economic development under stalin

advertisement
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT UNDER STALIN
Problems facing the USSR in 1929
By 1929, Lenin’s New Economic Policy had generated significant economic
success. Agricultural production had exceeded its 1913 level, and GDP had reached
its pre-Civil War level. Russia could now embark on a program of industrialisation.
Because Russia was still so backward, virtually everybody recognised that much of
the technology and capital equipment necessary to facilitate development would have
to be imported. However, the Western nations were unwilling to lend Russia money
(given that the Bolsheviks had repudiated the debts incurred by the Tsarist regime), so
the foreign exchange would have to be earned, via exports.
In the early 1920s, Russia had only one exportable product – agriculture. However,
agricultural production was still inadequate to feed Russia’s growing urban
population, let alone provide a surplus for export. This led to significant criticism of
NEP.
The nation’s economic difficulties were not the only reservations being expressed
within the Communist Party at the time. NEP was benefiting the wealthy peasants
(kulaks), whom the Bolsheviks knew were never likely to support their socialist
ideology. Many were uncomfortable with this policy of Lenin’s, because it was really
just rural capitalism.
Stalin also had other concerns. In particular, he feared that Russia was very
vulnerable to external attack. If it did not industrialise quickly, the Revolution could
be swept aside by foreign invaders – particular Germany, which was lurching to the
right as the Depression hit.
Stalin also felt that the country needed to industrialise to strengthen the Party’s
support base, by creating a large working class. Once this was achieved, the regime’s
remaining enemies (such as the kulaks) could be eliminated.
Stalin’s plan for economic development
Stalin decided that the best way to achieve rapid economic development was to
concentrate most of the nation's resources on heavy industry. This meant very few
consumer goods would be produced, giving peasants little incentive to increase
production (since there was nothing to buy with the income they received).
To prevent the peasants from reducing production (in response to the lack of goods
to buy), Stalin collectivised the land, forcing the newly formed collectives to meet
strict production targets.
To ensure that the nation’s limited resources were directed to key areas of the
economy, NEP was replaced by command socialism, with all industry nationalised
and market mechanisms replaced by a series of five year plans. Imports were reduced
to a bare minimum – mainly capital equipment.
Finally, a reign of police terror was unleashed in order to deal with the unrest
resulting from collectivisation. Over 20 million people died during this period – some
because they refused to hand over their produce and livestock (they were shot), others
because they did hand over their produce (they starved).
1
Industrial development
The basis of Stalin’s industrialisation program was the Five Year Plan – a formal
expression of the major goals and priorities of the government. These goals included
high rates of economic growth, priority to heavy industry (especially fuel, steel and
machine building), military technology, scientific and technical education and
training, and economic self-sufficiency.
The core of a Five Year Plan (FYP) was the investment plan, because it was seen as
the key to growth. This determined the investment priorities of the government, and
therefore determined which areas of the economy would grow the fastest.
Under the First Five Year Plan (1928-33), Stalin determined that steel production
was to rise by 200 percent and electricity production by 400 percent. While these
targets were not met, industrial production did increase dramatically. By 1933, output
levels were four times that of 1913. Production of oil and gas rose by 130 percent
between 1929 and 1938. Over that same period, production of coal and iron ore rose
by 230 percent each, steel by 267 percent, electricity by 540 percent, and chemicals
rose by almost 1000 percent.
This rate of economic growth was a significant achievement, given that in the
Western nations, industrial output had fallen to below the 1913 level over the same
period (as a result of the Great Depression).
Stalin encouraged Russian workers to raise their production levels by offering them
increased wages. Propaganda (such as the Stakhanovite movement) was also used for
this purpose. Terror was another technique used to increase efficiency, with
unproductive workers or managers being shot. Forced labour was also used,
particularly for projects which were deemed to be very difficult and/or dangerous.
Despite the increase in wages and living standards for the most productive workers,
wages were generally kept very low, so that the surplus income could be reinvested in
industrial plant.
Collectivisation of agriculture
Reasons for collectivisation
Stalin believed that industrialisation would have to be largely financed by
agricultural surpluses, which meant squeezing (ie. exploiting) the peasants. But he
feared that they might react to high taxes by reducing production. The solution he
devised was to force the peasants to produce by organising them together into
collectives, thereby denying them the opportunity to withhold production.
Stalin believed these collectives would be highly efficient, since they could utilise
the machinery produced by heavy industry. He also knew that collectivisation would
be highly disruptive, with many peasants driven off the land. These people would be
forced into the cities, becoming the labour force for the newly created industries.
At an ideological level, Stalin believed that the peasants were reactionaries, who
would never support the Bolsheviks unless divested of their private property. Given
that they represented 80 percent of the population, their resistance had to be crushed.
