1 Charter Change – the 2014 Version Rotary Club of Makati Peninsula Hotel, September 30, 2014 By: Christian S. Monsod Thank you for inviting me. I am told to finish in 20-25 minutes. My talk consists of three parts: (1) Previous attempts at charter change and why Joint Resolution No. 1, of which you have a copy, is dangerous and insidious, (2) why foreign investment? (3) Have we really closed the door on FDI? Since 1987, there have been five attempts to revise the Constitution: (1) Ramos – articulated purpose – remove obstacles to reform and growth, including the term limit of the President. Aborted when PIRMA (People’s Initiative for Reform, Modernization and Action) by Ramos allies was struck down by the Supreme Court as unconstitutional. (2) Estrada – articulated purpose – remove obstacles to reform and growth – but limited to changing equity caps on economic provisions. Proposed by CONCORD (Constitutional Correction for Development). Aborted by Estrada himself, when his popularity waned from accusations of corruption. (3) Arroyo early 2000 – change from presidential to parliamentary system, French version – not supported by Arroyo. Died a quiet death. (4) Arroyo (2006)– articulated purpose - good governance and economic growth with major revisions to a parliamentary, federalist system with a unicameral legislation plus changes in economic provisions – Aborted when the SC struck down the Sigaw ng Bayan People’s Initiative, as unconstitutional by an 8-7 vote. The ten appointees of the Arroyo voted 5-for and 5-against – a golden moment in the history of the Supreme Court. (5) Arroyo (2009) – initiative by the House – proposal to make revisions by a joint session with a joint vote, i.e. giving equal vote for congressmen and senators. Supported by Arroyo but withdrawn in the face of widespread opposition including from the Senate. These attempts were unsuccessful because the people perceived the articulated purposes as mere smokescreens for Ramos and Arroyo to stay in power. As for Estrada it was about self-interest on how to make money in public office without calling it corruption. The articulated purpose of the Joint Resolution No 1 is the same as previous attempts – to improve the well-being of our people. Even if Joint Resolution No. 1 is not a smokescreen to remove or circumvent the term limits, it is still a dangerous move because it would give too much power to the Congress and open the door wider to corruption. And it is insidious because it is a bad precedent in trivializing the basic law but is being represented as only 1 2 giving the Congress “flexibility” with an innocuous and seemingly harmless insertion of the phrase “unless otherwise provided by law” in 6 provisions (land, natural resources, public utilities, media, advertising and educational institutions) It is also a clever tactic – it forecloses debate at this time because there are no specific changes being proposed on the foreign equity caps. The only issue on the table is the wholesale insertions. The business community has not expressed any concern about the implications of the insertions. Either business has been disarmed by its innocuousness or as a malicious mind would say - business does not mind transactional politics as long as it is the beneficiary. After all, there are many examples of this in the past – such as the loophole of stock distribution instead of land in agrarian reform that the Supreme Court finally struck down as unconstitutional in the case of Hacienda Luisita by a vote of 14-0 (another golden moment of the Supreme Court) and the loophole in the banking laws that allows an alternative compliance of buying government bonds in lieu of devoting 25% of its portfolio to agricultural development, which is critical to achieving a sustained high and inclusive growth as exemplified by the successful NorthEast Asian countries – Japan, Korea, Taiwan and China. The implication of the insertions is that once the insertions are in place (by a ¾ vote of all the members of the two chambers, voting separately, and by a plebiscite) the present provisions would become meaningless and the insertion would be virtually impossible to undo. Thus, the Congress will have the power to increase the equity caps to, say , 60%, 75% or even 100% or back down again through ordinary legislation, without need of a plebiscite. It does not only create instability on the rules of the game but would also provide the precedent for rendering meaningless any provision of the Constitution by ordinary legislation. Only the majority vote of a quorum is necessary. For example, in the case of the Senate, the vote can be as low as 7 senators compared to the present requirement of 18, In the House of 290 members, the equivalent number would be 73 instead of 218. Can we trust our legislators with a power that is so vulnerable to abuse and corruption? With respect to the economic provisions, or for that matter the provisions on territory or on social justice, the foreign companies and foreign countries who want to change them have the money to make it happen. Do our legislators have the values to resist the temptation? The country example is China with deals familiar to us - the ZTE and railway projects, the Chinese management control of our national grid, the aborted Arroyo deal to lease Chinese companies more than 1 million hectares for food production to be totally exported to China. That deal is actually unconstitutional under Section 3 of Article XII, which is one of the provisions targeted for an insertion. Finally, JR-1 is potentially a divisive and costly exercise. Of course it can be stopped if the Senate does not come up with 18 votes. After all, JR-1 reduces the Senate’s power in the system of checks and balances of a bicameral legislature.. 