Market Myopia and Firm Specific Risk: Reexamining the Financial Value of Information Technology Decisions Under Revision, Information Systems Research Anitesh Barua* Deepa Mani** *University of Texas at Austin ** Indian School of Business May 2011 Abstract: Firm-level studies of the financial impacts of Information Technology (IT) events have often focused on announcement period returns based on the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). This approach may have two sets of distinct but related limitations for many classes of IT events. First, the use of announcement period assumes the market is efficient in its assimilation and pricing of all information about the event. However, a firm not be aware of the organizational changes required for success of the IT event, or may not have the incentive to disclose such information for competitive reasons. Either way, we expect many types of IT events to be characterized by low information disclosure, which, along with investor biases, is likely to impede efficient pricing of the IT event by financial markets. Second, event studies in Information Systems (IS) largely rely on CAPM, which considers only systematic risks in the pricing of expected returns on IT assets, and assumes that idiosyncratic or firm-specific risks are eliminated through efficient diversification. Yet one of the foundations of the IS discipline is the notion that IT matters, largely because firms have different capabilities to develop, deploy and manage IT resources to create value. Thus there is a disconnect between a basic theoretical tenet of the IS field and the methodology deployed to assess the value of IT events. We develop a framework involving the maturity of the IT event and the scope of complementary changes to assess the extent of information disclosure and idiosyncratic risk, which, in turn, indicate the suitability of different methodologies to assess financial value of the IT event. We empirically illustrate our approach for the case of large scale IT and IT-enabled outsourcing, and conclude with implications for future IS research. 1. Introduction One stream of firm-level studies of Information Technology (IT) impacts has deployed market-based measures of performance developed from capital market theories (Im et al. 2001; Melville et al. 2004). Such market based models assess the impact of IT “events” on shareholder value by estimating the difference between stock market returns conditional on the event and the unconditional expected returns over the announcement period. This approach assumes that the market efficiently prices the IT event during the announcement period itself. Further, these studies are based on the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), which considers only systematic risks stemming from the macro environment of a firm, but not firm specific or idiosyncratic risks (Bettis 1983; Chatterjee et al. 1998). We posit that depending on the nature of the IT event, there may be serious issues involving the assumption of efficient pricing during the announcement period as well as the exclusion of firm specific risk. Therefore we seek to highlight these potential pitfalls and develop a framework to assess the suitability of various market based assessment approaches for different categories of IT events. The use of change in shareholder wealth associated with the event as a measure of value of the underlying technology investment is appealing for various reasons. Stock prices directly measure shareholder value, reflect several relevant aspects of firm performance such as growth and profitability, and can be easily obtained for all publicly traded firms (Lubatkin and Shrieves 1986). Thus event studies have become an important part of the literature on the business value of IT. They have been used to assess the financial value of investments in innovative IT applications (Dos Santos et al. 1993), Enterprise Resource Planning (ERP) (Ranganathan and Brown 2006), electronic commerce (Subramani and Walden 2001) and CIO appointments (Chatterjee et al. 2001). We draw on the fields of finance and strategy to argue that market based approaches using announcement period returns should be used with caution for a large class of IT events. The announcement period returns method is based on the efficient markets hypothesis (EMH), which posits that at any given time, the stock price of a firm reflects all publicly available information, and, in turn, the collective belief of investors regarding future prospects of the firm. However, for many types of IT events, the market may not have enough information to be efficient during the announcement period. While it may appear that greater disclosure by a firm of its IT capabilities will help reduce its cost of capital and increase its valuation, research in IS (e.g., Clemons 1991; Mata et al. 1995) finds that the extent to which IT confers competitive advantage is a function of its heterogeneity and imperfect mobility. This implies that information disclosure will likely engender competitive parity to an extent not justified by improvement in investor forecasts. This is especially pertinent to information on complementary investments in governance structures or work processes that determine heterogeneity in returns from IT investments (e.g., Brynjolfsson et al. 2002). For example, if a firm has conducted a comprehensive, ex ante cost-benefit analysis of a proposed investment in IT and business processes, a detailed disclosure of such information may have a negative impact in that competitors may act on such information to the detriment of the firm making the announcement. IT events may also involve substantial uncertainty in the realization of benefits. Any downward revision to the ex ante benefits communicated in a detailed announcement will result in an adverse reaction from financial markets, thus providing a disincentive for elaborate market disclosure. As a result, announcements of IT investments typically entail the nature and broad objective of the investment, vendors involved, and a qualitative statement of anticipated benefits. Generally there is no mention of risks, options, managerial capabilities and investments in processes and human capital that may be needed to realize payoffs from the IT investment. Yet another scenario involves a firm undertaking an IT initiative without being aware of the complementary changes required for the successful assimilation of the technology applications (Barua et al. 1996; Brynjolfsson et al. 1996; Zhu 2004; Tanriverdi 2005). In such cases, there will be no disclosure of the critical non-IT facets of the event, making it difficult for the market to assess the likelihood of success within the announcement period. A twin conundrum that limits the applicability of the market models involves their dependence on the CAPM, which incorporates only systematic risks in the pricing of expected returns on assets (Fama and MacBeth 1973), and which assumes that unsystematic, firm specific risks are eliminated through full diversification1. However, theory and research in the field of IS are based on the premise that firms differ in their ability to assimilate technology into their work processes, and that such differential capability is an important source of competitive advantage (Armstrong and Sambamurthy 1999; Bharadwaj 2000; Bhatt and Grover 2005). This argument, often invoked in response to Carr’s (2003) controversial thesis that “IT doesn’t matter”, underscores the point that even though an IT application or innovation may be easily available to most firms today, not all of them will be able to take advantage of such an opportunity due to firm specific differences, engendering significant variance in firm performance. There is also some empirical evidence that IT risk, which is idiosyncratic to the firm, explains variance in firm returns. The IT business value and productivity literature reports abnormally high estimates of returns to IT investments2. Further, Dewan et al. (2007) estimate about 30% of the gross return on IT investment may be explained by the premium associated with IT risk. They also find that IT risk is a significant contributor to firm risk. Thus there is both theoretical and empirical justification as to why firm specific differences (and hence, idiosyncratic risk) matter, and why deployment of methodologies based on CAPM may not be appropriate for many IT events. Despite such theory and evidence, to test the hypothesis that IT investments or decisions matter, IS researchers have often used methodologies for inferring information from stock prices that assume the alternative hypothesis. Thus, while on the one hand, IS theories have touted the idiosyncratic nature of how IT creates value as well as the risk of implementing IT successfully, market value based empirical studies have used variants of the capital asset pricing model that automatically assume that “IT (or any other idiosyncratic factor) doesn’t matter.” We propose a framework to qualitatively assess the market efficiency and idiosyncratic risk of an IT event which is consistent with the foundation of IS research that individual firm capabilities vary, and Systematic risk or the firm’s beta is defined as the ratio of covariance between the returns to the security and those to the market portfolio to variance in returns to the market portfolio. Unsystematic or firm-specific risk is defined as the variance in a security's returns that cannot be explained by movements in the market portfolio. 2 Brynjolfsson and Hitt (1996) find that the average marginal product of IT capital in their sample of firms was 81% while that of non-IT capital was 6.3%. Brynjolfsson et al. (2002) find that an increase of $1 in IT capital stock is associated with an increase of $10–15 in the market valuation of firms. Similarly, Anderson et al. (2003) report IT valuation multiples ranging from 26 to 62. 1 which offers a resolution to the twin challenges posed by the assumptions of efficient markets and idiosyncratic risk. The framework incorporates the maturity and the organizational scope of the IT event. Maturity is the extent to which the technical and organizational nuances of a technology event are wellunderstood and documented (Weiss and Dale 1998). The scope of an IT event comprises complementary changes that are required for the success of the event. For example, ERP implementations will require major changes in business processes, decision rights and incentives to be effective (Jarrar et al. 2000). Our theoretical framework enables us to assess the incompleteness of information disclosure and idiosyncratic risk characterizing an IT event, thereby providing guidance in selecting an appropriate methodology to assess the value of the event. We illustrate the use of the framework with an analysis of the financial value of large scale outsourcing of IT and IT-enabled business functions. We find that the financial market prices these outsourcing announcements inefficiently, resulting in long-term abnormal returns following the implementation of the outsourcing contract and a reversal of some results established in prior research. Further, we find that firm specific factors that influence returns to the outsourcing initiative are a significant contributor to the idiosyncratic risk of the firm. Together, the results emphasize the need to shift from market models to those that include firm characteristics in pricing IT events that are low in maturity and high in the scope of organizational change that they engender. The balance of this article is organized as follows. In section 2, we delineate the theoretical concerns in the use of announcement period returns to assess the financial value of IT events. Section 3 introduces our framework involving the maturity and scope of an IT event to assess the suitability of different methods to estimate the financial value of the event. Section 4 applies our framework to large scale outsourcing initiatives to provide empirical evidence of market myopia and the contribution of firm attributes, which influence long-term returns to the IT event, to the idiosyncratic risk of the firm. Section 6 enumerates implications for research and practice, and section 7 concludes. 