Competition Policy in Asean - International Network of Civil Society

advertisement
Competition Policy in ASEAN
G.Sivalingam1
I. Introduction
This paper discusses the structure of competition in several sectors of the economies of
the ten countries that are members of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations
(ASEAN). The ten countries are at various stages of development and of these only three
have a competition law, while the most advanced that is Singapore does not have a
competition law. The reluctance of governments to introduce competition law is that it
conflicts with the strategy of economic development that they have adopted. Most of the
countries have evolved from a communist, socialist, authoritarian, feudal or colonial past
and state intervention in the economy is quite pervasive. Their experience is in managing
mixed economies as most governments have to be concerned with distributional issues
because of the need to avoid social unrest and political turmoil.
The Asean countries have however been undergoing a process of change from a “growth
with distribution strategy’ to a market oriented economic strategy. The role of the
government has been dominant in the “growth with distribution” strategy and as a
consequence the transition to a market economy has been marked by tensions between
the market and the government. Not all countries in ASEAN have similar economic
systems but they have several features in common, that is, opening up to foreign trade,
being more responsive to deeper integration with the global economy, liberalizing their
investment regime to compete for foreign direct investment, closing of strategic sectors
of the economy to foreign competition, reducing tariff barriers consistent with the
demands of the Asean Free Trade Area (AFTA) and the World Trade Organization
(WTO). Most of them have also embarked on a strategy of privatizing state owned
enterprises and building institutions to sustain a market economy.
The rolling back of the role of the state has been due to government failure to generate
growth; corruption and mismanagement of state owned enterprises. The 1997 East Asian
financial crisis also exposed the vulnerabilities and weaknesses of the financial and
broader economic strucutures. This together with the decline in Foreign Direct
Investment flows, which went to China has made it mandatory for the Asean countries to
undertake far reaching reforms to strengthen institutions that will facilitate the operation
of a market economy. The reforms include improving standards of corporate governance
and the rule of law.
In this chapter we review the recent economic strategy followed by most of the Asean
countries before we look atexternal pressures for reform of these economies. We then
discuss the origins of the call for competition policy and theories of competition policy
before describing the status of competition policy and law in these ten countries.
1
Faculty of Business, University of Malaya, Malaysia
II. Growth with Distribution Strategy
The Southeast Asian economies are in a process of transition to a market economy as a
result of the deeper integration of these economies with the global economy and as a
consequence of membership in multilateral organizations especially the World Trade
Organization, ASEAN, AFTA and APEC (Lloyd and Associates, 1999:27) . In the
1970s, with the threat of communism looming high as the Vietnam War escalated, the
prevailing doctrine was that the market was not efficient at distributing the gains from
economic growth. The allocation of resources was not Pareto optimal because winners
did not compensate losers. The Kaldor-Hicks criteria sought to overcome this oversight
by providing some ground rules for the winners to compensate losers so that nobody was
made worse off as a result of economic growth and change. Even though winners could
compensate losers theoretically, using the Kaldor-Hicks criteria, in practice the
compensation did not take place and hence the need for government intervention.
Absolute poverty was perceived as increasing and income inequality was worsening and
this posed a threat to the world capitalist system as the probability that the impoverished
may opt for a communist state was high. The capitalist growth strategy, which ignored
distributional concerns and alienated or marginalized the poor was abandoned for a
growth with distribution strategy, which required government to correct market failure
and distribute the gains from growth more evenly by facilitating the participation of the
poor in the development process in the form of employment and in some cases in the
form of equity ownership in listed and unlisted incorporated companies.
The main instrument for achieving the redistribution goal were public enterprises or
state owned enterprises as they are known in several countries. However, by the early
1980s it was realized that these public enterprises distorted incentives when they
intervened in the market to set “politically correct” prices that did not recover costs and
promote sustainable development. It was also realized that they depended on government
subsidies and government protection from competition as they were inefficient and
generally loss making (Khemani and Dutz, 1995) as they pursued political and not
economic goals (Shleifer and Vishny, 1998). As a result of government industrial policy
and subsidies, dominant enterprises or public monopolies arose (Khemani and Dutz
(1995), which resulted in a loss of consumers’ surplus.
At the same time that public enterprises were intervening in the economy to correct for
market failure, many of the more developed Asean countries were liberalizing their
investment laws to attract labor intensive foreign direct investments to generate exports
and economic growth. Asean countries, most of whom had historically depended on
natural resources to generate growth, provided more and more attractive incentives to
foreign investment, at various stages of their development, as commodity prices fell. The
initial import substituting industrialization strategy gave way to a more labor intensive
and export oriented industrialization strategy as import substituting industries could not
generate sufficient jobs as they were capital intensive and the domestic market was too
small for these industries. Today, the multinationals engaged in manufacturing in several
Asean countries, for example, Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand, Philippines, Indonesia,
Vietnam and Cambodia account for a large portion of the export earnings generated in
these countries.
III. Industrial Policy
The governments’ industrialization strategy was also guided by either an explicit or
implicit industrial policy. The economic plans gave a large role to the public sector and
industrial policy coordinated by the government guided the process of industrialization.
Some of the governments also chose “national champions” or “captains of industry” and
cultivated close relationships with the conglomerates they created and emulated the Japan
Incorporated model by labeling themselves, for instance, as Singapore Incorporated,
Philippines Incorporated and Malaysia Incorporated.
Industrial Policy, it has been alleged, has been used consciously by governments to
discriminate against foreign competition in the domestic economy. Industrial policy
created two economies, that is, the enclave export processing zones dominated by
multinationals and the domestic economic sector dominated by small and medium
enterprises that depended on government subsidies and soft commercial loans. The
linkages between the foreign and domestic industrial sectors was not strong. The foreign
multinationals were not treated as national companies.
The multinationals were only given incentives to produce for exports and competition in
the domestic economy was discouraged in some countries. The hoped for liberalization
and deregulation of the domestic sector as a result of the large presence of multinationals
in the export processing zones did not occur. The domestic economy remained fairly
closed and dominated by inefficient monopolies. This was because of barriers to entry
and exit erected by governments of several countries.
According to the World Bank, “the main institutional barrier to domestic competition are
government regulations on entry and exit of firms. Even in the tradable sector,
international competition may not lead to domestic competition, partly because
institutional barriers to competition, such as government regulations in product and factor
markets that deter firm entry, exit and growth. Excessive and costly government
regulations also facilitate corruption and lead to adverse distributional consequences by
inducing workers and firms to escape into the informal sector” (World Bank, 2001:135).
