New Ways to Understand the Impact of Stock-outs (Julie Holland Mortimer and Christopher T. Conlon) Presented by: Julie Holland Mortimer Associate Professor Economics Department Harvard University Introduction: Economists have devoted a lot of energy to understanding demand in different industries. We can tell you all kinds of things about aggregate demand, especially for manufacturing. For example: we were very good at predicting which cars people would switch to when GM discontinued the Oldsmobile brand, using only data on national market shares. But believe it or not, we almost never pay attention to availability. Why has availability been ignored? • Previous work focused on manufacturing, not retail or distribution. • Data on availability was pretty scarce until relatively recently. • Many people thought of availability as a small "friction" but not a main focus of firms. When does "full availability" fail? • • • • Stock-outs Capacity constraints Search costs Awareness What goes wrong by ignoring availability? An example: • We stock 5 units of product A and 10 units of product B each week. • Product A sells out immediately. • Consumers that arrive looking for product A choose B instead, and B sells 10 units by the end of the week. • When we look at aggregate sales we get the story wrong. B appears to be more popular, but the product that truly sells is A. So sales data don't reflect true demand patterns. This gives two kinds of errors: • Censoring: We only observe demand up to capacity. This understates demand for the stocked-out product. • Forced Substitution: We observe sales for products that represent consumers' second choices as they substitute away from missing goods. This overstates demand for remaining products. Bad demand estimates lead to bad predictions about profitability. • Some consumers may walk away when a product is stocked-out. • Many others may simply purchase a different product. • Effect on profitability depends on this behavior, and on the margins of the different products. • The effects might be different in the short-run than in the long-run. Research goals: Incorporate availability in demand estimation, and estimate its impact for firms. • • • • Test the impact of stock-outs in the field. Quantify the impact of stock-outs on profitability. Develop a method to handle stock-outs, even with incomplete data reporting. Quantify the size of the error from ignoring the problem. Future goal: How can firms use wireless data to optimize restocking visits? (We need to understand the impact of stock-outs first.) Why vending? (I started in video rentals....) • • • Great data for identifying stock-out events. Some aspects of supply are relatively straightforward (e.g., pricing). Feasible laboratory for field experiments. Other settings: retail, perishable and seasonal goods, sporting/entertainment events, airlines, etc. Outline: • • • • • • Describe field experiments on availability Results from field experiments Impact of stock outs on profitability in experiments Preliminary model of consumer decisions Results from the model Comparison of the model results to the field experiments • Implications for vending operators and lessons for economists Description of Field Experiments Field experiments implemented by Mark Vend Company in Chicago, Illinois. • A total of 62 machines in office buildings in downtown Chicago • Spread across 5 sites/locations • “White collar” customer base • Fairly stable demand patterns over time at these sites/machines Experimental design: • 8 experiments were run (2 were repeated for accuracy) • 6 experiments stocked out a single product • 2 experiments stocked out two products simultaneously The 8 experiments: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. Snickers Zoo Animal Crackers Dorito Nacho Cheetos Chocolate Chip Famous Amos M&M Peanut Dorito Nacho and Cheetos Snickers and M&M Peanut More on the experimental design: • For each run, we removed the focal product(s) for about 2.5 weeks • Each machine is visited about 3 times during the experiment • Data were collected from January, 2006 – February, 2009 • Experimental dates range from June 2007 to September 2008 • Experiments were run during the months of May – October (one in February, 2008) Data detail: • DEX data collected at each service visit for each product/machine • Few stock-outs occur outside of the experiments Small products are consolidated into “generic” category products for reporting. Example: 3-Musketeers (Reg., Dk Chc Mint) Heavenly Dark (Plain, Almond) Reeses (PB Cup, Pieces) Hershey (Almond, Take Five) Raisinets Butterfinger (Reg., Crisp) Heath Bar M&M (PB, Crunchy M-Azing) Cadbury (Milk, Caramello) Milky Way (Reg., Midnight) Nestle Crunch Rolo Peanut Butter Twix “Generic Candy Chocolate” Finding a baseline for comparison: • We compare each visit during the experimental periods to several “control visits.” • The control visits come from the same set of machines at other times. • We “match” each experimental visit to four control visits of similar length (adjusting for weekends). • In order to find a good “match” we use control visits with similar rates of sales for “non-substitutes.” Example of how we make a match: • The focal product is Snickers, so all Snickers bars are removed during the experiment. • To make a “match” we look at the rate of sales of salty snack products. • We find visits during the control period in which sales of Doritos, Ruffles, and Cheetos are the same as the sales of Doritos, Ruffles, and Cheetos during the experimental period. Calculating the effect of a stockout: • A stockout changes the rate of sales of substitute products. • Compare rates during the experimental periods to rates during control periods. There is one thing we can’t observe directly (at least without a video camera and approval from the Government): consumers “walking away” • But we can estimate this from the change in rate of total vends. • Economists call this the “outside good.” An example of the data, from Experiment 1: Product Category Generic Candy Chocolate M&M Milk Chocolate M&M Peanut Snickers Twix Caramel Candy Chocolate Total Generic Candy Non Chocolate Candy Non Chocolate Total Choc Chip Famous Amos Choc SandFamous Amos Generic Cookie Grandmas Choc Chip Rasbry Knotts Zoo Animal Cracker Austin Cookie Total Generic Other Kar Sweet & Salty Mix Other Total Generic Pastry Strwbry Pop-Tarts Pastry Total Cheeto LSS Dorito Nacho LSS Frito LSS Generic Salty Snack Hot Stuff Jays Original LSS Ruffles Smartfood LSS Sun Chip LSS Salty Snack Total Total Candy Chocolate Candy Chocolate Candy Chocolate Candy Chocolate Candy Chocolate Candy Chocolate Candy Non Chocolate Candy Non Chocolate Cookie Cookie Cookie Cookie Cookie Cookie Cookie Other Other Other Pastry Pastry Pastry Salty Snack Salty Snack Salty Snack Salty Snack Salty Snack Salty Snack Salty Snack Salty Snack Salty Snack Experimental Period Control Period Visits Sales S.D. Visits Sales S.D. ExpRate Rate Cntl 223 1.20 1.45 954 0.97 1.17 0.23 107 0.27 0.87 579 0.26 0.63 0.01 268 1.44 1.17 1076 0.92 0.84 0.52 270 0.00 0.00 1069 0.83 0.77 -0.83 218 0.75 0.78 866 0.50 0.69 0.24 270 3.66 2.61 1080 3.48 2.57 0.18 244 0.48 0.84 1009 0.63 0.97 -0.14 244 0.48 0.84 1009 0.63 0.97 -0.14 270 0.53 0.60 1070 0.45 0.56 0.08 91 0.12 0.55 452 0.09 0.39 0.02 253 0.48 0.65 1050 0.45 0.63 0.02 208 0.23 0.37 803 0.22 0.43 0.00 204 0.15 0.36 842 0.15 0.33 0.00 270 0.79 0.94 1078 0.52 0.62 0.28 270 2.29 1.57 1080 1.89 1.56 0.40 270 1.35 1.31 1080 1.45 1.38 -0.10 170 0.33 0.63 674 0.26 0.56 0.06 270 1.68 1.54 1080 1.71 1.58 -0.04 68 0.06 0.43 471 0.10 0.58 -0.04 244 0.36 0.48 960 0.36 0.59 0.00 257 0.42 0.52 1013 0.46 0.68 -0.04 264 0.73 0.81 1059 0.72 0.66 0.01 270 0.54 0.58 1079 0.55 0.52 -0.01 217 0.41 0.68 806 0.39 0.61 0.02 270 4.37 3.42 1080 4.19 2.68 0.19 235 0.22 0.38 879 0.21 0.38 0.01 244 0.61 0.72 933 0.57 0.66 0.03 131 0.19 0.48 655 0.19 0.43 0.01 247 0.49 0.53 967 0.44 0.49 0.06 270 7.57 5.17 1080 7.25 4.21 0.31 270 16.09 9.40 1080 15.41 9.03 0.68 Sig. (1%) ** ** ** ** ** ** Identifying the best substitutes: • There is always noise in sales rates, so we look at products with a statistically significant increase in sales. • Call these products “substitutes.” Identifying “walkers”: • The experiments show no change in total vends, implying no “walkers”. • We calculate the impact of the stock-out under two scenarios: – Assume there really are no walkers (May be OK in the short-run). – Assume that some percentage of people walk away when their favorite product is stocked-out. – Estimate the percentage that walk away for each product from a model of consumer choice, which examines how total vends fall when a product is not carried in a machine. Modeling “walkers”: • • • • Use the maximum rate of sales at any machine for a visit. This allows for slower sales rates at Christmas, for example. Assumes that no machine beats your busiest machine. Under this assumption, model consumer choice during control periods to see how total sales respond when various products are not stocked. (This includes responses from machines that have different facings, in addition to stock-out events.) Results (for these machines/locations): • Consumers of salty snacks rarely walk away (1%). • Consumers of cookies walk away more often (11-12%). • Consumers of chocolate bars walk away most often (20%). Alternatives: • See how your own machines respond and use that to deflate. • More data collection (use pressure pads or video cameras). • Best method may vary based on machine location (public, office, school). Where do Snickers consumers go, under the two scenarios? What is the impact on the sales of Snickers substitutes? The impact on profitability depends on: • The number of “walkers” • The