2. Challenges to the Use of Short-term Market Performance Measures Event studies are an important part of the literature in management and economics. Their usefulness primarily stems from the assumption that the magnitude of abnormal returns following an organizational event provides an estimate of the impact of the event on shareholder value creation, which, according to many schools of thought, is the most important objective of a publicly traded firm. Several studies in IS (see Table 1) have used announcement period returns to provide evidence of value creation or destruction by strategic decisions in a firm. In doing so, these studies implicitly assume (i) efficient pricing of the decision by financial markets, and (ii) diversification of idiosyncratic risk. However, while prior research in IS has assumed market efficiency and largely estimated the magnitude and direction of announcement returns, event studies have been used in Finance to test market efficiency: “…Systematically nonzero abnormal security returns that persist after a particular type of corporate event are inconsistent with market efficiency. Accordingly, event studies focusing on long-horizons following an event can provide key evidence on market efficiency…” (Kothari and Warner 2004): Tests of market efficiency involve estimation of abnormal returns over longer horizons, typically twelve months or more. Interest in the finance literature in long-horizon studies was spurred by accumulation of evidence inconsistent with the efficient markets hypothesis and the identification of risk factors other than market risk that explained variance in firm returns. Yet, there is little research in IS that examines whether the response of the financial market to IT choices or events is slow, incomplete or even biased. Table 1 summarizes selected articles identified in our review of IS journals3 from 2000 to 2008. These studies involve a range of technology decisions from internal IT investments to externalization of IT assets to appointments to IT leadership positions. All these studies assume market efficiency and consider event periods ranging from one to ten days. They do not analyze long-term returns following the implementation or announcement of the IT event. -----------------------------Insert Table 1 about here -----------------------------We searched for keywords such as “event study”, “financial value”, “market value”, “stock market returns”, “shareholder value”, “information systems” etc. in literature databases such as Business Source Premier (EBSCO), JSTOR, and Science Direct. We identified twenty three papers that were published in major IS journals such as MIS Quarterly, Information Systems Research, Management Science and Journal of Management Information Systems. Twenty two of the sample papers were published between 2001-2008; the exception was DosSantos et al. (1993). 3 2.1 Efficiency of Market pricing The assumption of market efficiency is critical to inferences drawn from short-horizon event studies. However, we argue that this assumption is not particularly suited to the evaluation of complex IT decisions. Research in finance (e.g., Eberhart et al. 2003) distinguishes between various types of information that financial markets respond to - scaled measures of past performance such as book to market ratios, long-term investments such as R&D, and managerial decisions such as stock repurchases. The finance literature also distinguishes between tangible and intangible information. This distinction is described in the finance literature as the difference between explicit measures of past performance such as sales or cash flow information that can be observed from the firm’s accounting statements and the orthogonal component of information about future performance, which is unrelated to past accounting performance (Daniel and Titman 2006). Daniel and Titman (2006) demonstrate that there is no discernible relation between a firm’s future stock returns and tangible performance information. The returns are related to realizations of intangible information. Thus, markets are imprecise in interpreting intangible performance information. Although the finance literature posits a relation between intangible information and long-term abnormal returns, the nebulous definition of intangible information in terms of what it is not limits the ability of the field to explicitly define sources of intangible information At best, Daniel and Titman (2006) conjecture intangible information is related to firms’ growth opportunities. We suggest that large and complex IT decisions are akin to long-term investments. Further, even though IT events are represented by their direct costs when expensed in accounting statements, we argue that the benefits of the IT decision reflect intangible information on future cash flows. This is because many decisions such as governance choices for IT outsourcing or management processes to assimilate new technologies that impact returns to the IT investment are rarely announced formally, engendering important acquisition costs for such information. Further, even if this information were disclosed, financial markets may incur important learning costs in interpreting and in turn, pricing the information. Information acquisition and learning costs incurred in pricing IT events lead to multiple cognitive biases that are well documented in the finance literature (Oler et al. 2008). For instance, the prior hypothesis bias describes the proclivity of investors to make choices based on prior beliefs regarding relationships between investment variables despite evidence to the contrary (Levine 1971; Pruitt 1961). This behavior often leads investors to severe and systematic errors. Similarly, the representativeness bias (Tversky and Kahneman, 1974) reflects the inability of decision makers to accurately assess the representativeness of available information so that the true value of the information in making predictions is unrecognized. The effects may be severe for complex, ambiguous information events that are difficult to interpret (Oler et al. 2008; Daniel and Titman 2006). For example, Zuckerman (2004) finds that both volume and volatility of stocks with “incoherent” market identities are higher because such stocks are more likely to be subject to differences in the interpretive models used to understand material information. Similarly, Zajac and Westphal (2004) find that the efficiency of market reactions to certain corporate practices is contingent on the degree of institutionalization of the practice. They find that stock market reactions to stock repurchase plan announcements dramatically changed from negative in the late seventies, when repurchase plans were largely seen as an indicator of lack of attractive investment prospects for the firms, to positive in the mid eighties, when they were viewed as a means of preventing managers from expending free cash flow on “empire-building projects”. The above biases may be particularly salient to IT investments. For example, investment in ERP systems may result in a lukewarm initial reaction from the market based on several prior failures in ERP implementation or the initial dip in firm productivity due to lack of familiarity with resultant new systems and/or processes. Similarly, since there is mixed evidence regarding operational gains from business process outsourcing (BPO) (Mani et al. 2010), the market may not react significantly to a large BPO announcement. The market may wait for more definitive signals to price the event or correct its price as firms realize major benefits from such investments. 2.2 Idiosyncratic risk Another assumption that is integral to short horizon studies is that of diversification of firm specific risk. We first discuss why this assumption has been challenged in finance and strategy, and then proceed to discuss the implications for the IS discipline. Chatterjee et al. (1999) point out that “investors are not as diversified” as assumed by asset pricing models used to calculate expected returns unconditional on the event. They propose that the concept of risk premium is multivariate comprising macroeconomic, tactical, strategic, and normative risks, and it is dynamic, involving an ongoing interplay between elements of the firm's activities and market forces. Bettis (1983) argues that the incorporation of unsystematic risk in asset pricing models is especially important since the very idiosyncratic risk that the equity markets do not reward lies at the heart of strategic management. In addition to these theoretical arguments, empirical studies also contend that markets care about more than just systematic risk. For instance, Chan, Hamao and Lakonishok (1991) find that earnings and cash flow yield, size, and book to market ratio are significantly correlated with expected returns in the Japanese market. These variables proxy for risks not otherwise accounted for by beta. Bhandari (1988) concludes that “a measure of risk different from beta is required” in evaluating investment performance and estimating the cost of capital of firms. Other studies which find idiosyncratic risks to be important predictors of stock returns include Basu (1983), Brown, Harlow and Tinic (1993), and Merton (1987). The most prominent empirical challenge to the predictive validity of systematic risk comes from Fama and French (1992, 1996). They examine several variables such as size, book to market ratio, leverage and dividend yield, and find that the cross-sectional variation in expected returns of assets is explained by two characteristics – size and book-to-market. Beta, the traditional measure of systematic risk, explains insignificant cross-sectional variation in expected returns once size is taken into account. Consequently, they propose a factor model comprising three risk factors – market risk, as measured by MKT, is long in the market portfolio and short in the risk-free asset, growth risk, as measured by SMB, is long in a portfolio of small capitalization stocks and short in large capitalization stocks, and value risk, as measured by HML, is long in high book-to-market stocks and short in low book-to-market stocks. The Fama and French (1993) three factor model has emerged as the dominant choice of model for estimation of expected returns in the finance literature. More recently, Daniel and Titman (1997) argue that the superior returns to the factors described by Fama and French (1993) are not compensation for factor risk; rather, firms in similar factor portfolios have similar firm characteristics. These characteristics are a component of undiversifiable firm risk, and explain abnormal returns. These arguments are especially pertinent to the pricing of IT events. Heterogeneity in performance of IT investments is often attributed to firm level characteristics including organizational structures, processes and other capabilities that complement the IT investment (Armstrong and Sambamurthy 1999; Brynjolfsson et al. 1996). These firm attributes are an important predictor of volatility in cash flows from the IT investment and hence, an important component of IT risk. Further, the risk associated with large IT decisions, due to the latter’s broad scope and salience to a firm’s strategy and operations, is likely to affect firm risk. The initial failure of Nestle’s ERP project had such an adverse firm-wide impact that an HSBC securities analyst downgraded the stock (Worthen 2002). Similarly, Nike’s operational problems, resulting from the implementation of its supply chain management system, is said to have caused the firm’s stock price to decline by 20% in 2000 (Koch 2004). Dewan et al. (2001) find that (a) about 30% of the gross return on IT investment corresponds to the risk premium associated with IT risk, and (b) IT risk is an important contributor to firm risk. Together, the results suggest that the pricing of IT events must shift from models that consider market risk alone to include idiosyncratic firm characteristics and risk. In the next section, we address these issues and offer a theoretical resolution for the use of performance measures in market value based IS research. 