Marcus Noland of the Institute for International Economics argues that not only was the
foreign firm discriminated against in the domestic economy but the government also
affects the level, composition or form of foreign investment, “through official
prohibitions, restrictions or official approvals processes, in which the government
intervenes directly” and sometimes by the “behavior and practices of private parties,
facilitated by government policies not directly aimed at foreign investment”(Noland,
1999:1).
Several sectors of the domestic economy including the services sector were not opened
until recently to foreign entry. These included telecommunications, water, power and
financial services which are characterized by important dominant positions by incumbent
firms where contestability of markets is limited because of large fixed costs. The utilities,
for example, water, telecommunications, power were considered as natural monopolies
before technological changes occurred and as such were considered as appropriate to be
left to public provision. New banking licenses were seldom issued and foreign banks
were denied entry. Government and family owned banks dominate in many of the Asian
countries. Wholesale and retail trade was also protected from foreign competition and
kept as a national preserve.
Industrial policy was also pursued to protect domestic industries that were not
competitive internationally. Ross in reviewing research in this field reports that Gifford
and Matsushita (1996) found that the most frequent and widely experienced conflicts
between industrial policy and competition policy occur in circumstances where domestic
industry is subject to competition from foreign competitors after having lost its
international competitiveness. Under such circumstances , governments may intervene to
encourage the restructuring of the domestic industry and to temporarily protect the local
industry from foreign competition. The restructuring often consolidates domestic firms,
reducing domestic competition as well as preventing foreign firms from acquiring the
assets of these firms no longer able to compete with foreign firms (Ross, 2003:3).
Sometimes the infant industry argument has also been used to justify protecting domestic
firms from foreign competition until they reach a certain degree of dominance in the
domestic market to compete in the international market.
The industrial policies pursued by the various governments in a creating a dual economic
structure came under pressure as commodity prices collapsed in the mid 1980s.
Governments dependent on natural resources had to provide more incentives to attract
labor intensive, export oriented industries to substitute for the loss of export earnings
from primary commodity production and to provide employment to the growing labor
force. At the same time the multinationals were campaigning for national treatment in the
host countries and to roll back the role of the state and to allow resources to be allocated
by market forces worldwide so that resources will flow to their most valued users or uses.
IV. Neo Liberalism and Competition Policy
The ideological underpinnings of the current reversal of policy to roll bank the role of the
state and to make the private sector the engine of growth in most or all the Asean
countries can be found in the Reagan-Thatcher doctrine enunciated in 1983 in which the
virtues of privatization and the market economy were enunciated. The Reagan-Thatcher
doctrine provided support for the Washington Consensus as a strategy of global resource
allocation. The focus of the Washington Consensus according to the person who coined
the term in 1990, that is, John Williamson of the Institute for International Economics
was: fiscal discipline; a redirection of public expenditure priorities towards fields offering
both high economic returns and the potential to improve income distribution, such as
primary health care, primary education and infrastructure; tax reform to lower marginal
tax rates and broaden the tax base; interest rate liberalization, a competitive exchange
rate; trade liberalization; liberalization of inflows of foreign direct investment;
privatization; deregulation to abolish barriers to entry and exit and secure property righ
(Williamson, 2004). Privatization is perceived to be pro-competition as it opens entry to
private participation in the production of goods and services under competitive market
conditions.
The theoretical justification for the Reagan-Thatcher doctrine and the Washington
Consensus was provided by the Chicago School. In the 1970s, Milton Friedman and the
Chicago School economists developed free market ideas based on deregulation and
privatization similar to the laissez-faire capitalism of the nineteenth century (hence the
term neo-liberalism). This was to become the economic orthodoxy of globalization. In the
early 1980s, the full political resources of corporate America were mobilized to regain
control of the political agenda and the court system. Reagan and Thatcher, using the
Chicago School ideas, made the world safe for corporations. They dismantled the social
contract through tax cuts, ignoring unemployment, rolling back social welfare and
increasing privatization. The debt crisis of 1982 gave the USA its chance to dominate the
world economy and for the rich nations to re-subordinate the global South through
structural adjustment via the World Bank and the IMF (New Internationalist, 2002:2).
In support of rolling back the role of the state, Ronald Coase (1991) of Chicago argued
that the market is the most efficient allocator of scarce resources. According to Coase if
property rights are clearly defined and enforceable and if economic agents had full
information and transaction costs are low or zero and if there is a market to buy and sell
these property rights than these resources will flow to their most valued uses. There is no
need for government intervention to correct for externalities because the economic agents
can bargain to achieve a Pareto optimal allocation of resources. Furthermore, the ability
of economic agents to achieve the Pareto optimal allocation does not depend on which
economic agent is given the property right. This argument was recast into what is today
the most cited theorem in economics, that is, the Coase theorem (Stigler, 1989) for which
the author won a Nobel Prize awarded to the science of economics in early 1991 (The
Bank of Sweden, 1991).
The Coase theorem gave a powerful reason to roll back the role of the state and to define
private property rights and to create market institutions and a sympathetic court system so
that these property rights could be traded continuously so that they could be used
efficiently. Even if one distributed assets to someone who did not know how to manage
them well, in a society with well defined property rights that person would have an
incentive to sell to someone who could manage the assets more efficiently. However,
when property rights are vested in public enterprises or State Owned Enterprises they
cannot be bought and sold and as a result the probability is high that they would not be
used efficiently.
The Coase theorem as stated earlier provide theoretical support for the Washington
Consensus to push for reducing tariff barriers and free trade so as to reduce transaction
costs and to facilitate the free flow of resources to their most valued users. The three big
ideas of the Washington Consensus were macroeconomic discipline, market economy
and openness to the world (Williamson, 2002:2). The formation of the World Trade
Organization in 1995, provided an opportunity not only to reduce tariff barriers but also
to push for measures that would open domestic economies to competition. The need for
liberalizing the domestic investment regime had been discussed at WTO Ministerial
Meetings in Singapore, Doha and Cancun. The issue of competition policy had been
classified together with investment, transparency in government procurement and trade
facilitation as the Singapore Issues, which were brought up in Doha and Cancun but not
resolved.
