the modern nation state” that was very different from the way that Spain had dissipated its energy during the Eighty Years’ 153 Although the great majority of the dead were foreign mercenaries, the financial burden of paying the mercenary’s wages underlines the challenges that the population-poor Dutch Republic faced when at war with vastly more populous neighbors. Not to be forgotten in the context of a population drain are the voyages of the V.O.C from which two-thirds of the crew did not return. 154 Boxer, “Dutch Economic Decline”, 243. 155 Ibid., 242. 156 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 113. 157 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of crisis, 112. 158 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 75. 159 Ibid., xviii. 45 War.160 Compared to its two behemoth neighbors of France and England, the Dutch Republic already midway through its Golden Century was simply too small. Due to the astronomical increase in military expenditure already at the end of the sixteenth century and the coinciding of the onset of Dutch economic stagnation with the long series of wars against England and France (the first Anglo-Dutch War began in 1652), this variable will be assigned a positive value. Interfering Measures taken by a Foreign Nation After reading the above section on the effects of war it would seem only logical that the Dutch Republic would not pass through the mercantilist era unscathed. Indeed this is not only the case but without much doubt the principal explanation of Dutch economic decline in the pertinent literature.161 The first deeds of foreign economic intervention in the case of the Dutch Republic are the English Navigation Acts of 1651. Designed to undermine Dutch shipping by restricting the access of Dutch ships to British ports and barring the Dutch from trading with English colonies, the Navigation Acts should be understood as part of the larger effort of England under Cromwell to curb Dutch economic activity.162 This in turn must be seen in the wider context of England’s growing economic and political aspirations. From 1550 to 1700 England actively sought to grab ever bigger shares of overseas opportunities through diplomacy or, and more frequently, war.163 The three Anglo-Dutch Wars in the quarter century after 1652 can be considered the military equivalent of the Navigation Acts. Together English economic sanctions and war resulted in the Dutch Republic losing its monopolistic trading privileges with Britain and France, the “significant contraction of Dutch trading opportunities in America and Africa”, and a gradual reorientation of its economy from manufacturing to agriculture.164 French economic provisions designed to aid French industry and agriculture began around 1600 under Henry IV, were first overseen by his Huguenot minister the Duke of Sully, and later given new impetus by Colbert under Louis XIV. These 160 Maddison, The World Economy, 80. DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 252. 162 Maddison, The World Economy, 80. 163 Ibid., 94. 164 Ibid., 82. 161 46 measures reduced the taille, increased spending on infrastructure, and encouraged cloth production through sheltering tariffs and the establishment of royal factories.165 In the 1640s fully one third of Dutch textiles were exported to France.166 By the earlyeighteenth century this amount had shrunk to less than 10 percent.167 Furthermore, French ministers succeeded in fostering fledgling French industries by luring skilled Dutch workers to France.168 Of all Dutch finishing industries the most important was by far the textile industry. Between 1650 and 1700 England and France increased the import duties on Dutch textiles until these had reached prohibitive levels.169 In the first decades of the eighteenth century, similar mercantilist policies were introduced by Russia, Prussia, Denmark, Norway and Spain.170 In the 1720s and 1730s the Dutch textile industry declined accordingly.171 The Great Northern War (1700-1721) led to a heightened sense of competition among northern powers and by the 1740s most northern European countries had put a “systematic industrial mercantilist policy” into place.172 All countries made vigorous attempts to stimulate domestic cloth and silk production, as well as sugar refining, tobacco processing and sail cloth weaving.173 The spread of such a pan-European form of organized interventionism coincided with the decisive decline of the Dutch world-trade system and had disastrous consequences for Dutch manufacturing.174 By the 1740s Dutch manufacturing had declined irreversibly.175 The pan-European mercantilist policies also changed the nature of trade. Almost overnight the nature of Dutch exports shifted from the export of manufactures to the export of raw materials and spices.176 Although still a major player in the carrying trade as late as the beginning of the nineteenth century, the mere volume of unfinished goods that were still being shipped could not compensate for the loss of former markets for Dutch processed goods. Shipbuilding, the paper industry, tobacco processing, sail canvas weaving, salt-refining and the Delftware industries all 165 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 73. Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 384. 167 Ibid. 168 Ibid. 169 Boxer, “Dutch economic decline”, 256. 170 Ibid. 171 Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 386. 172 Ibid., 384. 173 Ibid. 174 For ‘pan-European interventionism’ see ibid., 386, for ‘consequences for Dutch manufacturing’ see ibid., 384-389. 175 Ibid., 399. 176 Ibid., 386. 166 47 experienced severe decline or collapse in the decisive years between 1713 and 1750.177 By 1750 a new era dawned in which the British, French, Danes, Swedes and northern Germans also shipped and stored goods that fifty years earlier would had been reserved for the warehouses of Amsterdam.178 The Dutch had lost their grip over the essential mechanism of international trade of controlling supply and creating demand.179 The most glaring example of this loss of control is Britain’s early dominance of the Triangular Trade of the Atlantic already by the 1720s from which the Dutch were almost wholly excluded.180 By 1740 the Dutch Republic was a mere transit point for unprocessed tobacco and raw sugar.181 Although outside of Europe the Dutch fared better and could still rely on a network of forts, colonies, and political backing, here too there was a marked deterioration in Dutch competitiveness in face of growing competition from the British, French, Danes and others.182 The English Navigation Acts, the first and most serious act of foreign intervention, were enacted simultaneously with the onset of Dutch economic stagnation in the middle of the seventeenth century. A small parenthesis must be made here to prove that we are not deviating from our methodology that demands that possible causes of stagnation predate the onset of stagnation to be considered a true cause of stagnation. As is made apparent by the urbanization data, the transition from growth to stagnation in the Dutch Republic was very abrupt. From a 7.4% increase in urbanization between 1600 and 1650, to a 1.9% increase between 1650 and 1700. It is very plausible that the tenacity of the British resolve to undermine Dutch commercial supremacy that is reflected in the Anglo-Dutch Wars, and the less vehement but nonetheless persevering French actions to bolster national production at the expense of the Dutch manufacturing and exports, were causes of this abrupt transition to economic stagnation. Due to this, this variable will be assigned a positive value. Outdated Technology To begin with, it is worth stating that outdated technology is not frequently mentioned in the discussion surrounding Dutch economic decline. On the contrary there is 177 Ibid., 388, 391. Ibid., 401. 179 Ibid., 401. 180 Ibid., 393. 181 Ibid., 397. 182 Ibid., 391. 178 48 considerable unanimity among historians that the Dutch were particularly technologically innovative.183 Here a few examples of Dutch inventions and innovations must suffice. What is now known as ‘new husbandry’, a “set of modifications in agricultural practice” at the close of the Middle Ages first appeared in the Low Countries from where they radiated outwards, first to England, and eventually across the rest of Europe.184 Allen and DeVries both attribute overwhelming importance to the role that the ‘agricultural revolution’ played in allowing certain countries to experience fundamental shifts of their economic structure.185 Only greatly increased agricultural productivity could support a secondary sector, free rural labor for industry and allow some countries to break away from the inherent growth constraints of agricultural economies. Italy and southern Europe largely missed out on the ‘agricultural revolution’, thereby conserving both their economic structures of traditional agrarian societies, and the minimal economic growth inherent to an agrarian economy until the end of the nineteenth century.186 At sea the Dutch displayed a similar tendency to innovate. In the latefourteenth century the technique of salting fresh herring was introduced by Dutch fishermen. This allowed Dutch ships to spend more time at sea than their competitors as well as conserve their catch for distant markets. Drift nets that greatly increased the catch were subsequently introduced in 1415.187 The dominance of Dutch busses in North Sea fishing that processed their catch on board, also dates from the earlyfifteenth century and was to last for several centuries.188 The Fluytschip, “the crowning achievement of a century of continuous rationalization and improvement”, first built in 1595, was cheap to build, required only a skeleton crew, could carry large cargoes, and until French and English imitations eventually mimicked them, were capable of undercutting foreign carrying trade by 30-50%.189 183 Maddison, The World Economy, 75, DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 20, Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s Economy, 20, 29, Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 4, 12, Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 407-409, Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 85, 87, Davids, “Shifts of technological leadership”, 340. 184 Mokyr, The Lever of Riches, 58. 185 Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 22, DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 7. 186 Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 21. For a discussion of the decreasing returns inherent to predominantly agricultural economies see Malanima, “Measuring the Italian Economy”, 272. 187 Mokyr, The Lever of Riches, 70. 188 Ibid. 189 For ‘crowning achievement’ see ibid., 69, for ‘undercutting of carrying trade’ see Derry, A Short History of technology, 209-210. 49 After the floods of 1421, Dutch hydraulic engineers, the “leading practical hydraulic engineers of the time”, incrementally reclaimed land by using power-driven scoop wheels and screw pumps.190 Maddison argues that Dutch hydraulic engineering was indispensable for the early success of Dutch agriculture when land reclamation relied on wind power.191 By the seventeenth century Dutch windmills were a source of cheap, clean and inexhaustible energy.192 Until the invention of the steam engine windmills also remained the most powerful pre-industrial prime mover.193 Although at the forefront of groundbreaking technologies during the late medieval period, in the late-seventeenth and eighteenth century the Dutch began to fall behind the technological frontier.194While the Dutch herring industry remained advanced, by 1750 the whaling industry had fallen behind that of the British who had heavier boats and mechanical harpoons.195 These innovations allowed British ships to hunt whales in ice flows that remained inaccessible to the lighter Dutch ships. Similarly in maritime cartography, navigational techniques and in new methods of ship building the Dutch began to fall behind their English and French rivals.196 Until the 1670s haughty reports of the directors and servants of the VOC (The Dutch East India Company) reflected a deep-seated belief in Dutch superiority in “energy and ability, as well as capital and in material resources.”197 Eighty years later such airs of arrogance had been replaced by complaints of English superiority. Boxer argues that technological improvements in eighteenth century agriculture were introduced both “tardily and incompletely as compared with contemporary France and England.”198 Despite lagging behind in the newest agricultural technologies Dutch agriculture fared much better in the eighteenth century than either manufacturing or shipping.199 In terms of manufacturing, Israel states that by the 1720s French fine cloth was available in more sought-after colors than that of Dutch production, a fashion faux-pas that is perhaps more indicative of the gradual disappearance of Dutch merchant colonies in important trading hubs 190 Mokyr, The Lever of Riches, 66. Maddison, The World Economy,75. 192 Mokyr, The Lever of Riches, 60. 193 Smil, Energy in World History, 226. 194 Davids, “Shifts of technological leadership”, 354, 361. 195 Boxer, “Dutch Economic Decline”, 244-245. 196 Ibid. 197 Ibid. 198 Ibid., 254. 199 Ibid., 252, 254. 191 50 abroad than of a true technological or aesthetic falling behind.200 After all, in the general process of economic renewal that took place after the Great Northern War (1700-1721), the Dutch played a key role in the diffusion of technologies and skills that in many parts of northern Europe were still considered groundbreaking.201 In regards to the Dutch falling technologically behind in the late-seventeenth and eighteenth century, it seems plausible this process was a consequence of the general political and economic challenges that the Republic faced from the midseventeenth century onwards. Foreign mercantilist policies shutting Dutch manufactures out of foreign markets, increasing competition at sea in both the fishing and freightage industries, rising wages due to a growing labor shortage, and an absence of coal are only four factors that might have deterred Dutch entrepreneurs from investing in new technologies.202 Mokyr underlines the close link between the rise of the nation state and the increasingly systematic approach to the development and fostering of technology.203 He also argues that 1750 might be considered a watershed in terms of the pace of technological change.204 Although already in the 200 years prior to 1750 technology more than anything else in the preceding seven millennia had radically reshaped the way humans lived, technological advance during the Industrial Revolution would accelerate again until reaching an unprecedented pace.205 It is only after 1750 that the Dutch Republic began to seriously lag behind the UK in terms of technology. Mokyr argues that this was nothing to be ashamed of. For roughly a century after 1760, the UK was able “to generate and diffuse superior production techniques at a faster rate than the Continent, and serve as a model that all European nations wished to emulate.”206 Despite the Dutch Republic clearly losing its technological lead in sectors important to its economy, the variable of outdated technology will be assigned a negative value. By the time the Dutch Republic began to fall behind technologically in the mid-eighteenth century, its economy had been stagnating for a full century. 200 Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 383. Ibid., 384. 202 For ‘factors related to the decline of Dutch technological leadership’ see Davids, “Shifts of technological leadership”, 354-361. 203 Mokyr, The Lever of Riches, 78. 204 Ibid., 81. 205 Ibid. 206 Ibid., 239. 201 51 Poor Organization in Sectors Important to the Economy For the purpose of this thesis the work of Jan Luiten van Zanden on the social and economic structure of the Dutch Republic between the late Middle Ages and the end of the sixteenth century is of great interest.207 Van Zanden explains the rise of the Dutch economy between 1350 and 1600 with the proto-capitalistic structure of the countryside.208 Rural inhabitants combined agricultural activities with wage labor and due to an extraordinarily fecund pattern of reproduction represented an “almost inexhaustible reservoir of cheap labor” for urban industries.209 Particularly after 1350 this, along with the proximity of the rich markets of Flanders and Brabant, contributed to the rise of export industries such as textiles and beer.210 This cheap labor fueled late-medieval economic expansion is clearly reflected in the urbanization data that confirms a doubling of urbanization rates between 1400 and 1650.211 If readily available and cheap labor was a key ingredient of early Dutch economic growth, lasting economic growth also hinged on labor’s ability to sufficiently reproduce itself. It is precisely in this point that Van Zanden argues that an organizational shortcoming, one that put an end to the supply of cheap labor to urban industries, undermined the possibility of sustained economic growth. Although economic development accelerated in the period after 1580, to such an extent that it has been labeled as an economic ‘take-off’ phase, the socio-economic structure underpinning the sustainability of cheap labor was simultaneously and irrevocably being undermined.212 Van Zanden describes this erosion as an interrelated process of increases of scale and concentration of capital on the one hand and increasing proletarianization on the other.213 With the “remarkable tendencies towards concentration” in the most important economic sectors (export industries, agriculture, trade, and shipping), the rural existence of small-scale craftsmen, putter-outers and unspecialized small landholders began to lose its economic viability.214 207 For a concise overview of earlier work on Holland’s socio-economic development see Van Bavel, Van Zanden, “The jump-start of the Holland economy”, 507 – 509. 208 Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s economy, 19, 34. 209 Ibid., 34. 