3. Reconciliation of Market Performance Measures with Research in Information Systems We present a theoretical framework to classify IT events in terms of the maturity of the event and the scope of organizational changes required to successfully assimilate the event. We argue that such classification helps us choose the right methods to price or asses the financial value of the event. IT maturity has been studied in terms of the S-shaped adoption curve, which captures how the total number of adopters increases over time. Weiss and Dale (1998) argue that IT risks decrease with longevity. Mature technologies are “easy to use and possess the comforting attributes of consistent performance and predictable life-cycle costs” (Weiss and Dale 1998). A technology’s longevity confers advantages of customer trust and a history of incremental improvements that have resulted in very stable products and services. Organizational learning that accompanies mature technologies also contributes to lower risks of implementation (Boudreau and Rose 2000). When a technology is immature, successful implementation may entail multiple risks such as knowledge of critical success factors or adoption by business partners. While some firms may manage such uncertainty well, others may face significant challenges. If a firm is aware of such challenges, it may not have the incentive to disclose information on such challenges or its potential response to contingencies that may arise. While the maturity of the technology itself may be more of a systematic risk factor, the idiosyncratic risk arises from the variance in the ability of the firm to assimilate a relatively new and unproven technology. Thus with a less mature technology, there is lower information disclosure and higher idiosyncratic risk. The scope or the extent of the effort required to manage the IT event also determines the level of idiosyncratic risk and information disclosure. Barua et al. (1996), Brynjolfsson et al. (1996), Zhu (2004) and Tanriverdi (2005) have argued that successful IT investments need complementary organizational changes that involve strategies, business processes, decision rules, and authority. Some IT decisions such as the adoption of a new supply chain system require major technology and business process changes, not only within the focal firm, but also in partner organizations (Barua et al. 2004).These changes required for IT events, if not properly managed, can lead to significant organizational turmoil, even “jeopardizing the core operations of the implementing organization” (Hong and Kim 2002). The larger the scope of an IT event, the larger is its potential impact on the performance of the firm. As outlined earlier, the firm may not have the incentive to disclose information on such risk at the time of the announcement for competitive reasons. Thus, the greater the investment in complementary organizational capital required to manage an IT initiative, the higher is the idiosyncratic risk, and lower is the information disclosure. Together, the maturity and the organizational scope of the IT event determine the ex ante uncertainty in cash flows from the IT investment and, in turn, the market efficiency in valuing the investment (Figure 1). We discuss four cases below to illustrate our framework: Scope of the IT event Figure 1: IT Event Attributes and Market Efficiency Highest idiosyncratic risk Lowest information disclosure Lowest market efficiency E.g., Large-scale outsourcing of IT services and business processes High idiosyncratic risk Low information disclosure Low market efficiency E.g., Enterprise Resource Planning Medium idiosyncratic risk Medium information disclosure Medium market efficiency E.g., Cloud computing Lowest idiosyncratic risk High information disclosure High market efficiency E.g., Electronic Data Interchange Maturity of the IT event Electronic Data Interchange (EDI) is characterized by high maturity owing to its existence and widespread adoption over nearly three decades (http://www.edi-guide.com/edi-history.htm). Moreover, being a document exchange standard, the adoption of EDI may not require significant complementary changes in the firm and may be easily replicable across firms. Thus, as shown in Figure 1, EDI and other document related standards belong to the category of high maturity-low scope events. As a consequence, this category of IT announcements is likely to be priced efficiently by capital markets. Cloud computing, which is defined as “Internet-based computing [with] shared servers [providing] resources, software, and data to computers and other devices on demand, as with the electricity grid” (http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cloud_computing), is a relatively new mode of technology delivery, which is rapidly evolving along technical and organizational dimensions. Although technical challenges such as data security and performance guarantees are gradually getting resolved, organizations are still trying to understand how their IT infrastructure strategies can leverage cloud computing effectively to extract benefits such as flexibility, scalability, and increased availability of their infrastructure, and reduced implementation and maintenance costs (Rittinghouse and Ransome 2010). As cloud computing evolves, organizations may leverage it to reduce time to market and empower mobility in the future which will require major changes in business processes or even organizational strategies. However, today, since it mainly affects the technology infrastructure choices of a firm, it requires little complementary investments relative to certain other IT events discussed in this section. In spite of the low scope of organizational changes, some market inefficiency is still expected in pricing cloud computing investments due to the differential ability of firms to assimilate this evolving technology. In its modern form, ERP has been in existence since the early nineties (Hong and Kim 2002). Many academic and industry studies have uncovered best practices and critical success factors for ERP implementations. To that extent, the decision to implement an ERP system today can be considered a mature event. However, it is well established that ERP success is contingent on several complementary organizational changes, including assimilation of new processes and work systems, end user training, top management support, and other change management procedures. The business press is replete with examples of high-performing firms (e.g., Nestle, Hershey, etc.) which experienced major snafus in their ERP implementations because of their inability to make some of these complementary changes (Worthen 2002; Katz 2001). Thus, in spite of high maturity of the event, ERP implementations may be associated with high idiosyncratic risk, low information disclosure, and in turn, high market inefficiency. To provide some prima facie empirical evidence that markets may significantly underreact to ERP events, we consider two published studies by Ranganathan and Brown (2006) and Hayes et al. (2001), which found announcement period returns of 1.47% and 0.19% respectively. In line with the efficient markets hypothesis, we interpret the increase in the market value of a firm during the announcement period as the net present value (NPV) of the ERP project. We use the ERP cost/revenue ratio from documented case studies to create a proxy for ERP costs 4, and calculate the implied ERP cost for the Ranganathan and Brown (2006) and Hayes et al. (2001) studies as shown in Table 2. 4 In 1999, Hershey spent $115 million on an ERP system (Katz 2001), while Nestle U.S.A., the $8.1 billion subsidiary of Nestle, invested $210 million on an ERP project to overhaul its existing IT systems (Worthen 2002). ---------------------------------Insert Table 2 about here ---------------------------------- If markets are efficient, then the NPVs in Table 2 represent the true value of ERP implementations in the sample. However, are these NPVs large enough for rational managers to invest in large, complex, and transformative initiatives like ERP? One survey found that 80% of ERP projects experience cost overruns that range between 40 and 85%, while another found an average cost overrun of 178% (http://www.snartak.com/erp.htm). It would take a cost overrun of 40.2% (the minimum reported overrun in the above survey) and just 6.2% in the cases of Ranganathan and Brown (2006) and Hayes et al. (2001) respectively to drive the corresponding NPVs to zero. At the highest reported overrun of 178%, the corresponding NPVs would be -439M and -$316M respectively. Given the well-documented risks of cost overruns as well as major delays and other organizational disruption, senior management would not have approved projects with such high costs and relatively low benefits. Assuming firms made rational investment decisions, we can infer that the market under-reacted to these ERP events during the announcement period, and that only long-term returns can capture the impact of such an investment. Large scale outsourcing of IT and IT enabled business functions, the focal case for the balance of the paper, is a relatively new phenomenon (for example, a majority of our sample of 100 largest outsourcing engagements occurred after 2000) compared to, say, ERP or EDI. Firms engaging in large, complex outsourcing deals are still experimenting with appropriate governance mechanisms, reflected in the misfit between governance choices and the nature of the outsourced task in a significant percentage of outsourcing engagements (e.g., Mani et al. 2010, Susarla et al. 2009). Further, large-scale outsourcing engagements entail significant effort in contract design and management, and communication and coordination between the client and vendor, all of which necessitate important complementary investments in processes, control structures, and technologies (Bapna et al, 2010). Given the low maturity Using the ratio of ERP investment to revenues, we obtain 2.90 for Hershey (revenue = $3.97 billion in 1999), and 2.59 for Nestle U.S.A. as the upfront cost of ERP systems as a percentage of revenue. We use (2.895 + 2.59)/2 = 2.74 as the average ERP/Revenue ratio. We assume 10% of the upfront cost as annual maintenance cost and 8% as the cost of capital. and expansive scope of large scale outsourcing initiatives, we expect the latter to be characterized by high idiosyncratic risk, low information disclosure, and lowest market efficiency in our framework. These four technology decisions are representative of classes of IT investments that differ in maturity and scope of organizational change that they induce. The key implications of this framework are that IT events with lower maturity and higher scope are expected to be associated with lower information disclosure, higher idiosyncratic risk and higher market inefficiency relative to events involving higher maturity and lower scope. The assessment of the financial value of these events should use long-term abnormal returns and incorporate firm specific factors. In the next section, we use the context of large scale outsourcing initiatives to illustrate the importance of choosing market based measures that are consistent with the maturity and scope of IT decisions. 