1 Microeconomics I Lesson 2. CT(I): Budget constraint Budget constraint The budget constraint (bc) is a representation of the set of opportunities open to the consumer. If we have goods x and y , with prices px and p y , and the consumer’s income is m , then the bc is px x p y y m (time dimension of bc) The budget line (bl) is the line that limits the above set. It represents the set of bundles x, y that costs exactly m . px x p y y m Graphical representation Solve above equation for y m px y x py py This is a straight line with intercept m p y and slope px p y . 2 y m py Slope px py A 6 B 4 24 Properties 25 m px x -Given the two prices, the amount of money, m , determines the area of the budget set (the position of the two intercepts). More m means more opportunities open to the consumer. -The slope of the bl measures the rate at which the market is willing to “substitute” good x for good y . Going from A to B we see that according to the bl, obtaining 1 more unit of x means giving up 2 units of y. The price of 1 unit of x is 2 units of y. Thus, the slope measures the relative price of the two goods: the price of x relative to the price of y. 3 This can be seen more generally as follows: px x p y y m At A (i) At B (ii) px x x p y y y m Subtracting (i) from (ii) we see that these two equations imply px x p y y 0 p y y px x p y x x py That is, the slope of the bl is the (negative) of the ratio of prices. Changes in the budget line a) Changes in income (holding prices constant) m y x 4 m y x b) Changes in prices (holding income constant) px y x px and p y y x 5 c) Equiproportional changes in income and prices (all prices and income increase in the same proportion) y x The budget line remains unchanged. Proof: Suppose all prices and income double. The the new budget line will be 2 p x x 2 p y y 2m Divide both sides of the equation by 2 and you get p x x p y y m, which is the original budget line. Applications These changes in prices and the effects on the bl are directly applicable to the analysis of the effects of taxes and subsidies. 6 Taxes A tax of t € on good x has the effect of increasing the price of x. The bl in this case is px t x p y y m , and therefore the effect is a rotation clockwise around the vertical intercept like the one considered above for the increase in the price of x. m py Slope without tax px py Slope with tax m px t px t py m px The above tax is called a “unit” tax. It means that it increases the price of x by a given quantity of € (say, for example, 0.5 €). The most usual form a tax on goods takes is that of an “ad valorem” tax. In this case the tax is a percentage of the price of the good. Lets us call this tax . Then, the bl is px 1 x p y y m If, for instance, the ad valorem tax is 10%, then equals 0.1, and the bl would be px 1 0.1 x p y y m 7 Subsidies A subsidy is the opposite of a tax. A tax on a good increases its price. A subsidy on good decreases its price. Let us call the subsidy s. The the new bl is px s x p y y m and the bl rotates anticlockwise around the vertical intercept. As with taxes we have “unit” subsidies and “ad valorem” subsidies. Rationing Suppose there is a law that says that the maximum quantity of good x that can be consumed per unit of time is 10 units. Income and prices Law Both 10 10 Discounts Good x becomes cheaper for all units in excess of 10 y px py 10 p x' py x 8 Surcharge Good x due to a tax becomes more expensive for all units in excess of 10. px py px t py 10 In these two last cases, the crucial thing in order to draw correctly the bl, is to identify the corresponding corner points. To illustrate how to do this we complete this lesson with the solution to two problems taken from the problem set. 9 Lesson 2. Problem 9 m 200 If 0 x 10 If x 10 px 4; py 2 px 2 for units in excess of 10; p y 2 Budget line when purchase of x is less than or equal to 10 units 4 x 2 y 200 y 100 2 x Budget line when purchase of x is 10 units or more. Here the thing to understand is that the consumer has already made the purchase of x 0 units of x at p x0 and that further purchases will be at px' . In general the budget equation for these circumstances is m px0 x0 px' x x0 p y y Substituting in the numbers of the problem, we have 200 40 2( x 10) 2 y 160 2 x 20 2 y 180 2 x 2 y y 90 x 10 y 100 90 A 80 10 50 100 Another way of finding out the second bl At A we know two things a) px 2 and p y 2 b) to make bundle (10, 80) affordable at these prices, what income does the consumer need? (in other words, what is the vertical intercept of the new bl?). Let us call this intercept m . Then x 11 m 2 x 2 y m 2(10) 2(80) 180 Therefore, 180 2 x 2 y y 90 x Repeat the problem at home, but suppose that after 10 units of x a per unit tax of 2 € is imposed on all units in excess of 10. Lesson 2. Problem 10 a) 200 4 x 2 y y 100 2 x y 100 50 x b) If the subsidy was transferable, it would be like money for the consumer. So then, 200 50 4 x 2 y y 125 2 x But it is not transferable. So the above budget line does not apply until the consumer has not spent entirely the subsidy on good x. That is, until the 12 consumer has consumed 12.5 units of x. So the complete budget equation is if x 12.5 y 100 if x 12.5 y 125 2 x y 125 100 x 12.5 c) 50 62.5 200 4 x (2 1) y 200 4 x 3 y 100 200/3 50 y 200 4 x 3 3