210 Ibid. 211 From 15% in 1400, to 31% in 1650. Maddison, World Economy, 248, Malanima, unpublished manuscript, DeVries, European Urbanization, 39. 212 Ibid., 35. 213 Ibid., 36. 214 Ibid. 52 The concentration of wealth in the hands of urban merchants and the growth of urban manufacturing drew workers from the countryside to the cities. In the cities the working population’s living standards decreased until they represented a forerunner of the miserable living conditions of England’s eighteenth century industrial proletariat. In the sixteenth century small farmers began to disappear from the countryside as did semi-proletarian craftsmen from important export industries. By ca. 1580 mortality rates in cities – that were not fortuitously called ‘death traps’ – and the urban proletariat’s deteriorated standard of living had begun to undermine labor’s hereto prodigious reproduction pattern, curtailing the elastic supply of labor that was required by the growing Dutch economy.215 One example for such a shortage of manpower can be seen in the VOC having to recruit “louts from the heart of Germany” for their voyages to Asia.216 Despite these foreign recruits the VOC’s voyages to the East Indies, during which two thirds of the sailors died, represented an ongoing “demographic leak”.217 The problems caused by seventeenth century demographic stagnation were compounded by changes in the redistribution of profits that increasingly favored the relatively inefficient but highly-paid sector of non-tradables that benefited from a favorable tax structure as well as from other social and political measures arising from the entwinement of the regent oligarchy and craft industry.218 Swart argues that the overwhelming influence of Amsterdam merchants on national policies was based on the fact that they paid half of the provincial and one quarter of the federal taxes.219 Such fiscal responsibilities went hand in hand with considerable political influence. Where commercial and industrial interests conflicted, mercantile interests were favored. Protective legislation for industry was “rare and unenforced”, and fiscal policies that ultimately increased industrial production costs were a common occurrence.220 The political influence of the merchant class ensured that industryadverse policies were pursued far into the eighteenth century when it was long clear that Dutch commercial preeminence belonged irrevocably to the past.221 215 Ibid., 20. Boxer, “Dutch economic decline”, 245. 217 Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s economy, 37-38. 218 Ibid., 139. 219 Swart, “Holland’s Bourgeoisie”, 45. 220 Ibid. 221 Ibid. 216 53 This group of rentiers who profited from holding the state’s debt that was paid for by the excise tax and did not offset their parasitic presence with any productive activities, grew much larger in the eighteenth century as other sources of income from manufacturing and trade dwindled. The resulting upward pressure on the cost of living and wages through the increased tax burden was carried primarily by entrepreneurs of labor intensive export industries, and led either to their relocation or disappearance. And so as the sixteenth century drew to a close, processes of capital concentration and skewed profit redistribution were beginning to undermine the very proto-capitalistic socio-economic structure that had fueled the growth of the Dutch Republic’s domestic industries. By the middle of the seventeenth century the Dutch Republic was suffering from labor shortage and was forced to obtain workers from increasingly far away.222 The variable ‘poor organization in sectors important to the economy’ can be seen as an endogenous cause of economic stagnation and will be assigned a positive value. Access to the Dominant Form of Energy In this context there is one easily identifiable and significant difference between the Dutch republic and the UK; coal. Put simply the UK had it and the Dutch Republic didn’t. In the period leading up to its Golden Age, the Dutch had used their abundant peat supply as a source of heat required by numerous industries. Among others these included brick making, madder production, kiln firing, salt refining, baking, bleaching, and tile making.223 Coal, however, produces twice the amount of heat that is won from burning the equivalent quantity of peat.224 Wrigley argues that it was primarily the substitution of coal for traditional organic fuels (primarily wood, but also peat) that allowed England’s advanced organic economy to break its energy constraints and become the first fossil fuel based economy of Europe.225 In a similar vein Malanima argues that the rising use of fossil fuels was the main innovation of the new energy system that evolved in early modern Europe and replaced that of the late Middle Ages. Despite the late medieval innovations - the large scale introduction of draught animals and the increased use of Van Zanden, The rise and decline of Holland’s economy, 171. Mokyr, The Lever of Riches, 62. 224 Wrigley, Continuity, Chance and Change, 59. 225 Ibid., 70-71. 222 223 54 wind and water power - already by the early-thirteenth century the energetic limit of the medieval energetic system had been reached.226 The increased use of coal in England beginning in the early-sixteenth century symbolized the second and crucial step - the exploitation of peat was the first step - towards the fossil-fuel based economies of the nineteenth and twentieth century. Although abundant fossil fuel did not in itself guarantee that pre-industrial, organic fuel-based economies would industrialize, the key role of massively increased energy consumption in sustaining the extensive growth of per capita production in Britain’s budding secondary sector is undeniable.227 In the UK a growing demand for energy and an increasing scarcity of fuel (primarily wood) led to dramatic increase in the mining of coal. It rose from 210,000 tons in 1551-60, to almost 3 million tons in 1681-90, to more than 10 million tons in 1781-90.228 In an era of a growing Europe-wide ‘ecological bottleneck’, the energy windfall that coal represented for the UK cannot be sufficiently stressed. In 1815 British coal was providing British industry with the energy equivalent of 15 million acres worth of forest.229 Comparing the energy output of prime movers illuminates the importance of coal in the age of industrialization. Around 1000 AD a waterwheel, by far the most powerful prime mover at the time, produced an equivalent of 5000 watt.230 In comparison a steam engine around 1800 produced 100 000 watt.231 Although peat had supplied the Dutch Republic with a cheap supply of energy from the sixteenth to eighteenth century, peat would prove “inadequate for truly sustained large-scale industrial growth.”232 By the end of the eighteenth century, the usefulness of Dutch peat was petering out and along with the rest of Europe deficient in its own coal reserves, the Dutch Republic became an importer of British coal.233 Clearly the increasingly important role of coal in the process of economic growth in the seventeenth century put the Dutch Republic at a marked disadvantage Malanima, “The energy basis for early modern growth, 1650-1820”, 57. For a discussion of the energy system of the Late Middle Ages see ibid., 58. 227 Ibid. 228 Van Zanden, “A survey of the European Economy”, 83-84, for alternative figures on coal mining see Smil, Energy in World History, 159. 229 Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 276. 230 Smil, Energy in World History, 228. 231 Ibid. 232 Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 221. 233 For ‘waning use of peat’ see Wrigley, Continuity, Chance and Change, 104, 115, for ‘import of coal’ see Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 222. 226 55 compared to England where the spin-off industries that developed around coal and the positive feedback of a fossil fuel-based economy positively affected large sectors of the economy.234 As coal was employed in an ever-growing variety of uses – primarily as a source of mechanical energy but also as a source of heat that lessened the burden on English agriculture to produce both food and fuel – eighteenth century England was able to hold open the ‘ecological window’ and gradually but successfully transition to an industrialized fossil fuel-based economy.235 Although the significance and precise definition of the Industrial Revolution remains controversial, increased energy consumption played an undeniable and characterizing role.236 The increased availability and use of energy led to a surge of technological inventions and improvements in the UK in the period after 1750. In the words of Mokyr, “a clustering of macro inventions occurred, leading to intensified work in improvement and adjustment, and thus creating a complementary flow of micro inventions.”237 The Dutch experience from the mid-eighteenth century onwards couldn’t have been more different from that of the UK. Although Pomeranz argues that it was the demand side that hampered Dutch economic growth and not a lack of cheap energy – in the nineteenth century there were still peat fields left unexploited and coal could be imported from England at competitive prices - both Boxer and DeVries argue that Holland was at a marked disadvantage compared to the UK due to a poor natural resource endowment and little access to land-intensive raw materials.238 By comparison, in 1830 Britain was importing 25 and 30 million acres worth of cotton, sugar and timber from its colonial ghost acreage.239 That represents a surface close to twice the arable surface of land in England! Had the Dutch Republic developed industries similar to those of England in the eighteenth and nineteenth century it For ‘positive feedback’ see Wrigley, Continuity, Chance and Change, 30, for ‘spin-off industries’ see ibid., 70-71, 75; Wong, China Transformed, 56,57; Smil, Energy in World History, 160. 235 Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 207. 236 For a survey of competing definitions see Van Zanden, “Early Modern Growth”, 69-70, for ‘importance of mineral sources of energy for the industrialization process’ see Wrigley, Continuity, Chance and Change, 32, 75, Malanima, “The energy basis for early modern growth” 63,85, Wong, China Transformed, 50, Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 241. 237 Mokyr, The Lever of Riches, 82. 238 For ‘Dutch energy’ see Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 221, for ‘poor natural resource endowment’ see Boxer, “Dutch Economic Decline”, 245, for ‘Britain’s superior access to landintensive raw materials’ see DeVries, Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 253. 239 Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 276. 234 56 would have been at a great disadvantage for lack of coal, iron and timber.240 In this context Davids argues that it was precisely the Dutch Republic’s lack of coal that undermined the interest in the application of science to technology which was a key ingredient to the many innovations of Britain’s manufacturing sector.241 Although with the advent of the Industrial Revolution the Dutch Republic was at a marked disadvantage due to a lack of coal and otherwise poor access to the land intensive natural resources that billowed the sails of the British economy from mideighteenth century onwards, the importance of coal as a source of energy that would revolutionize western economies in the latter-eighteenth and nineteenth centuries appears too late in our established chronology to be considered a cause of Dutch economic stagnation. It is for this reason that it will be assigned a negative value. Climatic Influence In the context of our chronology it is the ‘Little Ice Age’ of the mid-sixteenth to nineteenth century that is of interest. In the Dutch Republic the ‘Little Ice Age’ expressed itself in “weather extremes” in the 1560s and 70s, frequent “severe winter weather” in the seventeenth century, and otherwise recurring episodes of “highly variable” climate.242 Although short-term crises based on harvest failures ensued, the highly diversified economy “open to international markets, farmers, merchants, and other affected parties” mitigated the effects of an unfavorable climate to the point that DeVries describes its economic consequences to have been “marginal.”243 The ‘Little Ice Age’ also coincided with the ‘regression phase’ of the sea level, and marked the end of the destructive inundations of the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries.244 The sixteenth century cooling of the North Sea drove the herring closer to England, making them more accessible to Dutch fishermen. Similarly, in the first half of the seventeenth century the migratory patterns of the Greenland whale adapting to colder polar summers, drove it into the arms of Dutch whalers.245 For different versions of the Dutch Republic’s disadvantages see: Wrigley, Continuity, Chance and Change, 25,104, Ormrod, “Dutch commercial and industrial decline”, 35, Boxer, “Dutch Economic Decline”, 256. 241 Davids, “Shifts in technological leadership”, 361. 242 DeVries, Van der Woude, The First Modern Economy, 21. 243 Ibid. 244 Ibid. 245 Ibid., 22. 240 57 On the topic of the ‘Little Ice Age’ DeVries and Van der Woude tentatively conclude that by the sixteenth and seventeenth century the Dutch Republic possessed the “technical powers and social organization that were sufficient to diffuse and dampen the adverse influence of climatological shocks.”246 Despite the apparently negligible impact on the Dutch economy the timing of the climatic changes related to the ‘Little Ice Age’ require that they be assigned a positive value. The contradiction of an unimportant variable being assigned a positive value due only to its chronological appearance points to the possible shortcomings of the methodology and will be addressed in the conclusion. Rise of a Foreign Nation DeVries attributes the Dutch Republic’s rise to economic leadership to its successful implementation of “cost-reducing measures” in agriculture, industry and commerce.247 Maddison stresses the advantages of the Dutch Republic’s fortuitous geographic position, and Van Bavel a set of endogenous factors that put the Dutch in an ideal position to exploit the new economic possibilities that emerged in Europe in the early modern period.248 Indeed, until it was confronted with competitors that could not be either outmuscled (the cities of Flanders), bullied into submission (Denmark) or underbid (France and England), the Dutch Republic enjoyed an economic heyday that lasted from the mid-fourteenth to the mid-seventeenth century.249 In regards to the rise of a foreign nation it is precisely the rise of England and France in the midseventeenth century, the consolidation of power of their centralized governments, and the latter’s growing political and commercial ambitions that would first undermine then put an end to unhampered Dutch economic growth. In the case of France the successful military action against Spain under Henry IV (1589-1610) already hinted at the latent wealth and power of this populous 246 Ibid. DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 251. Van Bavel makes a similar argument regarding the endogenous factors of Holland’s economy that allowed it to benefit from the increasing market integration of the early modern period. Van Bavel, Van Zanden, “The jump-start of the Holland economy”, 528. 248 For ‘geographic advantages’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 75-79, for ‘endogenous factors’ see Van Bavel, Van Zanden, “The jump-start of the Holland economy”, 526-528, for the ‘new economic framework emerging in Early Modern Europe’ see DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 6,27,245-249. 249 Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 411, 412. 247 58 country.250 The rise of France was postponed by the period following Henry IV’s assassination in 1610 that was characterized by the Thirty Years’ War, poor political leadership, aristocratic intrigue, peasant and worker uprising, recurring plague incidents and a general decline of the population.251 Despite this internal turmoil, France – with the help of England under Cromwell - succeeded in decisively defeating Spain at the Battle of Dunes in 1658. The Treaty of the Pyrenees, signed in 1659, reinforced the tenets of the Treaty of Westphalia (1648) and with the Spanish Habsburg bid for political hegemony in Europe defeated once and for all, confirmed the political plurality of Europe.252 Kennedy speaks of the “maturing of a genuinely multi-polar system of European politics” in which the balance of power was maintained by short-term and shifting alliances.253 England’s intervention in European affairs had been largely undermined by the ongoing conflict between crown and parliament between 1603 and 1643.254 When it finally reemerged in the 1650s under the tutelage of Cromwell, and emboldened by its New Model Army, it challenged Dutch trade hegemony in the First Anglo-Dutch War (1652-54). Although siding with France against Spain had caused the English to lose much of the profitable Spanish trade to the neutral Dutch as well as burden English tax payers with the huge costs of its rapidly expanding navy (it doubled between 1649 and 1651), the growth of inland and overseas commerce, the growing benefits from the colonies and the consolidation of a market economy set England on a solid economic footing.255 Kennedy argues that the period between 1660 and 1815 was characterized by the decline of certain states (the Ottoman Empire, Spain, the Dutch Republic, Sweden) and the rise of others, most notably the continental trilateral equilibrium of France, Prussia and the Austrian Habsburgs as well as the two peripheral powers of England and Russia.256 Viewed from this perspective the period of Dutch economic hegemony had coincided with a period in European history where shifts in the balance of power had become frequent compared to the period between 1500 and 1650 that had been characterized by the Spanish Habsburg’s stubborn bid for political power. 250 Maddison, The World Economy, 72-75. Ibid., 74. 