4. Market Myopia and Idiosyncratic Risk in the Context of Outsourcing: An Illustrative Example 4.1 Theory and Hypotheses Development To illustrate the use of our framework and assessment of the financial value of large, complex IT events, we collected and analyzed data on the 100 largest outsourcing initiatives implemented between 1996 and 2005. At the end of 2008, the outsourcing of IT and IT-enabled business processes constituted over 50 percent of the average firm’s technology budget (Gottfredson et al. 2005). Further, outsourcing has transitioned from a cost saving tool for transaction intensive functions such as payroll to include the externalization of end-to-end business functions such as product development or financial management that directly impact firm competitiveness. This shift in the nature of outsourcing is evidenced in the growing value of outsourcing contracts – Gartner reported that in 2007, the average outsourcing contract value was $204 million while the total contract value for that year was $30 billion. However, despite their expanded reach and impact, researchers and practitioners have highlighted the high failure rate of emergent large scale outsourcing initiatives5, emphasizing that organizations 5 70% of the respondents in a 2005 survey by Deloitte Consulting expressed significant dissatisfaction with their outsourcing projects. Similarly, a survey conducted by Bain Consulting found that although 82% of large firms in North America engage in remain largely unprepared to manage the transformation brought about by these initiatives. As a consequence, although the cost of a large outsourcing decision is tangible because it is announced and expensed, its benefits are uncertain and reflect “intangible” information about future cash flows. The uncertainty in future cash flows and allied unpredictability in lifecycle costs emphasizes the low levels of maturity of emergent, broad outsourcing initiatives in the firm. Further, the management of large-scale, end-to-end services outsourcing poses a set of challenges that are relatively new and still evolving. Prior research (e.g., Mani et al. 2010; Gopal et al. 2003) shows that the performance of such outsourcing initiatives is contingent on choice of appropriate governance mechanisms, including contractual structures and relationship management processes. In particular, the outsourcing firm must design governance mechanisms that are aligned with the uncertainty and complexity of the outsourcing engagement to realize performance gains. Simpler and more stable tasks such as payroll or benefits management may readily scale to the provider’s existing capabilities and performance expectations may be more easily specifiable. In this case, the ownership and control of the outsourced process may be transferred to the provider through an arms length contract that provides the right incentives to meet service expectations. On the other hand, more complex and dynamic tasks such as financial planning or new product development are characterized by significantly higher transaction costs. The provider must be incentivized to make relationship specific investments that add strategic value to the outsourcing firm and often needs to coordinate extensively with various constituents in the outsourcing firm through the lifecycle of the contract. The need to discern these unique management challenges and invest managerial time and effort in solutions in large outsourcing initiatives reflects the relatively greater scope of these initiatives. Figure 2 below reflects the transition in outsourcing from the periphery to the core of the firm and the allied shift in maturity and organizational scope of the outsourcing initiative. Figure 2: The Shift in Maturity and Scope of Outsourcing Initiatives Scope of the IT Event Emergent, large scale, end-to-end outsourcing BPO, almost half of the respondents sayinitiatives their outsourcing programs fall short of expectations. According to SAP INFO Solutions, four out of five BPO contracts inked today will need to be renegotiated within two years. Further, 20% of all such contracts will collapse (SMR Intelligence 2006). Early transactional outsourcing initiatives The relatively lower maturity and expanded scope of large scale outsourcing events render them an ideal context to study whether markets are efficient or myopic in their evaluation of complex IT decisions. In order to efficiently price the outsourcing event, financial markets must be able to distinguish between different types of outsourcing initiatives in terms of various task and relational attributes, and their associated management challenges. The outsourcing firm itself may not recognize the above challenges and solutions, and even if it does, it may not have the incentive to disclose such information for competitive reasons. Thus, financial markets must incur information acquisition costs to efficiently price the outsourcing event. In addition to costs the market must expend on acquiring information on firm and task attributes that may impact the outcome of outsourcing, the interpretation of such information involves important information learning costs. When information is inexpensive, or when informed traders get precise information, then the market price will reveal most of the informed traders’ information (Grossman and Stiglitz 1980). However, prices cannot perfectly reflect costly information, “since if it did, those who spent resources to obtain it would receive no compensation” (Grossman and Stiglitz 1980). The acquisition and learning costs associated with information on the outsourcing event render arbitrage costly. Thus, the assumptions that all markets are always in equilibrium and always perfectly arbitraged are inconsistent with the nature of the event. We expect that information asymmetries introduced by acquisition and learning costs will be persistent and take a long time to be corrected by arbitrage forces. This engenders abnormal performance over a long horizon following the outsourcing event so that the price response to this IT event refutes the principle of efficient markets: Hypothesis 1 – Financial markets will be myopic rather than efficient in incorporating information on large-scale outsourcing of IT and IT enabled business functions. This results in significant long-term abnormal returns following the implementation of the outsourcing initiative. The risk of outsourcing a modular and simple business function like payroll is relatively low and unlikely to affect firm level risk. However, large scale outsourcing such as the externalization of end-toend functions such as supply chain management or new product development may carry significant risk for the entire firm, for any failure is likely to cause major disruptions to its operations. Outsourcing risk starts with the very decision to externalize IT services or one or more business function(s). Given that firms differ considerably in their work processes and routines, the outcomes of externalization of end-to-end functions may have high variance. For example, a firm may have modular processes while another may have a tightly coupled value chain; if both firms decide to outsource a given business function, the former is likely to extract more value from the arrangement, everything else being equal. Similarly, many firms are less prepared than others to handle the management of the outsourcing relationship as well as ensuing transformations in the management of their value chain. A second contributor to outsourcing risk stems from the differential ability of firms in selecting and executing the right governance mechanism. Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) focuses on relational uncertainty, and provides guidance on the choice of governance structures to mitigate hazards in exchange relationships. For example, Mani et al. (2009) posit that simple outsourcing tasks should be governed by arms length relationships and well-defined performance criteria, while more complex engagements may require elaborate relational governance mechanisms. Misfit between the ideal and actual governance choices lowers operational performance and client satisfaction (Mani et al. 2010). These above challenges are further exacerbated by factors such as the uncertainty in the firm’s business environment (which necessitates frequent changes in the outsourced task(s)) and the level of coordination required with the service providers (Barua et al. 2008). Mani et al. (2011) demonstrate that more complex outsourcing tasks require significant attention to joint action with the vendor and investment in communication technologies. Similarly, experience in outsourcing management and prior association with vendor(s) are expected to help clients realize favorable outcomes from the outsourcing engagement (Mani et al. 2009). In other words, various firm attributes make it easier or more difficult for some firms to succeed in their outsourcing endeavors than others. Given the scale and impact of the IT event, these attributes that determine abnormal returns to the outsourcing initiatives are an important component of idiosyncratic or firm specific risk. Thus we posit: Hypothesis 2 –Firm characteristics explain variance in the cross section of abnormal returns as well as idiosyncratic risk in large-scale outsourcing of IT and IT enabled business functions. 