V. WTO and Competition Policy – The Singapore Issues
The Working Group of the WTO on the Singapore Issues summed up the need for
competition policy as follows: “as government barriers to trade and investment have been
reduced, there have been increasing concerns that the gains from such liberalization may
be thwarted by private anti-competitive practices. There is also a growing realization that
mutually supportive trade and competition policies can contribute to sound economic
development, and that effective competition policies help to ensure that the benefits of
liberalization and market-based reforms flow through to all citizens” (WTO,2004:1)
The Working Group looked at the interaction between trade and competition policy
including the impact of anti-competitive practices of enterprises and associations on
international trade; the impact of state monopolies, exclusive rights and regulatory
policies on competition and international trade; the relationship between trade related
aspects of intellectual property rights and competition policy; the relationship between
investment and competition policy and the impact of trade policy on competition. It also
addressed the issue of the contribution of competition policy to achieving the objectives
of the WTO including the promotion of international trade.
The Singapore Issues were not resolved in Singapore and were brought forward to the
WTO ministerial meeting at Doha in 2001. There was no consensus achieved and the
issues were brought forward to the Cancun WTO ministerial meeting in 2003, with the
USA and the EU pressing for resolution of the issues because “in the context of
globalization, … competition policy is intimately connected with the policy pillars of
liberalization, deregulation and privatization, known as the Washington Consensus or
neoliberalism” (Lee and Morand, 2003:1). There has been a clear recognition that in the
absence of a strong competition policy, deregulation may result in the transfer of power
from the state to powerful private sector oligarchies.
Competition policy is seen as critical in creating a market economy because it is
concerned with reining in the excessive market power of large corporations as manifested
in cartels, restrictive business practices and abuse of market power. There has been
opposition to competition policy from the developing countries because from “the
developent perspective … there is a need for government to assist and promote local
firms so that they can be viable and develop despite their present relative weakness, so
that they can successfully compete with their foreign firms and their products”
(Choudhury, 2004:2). The developed countries however argue that the foreign firm
should be given the right and equality of opportunity to compete with local firms in the
local market, and governments should be prohibited from giving preferences or assistance
to local firms. They invoke the WTO’s non discrimination principle in support of their
argument (Choudhury, 2004:2-3).
However, regardless of the outcome of the WTO meetings, competition policy and law
has been pursued by developing countries, including Asean countries such as Indonesia,
Thailand and the Philippines, interested in benefiting from foreign direct investment and
trade and deeper integration with the world economy. Competition policy is not rejected
outright as the debate is on the form of regulation that is needed for developing countries.
There have also been arguments to have a dual competition policy, one for domestic
enterprises and the other for foreign enterprises (Third World Network, 2003:1). There
have also been conflicting theories of competition policy.
VI. Theories of Competition Policy
Theories of Competition Policy can be classified as belonging to the Chicago School, the
Austrian School a’la Schumpeter and the German School.
The Chicago School (Demsetz, 1979) argues against government intervention in the
market because governments more often than not prohibit competition and the emergence
of efficient firms. If the government provides the framework for competition in the form
of policy and law, then competition between firms will see the “survival of the fittest.”
The inefficient firms will be forced out of the market. In other words the most efficient
and lowest cost firms will emerge and the consumers will benefit with better quality
products and more choice and affordable goods and services.
According to Singleton (1997:2), “concentrated market structures and even dominant
firm market structures that result from this process (survival of the fittest) are assumed to
be efficient and to generate maximum social welfare … According to this school, policy
makers impede the competitive process by prohibiting business practices that enhance
efficiency and innovation or by punishing firms that have attained a large market share by
virtue of superior efficiency or innovation.” There is no need for competition policy
because the threat of entry forces enterprises to increase efficiency and pursue product
and process innovation. There is also no need for government induced barriers to entry
and exit.
The Chicago School of thought is of the views that monopolies are not inefficient
because they are the outcome of a long process of survival of the fittest. The monopolies
entered a competitive industry and were able to become large and dominant because of
superior technology, economies of scale and other attributes. So the existence of
monopolies are not by themselves a detriment to consumer welfare.
Posner has argued that the existence of a natural monopoly does not provide adequate
justification for government regulation. Natural monopoly is a circumstance where it is
economically more efficient for a single organization to have a monopoly in order to
avoid duplication and wasted investment. The arguments in favor of a natural monopoly
are (i) overheads are reduced; (ii) zero competition means less money on advertising,
sales and marketing and (iii) more money is available to be spent on product
development.. Examples of natural monopolies are the utilities, for example, water,
power, telecommunications and cable (Lea, 1999:1).
However, as pointed out earlier natural monopolies tend to become non dominant
because of technological change. The telephone industry was considered a natural
monopoly because it had huge fixed costs and was non contestable. However, with
technological change the cellular phone companies have eroded the market share of fixed
line operators. The Chicago School claims that monopolies are occasional, unstable and
transitory. As a consequence, antitrust law is really unnecessary, since all monopolies
will eventually be broken by competitive pressures (Cobb, 1999:4). The Chicago School
reminds us that the aim of competition law is to provide the framework for competition
that increases efficiency and not the equitable distribution of income.
The emergence of monopolies has also been argued by Schumpeter (1954) and the
Austrian School as not being detrimental to social welfare if they emerge as a result of
technological innovation and efficiency. Technical change lowers the average total cost
and as a result one firm may become dominant. The dominant monopoly may not be
dominant for long because other firms may enter the industry and capture some of the
abnormal profits. A new discovery may also displace the existing monopoly by a process
which Schumpeter terms “creative destruction.” According to the Austrian School
competition is a dynamic discovery process as rival entrepreneurs seek new profit
opportunities in a world that is changing. Through successful innovation, firms out
compete rivals and dominate the market for a while. The dominant position is constantly
threatened. High profits mean that the industry is active. Competition policy ought not to
prohibit or penalize enterprise behavior that may be regarded as efficient in a dynamic
sense, although it does agree that policy ought to ensure that the playing field is level.
The third view of competition calls for an explicit competition policy. According to this
view, the origins of which can be traced back to Germany and the United States of
America, competition policy is necessary to curb the power of large firms. According to
Kerr and Word, “in general, the objective is to protect small firms from the abuse of
dominant firms and thereby encourage competition to flourish. German law singles out
dominant firms for special treatment. They alone are prohibited from engaging in certain
business practices that are thought to impede the entry or expansion of smaller firms.