252 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 39. 253 Ibid., 94. 254 Ibid., 79. 255 Ibid., 80, for ‘huge cost of standing armies’ see ibid., 109-110. 256 Ibid., 95. 251 59 The height (and abrupt end) of Dutch economic power coincided with a new era of fierce interstate competition. If the geographical location of the Dutch Republic had until the earlyseventeenth century provided the Republic with many ingredients for economic growth (a river network that acted as a barrier to Spanish forces, access to the North Sea’s rich herring fisheries) its location within Europe had become a liability by the mid-seventeenth century. Locked between England and France it suffered under the mercantilist policies of Cromwell and Colbert that aimed at undermining its commerce and shipping.257 At sea it was increasingly challenged by England in the Indies trade, North Sea fishing, and entrepôt commerce, and at land it was threatened by France from the 1660s onwards. As has been outlined in the section on mercantilist measures, the last decades of the seventeenth and the first half of the eighteenth century were calamitous for many sectors of the Dutch economy.258 Such comprehensive mercantilist measures are unthinkable in the absence of centralized governments, precisely those that arose first in France under Louis XIV and in England under Cromwell, and later spread across Europe, until by 1740 “most states of Northern, Central and Eastern Europe had adopted powerful mercantilist strategies shutting out most manufactures and Dutch processed goods.”259 Israel argues further that the treaties, alliances, blockades, restrictions, monopolistic devices and other trade engrossing factors that had underpinned Dutch supremacy, where irremediably lost after 1740.260 The contemporaneous rise of England and France and the decline of Spain after the signing of the Treaty of Westphalia has led O’Brien to date the beginning of Dutch economic decline to the year 1648.261 With Spain defeated and bankrupted, first France and then England would demand growing shares of the commerce that had hereto been largely controlled by the Dutch.262 Mercantilist measures, commercial and military wars, industrial espionage, and import tariffs in the later-seventeenth and early-eighteenth century ensued. The Dutch did not sit idly by as their commercial hegemony was challenged and developed into a formidable defensive military power 257 Ibid. For a step by step outline of the effects of foreign mercantilist measures, as well as an overview of the competing views of Dutch economic decline see Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 377-402. 259 Ibid., 399. 260 Ibid., 401. 261 O’Brien, “Mercantilism and Imperialism”, 483. 262 Ibid., 485, 490. 258 60 on land and naval power at sea.263 But even the colossal Dutch surplus capital proved inadequate in the face of such crushing odds and behemoth neighbors, and by the time of the Napoleonic struggle the Dutch Republic its commerce, industry and political clout had been reduced to “wretchedly low levels”.264 In terms of assigning the variable of the ‘rise of a foreign nation’ a positive or negative value, we find ourselves in the same predicament as when evaluating the variable of ‘interfering measures taken by a foreign nation’. If any true cause of economic stagnation must predate the onset of economic stagnation, then the significance of the Treaty of Westphalia (1648) as defined by O’Brien does indeed satisfy this criteria (unlike the Navigation Acts (1651) and the First Anglo-Dutch War (1652-54) that both post-date the onset of stagnation) but only by a historical hair’s breadth of a mere two years. However, given the Dutch Republic’s fast and furious transition from growth to stagnation and finally decline – in a mere fifty years its luck had turned – and the role that England and France now unencumbered by the responsibility of keeping Spain at an arm’s length played in curtailing the Dutch Republic’s economic heyday by a barrage of economic and military measures, this variable will be assigned a positive value. The variables that have been discussed in detail above are summarized in the table below. War Dutch 1 Interfering Outdated Poor Access Measures Technology Organization Dominant Foreign Energy Nation 1 0 1 0 Climate Rising 1 1 Rep. 263 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 85. For ‘surplus Dutch capital’ see Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 114, for ‘wretched state of the Dutch Republic during the Napoleonic Wars’ see ibid., 402. 264 61 Chapter 4: The United Kingdom Economic Chronology The economic phases that will be used in this chapter are as follows. The period between 1820 and 1870 will be considered one of growth, the period between 1870 and 1950 as one of relative stagnation, and the period between 1950 and 1973 as one of relative decline. As has already been mentioned British economic growth that can be considered extraordinary in the European context began as early as the sixteenth century.265 It is the search for variables leading to economic stagnation that makes the UK’s economic performance of the nineteenth and twentieth century the focus of this chapter. The Rise of the United Kingdom An unknown European backwater as late as the fifteenth century, Maddison argues that England began its gradual transformation into a modern nation state after the end of the civil war in 1485.266 Fragmented feudal power was centralized under Henry VII, whose son’s schism with the papacy in the first half of the sixteenth century and the ensuing seizure of monastic lands greatly enhanced the wealth and power of the state.267 The seventeenth century saw royal power curtailed by the creation of the House of Lords controlled by a secular elite of landlords and merchants.268 Royal expenditures became dependent on approval of the House of Lords and a general overhauling of the state’s finances resulted in a robust system of public finance.269 The Glorious Revolution (1688) and the reign of William III and Mary Stuart marked the successful consummation of the England’s institutions’ attempts to emulate those of their seventeenth century nemesis; the Dutch Republic.270 Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 3. Maddison, The World Economy, 91. 267 Ibid., 91. 268 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 102-106. 269 Ibid. 270 Maddison, The World Economy, 90-91. 265 266 62 The geography of the British Isles encouraged both the expansion of its domestic market and the development of its merchant fleet.271 The exploitation of land-rich resources from the American colonies, control of the Triangular Trade of the Atlantic, and the imports of the new industriousness enhancing and consumption encouraging drugs (sugar, tobacco, tea, coffee) went hand-in-hand with a series of wars prompted by a desire to grab increasingly bigger shares of overseas commercial opportunities.272 By the eighteenth century trade, colonies and the navy formed a virtuous and reciprocally interacting triangle in the mind of British policy makers who did not hesitate to fund a large war fleet.273 The severely deleterious effects of this expansion of English trade on the Dutch economy have already been noted. As important as the expansion of trade was to Britain’s economy, its economy remained fundamentally agricultural until well into the eighteenth century.274 Postplague land enclosures, yeoman, important advances in technology and technique (four-field crop rotation, early mechanization, selective breeding) and the increasing market orientation of English agriculture allowed it to break the typical pattern of stagnating per capita output after 1600.275 By 1750 output per agricultural worker had surpassed that of all other European countries.276 The ability of agriculture to sustain both a growing population while freeing an increasing portion of the population for non-agricultural activities led to a steady rise in urbanization rates from the beginning of the seventeenth century.277 From the sixteenth to the eighteenth century agricultural surpluses fueled urban industries in an era when the city of London increased in size fourteen times!278 The Victorian Era was symbolic for a triumphant England. The fruits of industrialization that were first reaped by England accelerated the rate of technological progress until England became known as the ‘workshop of the world’.279 In the nineteenth century English per capita income grew three times as fast 271 For ‘expansion of merchant fleet’ see ibid., 92, for ‘trade enhancing geography’ see Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 66. 272 Maddison, The World Economy, 92. 273 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 124. 274 Ibid., 125. 275 Allen, “Economic structure and agricultural productivity”, 22. 276 Ibid. 277 Maddison, The World Economy, 248. 278 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 91. 279 Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 27-30. 63 as it had between 1700 and 1820, and the domination of global commerce resulted in an accumulation of wealth at a rate greater than that of any other European country.280 Not to be left unmentioned in an age when ecological constraints loomed perennially in the form of either a Malthusian crisis or as a restraint to economic growth were the UK’s imports of cotton, sugar and timber from the four corners of its vast empire. By the 1830s the land-intensive imports from this ‘ghost acreage’ were equivalent to a cultivated area of twenty-five to thirty million acres.281 Almost twice the size of the British Isles themselves! In 1914 the British Empire encompassed a quarter of the world’s land and population. As with the Habsburg Empire of the sixteenth century it was an empire on which the sun never set. A mere four years later the revision of the status quo of empire prompted by the devastation of the First World War had laid bare serious cracks in the imperial edifice.282 Although the UK was able to conserve its position in international politics in the interwar years, this was due more to the isolationism of the United States and Russia than to its own economic performance.283 By the end of the Second World War the British Empire had all but crumbled away, and new economic realities had relegated the UK to the secondary ranks of political and military power. How had this happened? The Effects of War Both Maddison and Kennedy argue persuasively that the stability of the nineteenth century characterized by an “absence of significant military conflict” and a “consensus among governments in the decades after 1815 to deal with domestic instability” helped the UK rise to the zenith of its power in “naval, colonial and commercial terms.”284 Unlike the period between 1688 and 1815, when six major wars lasting a total of 63 years had put a “considerable strain” on economic development, the stable international scene allowed the UK to interact favorably with its virtual monopoly of steam driven production.285 As shall be seen below, the stability of the nineteenth century also allowed the United States and Russia to expand 280 Ibid., 28, Maddison, The World Economy, 97. Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 276. 282 Douglas, Liquidation of Empire 2-10. 283 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, xxi. 284 Maddison, The World Economy 97; Kennedy, Rise and Fall, xix. 285 For ‘six major wars’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 97, for ‘steam driven production’, see, Kennedy, Rise and Fall, xix. 281 64 across their landmasses and begin work on their economic foundations as future superpowers. The First World War marked the definitive end of this period. Douglas argues that the war was a “great misfortune” for Britain and her Empire.286 The new acquisitions from the Ottoman succession as well as those obtained from Germany would prove to be more of a curse than a blessing, the constitutional advances in India of 1917 were disrupted by the aftermath of the war, Ireland had embarked irrevocably on a path that would drive it out of the empire and in South Africa old wounds had been re-opened.287 Kennedy argues that Britain had been “irretrievably weakened” by the First World War.288 Early twentieth century shifts in the global balance of power – the rise of the United States and Russia as imminent superpowers, of Germany and Japan as revisionist, militaristic powers and the decline of France, Austria-Hungary and Italy – that had eclipsed the three century-old Eurocentric world system and had been held in limbo in the interwar years by Russian and American isolationism, had by the end of the Second World War once again caught up with the global distribution of economic resources.289 When seen in a global comparison of economic resources and set alongside the emerging superpowers of the United States and Russia, the UK with its smaller population, outdated manufacturing technology, comparatively limited access to natural resources and shrinking market shares seemed hopelessly out-classed. Although the UK emerged victorious from the Second World War, it ironically did not benefit from the rebuilding and economic restructuring in the decade following the war as did the vanquished Axis powers or its equally devastated European allies. As indicated in the graph comparing GDP per capita, it is precisely in the period following the Second World War that the UK began to lose its lead to Germany and France who experienced rapid growth after 1945.290 Olson argues that the sustained political stability and victory in the two World Wars allowed special interest groups to consolidate their position in Britain.291 In a similar vein Hall argues 286 Douglas, Liquidation of Empire 10. Ibid., 5, 10. 288 Kennedy, The Rise and Fall, xxi. 289 Ibid., xix-xx, xxi. 290 Only after 1950 was the UK’s GDP per capita growth rate hopelessly outpaced by that of all other major western European economies. For the period between 1950 and 1973 the UK lay 1.49% below the western European average. Maddison, The World Economy, 186. 291 Olson, The Rise and Decline, 141. 287 65 that in the era of rapid economic change in the latter half of the twentieth century, the very stability of Britain’s political system which for so long had been a valued asset, had become a liability.292 The low levels of investment in British industries, a widespread reluctance to innovate or expand and poor forms of organization and management characterize Elbaum and Lazonick’s ‘institutional sclerosis' that they argue resulted partly from the absence of a shaking up of Britain’s economy in the twentieth century.293 In the section above it was argued that the relative peace and stability of the nineteenth century was crucial to the rise of Victorian England. It is of no surprise that the bloodshed and widespread physical destruction of the two World Wars in the twentieth century and the ensuing contraction of world trade, reduced international migration, loss of overseas assets and the dismantling of its overseas’ empire would have severe contrary effects on the British economy. 294 Ironically, the British economy suffered not only from the devastation of war, but also from the consequences of its stability as victor. Britain’s victory in both World Wars was at least economically speaking undoubtedly a pyrrhic one. Nevertheless, in terms of our chronology, the variable of the negative impact of war on the economy must be assigned a negative value. By the time the British Empire began to wobble and sway in the years following the First World War, the British economy had already been stagnating for nearly 50 years. Interfering Measures taken by a Foreign Nation What is interesting about this variable in the context of the nineteenth century UK, and more specifically in the period of its economic heyday between 1820 and 1870 where the seeds of economic stagnation are being sought, is that any Englishman would have scoffed at the mere thought of a foreign nation being able to undermine British commercial and manufacturing supremacy. Friedberg very convincingly conveys the smugness of the Victorian era. A high level of technological advancement, the ability to draw coveted raw materials from the far corners of its empire and the fabrication and export of “low-cost, high quality machinery and consumer goods” had earned British manufacturing the Hall, “The State and Economic decline”, 289. Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 2. 294 Maddison, The World Economy, 101. 292 293 66 reputation of being the ‘workshop of the world’.295 Due to its economic significance British manufacturing was widely viewed as crucial to British political and military power. The virtuous and reciprocally interacting triangle of “trade, colonies and navy” that since the eighteenth century had been a priority of British power politics, had by the closing decades of the nineteenth century resulted in Britain’s dominance of global commerce.296 Similarly Elbaum and Lazonick argue that the boom the British economy experienced in the third quarter of the nineteenth century was not only the culmination of the first Industrial Revolution, but also a culmination of three centuries of global conflict for control of world markets as well as seven decades of intense capital investment in British productive capacities.297 Changes in the UK’s commercial policy in the nineteenth century reflect its dominant position in international commerce. In 1846 protective duties on agrarian imports were removed, in 1849 the navigational acts were terminated, and in 1860 trade and tariff restrictions were unilaterally removed.298 Although on the surface free trade was the basis of the British Empire from the mid-nineteenth century onwards, colonialism favored British “exports, shipping, banking and insurance”, ensuring it a “de facto monopoly in Asia and Africa”.299 As long as Britain reaped the benefits of free trade, it would remain its greatest advocate.300 Friedberg argues that as the true reason for Britain’s early economic success was actually its industrial head start over other countries its unwavering belief in free trade was misinformed.301 And indeed as the nineteenth century drew to a close British manufacturing began to lag behind that of the United States and Germany in terms of both growth of output per capita and international competitiveness.302 The inevitable consequence of this “unencumbered exchange” - a definition for ‘free trade’ favored by Britain likely because it glossed over the fact that for most of the nineteenth century Britain benefited more from this ‘exchange’ than any of its trading partners – as a growing number of nations jockeyed to stay closest to the technological and organizational 295 Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 27-28. Kennedy, The Rise and Fall, 124, Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 28. 