4.2 Data Our data comprises of the hundred largest outsourcing initiatives implemented between 1996 and 2005. The largest outsourcing contracts have important advantages over a similar random sample. First, the firm-level economic impact of outsourcing is more likely to be detected when the contract value is large. The average lifetime contract value in our sample is $922 million. The aggregate contract value of $83 billion represents approximately 18 percent of the total outsourcing contract value for the sample period. Second, our focus on large deals reduces the probability of confounding events; firms are less likely to sign as large contracts immediately prior or subsequent to the outsourcing agreement. Our approach to sample selection follows prior research in finance (e.g., Healy, Palepu and Ruback 1992) that examines the performance impact of managerial decisions such as mergers or acquisitions. Information on the hundred largest outsourcing initiatives and their governing contracts is obtained from International Data Corporation’s (IDC) services contracts database. IDC tracks outsourcing contracts signed around the world with the database comprising nearly 21,000 service contracts. This data dates back to 1996, and is the primary input to this study. We use Lexis-Nexis and the Dow Jones News Retrieval Service to verify and supplement IDC information on announcement and signing dates. We use the Center for Research on Security Prices (CRSP) files to compute abnormal stock returns, and the Compustat Basic and Research files to assess firm characteristics, develop operating performance measures, and estimate insider trading activity. Our final sample comprises the 100 largest outsourcing contracts that satisfy two requirements. First, the firm must be publicly traded on a major United States stock exchange. Second, information on the contract used to govern the outsourcing initiative must be available. Our final sample of 100 contracts includes 66 firms. Table 3 describes the characteristics of our sample. Panel A lists the distribution of our sample across SIC codes and types of outsourcing initiatives while Panel B describes certain characteristics of the sample outsourcing firms and contracts. Outsourcing initiatives in our sample are classified as one of Information Systems (IS) Outsourcing, Business Process Outsourcing (BPO) or Processing Services, and Application, Network and Desktop Management. In the case of IS outsourcing services, the service provider takes ownership of and responsibility for managing all or large part of a client’s IS infrastructure and operations, often involving customized, one-to-one engagements. If only the network and desktop environment are outsourced, the spending is classified as network and desktop management services. Likewise, if only the application environment is outsourced, the spending is classified as applications outsourcing. Network management services involve the outsourcing of the operations of a specific segment or entire network communication system of a company. Desktop management captures contracts for which several desktop services are outsourced to the same provider. BPO involves outsourcing business processes or functional areas (such as logistics or HR), with performance metrics tied to new business opportunities, revenue generation, customer satisfaction and business transformation. -----------------------------Insert Table 3 about here ------------------------------ 4.3 Empirical Analyses and Results First, we test the market efficiency hypothesis (Hypothesis 1) by examining the significance of long-term abnormal returns following the outsourcing event. We also compare the magnitude and direction of longterm abnormal returns with that of announcement period returns to establish market myopia. Finally, we test Hypothesis 2 by analyzing the impact of various attributes that are idiosyncratic to the outsourced task environment on long-term abnormal returns and idiosyncratic risk of the firm. Long-term Abnormal Returns: As a first test of market efficiency, we report the three year buy and hold abnormal returns (BHAR) for all sample outsourcing firms following the implementation of the outsourcing contract. We use the characteristic based matching approach, also known as the event-time portfolio approach to calculate long-term abnormal returns. Mitchell and Stafford (2000) describe event time BHAR as “the average multi-year return from a strategy of investing in all firms that complete an event and selling at the end of a pre-specified holding period versus a comparable strategy using otherwise similar nonevent firms”. Thus, the BHAR for stock i over holding period T is: BHARi ,T BHRi ,T BHRm,T , (1) where BHRi,T is the buy-and-hold return of the sample firm and BHRm,T is the buy-and-hold return of the matching control firm over the same period. Here, the buy-and-hold return for holding period T beginning time a through time b is: b BHRi ,T [ (1 rit ) 1] t a , (2) where rit is the return for firm i in month t; in this study, period a is the month after the contract effective month and period b is the earlier of the firm’s delisting date or the end of the three year period following the contract effective date. Following Barber and Lyon (1997), we consider an industry-, size- and book-to-market matched sample as a benchmark of returns post implementation of the outsourcing contract. We begin with a group of firms in the same two-digit SIC code as the sample that do not engage in a strategically significant outsourcing initiative as of the beginning of the contract effective year. From this initial screen, a matched firm is defined as the firm that has the lowest absolute value of the joint difference in size (equity capitalization) and book-to-market ratio (equity capitalization divided by book value of equity). As noted earlier, prior research (e.g., Mani et al.2010) finds that the contractual risks – the risk of not choosing the right contract to overcome incentive conflict and facilitate cooperation between participant firms – and procedural risks – the risk of not establishing the right relationship management processes and information exchange mechanisms to overcome cognitive conflict and facilitate coordination between the client and the provider – increase with uncertainty and complexity of the outsourcing initiative, thereby, adversely impacting potential gains from outsourcing. The greater the uncertainty and complexity of the outsourcing initiative, the more difficult it is for participant firms to anticipate contingencies in the relational and task environments and design appropriate contractual and informational responses to these contingencies. Therefore, we expect that the magnitude and direction of the BHAR too will vary by the uncertainty and complexity of the outsourcing initiative. We draw on prior research to identify a set of firm, process and relational attributes that may influence such uncertainty and complexity and in turn, the transaction costs and operational and financial gains from outsourcing. These attributes include uncertainty in the business requirements of the client (UNCER), coordination requirements of the outsourced task (COORDN), prior association between the client and the provider (PRIOR), and experience of the outsourcing firm in managing similar outsourcing initiatives (EXP). The operationalization of these variables is described in Table 4. -----------------------------Insert Table 4 about here ------------------------------ Panel A of Table 5 reports the mean three year BHAR from outsourcing for the lowest and highest 30 percent of firms ordered by UNCER, INTER, PRIOR and EXP. In line with the greater transaction costs of managing complex, uncertain relationships, we find that outsourcing initiatives in the highest 30 percent of UNCER and INTER and the lowest 30 percent of PRIOR and EXP were characterized by negative BHAR. In contrast, outsourcing initiatives in the lowest 30 percent of UNCER and INTER and the highest 30 percent of PRIOR and EXP were characterized by positive BHAR. The “difference” column reports the difference in returns between the two sub-samples. Panel B reports equivalent results for the sample of firms for which all three years’ return data is available - the returns reported in Panel A underestimate those in Panel B. As a robustness check, we also estimated BHAR by contract type. These results are reported in Panel C of Table 5. Outsourcing contracts may be classified as fixed price or variable price contracts. Prior research (e.g., Crocker and Reynolds 1993; Gopal et al.2003; Mani et al. 2010) finds that given the tradeoff between ex ante contract design costs of more complete fixed price contracts and ex post contractual inefficiencies and coordination costs of more incomplete variable price contracts, highpowered incentives and high renegotiation costs of fixed price contracts, the latter are an optimal choice in the case of relatively simple, stable outsourcing initiatives while variable price contracts are often chosen to govern more complex, dynamic outsourcing initiatives. Thus, the contract type is a signal of the complexity of the outsourcing initiative. Consistent with the results in Panel A, we find that the sample of fixed price contracts was associated with large positive abnormal returns, while that of variable price contracts experienced large negative abnormal returns. Thus, the results in Table 5 confirm Hypothesis 1 – markets are unable to efficiently price large scale outsourcing events, low in maturity and expansive in their scope, resulting in long-term abnormal returns following the event. In particular, at the announcement of the event, the market is unable to distinguish between different types of outsourcing initiatives in terms of the management challenges posed by different firm, task and relational factors and the consequent performance impacts. -----------------------------Insert Table 5 about here ------------------------------ Announcement Period Returns: As further evidence of market myopia, we report announcement period returns and wealth effects for our sample of initiatives in Table 6. Prior research in IS on the financial value of outsourcing initiatives (see Table 1) has almost exclusively focused on announcement period returns. Consistent with this stream of research, we estimate daily abnormal returns for the firms as: , where day t while are firm specific abnormal returns. Here, denotes the daily returns for firm i on are the predicted daily returns. Following prior research on strategic alliances (e.g. McGahan and Villalonga 2003), we estimate the following market model: , where denotes the corresponding daily returns to the value weighted S&P 500. An estimation period of 150 days [-170,-21] prior to the announcement date is used to estimate the market model. Significance of the returns is based on the market model standardized residual method with Scholes-Williams (1977) betas. The estimates from this model are then used to predict daily returns for each firm i over three event windows6 – a 3 day period [-1,+1], a 12 day period [-10, +1] and a 20 day period [-10,+9] surrounding the announcement of the outsourcing initiative. Table 6 report results of the above event analyses for the lowest and highest 30 percent of firms ordered by UNCER, COORDN, PRIOR and EXP. Returns are positive and significant for initiatives characterized by high coordination complexity. The magnitude and direction of returns are consistent with the findings of prior research reported in Table 1. It is likely that the market views complex initiatives as characterized by strong strategic intent, and hence, rewards them. Similarly, the markets penalize prior association and reward firms for choosing a new vendor. Interestingly, both these outcomes are reversed in the estimation of long-term abnormal returns. The results are robust to estimation by contract type. The insignificance of announcement period returns and reversal of the direction of returns for various categories of outsourcing initiatives provide evidence of market myopia in support of Hypothesis 1. -----------------------------Insert Table 6 about here ------------------------------ Idiosyncratic Risk and Returns: In order to test Hypothesis 2, we analyze whether (a) characteristics of the IT event contribute to the long-term BHAR of the firm, and (b) characteristics of the IT event are an important