Furthermore, small and medium-sized firms are, by exemption, allowed to engage in
cooperative efforts to realize economies of scale and scope otherwise available only to
large firms” (Kerr and Wood, 2000:7).
The United States has had a long history of influencing competition policy around the
world. The Sherman Act of 1890 which forms the basis of US anti-trust law prohibits
agreements in restraint of trade, monopolization and conspiracies to fix prices. The
Clayton Act of 1914 prohibits price discrimination, tie in sales, exclusive dealing
contracts and prohibits acquisitions, mergers or joint ventures that may substantially
reduce competition. The Clayton Act “prohibits acquisitions, mergers, or joint ventures
that may substantially reduce competition” (Devuyst, 2000:320).
In reacting to the rise of Nazism, the United States of America, wanted to check the
concentration of industries because the large industries created the conditions for the rise
of Hitler and Nazism. To reduce concentration, the United States insisted on a strict anticartel policy for post War Germany, which was subsequently incorporated in the 1957
Treaty of Rome, which established the European Community (Devuyst, 2000:321). The
European Competition Policy today has the role of protecting new entrants especially
small enterprises from rivalry of large enterprises (Singleton, 1997). This was related to
the need to disperse economic power that is linked to political influence. This view is
based on the broad notion that large enterprises wield considerable political power that is
gained through influencing policies that end up protecting them from competition.
When the USA occupied Japan it also introduced the 1947 Antimonopoly Act. “The Act
was designed to break the power of the zaibatsu, the gigantic family trusts that dominated
Japanese society before and during the war. However, in 1952, once the American
Occupation had ended, Japanese anticartel policy was reviewed, and numerous
exemptions were granted to allow so-called crisis and rationalization cartels and to permit
anti-competitive coordination in the framework of business associations. During the late
1980s and the 1990s, under international pressure, the number of exemptions was
gradually reduced. At the same time, an important deregulation program was put in
place” (Devuyst, 2000:321). The USA has also influenced Competition Policy in the
Philippines to be modeled after the Sherman Act of 1840. The Philippines has had an Act
to Prohibit Monopolies and Combinations in Restraint of Trade since 1925.
The USA has also been active in advocating the opening of markets and the deeper
integration of ASEAN countries with the global economy. According to a former
Secretary of State, “the Asean nations form a half-trillion-dollar regional economy that is
expected to double in size over the next decade. With expanding middle classes, swelling
demand for consumer goods and services and need for infrastructure, ASEAN looms
large in the strategies of American companies …, and has attracted the attention of the
United States Government as one of the world’s ten Big Emerging Markets”
(Christopher, 2003:2).
The USA has also urged ASEAN to speed up regional liberalization, promote greater
openness to global economy, make a commitment to market reforms, seek AFTA’s
(Asean Free Trade Agreement) agreement to intellectual Property Rights, promote trade
related aspects of International Property Protection; toughen enforcement of national
laws; liberalize trade in financial services; open up competition in massive emerging
telecommunications market; treat all service providers as equal; break up long entrenched
monopolies to encourage price competition and improve service. Create independent
regulatory bodies that will follow non-discriminatory and transparent procedures to
safeguard against monopoly domination of markets.(Christopher, 2003:1-4)
VII. Ingredients of Competition Policy
Competition policy is not a new issue in the world trading system. The 1947 Havana
Charter and the International Trade Organization that it contemplated highlighted the
need to prevent “Restrictive Business Practices”. Chapter V of the Havana Charter
contains a number of articles “to prevent, on the part of private or commercial public
enterprises, business practices affecting international trade which restrain competition,
limit access to markets or foster monopolistic control. The Charter specified six key
anticompetitive practices considered potentially harmful to trade, namely: (i) price fixing
and other related practices; (ii) exclusion of enterprises from markets or allocation of
markets and customers and fixing sales and purchase quotas; (iii) discrimination against
certain enterprises; (iv) output restrictions and quotas; (v) agreements preventing the
development of patented or unpatented technology and inventions and (vi) certain
extensions of the use of rights under patents, trademarks or copyrights. Furthermore, the
ITO envisaged investigating and ruling on complaints with the power to request members
to take remedial action” (OECD, 2002: 5).
The need for a competition policy in a free market economy is to regulate the invisible
hand of Adam Smith (1776) so as to promote the public good. As we have noted a
monopoly may be undesirable per se but it may perform a useful function by rule of
reason. If a monopoly arose because of efficiency and it is the lowest cost provider of the
good or service then its continued existence may be justified on grounds of rule of reason
although per se a monopoly may be declared undesirable. If however a monopoly
restricts entry and is inefficient then we need a competition policy and authority to
restraint the monopoly to avoid the deadweight loss to society of the monopolist’s
continued activity in the economy.
The focus of competition policy is to create the conditions and develop institutions for the
efficient allocation of scarce resources.
According to Maddock (1995:31), “Competition policy is guided by the belief that the
domain of markets should be exploited as far as possible to perform allocative tasks with
benefits expected in terms of allocative, productive and dynamic efficiency.”
The objective of competition policy is to ease entry and exit conditions by removing
government erected barriers, structural barriers and entry deterrent strategies of
incumbents. Government induced barriers include trade restrictions, regulations, price
controls, procedure for allocation of inputs. These barriers increase opportunities for rent
seeking. Structural barriers include the need for high sunk costs, that is investments that
do not have alternative uses and hence create markets that are not contestable. Strategic
entry deterrents by incumbent firms include: predatory pricing, product differentiation
and advertising (Dixit, 1982).
Cartels are also anti competitive as they are agreements to fix prices by reducing quantity
to the detriment of consumer welfare. Similarly mergers and acquisitions that lead to the
creation of inefficient monopolies may reduce social welfare. Three types of mergers can
be identified, they include, vertical, horizontal and conglomerate mergers. Horizontal
mergers occur between enterprises producing similar products. They may have an
incentive to reduce output and increase price thus adversely affecting consumer welfare.
Vertical mergers occur when enterprises combine their resources at different stages of
production and hence involve enterprises that are both supplier and producer or producer
and retailer of the same good or service. They may be motivated by economies of scale
but from the point of view of society there is a trade off between efficiency gains and
economic or market power. Conglomerate mergers occur when enterprises producing
different products combine their resources to capture economies of scope (Lipczynski
and Wilson, 2001).