2 3 But if that vote is somehow secured, then the plebiscite can be tumultuous once people realize its implications. And it will cost us precious time and opportunity to attend to more urgent matters. Why foreign Investment? The justification for FDI is that restrictions on foreign ownership stifles the investment climate resulting in lost employment and growth opportunities, and that such restrictions are anti-poor. (Now, that is hypocritical. The truth is closer to what Prof. Emeritus Michael Meyer of Wharton had the grace to admit in an article in yesterday’s BusinessWorld – that the “ethos of capitalism is you operate for your shareholders rather than for the whole people”.) The argument for opening our doors fully to FDI is that any investment is worth attracting because “at least they contribute something” and “everything helps”. I beg to disagree. The empirical evidence is clear – FDI has a role to play in development but it is not the game changer on development that it is made out to be. What counts is not the quantity of investment but its quality. And to determine quality, we need to make a full accounting not just of its benefits but also of its costs. And take account of such long-term considerations as brownfield vs greenfield investment, about its contribution to raising the trajectory of our technological development, about downstream plants that increase the value added in the country. The classic case in this regard is mining, which we can discuss some other time. It is no longer debatable in economic theory that a sustained high growth rate is necessary for poverty alleviation and that growth does not result in development without an equitable distribution of its benefits. The issue on inequality is now a major one even in developed countries. In the matter of the role of FDI role in development, these are some findings: (1) macro-level data may show an association between foreign direct investment and higher levels of income, but they do not establish causality. Similarly no generalization can be made between the activities of foreign firms and income distribution. (2) On a micro- or project level, a majority had positive effects on national income but a sizeable minority 1/3 in two studies and anywhere from 25% and 45% in a third study had deleterious effects. (3) Historically, FDI played only a minor role in the growth of highperforming Asian Economies. From 1966-1986 – their fast growth period - FDI was more than 5% of total GDI only in Hongkong, Malaysia and Singapore. Countries where FDI is less than 2% of GDI were Taiwan, Korea, Japan and China. More recently, except for China and Singapore, FDI in NE-Asia and SE-Asia have been less than 10% of GDI. (4) The Factors that Affect Investment decision according to the World Investment Report and others are: 3 4 a) Adequate infrastructure b) Skill levels (human capital) c) Quality of the general regulatory framework d) Clear Rules of the Game e) Fiscal determination f) Graft and corruption The World Bank (and the IMF) does not put lifting (constitutional/legal) restrictions on reserved areas as a priority condition to attract FDI. They know that it is a fact of life in all developing countries as it was a fact of life when the developed countries were themselves developing. Have we closed the door to FDI? What is the Philippine situation on the restrictions especially on land, natural resources and public utilities ? (1) On land – Leases are allowed up to 50 years, with another 25 years on public land; condominium laws allow ownership of residences. The favorite destinations now in our part of the world - China, Indonesia and Vietnam have similar restrictions on land with the same solution – lease and yet get more FDIs. Actually any project that relies on the windfall on land for its viability is not a good project. But there is a more important dimension to land in our culture. Unlike in the United States and Europe where land is just another economic commodity, and because of the history of colonization and historical injustices related to land, land is not just an economic commodity, it is a social asset. We cannot talk about land rights in the context of western culture and western legal maxims because to the poor land embodies their emancipation into mainstream society. Hence, social justice and agrarian reform. Even the Chambers of Commerce seem to understand a bit of it by admitting that lifting land restrictions may raise land prices beyond the reach of the poor. Those who argue for equal ownership rights to a foreigner on the ground that he cannot bring land out of the country, just don’t get it and should be summarily shipped out instead. (2) On public utilities - by a valid re-definition of an industry. Under the EPIRA (electric power industry reform act), only the natural monopolies are public utilities, i,e, transmission and distribution. Power generation and retailing can be 100% foreign-owned. Our problem today is generating capacity and the Constitution has no ownership