297 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 3. 298 Maddison, The World Economy, 97. 299 Ibid. 300 Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 29. 301 Ibid., 30. 302 For ‘industrial competitiveness’ see Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 1, for ‘output per capita’ see ibid., 9. 296 67 frontier was to prove ineluctable in the first decades of the twentieth century. 303 The UK, resting smugly on the laurels of its early accomplishments, had lost its lead. Kennedy argues that one of the historical macro developments at the end of the nineteenth century was the redistribution of shares in world manufacturing output away from Western Europe and to America.304 With its vastly greater natural resources, largely untapped domestic market and new corporate forms of business organization, the United States were set to reap the benefits of backwardness.305 In continental Europe it was Germany, although not until the first decades of the twentieth century, that monopolized key industries of the Second Industrial Revolution and with its national variant of corporate capitalism labeled ‘organized capitalism’ by Chandler was set to undermine the UK’s hegemonic role within Europe. The UK’s dedication to free trade became problematic when the economies of these late-industrializing countries began to gather steam in the late-nineteenth and early twentieth century. With British markets small and already saturated for the staple commodities of textiles and steel, English manufacturing’s dependence on much larger and untapped foreign markets forced Britain to keep its own markets open to foreign products that were often of higher quality and cheaper.306 By the end of the nineteenth century Britain’s ‘first mover advantages’ were beginning to be outweighed by the advantages of the latecomers.307 These enjoyed more secure and expansive domestic markets, more modern and capital-intensive technology and better organization.308 Initially British manufactures still enjoyed the competitive edge that stemmed from the higher quality and craftsmanship of their products, but as shall be seen in the section on technological falling behind, manufacturing in the twentieth century would increasingly be characterized by methods of mass production. Suffering from outdated technology and lacking the requisite control of product and input markets, stoically sluggish in adapting to new market opportunities, and faced with emerging competitors whose more successful experiences have been qualified as the ‘antithesis’ of the British model, all major 303 Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 30. Kennedy, Rise and Fall, xxiv. 305 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 6. 306 Ibid. 307 Chandler, Scale and Scope, 34. 308 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 7. 304 68 staple industries of British manufacturing eventually went into decline.309 Even after the Second World War when Britain’s competitors were fostering technical education and research, enforcing a public utility policy that favored manufacturing, forcing firms dependent on government orders to buy from national sources, and introducing specific protectionist measures for certain key infant industries, Britain, which failed to do any of the above, remained committed to an economic policy of laissez-faire.310 The spread of indigenous industrialization and the accompanying protective tariffs towards the end of the nineteenth century, as well as the contraction of global trade in the interwar years clearly undermined the manufacturing and commercial advantage that Britain had enjoyed for the first three quarters of the nineteenth century. In terms of the UK’s chronology of decline, however, this variable must be assigned a negative value. Restrictive trade tariffs, the rise of foreign manufactures, their appearance on foreign and the British domestic markets as competitors, and the full momentum of the Second Industrial Revolution in which British firms were noted for their absence did not begin to negatively affect the British economy until the decade before the First World War. By then the British economy had already been stagnating for almost 40 years. Outdated Technology There is considerable agreement among historians that Britain enjoyed many advantages derived from being the first country in the world to industrialize.311 Britain enjoyed firm linkages between its advanced industrial sector and its efficient commercial and foreign trade sectors that allowed it to undercut foreign manufactures, experience a rapid growth of its physical and capital stock, enjoy unparalleled overseas investment opportunities in technologies in which the British played a key role, and reap many indirect benefits from being at the head of the expanding liberal economic order that saw per capita income grow three as fast as it had between 1700 and 1820.312 These factors - some fruits of British efforts, other gratuitous consequences of greater historical forces at work - amounted to a lasting economic 309 Chandler, Scale and Scope, 236. Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 654. 311 See authors in footnote for the paragraph below, but also Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 28. 312 For ‘firm linkages’ see DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 253, for ‘physical and capital stock’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 97, for ‘overseas investment opportunities’ and ‘benefits of expanding liberal economic order’ see ibid., 100. 310 69 boom in the first three quarters of the nineteenth century that marked the culmination of the First Industrial Revolution, gave the U.K an unparalleled competitive advantage and until the end of the nineteenth century ensured it a largely unchallenged position in the global economy.313 Unsurprisingly for any seasoned historian accustomed to fair weather inevitably giving way to foul, such rosy circumstances could not be expected to endure. In the last decades of the nineteenth century, the Second Industrial Revolution that brought major innovations in the chemical, electrical, petroleum and steel industries, was to be dominated by American and German firms.314 As the advantages of the late-industrializers began to have effect and foreign competition increased, the obstacles to technological innovation in Britain proved numerous.315 An atomistic market organization with many firms holding small market shares was a deterrent for large-scale investment.316 Similarly Britain’s already saturated market characterized by heterogeneous consumer demand did not provide an incentive to create “modern integrated and centrally administered industrial enterprises” as was the case in the United States after 1880.317 Unlike Britain, the American domestic market was largely untapped and its consumers characterized by homogenous tastes. British banks lacked direct involvement in industry and with ample investment opportunities overseas were more interested in maintaining the value of the pound than investing in new technologies.318 Britain’s education system hampered industry by failing to provide appropriately trained managerial and technological personnel, and higher education imbibed a disdain for business and applied sciences in England’s elite.319 Finally, British trade unions proved an enduring obstacle to technological and organizational innovation on the shop floor and found their position strengthened by the emergence of the Labour Party and the emergency conditions of the two World Wars.320 For ‘lasting boom’ see Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 3, for ‘workshop of the world’ see Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 27. 314 Cameron, Concise Economic History of the World, 220-224; Coffin, Stacey, Western Civilization, 679. 315 For ‘late-comer advantages’ see Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 6. 316 Ibid., 7. 317 Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 647. 318 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 5. 319 Cameron, Concise Economic History of the World, 223, Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 5. 320 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 4, 6. 313 70 By the beginning of the twentieth century British manufacturing was using outdated technology to manufacture traditional products for an increasingly competitive global market.321 The 1907 Census of Production indicates that the largest industries (coal, iron, steel, textiles and ship building) accounted for 50% of net British industrial production and 70% of all British exports.322 Although the period between 1875 and 1900 was characterized by a “rapid increase in British output per head which drew on an important impetus from growth and technological advances in staple industries”, British growth in output per capita was slowing and beginning to lag compared to the United States and Germany.323 From 1899 to 1913 British manufacturing suffered from a serious loss in competitiveness that was linked with the failure of its industry to match the productivity advances of other countries, primarily in the development of mass production methods.324 By the time of the interwar years, Britain’s staple industries that bulked so large in its economy seriously lagged behind international standards of technology and managerial practices and contributed considerably to Britain’s relatively poor international growth performance.325 In the 1920s and 30s British market shares contracted massively, but even then government-sponsored rationalization programs failed to address the fundamental causes of Britain’s lagging behind and are qualified by Elbaum and Lazonick as being “half-hearted and with limited effectiveness.”326 By the First World War British manufacturing technology had clearly fallen behind that of the United States and Germany. When overseas nascent industries were protected by tariffs which the UK were forced to tolerate given their own dependence on overseas markets, the decline of Britain’s major staple industries, although with varying pace and timing, were sealed.327 Pollard argues that even after the Second World War a “sustained failure to invest in new technology and manufacturing capacity” remained a cause of relative economic decline after 1950.328 321 Ibid., 6. Ibid., 7. 323 Ibid., 9. 324 Ibid. 325 Ibid., 10. 326 Ibid., 8, 11. 327 Ibid., 7. 328 Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 651. 322 71 Compared to the nineteenth century, the speed of technological change in the twentieth century increased greatly. Measured in the response of output to the combined inputs of labor and capital, the speed of technological change between 1870 and 1913 was less than 0.4% per year.329 Between 1913 and 1950 this increased to 1.6% per year. In an era when technological innovation was removed from the hands of the rogue inventor and increasingly a result of institutionalized applied scientific research, it was not the UK but the United States and to a lesser extent Germany that developed the key technologies of the twentieth century.330 In any industrial economy there is a link between the level of technology and levels of per capita productivity.331 For the period of British economic stagnation – the last quarter of the nineteenth century and first half of the twentieth century – there is also an undeniable link between manufacturing output and economic strength.332 Between 1820 and 1890, as the first country in the world to industrialize, the UK had the highest labor productivity.333 When the catch-up advantages of the late industrializing nations began to make themselves felt at the turn of the twentieth century, specifically in this case the use of more modern technology and better organizational structures, Britain’s days as the ‘workshop of the world’ were numbered. Despite the glaring absence of Britain’s role in the Second Industrial Revolution and its technological falling behind even in those staple industries that were once synonymous with its reputation as a manufacturing powerhouse, the variable of outdated technology must be assigned a negative value. It was not until the first decades of the twentieth century that Britain’s manufacturing suffered visibly from outdated technology. As with interfering measures by foreign nations, when Britain began to feel the stinging economic consequences of technologically falling behind, its economy had been stagnating for close to 40 years. 329 Maddison, The World Economy,102. Ibid., 101. 331 Ibid., 102. 332 Chandler, Scale and Scope, 3, 4. 333 Maddison, The World Economy, 102. 330 72 Poor Organization in Sectors Important to the Economy In the specific case of the UK, more so than for either of the other two country cases, the literature on organizational shortcomings abounds. ‘Institutional rigidities’, ‘institutional sclerosis’, the absence of Chandler’s ‘three-pronged investment’, and an ‘institutional legacy’ associated with the atomistic organization of the nineteenth century are some of the buzzwords frequently used in the discussion of the role of Britain’s institutions in its economic decline.334 The gist of the argument is as follows. In the nineteenth century, when Britain was the world’s leading economic power, economic and social institutions developed that were consistent with Britain’s role as economic hegemon.335 Along with the already discussed belief in free-trade, which was revealed to have been less free than an expression of Britain making use of its dominant position in global commerce, Adam Smith’s ‘invisible hand’ of market forces was the main arbiter for resource allocation among British firms.336 Kirby argues that the resulting “atomistic economic organization” and its manifold implications that are discussed below, were already “well entrenched” by the beginning of the nineteenth century.337 The argument closes with the idea that this form of organization was consistent with the UK’s pre-1890 competitive advantage as the First Mover of the First Industrial Revolution, but largely excluded long-term technological and organizational innovation. To highlight the differences in organization and character between British, American and German firms, the national context in which each existed will be briefly outlined. It shall become clear that the respective national variant of capitalism had far reaching consequences on firms’ organizational structures. First the UK. Relying primarily on market mechanisms to coordinate economic activity, nineteenth century British firms were often family-owned and operated, relatively small, and comparatively simple in internal organization compared to their overseas competitors.338 The managerial staff tended to be small, 334 For ‘institutional rigidities’ see Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 2, for ‘institutional sclerosis’ see Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 638, for ‘three-pronged investment’see Chandler, Scale and Scope, 12, for ‘institutional legacy’ see Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 2. 335 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 2. 336 Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 638. 337 Ibid. 338 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 3, Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 638. 73 methods of cost accounting and production control were primitive or non-existent and the development of new techniques and products relied on trial and error rather than systematic in-house research.339 There was a marked absence of vertical integration in the production process, and different stages of production were not linked by managerial hierarchy but by market forces. Shop floor organization and the final decision regarding the introduction of new technology were firmly in the hands of the highly-unionized work force. These organizational traits were common to the major industries of cotton, textiles, iron, steel, ship building and motor vehicles.340 The eventual consequences of Britain’s nineteenth century ‘competitive capitalism’ proved to be growth inhibiting.341 On the one hand, independent, familyowned firms with small market shares were reluctant to adopt new forms of management and standardize products and their lack of control of product and input markets was an obstacle to adapting to new market opportunities.342 On the other hand, British labor used its considerable control of the shop floor to oppose any radical change in technology, and even amidst industrial decline fought tooth and nail to save even low wage jobs.343 Any substantial alteration to the routine of the shop floor bore in it the seeds of a major conflict and any compromise had to be bought by the management – if it could be bought at all - at a high price.344 Among the other growth-inhibiting institutional factors in Britain were the vested interests of the treasury-dominated civil service “obsessed with macroeconomic issues”, and an obstinate elite commitment to a “socio-economic culture that was antipathetic to an industrial spirit”.345 Further, a lack of corporate management skills and opportunities resulted in little broader entrepreneurial perspectives.346 As already briefly mentioned, British banks lacked direct involvement in industry, and due to their concentration in London and shared goals wielded greater political clout than the industrial capitalists who were divided on national policy. After the financial crisis of the 1870s, banks largely abandoned industrial financing and turned their attention to the many other investment opportunities that presented 339 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy,3 Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 638. 