Once the appropriate or enabling environment for competition is created by public policy,
the only form of government intervention will be in the enactment of Competition Law
and a Competition Authority to ensure that the rules of the game are adhered to.
Competition Law is a subset of Competition Policy because policy encompasses the
whole economic, political, social and legal environment, whereas law stipulates
appropriate standards of behavior, deviations from which can be penalized under the
provision of the law. An equally important focus of the government in formulating
competition policy is to give sufficient protection to consumer interests so that the
consumer is not made worse off as a result of the introduction of competition policy.
The focus of competition authorities is to prevent the formation of monopolies that
cannot be justified by rule of reason or on economic grounds. Monopolies may be formed
by collusive behavior, price fixing, vertical and horizontal integration and government
regulation. The most pervasive form of monopoly formation in ASEAN countries has
been by the government as it feels that it has superior information in “picking winners”
This restricts competition and the efficient allocation of resources.
Vertically integrated industries also tend to have considerable monopoly power especially
if they require heavy capital investments for start ups and are in essence, therefore, noncontestable. Examples are power, telecommunications and water, which were previously
defined as natural monopolies because scale economies are achievable only at very high
levels of output and the plant size required as a result is only affordable by the
government or very large enterprises.
In the case of power, vertical integration occurs because power generation, distribution,
retailing and billing are concentrated in one agency. This has recently been broken up by
privatizing power generation by competitive bidding to Independent Power Producers
(IPPs). Theoretically, these IPPs are to compete to lower costs and these costs are
expected to be passed on to consumers in the form of lower prices. In the case of
telecommunications, vertical integration occurs because the fixed lines are laid by the
authority, which also retails and bills the consumers. However, with the introduction of
mobile or cellular phones and the internet and the granting of equal access to all operators
at a cost, the competition in the market has become intense and the former so-called
natural monopoly has lost a considerable portion of its market share in the
telecommunications market.
The objectives of competition policy are then: (i) to ensure efficient allocation of
resources; (ii) to prevent domination of the economy and price fixing by a few large
conglomerates. The focus of anti-trust policy is to break up monopolies unless there are
strong economic reasons to justify that they are better able to allocate resources than a
competitive firm; (iii) to protect consumers against abuses of market dominance and
against price increasing and choice reducing agreements between companies; (iv) to
create conditions whereby competition helps to stimulate technological change and
innovation and (v) to keep markets open to competitors, whether local or foreign.
VIII. Competition Policy and Development
The distributional consequences of open competition among firms is not the direct
concern of competition policy. This is because it is expected that through a competitive
process, economic growth will occur and this growth will trickle down and hence it is
argued that there is no need for government intervention. This form of economic growth
through open competition is superior to a government led growth process because it uses
resources more efficiently.
However, there is no broad agreement on this interpretation of economic growth and
there are doubts that the benefits will trickle down to the poor and the disdavantaged.
There are those who believe that a competitive growth process based on the philosophy
of the “survival of the fittest,” will marginalize the poor and isolate them. This is the
point of contention between the developed and developing countries over the Singapore
Issue on competition policy. It has been noted the deregulation and privatization, the
cornerstones of the Washington Consensus did not lead to a flowering of liberal markets
but simply served the interests of powerful capitalists, whose wealth and authority had
previously been based on their control of protected industries.
However, the developmental role of monopolies has been highlighted by Ajit Singh
(2002), who argues that the chaebols in Korea although dominant as conglomerates were
the prime movers of the rapid economic growth of Korea, which was also adversely
affected by the 1997 East Asian crisis. The chaebols received subsidized credit,
government protection and used their resources to make huge investments, which
generated massive rents. The investments were necessary to increase productivity and
generate economic growth. In the case of Japan, the oligopolies were also competitive as
contest based competition among them was encouraged so as to enable them to get cheap
credt, foreign exchange and protecton from international competition. According to Ajit
Singh, “these rewards were contingent on relative performance either in export markets,
technological development, or in introducing new products” (Singh, 2002:24).
Similarly, in other Asan countries privatization of infrastructure projects required
massive investments, which it is believed can only be carried out by conglomerates with
close relations with the government. However, this is transferred as higher prices to
consumers because the present vlue of tolls are mortgaged to banks for loans. The cost of
construction in other instances may include the present value of the tolls so that the
conglomerate does not bear any risk. In these cases, the benefits are privatized to the
conglomerate and the costs are socialized to the public.
Ajit Singh (2002) is of the opinion that the developing countries are not ready for
competition. He cites Laffont, who calls for a second best solution to the competition
problem. According to Laffont:
“Competition is an unambiguously good thing in the first-best world of economists. The
world assumes large numbr of participants in all markets, no public goods, no
externalities, no information asymmetries, no natural monopolies, complete markets,
fully rational economic agents,a benevolent court system to enforce contracts, and a
benevolent government providing lump sum transfers to achieve any desirable
distribution. Besides developing countries are so far from this ideal world, it is not always
the case that competition should be encouraged in these countries” (Laffont, 1998:237).
The conditions that Laffont lists for the encouragement of competition do not even exist
in the developed countries. Negative externalities, forexample, air pollution, crime an
terrorism are common throughout the world. When the history of the recent performance
of the New York stock market is written, it will be a story of imperfect markets and
asymmetric information. Furthermore, Laffont does not address the problem of whether
competition that is based on the “survival of the fittest” is inferior to feudalism as an
economic philosophy. Whether a country adopts a country adopts a competitive regime is
not dependent on policy but technology especially if it is dependent on foreign capital to
generate growth. Competition in telecommunications was not generated by policy but by
technology, which put a check on the abuse of dominant power by the fixed line
monopolies because mobie phones were a substitute. The mobile phone market is
contestable because of equal access to the fixed line. The mobile phones are needed to
generate economic growth.
According to Ajit Singh, “Laffont is quite pessimistic about developing countries being
able to implement competition laws because of widespread rent seeking, corruption and
ineffective governments in these countries. He makes a valid pioint that implementation
of competition laws requires a strong state which many developing countries lack”
(Singh, 2002:20).
However it must be pointed out that the East Asian miracle economies were credited with
a strong state and that is why they were able to create huge conglomerates as the
generators of economic growth and development (World Bank, 1993). Corruption and
rent seeking is endemic in all societies where enforcement is weak. The problem is if
states are unwilling to generate competition and enforce laws then because of
technological change driving the globalization of capital, external forces may take over
the role of national governments in creating strong states. Global technological changes
are forcing countries to formulate and implement competition laws or be subject to
foreign domination or be marginalized from the benevolence or otherwise of the world
capitalist machine.