restriction in that business, why then are foreign interests not investing? (3) On natural resources – minerals, petroleum, other mineral oils. The Constitution allows FTAA (financial and technical assistance agreement ) to be a 100% foreign-owned company 4 5 with management of the operations, thanks to a liberal interpretation of the provision in the La Bugal SC decision. (4) Media – the issue of content has been overtaken by technological developments and globalization, i.e. cable tv, internet, social networking, annexes in local papers of articles in foreign newspaper. (5) Advertising – the separation of creative work from the advertising function in partnerships appears to be a workable compliance with the Constitution. (6) On control – foreign equity with 40% or less ownership can be protected by super-majority votes on key decisions; (7) For foreign investors interested only in the financial returns, there are innovative financial instruments like the global depositary receipt (GDR) that separate financial benefits (which goes to the investor) from voting rights (which goes to a Filipino company who is interested in management control). (8) Educational institutions – I do not understand why this is included since this is not an economic provision. Besides, the Constitution allows exceptions like fully foreign-owned schools for the diplomatic community and transient foreigners, and mission schools. Many schools have foreign partners. But surely our legislators know that the content of education is part of the patrimony of the country – our history, cultural roots, our values, patriotism, the heroism of our ancestors, the EDSA event that is already being subjected to revisionism – these cannot be left for foreigners to interpret. The headline today in one newspaper about ISIS recruiting from our schools in Mindanao is another reason why our educational institutions should be firmly under Filipino control. (9) An insertion in Article XII, Section 10. I do not understand the sense of including it for insertion because that provision gives the Congress the power to add to the list of restricted activities (the so-called Negative List). To summarize: Previous attempts to revise the Constitution have failed because the articulated purposes were perceived as smokescreens for the real purpose – to stay in power beyond the term limits prescribed by the Constitution. Joint Resolution No. 1 articulates the same objectives of growth and the well-being of the people. It also assumes that foreign direct investment is the game changer towards that objective and that our Constitution has closed the door to FDI. Both these assumptions are not borne out by the facts. 5 6 Even if JR No. 1 is not a smokescreen to stay in power, it is a dangerous and insidious attempt by the Congress to transfer power from the Constitution to itself by the wholesale insertion of “unless otherwise provided by law”. If enacted, it means that the Congress has the power to change the restrictions by ordinary legislation and opens wider the door to corruption. More important it is a bad precedent in putting any provision of the Constitution at risk for selfserving purposes. Moreover, there appears to be no compelling case for lifting the restrictions. Even the House appears to agree with the lack of urgency -- the target date, and only for the wholesale insertion, is 2016, which will benefit, the good Speaker says, the next administration. Which could mean that the real purpose of the insertion proposal is to test the waters, so to speak. If it succeeds, other proposals could follow. The fact is that foreign investors are in control or in beneficial ownership of their investment, either by express provision of the Constitution (FTAA), an alternative to ownership in using the land (long-term lease), liberal judicial interpretation (La Bugal case), redefinition through legislation (EPIRA), and innovative financial instruments (GDR). In the 2014 Doing Business rankings of the World Bank, the Philippines improved 30 places out of 189 countries from 138 in 2013 to 108 in 2014 without any constitutional changes. With respect to the 2014 OECD rankings on restrictiveness where the Philippines is no. 1, those who say that lifting the constitutional restrictions is urgent to increase our FDI do not mention that China is no. 2, Indonesia no. 5 and Vietnam no. 10 in the restrictive rankings and yet get considerably more FDIs. Is the Constitution the real hindrance in that regard? Those who cite that study as gospel truth should first read the footnotes and the acknowledged limitations of the rankings. What all the foregoing is telling us is that charter change is not the answer to finally address the twin problems of mass poverty (which everybody else has successfully addressed in our part of the world) and of inequality, for two reasons: (1) Amending the Constitution is not likely to open any new doors to FDI because for all intents and purposes, they are already open and that, (2) Amending the Constitution may not even need to be debated if we successfully address all the factors that are the real hindrances to quality FDI. Certainly, JR No. 1 is not the answer to anything. Like previous attempts at charter change, it is just another exercise on the taking and the use of political power for self-serving ends. And that should not be allowed to happen. Thank you. 6 7 7