341 Chandler, Scale and Scope, 235. 342 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 6. 343 Ibid., 7, Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 654. 344 Ibid. 345 For ‘treasury-dominated civil service’ see Kirby, “Institutional Rigidities”, 637. 346 Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy, 5. 340 74 themselves in large-scale projects overseas such as railways.347 Portrayed in the same unfavorable light as in the discussion surrounding outdated technology, Britain’s poorly-adapted education system is another favorite scapegoat in the discussion surrounding the absence of English firms in the Second Industrial revolution. It is widely characterized as having failed to provide appropriately trained managerial and technical personnel, as well as having suffered under the social cleavages between classes that hampered communication and teamwork between generalists and specialists and thwarted all hopes for managerial coordination.348 When at the beginning of the twentieth century British products faced increasing competition on both domestic and foreign markets, the above-outlined characteristics of Britain’s ‘competitive capitalism’ represented a severe challenge to Britain’s own competitiveness. While Britain basked in the glory of its early industrialization and enjoyed the benefits of empire, important innovations in business management and production processes were occurring in the United States, Germany and Japan. ‘Corporate capitalism’ with its industrial oligopoly, hierarchical managerial bureaucracy, vertical integration of production and distribution, managerial control over job content and production standards, integration of financial and industrial capital and systematic research and development might be considered the antithesis of Britain’s ‘competitive capitalism’.349 The economic consequences of this new form of business organization were manifold. Long-term planning facilitated investment especially when required on a huge scale.350 Managerial coordination and control over job content and production standards led to the introduction of new, high throughput technologies which reduced the unit cost. The integration of financial and industrial capital and managerial bureaucracy made large amounts of capital geographically flexible and capable of easily exploiting new or growing markets. Systematic research would become the mainsprings for technological innovation, especially in the field of electrical and mechanical manufacturing. The speed with which the US, Germany and Japan overtook Britain in terms of per-capita productivity highlights the importance of the ‘visible hand’ of corporate 347 Ibid., 3. Ibid., 5-6. 349 Ibid., 4. 350 For this and other consequences of ‘corporate capitalism’ see ibid., 5. 348 75 business management.351 Chandler’s ‘Modern Industrial Enterprise’ - a result of the prerequisite ‘three pronged investment’ in production facilities, a marketing and distribution network and professional management – was responsible for the major innovations in processes of production of the last quarter of the nineteenth century, exploited unprecedented cost advantages of economies of scale and scope, and quickly benefited from first mover advantages in the industries of the Second Industrial Revolution.352 Once such a firm was sufficiently large to exploit economies of scale or scope, it tended to acquire or merge with enterprises producing for the same market, take on units involved in earlier or later stages of production, expand geographically and make new products.353 Furthermore, there was little turnover among the leading firms and the main industries remained oligopolistic or monopolistic.354 Already before the First World War, the United States dominated the market for light machinery (sewing machines, office, agricultural machines, elevators, printing presses and later automobiles).355 In the same period Germany established its dominant position in the field of dyes and pharmaceuticals. By 1913 the United States was producing 36% of the world’s industrial output, compared to Germany’s 16% and Britain’s 14%.356 Developments in Germany were similar to those taking place in the United States, but with two main differences. First, its industries concentrated primarily on industrial goods, and second, its managerial capitalism was more ‘cooperative’ than the ‘competitive’ American variation.357 Nevertheless it was the first continental European country to adopt the organizational principles of ‘corporate capitalism’ which allowed it to swiftly surpassed Britain as Europe’s leading industrial nation in the first decade of the twentieth century, and quickly recover from the ravages of the First World War.358 351 Ibid., Chandler, Scale and Scope, 3. For ‘Modern Industrial Enterprise’ see Chandler, Scale and Scope, 3-4, for ‘Three-pronged investment’ see ibid., 8, for ‘economies of scale and scope’ see ibid., 21, for ‘First Mover advantages’ see ibid., 34. 353 Ibid., 36-37. 354 Ibid., 36. 355 Ibid., 40. 356 Ibid., 47. 357 Ibid., 12. 358 Ibid., 393-394. 352 76 The legacy of Britain’s ‘institutional sclerosis’ and its failure to foster modern industrial enterprises resulted in British firms’ meager involvement in the Second Industrial Revolution, as well as the prolonged period of relative economic stagnation that characterized the British economy from 1870 until 1950.359 Its share of world exports of manufactures decreased steadily in the twentieth century – from 31% in 1913 to 8% in 1983 – at which point its per capita productivity was the second lowest of the ten largest Western economies.360 It was not until the heavily-interventionist government policies after the Second World War took effect that Britain began to close the gap to the western European countries by which it had been overtaken, and in turn enjoy the benefits of being a late-comer.361 As the roots of Britain’s growthimpeding institutional structures can be found already at the beginning of the nineteenth century, this variable will, with more conviction than any other, be assigned a positive value. Access to the Dominant Form of Energy The dominant type of energy for the greater part of the nineteenth century was coal. Britain, as was seen in the previous chapter’s discussion on its energetic advantage over the Dutch Republic and most other Western European countries, had coal in abundant supply.362 Whereas the rest of Europe only saw the slow diffusion of coal in the course of the eighteenth century, Britain’s copious and easily accessible coal deposits provided its industries with the energy required to exploit first-mover advantages.363 Towards the end of the nineteenth century, however, crude oil and natural gas slowly began to emerge as future coveted sources of energy. With a fuel density 50% higher than coal, crude oil was extracted on a large scale beginning in the late nineteenth century.364 The twentieth century marked an increase in the consumption of energy that was unparalleled in human history.365 The mutually reinforcing relationship of coal 359 Ibid., 253. Hall, “The State and Economic Decline”, 266. 361 For a discussion of the ‘Opportunities of Backwardness’ in the 20 th century see Maddison, Explaining the economic performance of Nations, 56. 362 Smil, Energy in World History, 160. 363 For diffusion of coal see ibid., 161, for Britain’s coal related ‘First Mover advantages’ see ibid., 164. 364 Ibid., 167. 365 Ibid., 185. 360 77 and technological innovation of the nineteenth century continued to gather momentum in the more abstract relationship between energy availability and per-capita productivity in the twentieth century.366 To give an idea of scale, Smil estimates that coal consumption in Western Europe and the United States increased 100 fold between 1810 and 1910.367 The consumption of crude oil increased 300 fold between 1880 and 1980, and the consumption of natural gas rose 1,000 fold in the same period. In total the consumption of fossil fuels in the western world rose from under 10 million tons in 1700, to over 8,000 million tons in 1990. This enormous increase in energy consumption was also characterized by a “riotously unfairly distributed rise in available and consumed energy.”368 The twentieth century would only reinforce these trends of rising consumption and unequal availability and use. Although Britain unlike the United States did not in the period in question possess its own oil reserves and was forced to grudgingly accept America’s growing international influence in global affairs due its own dependence on first American and then Venezuelan oil, difficulty of access to the dominant type of energy cannot be considered a cause of British economic stagnation.369 Despite the clear advantage that the United States enjoyed because of its vastly richer endowment in natural resources –especially in regard to its domestic oil supplies that would gain great economic significance after the First World War - when the UK’s economy began to stagnate, oil was little more than a rumor of things to come. In the context of the chronology of economic rise and decline, this variable will be assigned a negative value. Climatic Influence Although the end of the ‘Medieval Climatic Optimum’ at the end of the thirteenth century, and again the ‘Little Ice Age’ that lasted from the mid-sixteenth to the nineteenth century were capable of negatively impacting the agrarian economies of Europe, by the end of the Victorian Era industrialized economies had become largely immune to weather.370 Indeed, already in the case of the Dutch Republic it was noted 366 Wrigley, Continuity, Chance and Change, 81, Smil, Energy in World History, 232-234. Smil, Energy in World History, 185-186. See the same two pages for similar numbers in same paragraph. 368 Ibid., 187. 369 McBeth, British Oil Policy, 148-149. 370 For ‘Medieval Climatic Optimum’ see Capasso, “Economy and Population”, 24-25, for ‘seventeenth century Ice-Age’ see DeVries, Van der Woude, The First Modern Economy, 21. 367 78 that its level of technology and social organization as early as the sixteenth and seventeenth allowed it to mollify the economic repercussions of the ‘Little Ice Age’. In the specific case of the UK, and as if to provide further evidence with which to discard this variable, the latter-half of the nineteenth and twentieth century were characterized by a stable and warming climate.371 The more fundamental reason, however, for which the variable of climatic influences will be attributed a negative value in the case of the UK, is the immunity of its industrialized economy to weather fluctuations compared to the susceptibility of earlier agrarian societies to climatic influences. Although Zhang’s study of the preindustrial era provides us with evidence for a causal relationship between a worsening of the climate, economic decline and social unrest, the immediate, drastic and possibly lethal effects of climate change had already been greatly diminished by the most varied economies of sixteenth and seventeenth century.372 The massive imports of cheap North American grain, beef and other primary products to Britain from the midnineteenth century onwards, and the sharp increase in agricultural production with the advent of mechanical farm implements and natural and artificial fertilizer greatly reduced the impact of climate change on industrialized economies.373 Rise of a Foreign Nation After exhibiting a marginally higher GDP per capita growth rate than the UK between 1820 and 1870, the United States relieved the UK as economic hegemon at the beginning of the twentieth century.374 As much as the combination of the UK’s once enviable access to raw materials (wool and coal), and its “highly efficient commercial and foreign trade sector” at the end of the eighteenth century found its economy of all the western European nations “best poised for rapid growth in the nineteenth century”, a similar confluence of geographic, organizational and social factors already from the late-eighteenth century onwards allowed the United States’ economy to slowly but surely gather steam.375 Jones, “The Evolution of Climate over the Last Millennium”. Zhang, “Global climate change, war.”, DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an age of crisis, 7. 373 Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 192, 224. 374 Maddison, The World Economy, 264. 375 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an age of crisis, 253-254. 371 372 79 Maddison argues that the initial economic dynamism of the United States came from a “comparatively greater advantage in natural resources, higher investment rates, higher levels of education and research and the larger scale of the economy.”376 Already by the mid-eighteenth century the American colonies occupied a “significant place in the pattern of maritime commerce”, by 1776 produced more pig iron than Britain, and by the 1830s were the sixth industrial power worldwide.377 In this chapter the ample evidence that supports the ‘head start’ hypothesis of Britain’s nineteenth-century economic success has already been discussed. Early industrialization, a high level of technological advancement, and enviable access to the land-intensive resources of its empire helped the UK achieve dominance in global commerce.378 As industrialization began to spread to other western countries in the latter half of the nineteenth century and tilt the international balance of power, the advantages that Britain had derived from its ‘head start’ began either to dwindle or, as ‘path dependency’ set in, become outright liabilities.379 Among the ‘opportunities of backwardness’ enjoyed by those nations who during the reign of one hegemon find themselves lagging behind, Maddison lists the considerable range of technologies that followers can emulate without significant expenditure, a higher rate of capital formation per worker that will not run into diminishing returns until the technological frontier has been reached and rapid structural change.380 As latter-day industrializing countries experienced “augmenting yields of factor inputs” based largely on their hereto underdeveloped status, Britain’s position as the hegemonic power closer the ‘best practice’ situation increasingly became tantamount to diminishing returns, outdated technology and saturated markets.381 American per capita productivity overtook that of the United Kingdom in 1890, its GDP per capita surpassed that of Britain around 1900 and by 1918 it was indisputably the greatest economic and military power in the world.382 Kennedy argues that only the anomalous disconnect between political and economic power in 376 Maddison, Explaining the Economic performance of Nations, 56. Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 120. 378 Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 27-28. 379 Kennedy, Rise and Fall, xix. 380 Maddison, Explaining the economic performance of Nations, 56. 381 Ibid., Elbaum, Lazonick, The Decline of the British Economy 6. 382 For ‘per capita productivity’ see Maddison, Explaining the Economic Performance of Nations, 102, for ‘GDP per capita’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 264, for ‘greatest economic and military power’ see Kennedy, Rise and Fall, xxi. 377 80 the interwar years allowed Britain to conserve its position in international politics, but by the end of the Second World War in which the Allies’ combined productive resources ultimately led to the defeat of the Axis powers, the military balance of power had “once again caught up with the global distribution of economic resources.”383 The bi-polar world that had been forecast in the decades prior to the First World War was confirmed by the end of the Second World War. In the period between both wars the UK had been “irretrievably weakened.”384 Economically speaking, the rest of the twentieth century would belong to the United States, followed by the laboring behemoth of the Soviet Union until its delayed collapse, and in the closing decades also to the economies of Western Europe and Japan that benefited from the tabula rasa effects of war.385 Although American economic hegemony would not become a reality until the beginning of the twentieth century, its uninterrupted economic growth already from the first decades of the nineteenth century that ate away at Britain’s lead warrant a positive value for the variable of a rising foreign nation. The above findings are summarized in the table below. UK War Interfering Measures Outdated Technology Poor Organization Access to Dominant Energy Climate Rising Foreign Nation 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 383 Ibid. Ibid. 385 For ‘US and Soviet Union’ see ibid., xxi-xxiv, for the ‘tabula rasa effects of war’ see Hall, “The State and Economic decline”, 289. 384 81 Chapter 5: Conclusions The following table summarizes the findings of this thesis. War Interfering Measures Outdated Technology Poor Organization Access to Dominant Energy Climate Rising Foreign Nation Italy 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 Dutch Republic 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 UK 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 Before interpreting the results, the following conclusions can be made: 1. No single variable caused economic stagnation in all three country cases. 2. The variables ‘outdated technology’ and ‘access to the dominant form of energy’ proved to be irrelevant in all three cases. 3. The Italian economy began to stagnate because of the effects of a climatic downturn. 