IX. Current Status of Competition Policy in ASEAN
Some ASEAN countries have tended to use the Japanese model of competition law as an
example of anti-competitive legislation that seems workable. The origins of the Japanese
Antimonopoly Act (1947) can be traced back to the American occupation of Japan. As a
consequence it has been influenced by the American anti-trust law and is focused on
ensuring free and fair competition (Matsusita, 1990). Malaysia has been discussing using
the Japanese model to enact its anti-competitive legislation, which is currently in the draft
legislation stage. Only three out of the ten ASEAN countries have enacted Competition
Acts or Anti-Monopoly Acts. These include Thailand, the Philippines and Indonesia. We
review the status of competition policy and law in the ASEAN countries below. In depth
studies of competition policy in each of the ten countries discussed below is provided in
the country studies that follow this chapter.
Indonesia
The introduction of legislation to prohibit anti-competitive activities in Indonesia came
as a consequence of the adverse effects of the 1997 East Asian crisis on the Indonesian
economy. The American response was to subject Indonesia to the conditionality of the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) in exchange for financial aid to resolve the balance of
payments and the rupiah crisis. As part of the conditionality, Indonesia signed the Letter
of Intent committing itself to “promoting competition in the domestic economy by
accelerating privatization and expanding the role of the private sector in the provision of
infrastructure” (IMF, 1997).
A draft competition bill was submitted to the Indonesian Parliament in July 1997, which
was subsequently passed by the Parliament in 1999. The Act that received the assent of
the President and came into effect in 2000 was “The Law Concerning the Prohibition of
Monopolistic Practices and Unfair Business Competition”. The Law covers unfair
business practices with regard to: prohibited agreements; oligopoly; price determination,
division of territory; boycotts; cartels; vertical integration, oilgopsony; trusts; monopoly;
monopsony; conspiracy; dominant position; mergers, consolidations and acquisitions and
share ownership. The law has also provisions for dispute settlement and penalties for
violations of the law.
The law which was inspired by the German model is expected to be implemented by the
newly formed Business Supervisory Committee, which also is expected to play an
advisory role in advising the government on needed policy and legislative reforms to
further enhance the conditions for competition in the domestic economy. The members of
the Committee are appointed by the President and have wide powers to regulate
restrictive business practices, abuse of dominance and mergers and acquisitions that lead
to monopolies. The Committee has the powers to suspend, cease or vary any anticompetitive agreements or behavior.
The Committee has just begun its work and it is too early to evaluate its effectiveness.
However, there have been critics of the need for a competition law in Indonesia.
According to the Asean Focus Group at the Australian National University, “many of
Indonesia’s anti-competitive problems have been the direct result of government-
sanctioned monopolies, in the form of protection for cronies and state-owned enterprises.
It would have been far simpler to remove these distortions at their source, rather than to
create a whole new, complex apparatus,” that is, the competition law that has just been
enacted (Asean Focus Group, 1999:1).
Malaysia
Malaysia has yet to enact a Competition Law although it has a Consumer Protection Act.
The Ministry of Domestic Trade and Industry has been drafting a comprehensive
competition law since 1993 based partly on the Fair Trade Act of Japan. The Malaysian
Government has gone through various drafts of the law but the bill has not been tabled in
Parliament and this has led some commentators to speculate that this inertia
“demonstrates a reluctant attitude … toward competition policy” and this reluctance may
be due to the fact that they “consider that it might hinder rapid economic development
because it deprives the government of its discretionary and regulatory power for
development” (Yasuda, 2000:5).
Malaysia has since the early 1980s, privatized several government agencies including
education and utilities (power, water, telecommunications). Infrastructure development
has also been privatized. However, regulatory reform has lagged behind and the only
privatized activity that has a regulatory commission is telecommunications. The
Malaysian Multimedia and Communications Commission was formed in 1999 to regulate
the telecommunications sector.
Philippines
Competition legislation in the Philippines has been in existence since 1925 when the “Act
to Prohibit Monopolies and Combinations in Restraint of Trade” was enacted. It was
influenced by the Sherman Anti-Trust Act of the United States of America. There are two
pieces of legislation to protect consumers. These are: the Consumer Protection Price Act,
1991 and the Consumers Act of the Philippines, 1992. However, the Act to prohibit
monopolies has not been implemented given the Philippines’ long history of close
relations between the government and businessmen and the practice of granting
monopolies by the government to favored businessmen. Recent attempts to draft a
comprehensive Competition Act has not been tabled in Congress because of failure to
reach a consensus.
A recent review of Competition Policy and Law in the Philippines suggests that:
“The present laws have proven to be inadequate or ineffective to stave off the ill-effects
of anti-competitive structure and behavior in the market. Despite the considerable number
of laws and their varied nature, competition has not been fully established in all sectors of
the economy, nor has existing competition in other sectors of the economy been
enhanced. These laws have hardly been used or implemented, as may be seen by the lack
of cases litigated in court” (APEC,1999:82).
Singapore
Although Singapore has liberalized and deregulated her economy well ahead of her
ASEAN neighbors given that it is an open economy and a global entrepot city, she has
not enacted a Competition Law. The explanation appears to be that one of the
externalities of international competitiveness will be the creation of the conditions or
environment for domestic competition. The privatized entities are also not regulated by
independent institutions.
Singapore has argued that an open trade and investment regime will transmit competitive
forces throughout the domestic economy. However, the experience of other countries
shows that local firms and even government monopolies may collude to restrict entry. As
Kerr and Wood have pointed out, “Although an open trade and investment regime is a
powerful device to ensure competition, it may not be adequate in the face of concerted
efforts by firms to collude or to restrict entry” (Kerr and Wood, 2000:10). Success in
trade and liberalization is also dependent on a domestic competitive market environment.
Thailand
There is a provision in Article 87 of the 1997 Constitution of Thailand to prevent or
regulate private monopolies. Article 87 of the 1997 Constitution of Thailand explicitly
states that “the State shall encourage a free economic system through market forces,
ensure and supervise fair competition, protect consumers and prevent direct and indirect
monopolies, repeal and refrain from enacting laws and regulations controlling businesses
which do not correspond with the economic necessity, and shall not engage in an
enterprise in competition with the private sector unless it is necessary for the purpose of
maintaining the security of the State, preventing the common interest, or providing public
utilities.”