component of idiosyncratic firm risk. In this case, we analyze whether attributes of the outsourced task environment – UNCER, COORDN, PRIOR and EXP – influence the BHAR following the implementation of the outsourcing contract and the idiosyncratic risk of the outsourcing firm. 6 Prior research in IS has focused almost exclusively on the 3 day window. However, given the scale of the initiative, we expect information leakage in the market, and report returns for longer event windows as well. Table 7 presents the results of our analyses. Model I estimates the influence of the firm-, processand relationship-level attributes on the three year BHAR following the implementation of the outsourcing contract while controlling for self-selection into the outsourcing decision and choice of outsourcing contract7. Firm and time effects are also controlled for. Robust standard errors clustered by firm are reported in parentheses. We find that uncertainty in the outsourcing firm’s business environment, coordination requirements and prior association with the vendor impact returns to the outsourcing initiative. The results suggest that complex outsourcing initiatives, characterized by changing business requirements and higher levels of coordination, are correlated with dissipation of efficiency gains from outsourcing. This is likely because of greater risks of cost overruns, opportunism, and coordination failures in these environments. There are “severe limits to what can be achieved through contracting” (Banerjee and Duflo 2002) to mitigate these risks, and outsourcing firms must often invest in appropriate relationship management procedures to counteract the problems created by the limitations of contracting. Yet, empirical research (Mani et al. 2009) on outsourcing governance finds that the lack of organizational awareness or preparedness for such investments results in efficiency losses from outsourcing. Our results are consistent with this outcome. Further, they suggest that efficiency losses in complex outsourcing environments are exacerbated by lack of prior association between the outsourcing firm and the vendor. More importantly, our results emphasize that idiosyncratic characteristics of the firm that impact its ability to manage an IT event are important determinants of the financial value created by the IT event. Our measure of buy-and-hold abnormal returns controls for industry, value and growth risks. Our results suggest that in addition to these risks, idiosyncratic characteristics of the outsourcing firm, relationship and task environment also influence returns to the initiative. Model II analyzes whether the characteristics of the outsourced task environment that impact returns to the outsourcing initiative are an important component of the idiosyncratic risk of the firm. We measure the idiosyncratic risk for each of the outsourcing firms as the annualized standard deviation of residuals from a market model regression based on daily returns (Bali et al. 2005, Ali et al. 2003, Malkiel and Xu 2006). We find that uncertainty in the firm’s business environment positively contribute to the idiosyncratic volatilities of the firm. The results in Table 7 also suggest unobserved firm attributes that influence the choice of a contract are associated with long-term returns and idiosyncratic risk of the firm. Overall, our results confirm that firm capabilities to manage IT events are important determinants of returns to the event. Further, our findings suggest that these capabilities are an important element of idiosyncratic firm risk. Thus, the use of asset pricing models such as CAPM that assume diversification of idiosyncratic risk and only consider non-diversifiable market risk in pricing IT events is inconsistent with the very nature of IT events. Abnormal returns to IT events may be estimated after controlling for market risk and other risks such as value or growth risks; however, the association between these abnormal returns and firm characteristics must be understood to accurately price the IT event. -----------------------------Insert Table 7 about here ------------------------------ 5. Implications for Future Research The above theoretical arguments and empirical evidence have important implications for what measures of financial value should be used to price IT events in consonance with the basic tenet of IS research firms differ in their ability to manage and extract value from IT investments and such differences are a key source of competitive advantage. In this context, we identify below research issues that require attention while testing hypotheses pertaining to the financial value of IT management decisions. Time horizon for calculation of returns to the IT investment: Our study emphasizes the need to consider the maturity of the underlying technology and the scope of complementary investments in organizational structures and process in valuing the IT event. These attributes provide guidance regarding the expected level of information disclosure and hence the magnitude of information acquisition and learning costs incurred by financial markets in valuing the IT event, and in turn, the efficiency of the market in valuing the IT decision. As already noted, in many studies published in the field of information systems and strategy during the past decade, researchers have used announcement period returns to assess the financial value of strategic technology investments. In doing so, these studies ignore important information acquisition and learning costs associated with information on these IT events (Hypothesis 1) and assume the market model as a predictor of returns unconditional on the event (Hypothesis 2). This introduces dissonance between hypotheses and their empirical formulation and testing (Chatterjee et al. 1999). Further, IT events are often the outcome of a series of related events, their announcement being one of them. To this extent, announcement period returns may underestimate the full magnitude of abnormal returns related to the IT event. The above problems are minimized by extending the time horizon for calculation of abnormal returns. Long event windows also introduce bias by increasing the likelihood of capturing extraneous and related events in the event window. Related events are often common to the sample experiencing the strategic information event and hence, may be captured by systematic controls in the returns model. The influence of extraneous events may be reduced by choosing a window length that represents an “acceptable tradeoff between estimating reasonably stable coefficients and capturing the impact of extraneous events” (Lubatkin and Shrieves 1986). Window lengths of three to five years have been shown to achieve this objective. They reduce the likelihood of confounding events since firms are unlikely to engage in equally economically significant initiatives immediately prior or subsequent to the strategic information event. Hence, the sample size is largely unaffected in these window lengths. In summary, the properties of long-term abnormal returns render them an appropriate measure of price response that is consistent with the nature of strategic information events. However, issues of expected return modeling, aggregation of security specific returns and the calibration of their statistical significance are critically important in long horizon event studies (Kothari and Warner 2004), and must be addressed. Model of predicted returns: As argued in Hypothesis 2, CAPM based measures of risk and return are inappropriate in determining predicted returns unconditional on information events with low maturity and/or high scope. We have demonstrated in the context of outsourcing that incorporating firm specific factors such as experience and prior association and task characteristics such as coordination requirements can help better explain the variance in abnormal returns. Our prescription of including firm and task specific factors in IT value research also relates to sample stratification issues. Studies in finance largely analyze uncategorized samples of events that are assumed to be drawn from a homogeneous population (Lubatkin and Shrieves 1986). However, emergent research in economics suggests that identifying discrete event characteristics and comparing performance outcomes associated with each characteristic may reveal important patterns in the market’s price response. For instance, in our sample of the 100 largest outsourcing initiatives implemented between 1996 and 2005, we find no significant long-term abnormal returns. However, the mean three year buy-and-hold abnormal return for firms engaged in complex outsourcing initiatives governed by variable price contracts and characterized by dynamic process requirements, high coordination costs, lack of prior cooperative association with the provider, and limited experience is -21.2 percent. The equivalent return for relatively simple outsourcing initiatives governed by fixed price contracts is 17.5 percent. Similarly, Gompers et al. (2003) construct a “Governance Index” to proxy for the level of shareholder rights at about 1500 large firms during the 1990s. An investment strategy that bought firms in the lowest decile of the index (strongest rights) and sold firms in the highest decile of the index (weakest rights) earned abnormal returns of 8.5 percent per year during the sample period. These studies demonstrate how theoretical stratification of the sample can reveal important patterns in returns to information events. A unique strength of the field of IS is its ability to ascribe meaning to performance differences between organizations and the persistence of such differences. Thus, the field is best positioned to identify theoretically distinct groups within a sample of firms experiencing the event to identify what drives price responses to the event. For instance, prior research in strategy suggests that heterogeneity in performance across joint ventures may be explained by various factors - limitations posed by partners’ size, age and prior performance, the compatibility between partners, resource complementarity, partners’ inability to transfer resources to the venture, or the cumulative experience of the firm in managing similar ventures. The assumption that a sample of joint ventures is drawn from a homogenous population results in the reporting of returns that fail to reflect these regularities in returns to joint venture activity. Thus, moving forward, it is important that research in IS leverage its theoretical knowledge of strategic information events to identify drivers of abnormal returns. Implications for Practice: Our framework has implications for asset managers who seek investment opportunities based on major IT events while avoiding the pitfalls. Given the lack of information disclosure regarding firm specific competence and risks involved in managing an IT event with low maturity and/or high scope of complementary changes, asset managers must incur the cost of learning about a firm’s basic ability to manage or mitigate the risks associated with the IT event and to extract maximum value through effective governance and the inculcation of a culture of business innovation. Traditional asset pricing models have assumed efficiency of capital markets, and largely focused on the management of beta or market risk in portfolios. However, our results underscore the inefficiency of markets in pricing certain managerial decisions that reflect intangible information on future cash flows. This, in turn, points to the opportunity in shifting the focus of asset management from beta to the quality of management decisions that impact firms’ competitiveness and strategic value. Our study also suggests that since markets under-react to limited information disclosure, senior IT managers and business executives should carefully weigh the benefits of more detailed disclosure (when the firm is aware of the management challenges as well as its strengths in managing such complexity) against potential opportunity costs in the form of its specific skills and expertise becoming common knowledge to the advantage of its competitors. 