4. The economy of the Dutch Republic began to stagnate because of the consequences of war, interfering measures, poor organization, rising foreign nations, and climatic change. Why the climatic variable has been assigned a positive value despite having had a negligible economic impact will be explained below. 5. The economy of the UK began to stagnate because of poor organization and the rise of a foreign nation. The first goal of this thesis was to discover the true causes of economic stagnation in the three country cases. Conclusions 3, 4 and 5 are the result of this inquiry. Conclusions 1 and 2 will be returned to below when the evolving nature of the variables is discussed. But first the rather schematic results in the table above will be fleshed out by putting the variables in chronological order of their appearance. This will allow possible patterns in the conjuncture of variables to become visible. 82 Step-by-Step Chronologies of Decline Italy The following table summarizes Italy’s step-by-step chronology of decline. Italy War Interfering Measures Outdated Technology Poor Organization Access to Dominant Energy Climate Rising Foreign Nation 3 7 5 4 2 1 6 A deterioration of the climate occurred first. The end of the ‘Medieval Climate Optimum’ at the end of the thirteenth century irremediably weakened the agricultural sector. This caused gross and per capita agricultural output to decline even before the ravages of the Black Death and the wars of the fourteenth and fifteenth century devastated the countryside, decimated the population, and disrupted agriculture, trade and urban manufacturing. As agricultural activity accounted for 45-60% of the GDP, the climatic blow to the basis of Italy’s late medieval economy ended the 300 year long growth phase in 1300, and marked the beginning of economic stagnation. Then in 1348 the Black Death swept across Italy killing one third of the population. This resulted in a serious shortage of manpower. Brief per capita gains in productivity were reversed as soon as the population began to recover while gross output in all sectors of the economy continued to decline. The introduction of mezzadria share-cropping at the beginning of the fifteenth century hinted at the ‘internal rigidities’ that characterized Italy’s economy, for instance the prevailing imbalance of power between urban centers and their rural surroundings. Until the nineteenth century the organizational shortcomings of the mezzadria system would contribute to the low productivity and gradual impoverishment of the Italian countryside.386 The fifteenth century also marked the height of power of urban guilds. When they were gradually excluded from politics in the sixteenth and seventeenth century they grew increasingly hostile to “innovative techniques and entrepreneurial capitalism”, which contributed to undermining Italy’s chances of adapting to the changed economic parameters of the early modern period.387 386 387 Blim, Made in Italy, 25-26. Black, Early Modern Italy, 72. 83 Following closely on the heels of these two manifestations of Italy’s economy’s ‘internal rigidities’, were the wars of the mid-fifteenth and sixteenth century. These ensured that the recovery of the population would happen only slowly and that trade and industry would be interrupted for decades at a time. Fifteenth century changes in shipbuilding marked the beginning of the end of Italy’s edge in maritime technology. This technological lagging behind at sea had its equivalent in urban manufacturing, where outdated technology contributed to making Italian manufactures less desirable than foreign imports by the mid-sixteenth century. Between 1300 and 1500, the Italian economy was characterized by the ineluctable decline of gross agricultural output, a plummeting then stagnant population, an ever-increasing distance from the technological frontier, and various manifestations of organizational shortcomings. It is not hard to imagine that the confluence of these factors formed a solid foundation for prolonged and absolute decline that began in 1500 and was to last for more than 400 years. From the mid-sixteenth century onwards other European countries increasingly interfered in the economic realm where Italy had once been dominant. Whether in the spice trade, Mediterranean freightage, the export of subsidized manufactures or import restriction on Italian goods, already at the beginning of the early modern period the days of Italy’s economic hegemony were numbered. The Dutch Republic The following table summarizes the Dutch Republic’s step-by-step chronology of decline. Dutch Republic War Interfering Measures Outdated Technology Poor Organization Access to Dominant Energy Climate Rising Foreign Nation 2 4 6 1 5 N/A 3 First the climatic variable must be addressed. Although severe and unpredictable weather in the mid-sixteenth century resulted in harvest failures, the diversified nature of the Dutch economy and the Republic’s technological accomplishments and social 84 organization largely diffused the economic consequences of the ‘Little Ice Age’. The contradiction between an ultimately insignificant variable being assigned a positive value for purely methodological, in this case chronological reasons, underlines the importance of a final interpretation of the findings in which such paradoxes can be explained and rectified. Given the evidence climate can be discounted as a cause of Dutch economic stagnation.388 The four variables that did contribute to transforming the Dutch Republic’s three hundred and fifty year period of growth into one of relative economic stagnation can be divided into two groups of two factors. Those that predated the onset of stagnation by a time span of between fifty to seventy years, and those that appeared simultaneously with the onset of stagnation. Why those factors that coincided with the onset of economic stagnation were assigned a positive value was explained in chapter three. The two factors that pre-dated economic stagnation by a comfortable margin are the parallel processes of capital concentration and proletarianization that from the end of the sixteenth century undermined the Republic’s unique proto-capitalistic socio-economic structure and represent an organizational shortcoming, and the burden related to war that was apparent already in the closing decades of the sixteenth century. The next two stagnation causing variables – ‘interfering measures’ and ‘rising foreign nations’ – are strongly interconnected. The rise of England and France in the early decades of the seventeenth century found expression in the foreign interventionist measures and wars that would dominate the second half of the seventeenth century. The Peace of Westphalia (1648) and the Treaty of the Pyrenees (1659) marked the end of Spain’s bid for European hegemony and confirmed political plurality in Europe. In the ensuing multi-polar system characterized by short-term shifting alliances designed to maintain the precarious balance of power, France, Prussia, the Habsburg Empire and England emerged as key players. The Dutch Republic was increasingly forced to face the inevitable consequences of its small geographic size and population, and its dependence on foreign markets. England’s Navigation Acts and France’s mid-seventeenth century protectionism marked the beginnings of the purposeful undermining of Dutch hegemony in trade and 388 DeVries, Van der Woude, The First Modern Economy, 21. 85 manufacturing that help explain the Dutch Republic’s sudden transition from growth to stagnation. By the time coal had replaced peat as the primary source of energy and Dutch industries and fisheries were characterized by outdated technology in the mideighteenth century, the Dutch economy was already in a state of absolute decline. The United Kingdom The following table summarizes the United Kingdom’s step-by-step chronology of decline. United Kingdom War Interfering Measures Outdated Technology Poor Organization Access to Dominant Energy Climate Rising Foreign Nation 4 3 5 2 6 N/A 1 Evidence of the latent potential and steady growth of the American economy already in the last decades of the eighteenth century warrants that the variable ‘rising foreign nation’ is listed first. America’s comparative advantage in natural resource endowment, investment rates, levels of education and sheer scale of its domestic market, resulted in faster economic growth than the UK even while the latter was experiencing its economic heyday of the Victorian Era.389 It is not to be forgotten that a nation’s economic performance is relative to that of others countries. When the British economy did begin to stagnate it did so relative to that of its closest competitors. The second cause of economic stagnation is the manifestation of poor organization in sectors important to the economy. As has been observed these can largely be traced back to the UK’s atomistic nineteenth century economic organization.390 Although the consequences of this ‘institutional sclerosis’ would be varied and endure well into the twentieth century, the absence of British firms in the Second Industrial Revolution indicates that institutional shortcomings were already 389 390 Maddison, Explaining the economic performance of Nations, 56. Elbaum, Lazonick, The decline of the British Economy, 2. 86 present in the latter half of the nineteenth century. Only these two variables can be considered causes of economic stagnation. A confluence of variables in the last decades of the nineteenth and first decades of the twentieth century would ensure that Britain’s phase of relative economic stagnation would be long-lasting. The rise of indigenous industrialization and protective tariffs overseas highlighted the UK’s dependence on foreign markets as well as British industry’s increasingly substandard production technologies and products. The two World Wars did away with Britain’s empire ending its monopolistic advantages in trade and its once-enviable access to resources. In terms of access to the dominant form of energy, it was the First World War that hinted at the revolutionary effects oil would have on western economies in the later twentieth century. Lacking its own supply, the UK as a First World economy would always be at a disadvantage compared to those nations with domestic supplies. The economic problems resulting from the effects of these four variables culminated in a twenty-five year phase of relative economic decline that began in 1950. The root cause of the remarkable lack of innovation that characterized the most important sectors of British industry even after the Second World War might be found in the adjective ‘relative.’ Although Britain’s economy stagnated and then declined for an entire century, at no point was it reduced to a level of poverty that might have forced it to adopt new methods of organization and production. For the duration of the period in question, the British economy grew. Others economies simply grew faster. Due to its utter insignificance in the context of the UK’s industrialized economy of the nineteenth and twentieth century, the climatic variable will be declared ‘not applicable’. A comparison of the individual chronologies of decline demonstrates that there is no recurring order among the variables that led to economic stagnation in all three cases. Negative climatic influences are listed first in one case but are discarded in both others. Poor organization is listed in first and second position in two cases but as a variable could not be more different from the negative climatic influences and poor access to the dominant form of energy which in the case of Italy occupy first and second place. Although the effects of war that are third and second in line for Italy and the Dutch Republic respectively might at first seem closely related to the 87 interfering measures of a foreign nation that rank third in the case of the UK, eventual parallels between the two variables lose their significance due to the fact that they contributed only to cementing and not causing economic stagnation in the case of Italy and the UK. In short, if the country comparison proved that no single variable caused economic stagnation in all three cases as was stated in conclusion 1, a comparison of the variable-by-variable chronologies of decline indicates that no recurring sequence of variables caused decline. This finding addresses the second goal of this thesis which was to formulate a generally-applicable rule regarding the cause or causes of economic stagnation. The findings of this thesis suggest that no such generallyapplicable rule can be formulated. In an attempt to explain the absence of any pattern among the individual country chronologies that would be required to formulate a general rule regarding the causes of economic stagnation, and to establish why certain variables emerged as being significant while others did not, each variable will be briefly evaluated in the evolving historical context of the time frame covered in this thesis. The variables will be divided into two groups: significant and insignificant variables. Insignificant Variables The variables whose role in causing economic stagnation was insignificant in all three cases are ‘outdated technology’ and ‘access to the dominant form of energy’. Outdated Technology Given its ranking as last and penultimate variable in the individual country chronologies, there is reason to believe that outdated technology is a consequence and not a cause of economic stagnation. In the case of Italy, outdated technology had its root in the institutional rigidities best portrayed by the excessive conservatism and bureaucracy of urban guilds. In the case of the Dutch Republic, the waning profitability of manufacturing and fishing in the face of rising foreign competition, the increased burden of taxation that fell predominantly on the shoulders of entrepreneurs, and the lack of an indigenous coal supply undermined investment in new technologies. In the case of the UK, the widespread and sustained lack of technological innovation in the late-nineteenth and first half of the twentieth century 88 was a result of the economy’s ‘institutional rigidities’ as outlined by Elbaum and Lazonick. Although outdated technology doubtlessly contributed to transforming the periods of economic stagnation into ones of economic decline in each of the country cases, this variable clearly remains a consequence of the real causes of stagnation. Access to the Dominant Form of Energy What helps explain the waning importance of this variable – from second, to penultimate and finally last place in the cases of Italy, the Dutch Republic and the UK respectively – is the increased availability of energy and the greater diversification of modern economies compared to their pre-industrial predecessors. Of the three economies in question Italy’s had the least available energy and was the least diversified. Relying almost solely on manpower as mechanical energy, the drastic population decline caused by the Black Death lowered gross agricultural output and raised wages for workers further undermining the competitiveness of urban manufactures. With few alternative sources of power – Malanima carefully outlines the energetic limitations of the late medieval energy system - the economy of fourteenth century Italy relied largely on the sheer size of its population.391 Indeed only the rigid adherence to the established chronological benchmarks – the Black Death occurred a mere forty eight years after the onset of Italian economic stagnation – prevents this variable from qualifying as a cause of economic stagnation. Compared to that of Italy, the economy of the Dutch Republic was both more diversified and with its ample peat endowment well supplied with the era’s dominant form of energy. It was not until mercantilist measures and foreign competition both in manufacturing and at sea had undermined the profitability of manufacturing and trade and prompted a reorientation towards agriculture in the eighteenth century that the Dutch economy with its greatly reduced scope of economic activities was set to suffer the consequences of its lack of coal in the industrialized era. As with peat in the case of the Dutch Republic, the UK’s rich endowment in coal supplied it with abundant energy well into the twentieth century. It was not until oil gradually began to relieve coal as the primary energy carrier after the First World War that the UK would begin to feel the economic consequences of its dependence on foreign oil. These consequences might have meant having to make political 391 Malanima, “The energy basis for early modern growth”, 59. 89 concessions that were capable of leaving a bitter and lingering aftertaste, but were by no means comparable to the disastrous effects that Italy’s loss of manpower had on its economy. As the total amount of energy available to national economies gradually increased in the time span that has been the focus of this thesis, the link between energy and economic activity lost some of its immediacy. The Dutch Republic’s use of its abundant peat to fuel domestic industries in the early modern period, and the UK’s exploitation of its fortuitously located coal fields from the mid-seventeenth century onwards explains the waning importance of this variable in these two cases. With the advent of oil and natural gas exploitation the twentieth century would experience an energy glut unparalleled in human history. Simply put and limiting the statement only to the most successful First World economies, from roughly the latenineteenth century onwards the availability of energy was no longer the prime variable that limited economic growth.392 Significant Variables Variables that caused economic stagnation in one or more cases are the ‘effects of war’, ‘interfering measures taken by a foreign nation’, ‘poor organization in sectors important to the economy’, ‘climate’ and the ‘rise of a foreign nation’. The Effects of War Although war is intrinsic to human history, the nature of war evolved considerably in the time period in question. Granted that the economic consequences of the national and dynastic rivalries that characterized the late Middle Ages are not to be underestimated, the economic implications of the ‘military revolution’ of the sixteenth century and the ongoing military conflicts to maintain the balance of power within Europe from the late-seventeenth to early-nineteenth century greatly increased the cost and destructiveness of war.393 The Dutch Republic had the ill fortune of being an object of envy of neighbors with much greater military capacities in the period in which the economic consequences of warfare increased dramatically. Maddison 392 393 Smil, Energy in World History, 185, 187, 232-234. Kennedy, Rise and Fall, 55-58, 94. 