margins on Snickers and all its substitutes For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 827 sales of Snickers @ $0.24 margin (-$202.43). – We gain 827 sales of substitutes @ $0.30 avg. margin ($242.57). – The net effect is $40.14. • Scenario 2 (20% walkers): – We lose 827 sales of Snickers @ $0.24 margin (-$202.43). – We gain 664 sales of substitutes @ $0.30 avg. margin ($194.67). – The net effect is $-7.76. In this case: • The higher margin on substitutes (esp. cookie products) means that the stock-out may actually be profitable (depending on “walkers”). • At least, in the short run. • Longer-run effects, if clients get upset over time, aren’t captured here. Results from All Experiments, No Walkers Effects on Sales of Substitutes, No Walkers Effects on Profitability Snickers: For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 827 sales of Snickers @ $0.24 margin (-$202.43). – We gain 827 sales of substitutes @ $0.30 avg. margin ($242.57). – The net effect is $40.14. • Scenario 2 (20% walkers): – We lose 827 sales of Snickers @ $0.24 margin (-$202.43). – We gain 664 sales of substitutes @ $0.30 avg. margin ($194.67). – The net effect is $-7.76. Animal Crackers: For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 383 sales of Animal Crackers @ $0.43 margin (-$166.79). – We gain 383 sales of substitutes @ $0.34 avg. margin ($129.36). – The net effect is -$37.43. • Scenario 2 (11.5% walkers): – We lose 383 sales of Animal Crackers @ $0.43 margin (-$166.79). – We gain 339 sales of substitutes @ $0.34 avg. margin ($114.46). – The net effect is -$52.33. Dorito Nachos: For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 451 sales of Doritos @ $0.44 margin (-$197.02). – We gain 451 sales of substitutes @ $0.40 avg. margin ($179.05). – The net effect is $-17.97. • Scenario 2 (1% walkers): – We lose 451 sales of Doritos @ $0.44 margin (-$197.02). – We gain 447 sales of substitutes @ $0.40 avg. margin ($177.53). – The net effect is $-19.50. Cheetos: For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 568 sales of Cheetos @ $0.44 margin (-$252.30). – We gain 568 sales of substitutes @ $0.43 avg. margin ($244.29). – The net effect is $-8.01. • Scenario 2 (1% walkers): – We lose 568 sales of Cheetos @ $0.44 margin (-$252.30). – We gain 563 sales of substitutes @ $0.43 avg. margin ($242.20). – The net effect is $-10.11. Chocolate Chip Famous Amos: For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 363 sales of Famous Amos @ $0.47 margin (-$170.84). – We gain 363 sales of substitutes @ $0.46 avg. margin ($167.07). – The net effect is $-3.76. • Scenario 2 (11% walkers): – We lose 363 sales of Famous Amos @ $0.47 margin (-$170.84). – We gain 322 sales of substitutes @ $0.46 avg. margin ($148.07). – The net effect is $-22.77. M&M Peanut: For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 517 sales of M&M Peanut @ $0.24 margin (-$124.52). – We gain 517 sales of substitutes @ $0.34 avg. margin ($174.11). – The net effect is $49.59. • Scenario 2 (20% walkers): – We lose 517 sales of M&M Peanut @ $0.24 margin (-$124.52). – We gain 414 sales of substitutes @ $0.34 avg. margin ($139.61). – The net effect is $15.10. Dorito Nachos and Cheetos: For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 1019 sales of Doritos and Cheetos @ $0.44 margin (-$444.48). – We gain 1019 sales of substitutes @ $0.44 avg. margin ($444.48). – The net effect is $0. • Scenario 2 (1% walkers): – We lose 1019 sales of Doritos and Cheetos @ $0.24 margin (-$444.48). – We gain 1010 sales of substitutes @ $0.44 avg. margin ($440.49). – The net effect is $-3.99. M&M Peanut and Snickers: For the two scenarios, we have the following impact: • Scenario 1 (no walkers): – We lose 1344 sales of both products @ $0.24 margin (-$322.56). – We gain 1344 sales of substitutes @ $0.29 avg. margin ($388.80). – The net effect is $66.24 • Scenario 2 (21% walkers): – We lose 1344 sales of both products @ $0.24 margin (-$322.56). – We gain 1057 sales of substitutes @ $0.29 avg. margin ($305.89). – The net effect is $-16.67. Model of Consumer Decisions Model of Consumer Decisions • We generally don’t get the chance to run experiments, so we do our best with “observational” data. • We think of a consumer buying 1 unit. • She chooses the product that makes her the happiest, given her choice set. • Each product has an “average quality,” and people have “idiosyncratic” tastes for different products. • There are a few common models; a simple one assumes that a consumer’s tastes for products are similar within a category. Consumer Decision Tree No Purchase Pastry Chocolate Purchase Salty Snack Strawberry Pop-Tart Snickers Dorito Nacho LSS Generic Pastry M&M Peanut Candy Cookie Other Choc Chip Famous Amos Kar Sweet & Salty Mix Cheeto LSS Zoo Animal Cracker Austin Generic Other Twix Caramel Sun Chip LSS Grandmas Choc Chip M&M Milk