7. Conclusion The assessment of the financial or market value of large IT events is an important avenue for IS research. It may be the most convincing means to demonstrate the value of IT to C-level executives, who are concerned about shareholder value. However, such research must deal with many challenges, stemming primarily from the high cost of information acquisition and learning that are necessary for capital markets to price an IT event efficiently. We developed a framework involving the maturity and the scope of complementary changes associated with an IT event to assess the expected level of market efficiency in pricing the IT event. We argued that for three out of four possible classes of IT events in the framework, we expect to witness low levels of information disclosure, high idiosyncratic risk and low market efficiency. A direct implication of our study is that research on market value of IT events will generally involve significant under-reaction from the market during the announcement phase, and that long-term abnormal returns are likely to capture the true effects of major IT decisions. We also underscore the major limitation of market models such as CAPM that assume away firm specific idiosyncratic risks. We argue and demonstrate that this assumption is contrary to the central notion of the IS field that the capability to manage and create value from IT differs widely across firms. Thus our prescription, based on both theory and empirical evidence, is to incorporate factors other than market risk that are specific to the ability of a firm to manage the IT event as well as characteristics of the IT event. Such an approach will help uncover the contribution of a firm’s IT management capabilities to market value as a direct response to the assertion of “IT Doesn’t Matter.” We have also outlined the implications of our study to practice and asset managers. By investing in information gathering regarding firm capabilities and learning about the challenges of managing the information event, they will be able to better predict if the delayed reaction of the market will be positive or negative based on firm and task characteristics. Given the increasing share of IT events in the overall spend of the firm, understanding the nuances of market reactions to important IT events will help the asset manager in maximizing returns. References Ali, Ashiq, Hwang, Lee-Seok, and Mark A. Trombley. 2003. Arbitrage Risk and the book-to-market anomaly, Journal of Financial Economics, 69: 355 - 373. Armstrong, C. P., and Sambamurthy, V. 1999. Information Technology Assimilation in Firms: The Influence of Senior Leadership and IT Infrastructures, Information Systems Research, 10(4): 304-327. Bali, Turan G., Cakici, Nusret, Yan, Xuemin. and Zhe Zhang. 2005. Does Idiosyncratic Risk really Matter? The Journal of Finance, 60(2): 905 - 929 Bapna, R., Barua, A., Mani, D. and A. Mehra, “Cooperation, Coordination and Governance in Multi-sourcing: An Agenda for Analytical and Empirical Research,” forthcoming, Information Systems Research. Barua, A., Lee, C.H., and A.B. Whinston, 1996. The Calculus of Reengineering, Information Systems Research, 7(4): 409-428. Banerjee, A.V. & Duflo, E. (2000). Reputation effects and the limits of contracting: A study of the Indian software industry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 989-1017. Barua, A., and Mukhopadhyay, T., “Business Value of Information Technologies: Past, Present and Future, in Framing the Domains of IT Management: Glimpsing the Future through the Past, Robert Zmud (Ed.), 2000. Bettis, R.A. 1983. Modern financial theory, corporate strategy, and public policy: Three conundrums, Academy of Management Review, 8: 549-563. Bharadwaj, A. S. 2000. A Resource-Based Perspective on Information Technology Capability and Firm Performance: An Empirical Investigation, MIS Quarterly, 24(1): 169-196. Bhatt, G.D. and V. Grover, 2005. Types of Information Technology Capabilities and Their Role in Competitive Advantage: An Empirical Study, Journal of MIS, Vol. 22(2): 253-277. Brynjolfsson, E., Renshaw, A.A., and M. van Alstyne. 2006. The Matrix of Change: A Tool for Business Process Reengineering, Sloan Management Review, Winter 1996. Brynjolfsson, E., Hitt, L.M., and S. Yang, “Intangible Assets: Computers and Organizational Capital,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2002. Chatterjee, S., Lubatkin, M.H., and Schulze, W.S. 1999. Toward a strategic theory of risk premium: Moving beyond CAPM, Academy of Management Review, 24 (3): 556-567. Chatterjee, D., Pacini, C. and Sambamurthy, V. 2002. The Shareholder-Wealth and Trading-Volume Effects of Information-Technology Infrastructure Investments, Journal of Management Information Systems, 19(2): 7-42. Chatterjee, D., Richardson, V.J. and Zmud, R.W. 2001. Examining the Shareholder Wealth Effects of Announcements of Newly Created CIO Position, MIS Quarterly, 25(1): 43-70. Daniel, K. and S. Titman, “Evidence on the Characteristics of Cross Sectional Variation in Stock Returns,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. LII, No. 1, March 1997. Daniel, K. and S. Titman, “Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information,” The Journal of Finance, Vo.. 61, Issue 4, pp. 1605-1643, August 2006. Dehning, B., Richardson, V.J. and Stratopoulos, T. 2003. Reviewing Event Studies in MIS: An Application of the Firm Value Framework, Proceedings of the 36th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences (HICSS). Dewan, Sanjeev, Shi, Charles and Vijay Gurbaxani. 2007. Investigating the Risk–Return Relationship of Information Technology Investment: Firm-Level Empirical Analysis, Information Systems Research, 53 (12): 1829 – 1842. Dewan, S. and F. Ren. 2007. Risk and return of information technology initiatives: Evidence from electronic commerce announcements. Information Systems Research, 18(4): 366–390. Dos Santos, B.L., Peffers, K. and Mauer, D. 1993. The Impact of Information Technology Investment Announcements on the Market Value of the Firm, Information Systems Research, 4(1): 1-23. Fama, E.F., and French, K.R. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns, Journal of Finance, 47: 427-465. Gopal, A., Sivaramakrishnan, K., Krishnan, M.S. and T. Mukhopadhyay. 2003. Contracts in Offshore Software Development: An Empirical Analysis. Management Science. 49(12):1671-1683. Gottfredson, M. Puryear, R. and S. Phillips. 2005. Strategic Sourcing from Periphery to the Core. Harvard Business Review. 8 (2): 2- 9. Grossman, S.J. and J.E. Stiglitz, “On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets,” The American Economic Review, 1980. Hayes, D.C., Hunton, J.E. and Reck, J.L. 2001. Market Reaction to ERP Implementation Announcements, Journal of Information Systems, 15(1): 3-18. Hong, K-K and Y.G. Kim, “The critical success factors for ERP implementation: an organizational fit perspective,” Information and Management, Vol. 40, No.1, 2002, pp. 25-40. Hunter, S.D. 2003. Information Technology, Organizational Learning, and the Market Value of the Firm, The Journal of Information Theory and Application, 5(1): 1-28. Im, K.S., Dow, K.E. and Grover, V. 2001. Research Report: A Reexamination of IT Investment and the Market Value of the Firm - An Event Study Methodology, Information Systems Research, 12(1): 103-117. Jarrar, Y.F., Al-Mudimigh, A., and M. Zairi, 2000. ERP implementation critical success factors - the role and impact of business process management, Management of Innovation and Technology. D.M. Katz, “What if Your ERP Can’t Deliver?”, CFO.com, 2001, http://www.cfonet.com/article.cfm/2993965?f=search Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny, “Contrarian Investment, Extrapolation and Risk,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XLIX, No. 5, December 1994. Lubatkin, Michael H., and Ronald E. Shrieves. 1986.Towards a reconciliation of market performance measures to strategic management research, Academy of Management Review, 3: 497-512. Malkiel, B. and Y. Xu, March 2006, "Idiosyncratic Risk and Security Returns," working paper. Mani, D., Barua, A., and A.B. Whinston, “An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Information Capabilities Design on Business Process Outsourcing Performance,” MIS Quarterly, March 2010. Meng, Z. and Lee, S.-Y.T. 2007. The value of IT to firms in a developing country in the catch-up process: An empirical comparison of China and the United States, Decision Support Systems, 43(3): 737-745. Ranganathan, C. and Brown, C.V. 2006. ERP Investments and the Market Value of Firms: Toward an Understanding of Influential ERP Project Variables, Information Systems Research, 17(2): 145-161. Rittinghouse, J.W. and J.F. Ransome, “Cloud Computing: Implementation, Management and Security,” CRC Press, 2010. Subramani, M. and Walden, E. 2001. The Impact of E-Commerce Announcements on the Market Value of Firms, Information Systems Research, 12(2): 135-154. Susarla, A., Barua, A., and A.B. Whinston, “A Transactions Cost Perspective of the Software as a Service Model,” forthcoming, Journal of MIS. Tanriverdi, H., 2005. Information Technology Relatedness, Knowledge Management Capability, and Performance of Multibusiness Firms, MIS Quarterly, 29(2). Weiss, J.A. and B.C. Dale, “Diffusing Against Mature Technology: Issues and Strategy,” Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 27, No. 4, July 1998, pp. 293-304. Worthen, B., “Nestle’s ERP Odyssey,” CIO Magazine, May 2002, http://www.cio.com/article/31066/Nestl_eacute_s_Enterprise_Resource_Planning_ERP_Odysse y Zhu, K. 2004. The Complementarity of Information Technology Infrastructure and E-Commerce Capability: A Resource-Based Assessment of Their Business Value, Journal of MIS, 21(1): 167-202. Table 1: Selected Studies that Examine the Financial Value of IT Investments (Adapted from Roztocki and Weistroffer 2009, Ranganathan and Brown 2006) Reference Type of IT Investments Long-term focus? Event Window Dewan (2007) and Ren e-Commerce initiatives No (-1, +1), (-10, +10) Meng (2007) and Lee Value of IT investments to China versus the United States Transformative, informate or automate No (0, +2) No (-1, +1) Exploratory versus exploitative investments No (-1, +1) ERP Investments No (-1,0), (0,+1), (-1,+1), (0, +2), (-2, +2) Infrastructure versus Application Investments No (-1,0), (0,+1), (-1,+1), (-2, +2) Hayes et al. (2001) ERP No (0, +1) Im et al.