The Price Fixing and Anti-Monopoly Act was enacted together with the Consumer
Protection Act in 1979. The Public Limited Companies Act was enacted in 1979 to
encourage large family held companies to be listed in the Thai Stock Exchange to
improve public disclosure standards.
The objective of the Price Fixing and Anti-Monopoly Act was prevent unfair and
restrictive business practices including abuse of dominant position of monopolies and
price fixing. Price control was extended over to 22 items in 1999. According to the APEC
study the objective of this act is to promote free and fair competition among businesses.
The provisions of the Act focus on control of business conduct and the abuse of market
power (APEC, 1999:84).
Deregulation and privatization has been carried out. As in other countries, the state
owned enterprises became private monopolies after privatization and had to be regulated.
However, the regulatory mechanisms that have been instituted remain weak.
To improve conditions for corporate performance, the Trade Competition Act was
enacted in 1999 together with the Price of Goods and Services Act, 1999. The objective
of the latter is “to protect consumers against unfair service charges and to oversee
sufficient supply of goods to meet domestic consumption” (The Nation, 22 April, 1999).
The focus of the TCA is to restrict abusive of dominant position of monopolies and price
fixing. It also provides for the formation of the Trade Competition Commission (TCC),
the dispute resolution mechanism and penalties for offences committed under the TCA.
The TCC has powers to regulate restrictive agreements, check abuse of dominant position
by monopolies and to regulate mergers and acquisitions. The TCC has also the powers to
issue an order to suspend, cease or vary any anti-competitive act including the formation
of cartels. Thai Law applies the per se principle in regard to the formation of cartels or
restrictive agreements although the rule of reason principle is applicable to some market
domination and merger activities. However, to date the Thai Competition Commission
has only tried two cases, reflecting the strength of latent anti-competitive forces in
Thailand.
Vietnam
Vietnam is gradually being transformed from a socialist economy to a capitalist
economy. It does not have a comprehensive competition policy or law but has given
property rights to farm households, which rights hitherto had been held by the state. The
government has introduced new foreign investment regulation beginning in 1987 to
encourage the inflow of foreign direct investment. The government continues to be
dominant in the economy and the state owned enterprises operate as monopolies. The
growth of the market economy depends on further reforms especially with regard to the
role of the government in the economy.
Laos
Laos has been declared a least developed country where three quarters of the population
live in absolute poverty and are dependent on subsistence agriculture. The private sector
is underdeveloped and foreign direct investment is relatively miniscule. Public
monopolies are dominant in the economy. The economy is centralized and entry into the
various industries is highly regulated by the bureaucracy. However, recently there was
some attempt to introduce competitive bidding for hydroelectric projects. The
telecommunications sector has also been liberalized. Given the stage of economic
development it may be a bit premature to talk of competition policy and law for Laos.
Myanmar
Myanmar has been relatively isolated because of international economic sanctions
applied against the military regime. It is a poor agrarian economy with very high levels of
government intervention. Public monopolies are held by the military which restricts entry
into several sectors of the economy. The introduction of competition policy and law is
premature given the political and economic problems that Myanmar currently faces.
Brunei
Brunei is an oil rich economy which until the 1997 East Asian financial crisis did not see
a reason to encourage foreign direct investment or enlarge its private sector. The
government is dominant in the economy and operates several public monopolies.
Recently there was an effort to privatize non-strategic state owned enterprises. The
banking sector has been liberalized and is dominated by foreign banks. There has been an
implicit recognition of the need for a competition policy but its implementation is not
urgent as long as the economy can maintain its present standard of living with oil
revenues.
Cambodia
Cambodia is also one of the least developed countries of the world, where more than 80
percent of the population live in rural areas and more than a third live in absolute poverty.
Over the last two decades it has been war torn and subject to communism and the
Vietnamese occupation. It has only returned to normalcy since the UN brokered peace in
the early 1990s and the democratic elections in 1993. The economy is dominated by
public monopolies and growth has been dependent on foreign direct investment and
textile exports. The services sector is large but underdeveloped and is best characterized
as an informal sector. Growth is dependent on bilateral and multilateral aid and
investment and trade. Under these circumstances it may be unrealistic for the Cambodian
government to enact a competition law or formulate a competition policy.
X. Conclusion
It is interesting to note that only four of the ten ASEAN countries have enacted
competition or anti-monopoly laws. An APEC study in 1999 found that member
developing countries were reluctant to formulate and implement competition policies or
laws because of resistance from the politicians and bureaucrats, who perceive an erosion
of discretionary authority. According to the World Bank (1999) and Shirley and Walsh
(2000), “significant obstacles to reforming conditions for entry by enterprises into
markets continue to be mounted by particular interest groups in the public sector,
resisting competition for public enterprises, and by powerful private sector lobbies
wishing to protect their markets (Cook, 2002:14). The exit policy is also weak as there
are regulations that prevent enterprises from closing. According to Cook, inadequate
bankruptcy rules and policies enable the government to keep ailing public enterprises to
serve social and political purposes (Cook, 2002:14).
There was also an inadequate infrastructure to support a competitive system because of
excessive corruption, bureaucratic inertia, poor corporate governance and lack of
transparency. The judicial system in most countries are weak and independent and judges
are reluctant to act against the interests of the government or prominent businesses. The
study also found that countervailing sources of power in the form of professional and
consumer groups was also not well organized. The competition authority has also been
handicapped because of the lack of qualified personnel (APEC, 1999:43).
It is also difficult to detect anti-competitive behavior among firms because of information
asymmetry between the competition authority and the firms, which have an incentive to
conceal information from the regulators. As Cook has pointed out, ‘the lack of civil
society institutions, such as consumer lobbies and the absence of a relatively open media
and an auditing tradition, may seriously undermine the disclosure of collusive practices”
(Cook, 2002:16). Laffont (1998) has also argued that the attempt to police collusion in
developing countries may end up in replacing collusion between enterprises with a more
complex process, involving collusion with the regulators.
ASEAN has also not developed a common competition law or policy. The 1999 Hanoi
Plan of Action “to explore the merits of common competition policy” (ASEAN, 1999)
remains a plan. This has led some observers to note that competition law is relatively
underdeveloped in most of the ASEAN countries. (Lloyd and Associates, 1999:26).