Collectivisation was seen as a means of fostering socialism in the countryside.
Finally, Stalin believed that collectivisation would allow the state to take control of
the rural population, preventing the peasants from threatening the regime by
withholding agricultural production. This coincided well with his desire to increase
his own power in Russia.
2
The process of collectivisation
Stalin’s plan called for the elimination of private ownership of agricultural land, and
its replacement with a system of state-owned and collectively-owned farms.
His initial intention was to do this gradually (with only 20 percent of the land to be
collectivised by 1933), so as to avoid excessive disruption (which would reduce
agricultural production). However, in January 1930, he decided to implement the
entire plan immediately. Hence, by March of that year, 50 percent of all peasant farms
were collectivised.
The poorer peasants tolerated collectivisation, because they had little land and few
animals to lose. But the wealthier ones (the kulaks) bitterly opposed it. These farmers
had supported NEP and refused to accept its abandonment. Many refused to part with
their land, and reacted to government pressure by reducing production to subsistence
levels. Many also burned their farms and killed their cattle in preference to handing
them over to the government.
Stalin’s initial reaction was to call a halt to the collectivisation process, fearing it
was having serious economic consequences. But when large numbers of peasants
abandoned the collectives and returned to private farming (the proportion of collective
farms falling from 50 percent to 21 percent by August 1930), he looked for new
enemies to blame.
The Russian dictator decided that the kulaks were the reason for the failure of
collectivisation, because they were a counter-revolutionary force. He therefore
decided to eliminate them as a class in society. Their possessions were confiscated
and they were prevented from joining collectives. Those who continued to resist were
exiled to Siberia or shot; whole villages were burned.
The result was a precipitous decline in agricultural production. The number of sheep
and goats fell from 146 million in 1928 to 42 million in 1933. Cattle numbers fell
from 70 million to 34 million over the same period.
Because of the fall in agricultural production, the USSR was hit by famine in 193233. The worst hit region was the Ukraine, where resistance to Soviet rule had been
strong. Stalin was furious that the area had failed to meet its grain requisition targets,
and decided to use the famine as a means of punishing the people. All grain was
confiscated by the state, and troops were stationed on the Ukraine’s borders to prevent
people from leaving. The peasants were then left to starve. About 7 million people
died during the famine, 5 million of them in the Ukraine.
As a result of the collectivisation program, agricultural production in Russia did not
recover to its 1928 level until 1938.
The Stalinist system of agriculture
Under Stalin’s new system, agriculture was divided into three sectors: the state
sector, the collective sector and the private sector.
State farms (sovkhoz) were run like industrial enterprises. This meant they were
state owned, hired their workers, and were subject to rigid production plans.
Collective farms (kolkhoz) were created by amalgamating the land of between 50
and 100 families. They were jointly owned by their members, but had to produce what
they were told, and to deliver a fixed quota to the state each year. The rest they could
keep, after allowing for reinvestment. Individual peasants were paid in kind and/or
3
cash according to how hard they worked. Each region had a Machine Tractor Station,
which maintained the equipment on neighbouring collective farms.
In 1935, Stalin permitted peasant households to work private plots of land (up to
one acre in size) and sell the produce on the market. These plots represented only 3
percent of agricultural land, although they accounted for a quarter of all sales. This
was due partly to the fact that they were worked more intensively (since all the
resultant produced could be kept), and partly to the fact that they produced higher
value products (like meat, eggs and milk).
By 1936, all resistance to Stalin's will had been crushed and the economy
completely transformed – so much so that Stalin could declare that Russia was now
fully socialist.
Economic achievements of the Stalinist system
It is difficult to get accurate figures on Soviet economic performance. However, it
appears that the Soviet economy grew at an annual rate of between 4.5 and 6.3
percent between 1928 and 1960. When the destructive effects of the Second World
War are discounted, the growth rate was between 5.5 and 7.7 percent. Not
surprisingly, industrial output grew by the greatest amount (steel output, for example,
grew by 2,000 percent).
The big rise in industrial output was a product of three factors: the vast investment
in science and technology undertaken during this period; the achievement of
economies of scale utilising relatively unsophisticated technologies; and the decision
not to emphasise consumer goods, which allowed investment spending to reach
extremely high levels.
However, the successes in industry were not matched by that of agriculture.
Production in 1953 was barely above the 1928 level. As such, agriculture did not
generate the levels of capital expected by Stalin and Preobrazhensky. Had it done so,
Russia might have been able to develop at an even faster rate, or provide a bigger rise
in living standards than was experienced during the Stalinist period.
4
Download