90 carefully distinguishes between the Eighty Years’ War in which the Dutch Republic was but one theater of war for Habsburg Spain, and the Republic’s seventeenth century conflicts against England and France in which it felt the “concentrated energy of the modern nation state.”394 If the economic consequences of the Eighty Years’ War were already sufficiently grave to be considered a cause Dutch economic stagnation, the seventeenth century wars against England and France would fundamentally contribute to turning the Republic’s period of relative economic stagnation into one of absolute decline. Although the effects of war did not play a role in triggering economic stagnation in the case of the UK, Kennedy argues that the UK was “irretrievably weaken[ed]” by the First World War.395 The economic consequences of the destructive capacity of twentieth century militarized warfare are clearly exemplified by Germany. In the forty years leading up to the First World War the German economy grew at an average rate of 1.63% per year, 0.3% above the Western European average.396 In the period between 1914 and 1950 in which Germany was at the heart of two World Wars its growth rate was reduced to 0.17%, well below the Western European average of 0.83%. In the period between the two World Wars the Western European average growth rate dropped from 1.3% to 0.8%. Had the UK’s economy not already been outpaced by that of the United States at the end of the nineteenth century, it is not hard to imagine that the First World War would now be known as the turning point from growth to stagnation in British economic history. In the context of this thesis the issue of assigning a value to the variable ‘effects of war’ remains fundamentally one of timing. In all three cases the variable occupies a mid-field position in the country-specific chronologies. It is beyond the scope of this thesis to decide whether the drawn out conflicts of the late Middle Ages in Italy and the ongoing wars in which the Dutch Republic found itself embroiled caused more or less damage than the shorter but vastly more destructive World Wars in which the UK was involved. What is clear is that where war did not lead to economic stagnation as in the case of the Dutch Republic, it helped cement economic decline. 394 Maddison, The World Economy, 80. Kennedy, Rise and Fall, xxi. 396 Maddison, The World Economy, 186. The numbers from the next two sentences are also from page 186. 395 91 Interfering Measures taken by a Foreign Nation Although often not more than a hodgepodge of measures motivated as much by a malicious desire to do harm than by any verifiable economic rationale, mercantilist measures dominated national economic policies in the seventeenth and earlyeighteenth century.397 While tariffs designed to protect fledgling national industries appeared sporadically in the nineteenth and twentieth century, especially in economically difficult times, it is safe to say that by the end of the eighteenth century mercantilist measures were being replaced by policies intended to foment free trade. Of the three cases the Dutch Republic’s short-lived existence as economic hegemon comes closest to coinciding with the age of mercantilism and indeed the introduction of British and French mercantilist measures contributed to ending its growth phase. The spread of comprehensive mercantilist measures in the adjacent countries in the first decades of the eighteenth century contributed significantly to transforming the Dutch Republic’s relative economic stagnation into absolute decline. Given the timing of the heyday of economic measures willfully designed to interfere with foreign economies, the insignificance of this variable in the case of Italy’s fourteenth century and the UK’s late-nineteenth century stagnation is made plausible. Of the seven variables this one travels least well through the ages. Discounting its manifestations that were seen to have been irrelevant to causing economic stagnation in Italy and the UK, this variable was clearly at its zenith in the mercantilist era of the seventeenth and eighteenth century. That it contributed to causing economic stagnation only in the case of the Dutch Republic can therefore largely be explained by its chronological specificity. Poor Organization in Sectors Important to the Economy This variable was a cause of economic stagnation in the case of the Dutch Republic and the UK. In the case of Italy, the unresolved ‘internal rigidities’ of its mature industrial economy – that can be considered a manifestation of this variable – contributed to turning economic stagnation into almost five centuries of absolute economic decline. The comments here will be limited to the cases of the Dutch Republic and the UK. 397 Cameron, Concise economic history, 128-130. 92 Israel argues that the economy of Europe that emerged in the early modern era was very different from the fragmented localized economies of the medieval period.398 DeVries argues that the increasingly integrated markets characterized by a convergence of prices and emerging albeit imperfect factor markets allowed for innovation in the organization of production that would have been unthinkable in earlier centuries.399 Successfully implemented cost-reducing measures could mean success in vast international markets.400 ‘Innovation’ is the recurring theme and many states fell victim to their own inability to evolve and adapt to the new economic parameters. Habsburg Spain was blinded by the glory of its enormous but ultimately unprofitable territorial and administrative empire and clung to its imperial policy instead of pursuing measures that might have redressed the sclerotic tendencies of its economy.401 Similarly, Italy’s urban industries’ continued commitment to products and markets that were in relative decline contributed to driving capital and labor into agriculture - Cipolla’s ‘engine of decline’ – further exacerbating the regressive structural trends of Italy’s ailing economy.402 The Dutch Republic that thrived amidst these economically turbulent times did so precisely because of organizational innovations in agriculture, industry and most importantly commerce.403 The decline of the UK and the rise of the United States are further examples that can be used to highlight the increasing importance of innovation and efficiency in the organization of vital economic sectors. The combined consequences of the UK’s stubborn adherence to the principles and practices of ‘competitive capitalism’ are at the heart of the explanation of its absence in the Second Industrial Revolution and its comparatively poor economic performance in the twentieth century. The nineteenth and twentieth century equivalent of the seventeenth century cost-reducing innovations in which the Dutch excelled, were the mass-production techniques, marketing and distribution networks and professional management that characterized American ‘corporate capitalism’. DeVries argues that the marked differentiation in land use, the increased social stratification and the new powers of markets that were emerging in early modern 398 Israel, Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 405. DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of crisis, 247, 248. 400 Ibid., 27. 401 Ibid., 250. 402 For ‘urban industries’ see ibid., for ‘engine of decline’ see Cipolla, “The Italian Failure”, 10. 403 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an age of crisis, 251. 399 93 Europe caused the “long-established locational pattern of industry and commercial activities [to undergo] a dramatic revision.”404 As has been observed the innovation in the organization of production allowed the Dutch to fill the void that was left by Spain and Italy as they retreated into economic insignificance. The rise of the UK over the Dutch Republic is at least as much a military as an organizational victory, but here too innovative forms of organization contributed to the UK’s seventeenth and eighteenth century rise. A firm linkage between its industrial and highly efficient commercial and foreign trade sectors lowered transaction costs by making merchants and industrialists sensitive to mass markets and encouraged the shift of productive resources towards expanding markets.405 As the UK’s economic success of the Victorian Era was largely attributed to the early-nineteenth century principles of ‘competitive capitalism’ these remained unchallenged and unchanged despite growing evidence of the organizational advantages of ‘corporate capitalism.’ The UK’s slowly developing ‘institutional sclerosis’ eventually led to a loss of competitiveness in the later nineteenth and early twentieth century as progressive globalization opened up competition for domestic and foreign market shares to a greater number of players. In the two country cases whose periods of stagnation and decline occurred in the modern era – the Dutch Republic and the UK - a lack of flexibility and innovation in the key sectors of the economy played a decisive role in causing economic stagnation. In the case of Renaissance Italy, where it can only be assumed that the fragmentation of the late medieval economy attenuated the effects of international competition and postponed the inevitable consequences of Italy’s economic rigidities, similar organizational shortcomings might not have led to economic stagnation but were fundamental to buttressing half a millennium of absolute decline. The ‘institutional’ factor which is commonly acknowledged to encompass the totaled and multifarious aspects of human agency continues to elude a succinct and useful definition. Despite its dubious definition and across-the-board applicability the fact that all three economies in question failed to successfully adapt to the inevitably evolving economic parameters of their times only serves to pique the interest in the workings of this ‘institutional’ factor. For ‘dramatic revision see’ ibid., 27, for ‘marked differentiation in land use, increased social stratification and powers of markets’ see ibid., 245. 405 DeVries, The Economy of Europe in an age of crisis, 253-254. 404 94 Regardless of troublesome issues of definition, one cautious conclusion can be drawn. If with increasing globalization an economy’s ability to stay flexible and adapt to emerging trends had become at least if not more important to its enduring economic success than its geography, natural resources or access to the dominant form of energy, then the responsibility for ensuring economic growth and staving off economic stagnation clearly lies with no one other than its citizens. In a study of economic history this is a clearly anthropomorphic finding with undeniable cultural undertones! Does this warrant renewed interest in Max Weber’s difficultly quantified protestant ethic? The effects of culture on the economy that have been excluded from this thesis because of difficult quantification might deserve further investigation after all. Climatic Influence In the case of Italy the consequences of the sudden climate change are clear. The economy had an important agricultural component and the end of the ‘Medieval Climate Optimum’ had severe, economic stagnation-causing consequences. In the case of the Dutch Republic the variable’s initial positive value is misleading. It has been explained that the positive value was due solely to chronological and methodological thoroughness and does not accurately represent the actual economic impact of the ‘Little Ice Age’ of the mid-sixteenth century. Two and a half centuries after the end of the ‘Medieval Climate Optimum’ wreaked havoc on Italy’s agricultural sector, the diversified Dutch economy with its technological achievements and social organization was largely immune to the effects of climate change. Two and a half centuries later we encounter the UK’s industrialized economy of the Victorian Era characterized by food and grain imports and mechanized agriculture. By the nineteenth century weather was little more than a topic of polite conversation. Rise of a Foreign Nation In the country specific chronologies of decline this variable is listed in sixth, third and first place for Italy, the Dutch Republic and the UK respectively. The argument that can be made for the growing importance of this variable is as follows: with the increasing globalization of the world economy competition for market shares was 95 opened up to a greater number of competitors and became fiercer. The economic consequences of a nation successfully or unsuccessfully competing in this now international economic theatre became more immediate. A similar logic underlies the increased importance of good organization in important economic sectors. Globalization increased the speed with which the consequences of waning competitiveness were felt. If Venetian cloth exports took one hundred years to fall from 25 000 cloths to a paltry 200 cloths, there is considerable unanimity that Dutch manufacturing collapsed in the twenty seven years between 1713 and 1740.406 And if in 1870 only England and Belgium could be described as “highly industrialized countries”, by 1900 this was no longer the case with the United States, Germany, France, Russia and Japan also vying for a similar designation, but also the year in which the UK lost its GDP per capita lead to the United States.407 By the twentieth century the unprecedented capital and labor flows and booming commodity trade of the late-nineteenth century had led to a general convergence among the Atlantic economies.408 On a wider geographical scale the increased pace of technological development and its subsequent international diffusion led to a similar convergence in levels of GDP per capita among the major western economies by the end of the twentieth century.409 Given the increased pace of globalization of the past century one is tempted to ask whether the world of the twenty-first century is indeed ‘flat’ as Thomas Friedman tirelessly argues.410 ‘Flat’ refers to the level playing field upon which all competitors in the global economy presumably enjoy an equal opportunity. Thankfully this view is not uncontested.411 Regardless of one’s political views on the pros and cons of globalization there is little point in denying that the globalized economy of the twenty first century has pitted nations against one another in a competition for domestic and foreign market shares that is unprecedented in the history of mankind. The increasing speed and intensity of this globalization process that has made first neighboring 406 For ‘Venetian cloth production’ see Cipolla, “The Economic Decline of Italy”, 203, for ‘consensus on the collapse of Dutch manufacturing’ see Israel, Dutch Primary in World Trade, 377. 407 Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 24. 408 O’Rourke, Jeffrey, Globalization and History, 5. 409 For ‘increased pace of technological development’ see Kennedy, Rise and Fall, xix, for ‘convergence of levels of GDP per capita’ see Maddison, The World Economy, 132. 410 This point is reiterated throughout his book The World is Flat. 411 In Making Globalization Work, Nobel Prize winning economist Joseph Stiglitz concedes that although there have been drastic changes in the world economy, the world is far from flat and in many ways is getting less flat. 96 countries and then all countries regardless of their geographic location potential economic competitors can be clearly observed in the time span covered in this thesis. It can be concluded that the economic impact of each factor varied over time. The importance of climatic influence and the access to the dominant form of energy declined over time due to having been made redundant by a combination of modern technology, transport and increased market integration or being momentarily irrelevant due to the sheer abundance of available energy. The fact that the end of cheap fossil fuel has given the energy variable renewed importance is an indication that variables might temporarily lose their significance but can be returned to the foreground by unforeseeable developments. The variables of poor organization and rising foreign nations have gained in importance as a result of the increased competition of the globalizing world economy. Of the three remaining variables, outdated technology has been identified as a consequence and not a cause of the true causes of economic stagnation, interfering economic measures were more era-specific than any other variable and since the seventeenth and early-eighteenth century have become somewhat of a political anachronism and the economic effects of war remain negative. Three Final Observations The final goal of this thesis was to formulate general observations regarding the wider process of economic rise and decline.412 All good things come in threes. First, some words of warning regarding the potentially massive consequences of unforeseeable or unalterable developments. Examples of such epoch-delineating events that proved central to cementing their economic decline can be found for each of the three country cases. In the case of Italy it was the discovery of the Americas and the subsequent shift in focus of world trade from the Mediterranean to the Atlantic. In the case of the Dutch Republic it was the end of Spanish Habsburg’s bid for dominance in Europe and the subsequent and irreversible rise of England and 412 The three general conclusions listed here are based above all on the study of the three specific historical cases that have been the subject of this thesis. Any further inspiration, hunch or gut feeling has resulted from reading the works of the authors listed in the bibliography. Although as much as anyone else I would like to formulate universally-applicable rules of thumb regarding the labyrinthine process of economic rise and decline, I would imagine that any hypothesis resulting from such a study would require a much greater number of historical cases to bolster its applicability and credibility. 