References
“Government Draft Rules on Unfair Trade Practices,” The Nation, 22 April, 1999.
Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations,
(London: Methuen), 1776.
APEC, Study on Competition Laws for Developing Countries, (Singapore:APEC),
1999.
Asean Focus Group, Asian Analysis- Indonesia: An Uncertain Business
Environment, (Canberra: ANU), 1999
Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN), Hanoi Plan of Action, (Jakarta:
ASEAN Secretariat), 1999.
Christopher, W., Statement by His Excellency Mr. Warren Christopher, Secretary of
State of the United States of America, (Jakarta: ASEAN Secretariat), 2003.
Coase, R.H., The Institutional Structure of Production, Lecture to the memory of
Alfred Nobel, December 9 1991.
Cobb,C, “Review of: From Posner to Post-Modernism by Mercero and Medema,”
The School of Cooperative Individualism, January 1999.
Cook, P., Competition Policy, Market Power and Collusion in Developing
Countries, Center on Regulation and Competition, Working Paper Series, Paper
Number 33, University of Manchester, 2002.
Demsetz, H., Industrial Concentration and the Market System, (Washington, D.C.:
American Bar Association Press), 1979.
Devuyst, Y., Toward a Multilateral Competition Policy Regime?, Global
Governance, Volume 6, Issue 3, July-September 2000:319-339.
http://the register.com.uk/content/archive/7984.html
http://www.aseanfocus.com/asiananalysis/article.cfm?article ID=140
http://www.findarticles.com/cf_dls/MOJQP/2002_July/89148684/P3/article.jhtml?te
rm.
http://www.imf.org/external/np/loi/103197.HTM-memo
http://www.twnside.org.sg/title/cancun5.doc
http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/min99_e/english/about_e/16comp_e.htm
Hylleberg, S., and Overgaard, P.B, Competition Policy with a Coasian Prior?,
Department of Economics, University of Aarhus, Denmark, 1998.
International Monetary Fund, Letter of Intent, Indonesia, (Washington, D.C.:
International Monetary Fund), October 31 1997.
Lea, G., “Who the heck is … Judge Richard Posner,” The Register, 22.11.1999
Lloyd, P.J. and Associates, Harmonizing Competition and Investment Policies in the
East Asian Region. Paper presented at the Third Asia Development Forum on
“Regional Economic Cooperation in Asia and the Pacific,” organized by the Asian
Development Bank, 11-14 June 2001, Bangkok.
Maddock, R, “Australian Lessons in Implementing Competition Reform,” Economic
Papers, Vol 14, Number 3, September 1995: 31-40.
New Internationalist, July 2002.
Noland, M., Competition Policy and FDI: A Solution in Search of a Problem?
Institute for International Economics, Working Paper, 99-3, 1999.
OECD, The Relationship between Regional Trade Agreements and the Multilateral
Trading System: Competition, (Paris:OECD), 2002.
Schumpeter, J., Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, (London: Unwin), 1954.
Singleton, R.C., “Competition Policy for Developing Countries: A Long-Run EntryBased Approach,” Contemporary Economic Policy, Volume 15, Number 2, April
1997:1-11.
Stigler, J.G., “Two Notes on the Coase Theorem,” Yale Law Journal, 1989, 631-633.
Third World Network, The Singapore Issues – Rhetoric and Reality.
Williamson, J., Did the Washington Consensus Fail? (Washington, D.C.: Institute
for International Affairs), 2002.
World Bank, World Development Report, 2001, (Washington, D.C.: World Bank),
2001.
World Trade Organization (WTO), Trade And Competition Policy, (Geneva:
WTO),2004.
Yasuda, N., ASEAN Competition Laws: Current Status and Future Perspectives,
Graduate School of International Development, Nagoya University. Paper presented
at ASEAN Workshop: Making Markets Work, hosted by the Australian Competition
and Consumer Commission, Bangkok, 6 March 2000.
Lipczynski, J. and J.O.S. Wilson, Industrial Organization: An Analysis of Competitive
Markets, (London: Financial Times, Pearson), 2001.
The Bank of Sweden Price in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel, 1991.
http://www.nobel.se/economics/laureates/1991
Lee, M., and C. Morand, Competition Poicy in the WTO and FTAA: A Trojan Horse for
International Trade Negotiations, August 2003. Canadian Center for Policy Alternatives.
http://www.policy alternatives.ca/publications/competitionsummary.html.
Stigler, G., The Theory of Price, (New York: McMillan), 1966.
Stigler, Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist, (New York: Basic Books), 1989.
Dixit, A., “Recent developments in oligopoly theory,” The American Economic Review,
1982, 72:12-17.
Khmeni, R. Shyam and M. Dutz, “The Instruments of Competition Policy and t Revance
for Economic Development,” in C. Frischtak (ed.), Regulatory Policies and Refrm: A
Comparative Analysis, (Washington, D.C.: The World Bank), 1995.
Schleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., The Grabbing Hand, Government Pathologies and their
Cures, (Cambridge (Mass): Harvard University Press), 1998.
Gifford, D.J., and M. Matsushita, “Antitrust for Competition Laws Viewed in a trading
context: Harmony or Dissonance,” in J. Bhagwati and R.E. Hudec, Fair Trade and
Harmonization,Volume 2, (Cambridge, Mass: The MIT Press), 1996.
Williamson, J., The Washington Consensus as a Policy Prescription for Development. A
lecture in the series “Practitioners for Development,” delivered at the World Bank on
January 13, 2004. Institute for Intenational Economics, 2004.
Choudry, A., Another Corporate Steal? The Proposed WTO Competition Policy, 2004.
http://www.boell.org/docs/Cancun-Aiz-Competition Policy.pdf
Choudry, A., Propsed WTO Competition Policy Agreement, ZNET, August 24, 2003.
Kerr, I.A., and M. Wood, “Globalization and Competition Policy: Policies for the
Developing and Transitional Economies of Asia.” Paper presented at the EAMSA
Conference on Globalization and the Uniqueness of Asia, INSEAD Campus, Singapore,
November 23-25, 2000.
Budzinski, O., Pluralism and Competition Policy Paradigms and the Call for Regulatory
Diversity, (New York: New York University), 2003.
World Bank, The East Asian Miracle, (New York: Oxford University Press), 1993.
Download