6.b The Budget Constraint In the previous section we looked at indifference curves, which showed what the consumer would like to have with respect to two goods X and Y. In this section we will look at what the consumer can actually afford. A budget constraint is an equation, graph, or table that shows the bundles available to the consumer. If we again assume there are only two goods available X and Y, a budget constraint has the equation I = Px·X + Py·Y. In this equation I is the total money income, P x is the price of good X, and Py is the price of good Y. Since there are only two goods, the left side of this equation represents total expenditure. Let's go over an example of a budget constraint. Let total income I = $100, price of good X P x = $10 and price of good Y Py = $5. Table 6.b.1 shows the bundles that can be acquired under this budget constraint. X 0 1 2 Y 20 18 16 10 0 Table 6.b.1 shows the bundles that can be acquired under the budget constraint 100 = 10X + 5Y. If the consumer buys none of good X, then the budget allows for 20 units of good Y to be bought. If the consumer buys one unit of good X, then what is left in the budget is enough to buy 18 units of good Y. As the consumer buys more of X, less of Y can be bought all the way until the consumer buys 10 units of good X when nothing is left in the budget to by good Y. Plotting these bundles on a graph gives us the budget line. Diagram 6.b.1 shows the budget line corresponding to table 6.b.1. Diagram 6.b.1 Y 20 Vertical axis intercept = I/Py Budget line 100 = 10X + 5Y Slope of Budget line = Px / Py Y Diagram 6.b.1 shows the budget line for 100=10X+5Y. If all of the income was spent on good Y, then 20 unitsof Y would be bought. This gives the vertical axis intercept. Similarly, 10 units of X gives our horizontal axis intercept. Horizontal axis intercept = I/Px X X 10 We find the slope of a line by dividing the change in Y by the change in X, Y/X. Since the vertical axis intercept is I/Py and the horizontal intercept is I/Px we can substitute these in for Y and X respectively. I / Py Slope of budget line = = P x / Py I / Px The slope of the budget line is the price of good X divided by the price of good Y. This is also referred to as the relative price of good X. This is because it shows the number of good Y the consumer must give up in order to get one more unit of X. Shifts in Budget lines Budget lines can shift in three ways. The first is a parallel shift. This is where the budget line shift outward or inward in a parallel fashion. This happens when the Income I changes or when the prices of good X and Y change in a similar manner. If the income of a consumer is cut in half, then the consumer can buy half as many of goods X and Y as before. Similarly, if income stays the same but the price of goods X and Y both double, then again the consumer can only buy half as many of goods X and Y. Diagram 6.b.2 shows these situations. Y Case A: I = $100 Px =$10 Py =$5 Diagram 6.b.2 20 Budget line #1 Cases A & D Case B: I = $50 Px =$10 Py =$5 10 Budget line #2 Cases B & C X 5 Case C: I = $100 Px =$20 Py =$10 Case D: I = $50 Px =$5 Py =$2.5 10 Diagram 6.b.2. Shows four different cases which correspond to two different budget lines. Case A has the initial values for income and prices and corresponds to budget line #1. Then, income is cut in half, as shown in case B. This corresponds to a parallel shift in the budget line with case B represented by budget line #2. If income was not cut in half, but instead both the price of good X and good Y doubled as in case C, then we would have a similar shift in the budget line. Case D shows if income and prices were cut in half. In this situation, nothing real has changed; the consumer still has the same purchasing power and the corresponding budget line is budget line #1. The next type of shift in budget lines is called a pivot. The budget line pivots when the relative price of good X changes. In other words, a pivot is caused by a change one of the prices, either P x or Py. A per unit subsidy to the consumer for one of the goods would be an example of a pivot of a budget line. Diagram 6.b.3 shows a pivot in the budget line due to a $5 per unit subsidy for good X. Y 20 Initial condition: I = $100 Px = $10 Py = $5 Diagram 6.b.3 With $5/unit X subsidy: I = $100 Px = $5 Py = $5 X 10 20 Diagram 6.b.3 a five dollar per unit subsidy for good X causes the budget line to pivot. The third type of budget line shift is called a kinked budget line. This is where the budget line changes slope at some point. An example of a kinked budget line is the food stamp program. Lets say tat good X is food and the consumer receives a food stamp worth 5 units of food. The first 5 units of food are then free to the consumer, however the consumer must pay for every unit after 5. This situation is shown in diagram 6.b.4. Y Diagram 6.b.4 Original budget line 20 Budget line with food stamp Diagram 6.b.4 shows a kinked budget line. A food stamp worth 5 units allows the consumer to get up to 5 units of food and still acquire 20 units of Y. If the consumer wished to get a sixth unit of food, then the consumer would have to sacrifice a certain amount of good Y, representing the downward sloping part of the budget line. X food 5 10 15