97 France. For the UK it was the fortuitous geographical, geological and cultural makeup of the North American continent that together represented unparalleled ingredients for economic growth. Although it is unlikely that an unknown continent lingers somewhere waiting to be discovered and exploited, there is no lack of possible contemporary equivalents of such meta-historical developments that can be envisioned. The discovery of a hereto unknown source of energy, a sudden technological breakthrough or the colonization of a distant planet might suddenly and irrevocably alter the existing economic status quo. Although seemingly unlikely, history is nothing if not unpredictable. Less far-fetched but with similar implications for national economies is increasing globalization. With global container trade averaging double-digit growth since 2003 and every modern container ship carrying 560 times the cargo of a single Dutch fluyt ship, geographic location, resource endowment, and climate have become secondary to guaranteeing economic growth to what Maddison, ever fearless in the face of complex topics, defines as the ‘less tangible layers of causality’.413 Listed in no particular order they are the ‘character of institutions’, the ‘degree of social conflict’, ‘international order’, ‘ideology’ and the ‘nature of economic policy’.414 A nation’s efforts to manipulate these until they are respectively as efficient, minimal, stable, tolerant, and sustainable as possible might not guarantee that economic stagnation and decline can be staved off indefinitely, but will likely position the nation most successful in addressing these issues more favorably in an international comparison than those countries that fail to address these elusive social and political agendas. Second, a few observations on the evolving nature and everyday ramifications of economic stagnation and decline. In a few words, economic decline is not as bad as it sounds, and over time its implications for everyday life have grown less serious. In this thesis it has been observed that the epicenters of economic activity were able to conserve a large portion of their wealth and even during or after extended phases of absolute economic decline still fared better than many of their less developed contemporaries. Although perhaps least true in the case of Renaissance Italy where For ‘growth of container trade’ see www.shipsandboxes.com Own calculation for the comparison of cargo capacities. The average carrying capacity of a Dutch fluyt ship was averaged at 250 tons, that of a modern container ship 140 000 tons. 414 Maddison, Explaining the economic performance of nations, 91. 413 98 the city-states were nevertheless able to conserve their status of being the richest areas of Europe until the seventeenth century, the thesis of the softening of the implications of decline gains validity with increasing temporal distance from the late Middle Ages. The Dutch Republic declined in absolute terms from 1700 to 1800, but even during this period remained far above the European urbanization average and only lost its lead in GDP per capita to the UK at the beginning of the nineteenth century. Kossmann argues that even at its economic nadir the Dutch Republic benefited from its proximity to the much larger markets of England and France, the experience of its service sector, and its capital accumulation and colonial possessions that would have made a lasting farewell into poverty and backwardness unthinkable.415 The UK is a further case in point. Although losing its lead in per capita productivity to the United States around 1870, its economy continued to “prosper as it had never done before.”416 Between 1870 and 1900 the gross national income grew from 1.3 billion to 2.08 billion pounds, London remained the world’s financial center and “Britain continued to dominate world trade.”417 Even after seventy years of relative economic stagnation British GDP per capita remained above the European average and not even a quarter century of relative economic decline could dislodge it from among the most powerful economies of the world. The topic of economic stagnation and decline easily conjures up images of deserted villages, a disease-riddled population clad in rags, or a post-industrial wasteland leaking poisonous substances into the groundwater. Although the end of an economic heyday need by no means be pleasant, it is important – and comforting – to know that this study of economic rise and decline indicates that phases of stagnation and decline by no means imply destitution, nor that economic downturns are necessarily a lasting condition. If nothing else, this conclusion can be seen as a consolation for declining hegemons. This brings us to our third and final point. If above it was concluded that stagnation and decline are only ever relative to the economic performance of other nations and even the most severe manifestations of absolute decline needn’t necessarily imply hunger, indigence and a return to the Dark Ages, it must also be mentioned that there is strong historical evidence that economic decline, be it relative Kossmann, “Some Meditations on Dutch 18th century Decline”, 52. Friedberg, The Weary Titan, 24. 417 Ibid. 415 416 99 or not, is inevitable. In the history of mankind there has yet to be a political entity or nation that has sustained its economic hegemony indefinitely. In her search for ‘hyper powers’ in human history, Chua lists only six candidates over a time span of two and a half thousand years that can claim such a title.418 All of them, including the myriad of lesser powers that dotted the time spans between the reigns of these behemoths declined eventually. The technological accomplishments of the modern era and the creature comforts they have bequeathed to the First World can easily create a false sense of security. Satellites orbit the earth indefatigably, stock markets rest only grudgingly on weekends, experts tell us how much longer global oil reserves will last with such seemingly scientific precision that we are tempted to believe that technology will provide the solution to any future predicament, and the highways of Belgium can be seen from space. In terms of technological development, available energy, and scientific knowledge our world could not be more different from that of a Renaissance peasant hoeing under the sun, an East India Company seaman falling out of the lookout nest and disappearing into the sea, or a British petty bureaucrat shuffling back into his bamboo hut in the far flung reaches of the empire to refill his tumbler with gin. Despite the innumerable accomplishments of our age fundamental parallels to our most humble beginnings remain to remind us of our human condition. We continue to wage war, to interfere in the affairs of others, and to be exposed to the whims of our increasingly fragile and depleted ecosystem. What then should be done if economic stagnation and decline are indeed inevitable? This study suggests that the most any nation can do is to tend to its own affairs, in this case the ‘deeper, less tangible layers of causality’ known to economic historians as ‘institutional’ variables, and, and this is said in all academic earnestness and sincerity, hope for the best. 418 They are in order the Achaemenid Empire, the Roman Empire, the Tang Dynasty of Imperial China, the Mongol Empire, the 17th century Dutch Republic and the British Empire. Chua, Day of Empire. 100 Bibliography: Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson and J.A. Robinson. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107. (Nov. 2002), pp. 1231-1294. Allen, R. “Economic Structure and Agricultural Productivity in Europe, 1300-1800.” European Review of Economic History, Vol. 4. (2000), pp. 1-26. Bairoch, P. Cities and Economic Development: From the Dawn of History to the Present. Chicago: University of Chicago, 1988. Belfanti, C. “Town and Country in Central and Northern Italy, 1400-1800,” Town and Country in Europe, 1300-1800. Ed. S.R. Epstein. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004. pp. 292-315. Berner, S. “Italy: Commentary.” Failed Transitions to Modern Industrial Society: Renaissance Italy and Seventeenth Century Holland. Eds. Frederick Krantz and Paul Hohenberg. Quebec: Interuniversity Centre for European Studies, 1975. pp. 19-22. Black, C. Early Modern Italy. London: Routledge, 2002. Blim, M. Made in Italy: Small-Scale Industrialization and its Consequences. New York: Greenwood Publishing Group, 1990. Boxer, C.R. “Dutch Economic Decline.” The Economic Decline of Empires. Ed. Carlo Cipolla. London: Methuen & Co Ltd., 1970. pp. 235-263. Cameron, R. A Concise Economic History of the World: from Paleolithic Times to the Present. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1993. Capasso, S. “Economy and Population in Italy 1300-1913.” Popolazione e Storia, Vol. 2 (2007), pp.15-40. Chandler, A. Scale and Scope: the Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990. Cipolla, C. “The Economic Decline of Italy.” The Economic Decline of Empires. Ed. Carlo Cipolla. London: Methuen & Co Ltd., 1970. pp. 196-214. Coffin, J., Stacey, R., Western Civilization, (Volume two). New York: Norton & Company, 2008. Custers, M., Balancing Acts - Comparing Political and Cultural Unification and Persistence in the Roman Empire during the Principate and the Western Han Empire. Master Thesis Comparative History, Utrecht University. Oct, 2008. 101 Davids, K, “Shifts of Technological Leadership in Early Modern Europe.” A Miracle Mirrored. Eds. K. Davids and J. Lucassen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996. pp. 338-366. Derry, T. et.al. A Short History of Technology. New York: Dover Publications, 1993. Douglas, R. Liquidation of Empire: The Decline of the British Empire. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2002. Duggan, C. A Concise History of Italy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994. Elbaum, B. and W. Lazonick. The Decline of the British Economy. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986. Epstein, S.R. “Cities, Regions and the Late Medieval Crisis: Sicily and Tuscany Compared.” Past and Present, Vol. 130 (1991), pp. 3-50. Federico, G. and P. Malanima. “Progress, Decline, Growth: Product and Productivity in Italian Agriculture, 1000-2000.” Economic History Review, Vol. 57 (2004), pp. 437-464. Fei, J. and G. Ranis. Growth and Development from an Evolutionary Perspective. Oxford: Blackwell, 1999. Friedberg, A. The Weary Titan. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1988. Friedman, T. The World Is Flat. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2005. Hall, P.A. “The State and Economic decline.” The Decline of the British Economy. Eds. Bernard Elbaum and William Lazonick. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986. pp. 266-302. Hess, A. “The Ottoman Conquest of Egypt (1517) and the Beginning of the SixteenthCentury World War.” International Journal of Middle East Studies, Vol. 4, No. 1 (Jan, 1973), pp. 55-76. Israel, J. Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 1585-1740. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1989. Jones, G. The State and Emergence of the British Oil Industry. New York: Macmillan, 1980. Jones, P.D. “The Evolution of Climate over the Last Millennium.” Science, Vol. 292, No. 27 (April 2001), pp. 662-667. Kennedy, P. The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. New York: Vintage Books, 1989. Kirby, M.W., “Institutional Rigidities and Economic Decline: Reflections on the British Experience.” Economic History Review, Vol. 45, No. 4 (Nov., 1992), pp. 637-660. 102 Kolchin, P. “Comparing American History.” Reviews in American History, Vol. 10, No. 4 (Dec., 1982), pp. 64-81. Kossmann, E.H. “Some Meditations on Dutch 18th Century Decline.” Failed Transitions to Modern Industrial Society: Renaissance Italy and Seventeenth Century Holland. Eds. F. Krantz and P. Hohenberg. Quebec: Interuniversity Centre for European Studies, 1975. pp. 44-48. Kuznets, S. Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure, and Spread. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1966. Lane, F. Navires et constructeurs à Venise pendant la Renaissance. Paris: S.E.V.P.E.N., 1965. Lopez, R.S and H.A. Miskimin. “The Economic Depression of the Renaissance.” The Economic History Review, Vol. 14, No. 3 (1962), pp. 408-426. Ma, D. “Why Japan, not China, was the First to Develop in East Asia: Lessons from Sericulture, 1850-1937.” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 52, No. 2 (Jan., 2004), pp. 369-394. Maddison, A. et.al. The World Economy: a Millennial Perspective. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation & Development, 2001. Maddison, A. Explaining the Economic Performance of Nations: Essays in Time and Space. Aldershot: Elgar, 1995. Mahoney J. and Rueschemeyer, D. Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002. Malanima, P. “Measuring the Italian Economy. 1300-1861”. Rivista di Storia Economica, Vol. 19, No. 3 (2003), pp. 265-295. Malanima, P. “Teoria economica regionale e storia: il caso della Toscana. ” Lo Sviluppo Economico Regionale in Prospettiva Storica. Ed. Mocarelli, L. Milan: C.U.E.S.P, 1996. pp. 133-45. Malanima, P. La Decadenzz di un’Economia Cittadina, l’Industria di Firenze nei Secoli XVI-XVIII. Bologna : Mulino, 1982. Malanima, P. “Urbanisation and the Italian Economy During the Last Millennium.” European Review of Economic History, Vol. 9, No. 1 (2005), pp. 97-122. Malanima, P. “The Energy Basis for Early Modern Growth, 1650-1820.” Early Modern Capitalism. Economic and social change in Europe, 1400-1800. Ed. M. Prak. London: Routledge, 2001. pp. 51-68. McBeth, B. British Oil Policy, 1919-1939. London: F. Cass, 1985. 103 Mokyr, J. The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1992. Moore, B. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Boston: Beacon Press, 1993. O’Brien, P. “Mercantilism and Imperialism in the Rise and Decline of the Dutch and British Economies, 1585-1815.” De Economist, Vol. 148, No. 4 (Oct., 2000), pp. 469–501. Olson, M. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1982. Ormrod, D. “Dutch commercial and industrial decline.” Failed Transitions to Modern Industrial Society: Renaissance Italy and seventeenth century Holland. Eds. F. Krantz, and P. Hohenberg. Quebec: Interuniversity Centre for European Studies, 1975. pp. 36-44. O’Rourke, K. and G. Jeffrey. Globalization and History. Cambridge: MIT Press, 2001. Pamuk, S. “The Black Death and the origins of the ‘Great Divergence’ across Europe, 1300–1600.” European Review of Economic History, Vol. 11, (2007), pp. 289–317. Pomeranz, K. The Great Divergence. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001. Pryor, J. Geography, Technology and War. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992. Ragin, C. The Comparative Method. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1987. Sella, D. “The Two faces of the Lombard Economy in the Seventeenth Century.” Failed Transitions to Modern Industrial Society: Renaissance Italy and seventeenth century Holland. Eds. F. Krantz, and P. Hohenberg. Quebec: Interuniversity Centre for European Studies, 1975. pp. 11-15. Skocpol, Theda. States and Social Revolutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979. Skocpol, Theda. Protecting Soldiers and Mothers. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1995. Smil, V. Energy in World History. Boulder: Westview Press, 1994. Snook, J. Ice Age Extinction. New York: Algora Publishing, 2006. Stiglitz, J. Making Globalization Work. New York: W. W. Norton & Co, 2006. 104 Swart, K.W. “Holland’s Bourgeoisie and the Retarded Industrialization of the Netherlands.” Failed Transitions to Modern Industrial Society: Renaissance Italy and seventeenth century Holland. Eds. F. Krantz, and P. Hohenberg. Quebec: Interuniversity Centre for European Studies, 1975. pp. 44-48. Tilly, C. and G. Ardant. The Formation of National States in Western Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975. Tol, R. “A Concise History of Riverine Floods and Flood Management in the Dutch Rhine Delta.” Climate, Change and Risk. Eds. T. Downing and A. Olsthoorn. London: Routledge, 1999. pp. 162-172. De, Vries, J. European Urbanization, 1500-1800. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1984. De Vries, J. Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1976. De Vries, J., and A. Woude. The First Modern Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997. White, L. Medieval Technology and Social Change. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1964. Wong, R.B. China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1997. Wrigley, E.A. Continuity, Chance and Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988. Van Bath, B. S., Faber, J.A., Roessingh, H. K., Van der Woude, A. M., and van Xanten, H. J., "Population Changes and Economic Developments in the Netherlands: A Historical Survey," A. A. G. Bijdragen, XII (I965), 47-II0. Van Bavel, B., and J.L. Van Zanden. “The Jump-Start of the Holland Economy during the late-Medieval Crisis, c.1350-1500.” Economic History Review, Vol. 57, No. 3 (2004), pp. 503–532. Van Zanden, J.L. The Rise and Decline of Holland’s economy. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1993. Van Zanden, J.L. “Early Modern Economic Growth: A Survey of the European Economy, 1500-1800.” Early Modern Capitalism. Economic and social change in Europe, 1400-1800. Ed. M. Prak, Routledge, 2001. pp. 69-87. Zhang, D. “Global Climate Change, War and Population in Recent Human History.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America. Ed. Ehrlich, P. Stanford: Stanford University, 2007. 105