Recall the previous model, (Basic model, perfectly competitive model, introductory model): ο· ο· ο· ο· All market participants are price takers: Neither firms nor workers have pricing power, the power to set prices different from the equilibrium price without incurring costs that push firms/workers back to the equilibrium price. Product homogeneity: All workers offer identical knowledge, skills, and abilities; one worker is a perfect substitute for any other. No transactions costs or taxes: Firms can costlessly search for and replace workers. Workers can costlessly search for and replace employers. Government does not tax/subsidize firms’ or workers’ search efforts or employment changes. Profit maximization/Utility Maximization: Firms maximize profits by producing product where marginal cost equals marginal revenue and selling at a price equal to marginal cost. Workers maximize utility as a function of wages and leisure. Wage rate Supply w* Demand Q* Quantity The above illustrates the market-wide supply of and demand for labor. Let us now examine the labor market from an individual firm perspective. First, we need to note an assumption about firm behavior; firms maximize profits by producing a level of output which equates marginal revenue with marginal cost. Marginal revenue is the additional revenue earned for producing one more unit of output. Marginal cost is the additional cost incurred for producing one more unit of output. A firm maximizes profit by setting output level where: ππππππππ π ππ£πππ’π = ππππππππ πΆππ π‘ This is easy to illustrate; Mankiw’s example of milk production: In the above illustration, note that total costs are a function of fixed plus variable costs and that revenue is generated by fixed and variable inputs. Fixed inputs are the farm land, the barns, etc. Variable inputs are the workers. Further note that each additional worker generates less additional revenue than the previously hired worker. This is also easy to illustrate: Imagine that you are a dairy farmer and that you own one cow. If you hire one worker to milk the cow then your revenues will increase from $0 to $100. If you hire two workers then your revenue will increase above $100, but it won’t increase as much as it did by hiring that first worker. Say that revenue increases by $50 for a total revenue of $150. The second worker is productive and just as good as the first worker, but the first worker and the second worker will sometimes bump into each other, talk to each other instead of working, whatever. If you hire five workers to milk one cow then you have chaos. Ten hands are too many to milk one cow. That fifth worker is just sitting around and not producing much additional revenue. Wage rate Marginal Revenue Product of Labor Quantity The MRPL is downward sloping. As the firm hires more workers at decreasing wage rates, the revenue generated by each additional worker declines. Recall that the firm will maximize profits and that to do so requires setting marginal costs to marginal revenue. What does the marginal cost curve look like for an individual firm? If a firm is a price-taker, as assumed in a perfectly competitive market, then the labor cost curve is flat (and not upward sloping as in the market as a whole). If a firm pays below the market wage, then no one will work for the firm. And of course firms will never pay more than the prevailing market wage. Wage rate Labor Supply w* Marginal Revenue Product of Labor Quantity Now we will diverge from the ‘basic’ model and examine an ‘advanced’ model. One is not really more ‘advanced’ than the other; I use these terms for pedagogical reasons. In the perfectly competitive model, we assume that all firms are price-takers. Now we will relax this assumption and assume that firm hiring practices actually affect the wages that they are forced to pay—monopsony firms If firms’ hiring additional workers leads to an increase in the wage rate that they must pay, then the labor supply curve from an individual firm’s perspective is upward sloping, just as it appears in the market-wide labor model. Wage rate Labor Supply Marginal Revenue Product of Labor Quantity Further note that if a firm pays every worker the same wage, then each additional worker hired increases the total wages that have to be paid to every worker. If a firm hires ten workers at $10 each, then total wages equal $100. A monopsony firm hires an eleventh worker and since the supply curve is upward sloping for monopsony firms then the firm has to pay more for that worker, say $11. The firm has to pay every worker $11 instead of $10, which means that total wages jump to $121 instead of $111 if we could confine the pay increase to simply the last worker hired. This implies that the marginal cost curve for monopsony firms is strictly to the left and more upward sloping than that labor supply curve. Marginal Cost of Labor Wage rate Labor Supply Marginal Revenue Product of Labor Quantity Note that the equilibrium quantity of labor in the competitive market place where firms are price takers is higher that the equilibrium quantity in the monopsony market where firms’ hiring decisions affect the labor market. Marginal Cost of Labor Wage rate Labor Supply Marginal Revenue Product of Labor Qm Qc Quantity Note that Qm <Qc, so monopsony firms hire at a level that is strictly lower than labor is willing to supply. If monopsony conditions are in effect, then a minimum wage can possibly improve the employment outcome. Marginal Cost of Labor Wage rate wmin Labor Supply wc wm Marginal Revenue Product of Labor Qm Qmin Qc Quantity Wc is the wage rate that would prevail if the market were perfectly competitive. Wm is the wage rate that would prevail if the market were populated by monopsony firms. Wmin is a minimum wage rate established by the government. Note that Wmin > Wc > Wm. Qc is the quantity of labor employed if competitive market conditions exist. Qm is the quantity of labor employed if monopsony conditions exist. Qmin is the quantity of labor employed if the government imposes a minimum wage. Note that Qmin > Qm.