Chocolate Original LSS Ruffles Raspberry Knotts Generic Candy Chocolate Hot Stuff Jays Choc Sand Famous Amos Frito LSS Generic Cookie Smartfood LSS Generic Salty Snack Generic Candy Non Chocolate How does the model interpret sales data? • Products with more sales overall get higher “average quality” (more people choose these products). • When different products are stocked at different machines or time periods, we observe that people’s choices are different. Stock-out events and price changes give similar information. • The difference in these choices tells us about consumers’ tastes for different products. • We need to assume that consumer populations are similar across machines/time (both in tastes, and rates of arrival). • The model predicts “walkers” from choices of the “outside good.” (When a product isn’t stocked, total sales are lower.) Differences in the Baseline Data • In these results, we show substitution for different products from a single version of the model. • This version uses the entire set of potential “match” visits (January 2006 – February 2009). • Thus, the results don’t account for differences in the baseline data across experiments due to matching. • Example: suppose one experiment is run in August, when many people are on vacation, and vend rates are lower. The experimental results will compare outcomes to other “low” periods, but the baseline model will not. • Next step: estimate the model on the same “matched” data for direct comparison to the experiments. Results from the Model, (Only “Inside Goods”) Comparison of Experiments and the Model • Compare results from the experiments and the model • Assume that “walkers” are as predicted in the model for both experimental results and model predictions • Examine which products people move to, and the effects on substitutes • Current results not yet “apples to apples” because of differences in baseline data Comparison of Which Products People Move To Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Comparison of the Effects on Substitutes Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Experiment / Model Implications for Vending Operators and Lessons for Economists What is the Effect of a Stock Out? • In the experiments, most people buy something else. • The model predicts some “walkers”. This may be more likely in the long-run. • The impact on profits depends on how many people walk away, and on the margins of the focal products and its substitutes. A stock-out may actually be profitable in some cases. • Of course, consumers are a little less happy, and this may be an issue in the long-run. What is NOT the Effect of a Stock Out? • When a product stocks out, the effect on profitability is not the same as losing that product’s rate of sales. • Most consumers buy something else, and firms make a margin on those sales. • The nature of this substitution likely depends on: which other products are stocked in the machine, the type/location of the machine (office, school, public area, etc.), and even the time of day, or day of week. Implications for Operational Decisions • Servicing decisions should depend on the impact of stock outs on profitability. • Restocking machines frequently is costly, so if the impact of stock outs on revenues is not large, it might make sense to restock less frequently. • (Again: short run vs. long run implications!) • Capacity decisions affect stock out probabilities. • Acquiring more information about your own machines depends on data collection. (Wireless?) What might be the role of wireless data? • From an information point of view, wireless data are helpful for understanding the impact of stock outs across different machines, locations, or time periods. • Wireless data can help avoid over-servicing machines that are still relatively full. • They may also help streamline “binning” procedures in the warehouse so that drivers are more efficient. • Overall impact depends on the cost of the service, and the nature of demand at different machines. Lessons for Economists: Do Stock Outs Matter for Demand Estimates? • In related work, we’ve found that ignoring stock-outs can seriously impact demand estimates. • We find: products that frequently stock out are much better sellers than our “standard models” predict. • Allowing for stock-out events corrects this problem. The “sell-out” products are estimated to be more popular, and the “second choice” products less so. More Lessons for Economists: The Effect of Stock Outs on Other Calculations • When demand estimates change, we estimate different effects of many other policies. • Examples: the value of new products, the impact of mergers, and firms’ choices of optimal capacity. • Also, the impact of stock outs for firms and consumers. • This is a broad phenomenon. It’s important in vending, but also in retail, sports events, concert performances, airline pricing, etc.