(2001) IT investments between 1981-1996 No (-1,0) Dehning (2003) et al. Hunter (2003) Ranganathan Brown (2003) Chatterjee (2002) et and al. Magnitude of Abnormal Returns (-1, +1): CAR of 0.15%, 2.94%, and -1.29% in 1996, 1998 and 2000 respectively (-10, +10): CAR of 10.89%, and -4.49% in 1998 and 2000 respectively China: 1.08% USA: insignificant Firms investing in transformational IT: 1.51% Firms in industries with transform industry IT strategic role: 1.41% Firms making exploitative investments: -0.68% Firms making exploratory investments: -1.11% Overall returns of 1.47% in (0, +1) event period. Significant gains were found for all of the expanded event windows. Overall returns of 1.99% in (0, +1) event window. Infrastructure: 2.01% Application: 0.84% Overall mean standardized abnormal returns of 0.19% Small firms: 0.25% In subsample from 1991-1996, IT investments: 0.16% Financial firms: 0.27% Small firms: 0.63% Mid-sized firms: -0.22% Subramani and Walden (2001) Dos Santos et al. (1993) Florin et al. (2005) e-Commerce initiatives No (-5, +5), (-10, +10) Innovative IT investments No (-1,0) (-5, +5) event period: 7.5% (-10, +10) event period: 16.2% 1.03% IT/ IS outsourcing announcements and the moderating effect of organizational restructuring Yes (-30, -1), (0, +1), (+2, +250) (0, +1): Significant CAR of 1.9% Hunton, Reck and Hayes (1999) Farag and Krishnan (2003) IS outsourcing announcements IS outsourcing announcements categorized by project type and industry No (-1, +1) No 10 day and 5 day windows Agrawal, Kishore and Rao (2006) e-Business outsourcing announcements sorted by strategic intent, project execution swiftness and task complexity No (-1, +1) Hayes, Hunton and Reck (2001) IS outsourcing announcements No (0, +1) Restructuring changes after the announcement moderate the relationship between the short-term effect of announcements and long-term abnormal returns so that the latter become negative when followed by restructuring efforts resulting from outsourcing Significant returns of 0.35% on day +1. Overall CAR of 1.72% over a 10 day time window. For strategic projects, CAR over 5 day window: 3.34% CAR over 10 day window: 7.56% For cost cutting projects, CAR over 10 day window: 2.07%. 5 day window results were not significant. Strategic Intent: Commercial exploitation: CAR of 2.05% Other intent: CAR of -1.75% Execution swiftness: Regular execution: CAR of 1.73% Swift execution: CAR of 3.3% Task complexity: Low: CAR of -2.28% High: CAR of 2.08% CAR of 0.124% in the two day event window. Day 0 abnormal return of 0.02%;Day 1 abnormal return of 0.33% Table 2: Returns from ERP investments Average revenue of sample (R) Ranganathan & Brown (2006) Hayes et al. (2001) Announcement period return from ERP announcement (r) Implied NPV of ERP initiative NPV = M*r Calculated upfront ERP cost C=.0274*R $8.3B Average market capitalization of sample (M) $8.7B 1.47% $128M $227.4M Present value of maintenance cost for five years M = .1*C each year discounted at 8% cost of capital $91M $4.8B $6B 0.19% $11.4M $131.5M $52.5M Table 3: Sample Characteristics of Outsourcing Announcements, 1996 – 2005 Panel A reports the distribution of sample firms across primary SIC codes, and Panel B reports various characteristics of the sample outsourcing contracts and user firms. All accounting data are obtained one year prior to the contract effective year. Further, such data are adjusted by the CPI to reflect 2005 dollars. Panel A: Distribution of sample firms across primary SIC codes IS Outsourcing BPO and Processing Services SIC Sector Number 0 Agriculture, Forestry, and Fishing Mining and Construction Manufacturing Manufacturing Transportation, Communications, Electric, Gas, and Sanitary Services Wholesale and Retail Trade Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate Lodging and Entertainment Services Public Administration All Sectors 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Application, Network and Desktop Management Number % of all deals 0 0% All Deals 0 % of all deals 100% Number 0 % of all deals 0% 0 % of all deals 0% Number 0 10 16 10 0% 56% 55% 53% 0 5 8 4 0% 28% 28% 21% 1 3 5 5 100% 17% 17% 26% 1 18 29 19 100% 100% 100% 100% 3 10 60% 43% 2 8 40% 35% 0 5 0% 22% 5 23 100% 100% 4 0 0 80% 0% 0% 0 0 0 0% 0% 0% 1 0 0 20% 0% 0% 5 0 0 100% 100% 100% 53 53% 27 27% 20 20% 100 100% Panel B: Sample Characteristics of Outsourcing Initiatives Outsourcing Firm Characteristics Market Value of Equity ($M) Market to Book Ratio Tobin’s Q Contract Characteristics Contract Value – All Deals ($M) Contract Value – IS Outsourcing ($M) Contract Value – BPO and Processing Services ($M) Contract Value – Application, Network and Management ($M) Contract Length (months) Desktop N 100 100 100 Mean 37,331 3.27 0.18 Median 23,802 2.71 0.09 100 53 27 20 922 1,100 703 747 563 645 517 425 100 93 84 Table 4: Measurement of Variables Variable Description Measure Transactional Attributes TYPE Type of outsourcing Ordinal variable in decreasing order of maturity of the initiative outsourcing market is one of: 1. Information systems outsourcing 2. Application, network and desktop management 3. Business process outsourcing and processing services Relational Attributes CONTRACT Incompleteness of Fixed price: fixed payment per billing cycle or per outsourcing contract transaction per billing cycle Variable price: payment based on variable factors such as time and materials used during the billing cycle or improvements against key performance indicators or any combination of these factors COORDN Anticipated Anticipated interdependence based on the strategic rationale coordination for outsourcing the given business function. The Source IDC IDC IDC requirements of the outsourced function TRUST CONTINUITY Firm Attributes UNCERTAINTY STRIMP EXP SIZE BTM PRIOR_PERF outsourcing literature points to eight rationales that cover the spectrum of outsourcing logics: 1. Reduction of costs 2. Improve management focus on core competences 3. Access to competitive capabilities not available inhouse 4. Growth strategy 5. Speed to market 6. Access to new markets 7. Proximity to customers 8. Business transformation The rationales were assessed from the IDC description of the outsourcing initiative and the public announcement of the initiative. Mutual trust inferred We infer trust based on the bid type, which is one of IDC based on prior competitive, incumbent or sole sourced. Competitive cooperative association bidding suggests the absence of prior association between between the firms the firms. Incumbent bidding implies that the outsourcing firm has an existing relationship with the provider. A solesourced contract means that the provider is the only provider of the outsourced function. The outsourcing firm may enter into sole-source negotiations with an incumbent in which case the bid type is recorded as incumbent. Expectation of Length of the contract in months IDC continuity of the outsourcing relationship Uncertainty in business requirements of the outsourcing firm Strategic importance of the outsourcing initiative Outsourcing experience of the firm Market value of equity of the outsourcing firm Book to market ratio of the outsourcing firm Prior financial performance Variance in the outsourcing firm’s return on assets (RoA) Compustat over the three years prior to the contract effective year. RoA is defined as the ratio of operating income to total assets. Ratio of contract value to operating expenses. IDC, Operating expenses is defined as the sum of cost of goods Compustat sold, sales and administrative expenses, and depreciation and amortization expenses Market value of equity, defined as the product of the Compustat number of shares outstanding and market price Ratio of book value of equity to market value of equity of Compustat the outsourcing firm Buy and hold returns for the three year period preceding CRSP implementation of the outsourcing contract Table 5: Long-term Buy-And-Hold Abnormal Returns following Outsourcing Implementations Panel A reports buy-and-hold returns for the sample firms, and buy-and-hold abnormal returns (BHAR) for the sample firms relative to control firms, for the three year period following the date the outsourcing contract was signed. A control firm is defined as a firm in the same 2 digit SIC code as the outsourcing firm that has the lowest absolute value of the joint difference in size (equity capitalization) and book-to-market ratio (equity capitalization divided by book value of equity). Panel B reports BHAR for sample firms where return data is available for all three years. Panel C reports the mean three year BHAR from outsourcing for the lowest and highest 30 percent of environmental uncertainty, anticipated coordination requirements, prior cooperative association between the outsourcing firm and vendor, and outsourcing experience. The “difference” column reports the difference in returns between the two sub-samples. Panel D reports equivalent results for the sample of firms for which all three years’ return data is available. Panel A: Long-term BHAR – Full Sample Lowest 30 percent (a) UNCERTAINTY 0.34*** COORDN 0.39*** Highest 30 percent (b) -0.56*** -0.51*** Difference (a-b) 0.90*** 0.90*** PRIOR -0.15*** 0.22*** -0.37** EXP -0.23*** 0.15*** -0.38** Panel B: Long-term BHAR – Three Year Sample UNCERTAINTY 0.30*** -0.69*** 0.99*** COORDN 0.33*** -0.65*** 0.98*** PRIOR -0.24*** 0.31*** -0.55** EXP -0.33*** 0.21*** -0.54** Panel C: Three-Year Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Returns (%) – Full Sample Raw Return (in percent) BHAR (in percent) – Ind/ Size/ BTM Adjusted All Contracts Fixed Price Variable Price All Contracts Fixed Price Variable Price 32.21*** 48.41*** 21.51*** -6.15 17.45** -21.17* Panel D: Three-Year Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Returns (%) – Three Year Sample Raw Return (in percent) BHAR (in percent) – Ind/ Size/ BTM Adjusted All Contracts Fixed Price Variable Price All Contracts Fixed Price Variable Price 27.50*** 49.08*** 12.52* -9.78 23.62** -32.68** *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01 Table 6: Announcement Period Returns following Outsourcing Announcements Panel A reports announcement period returns for the 20 day event period (-10, 9) while Panel B reports returns for the 12 day event period (-10, 1). Panel A: Abnormal returns for the event period (-10, 9) Lowest 30 percent Highest 30 percent UNCERTAINTY 2.01% 1.55% COORDN 0.87% 2.98%** PRIOR -0.03% -0.64% EXP -0.47% 2.45% Panel B: Abnormal returns for the event period (-10, 1) UNCERTAINTY 0.41% -0.40% COORDN -0.36% 1.84%* PRIOR 2.01%* -1.61%* EXP 2.43% 0.57% Table 7: Model of buy-and-hold abnormal returns (BHAR) and Idiosyncratic Risk Model I tests the influence of attributes of the outsourcing firm, relationship and task environment on the three year BHAR following the implementation of the outsourcing contract. Model II tests the influence of these attributes on the idiosyncratic volatility of the outsourcing firm. The latter is estimated as the annualized standard deviation of residuals from a market model regression based on daily returns (Bali et al. 2005, Ali et al. 2003, Malkiel and Xu 2006). Gains in income efficiency, selfselection into the outsourcing and contracting decisions, and firm and time effects are controlled for in both models. Robust standard errors clustered by firm are reported in parentheses. Model I Model II (BHAR) (Idiosyncratic Volatility) 0.149 (0.114) TYPE -0.001 UNCERTAINTY -0.283* (0.141) 0.250 (0.315) 0.186 (0.131) -0.483** (0.230) -0.002 (0.101) 0.199** STRIMP EXP COORDN CONTINUITY PRIOR 0.485*** (0.172) 0.214 (0.348) -0.243 (0.168) -0.107 (0.142) -0.153 (0.123) -0.077 PRIOR FIN_PERF IMR1 – Outsourcing IMR2 – Contract Constant R-square *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01 (0.095) -0.091 (0.119) 0.379 (0.248) -0.285* (0.144) 0.099 (0.110) 0.39 (0.166) -0.145 (0.149) -0.512* (0.280) 0.319* (0.178) -0.130 (0.145) 0.36