Maturity Transformation and Interest Rate Risk in Large European Bank Loan Portfolios Galen Sher∗ and Giuseppe Loiacono†‡ This draft May 1, 2013 Abstract Financial intermediaries transform assets with certain risk characteristics into assets with other risk characteristics. We define net asset transformation from liabilities to assets in terms of the pricing characteristics of contingent claims. Maturity transformation can be defined as a special case, across the whole balance sheet or locally to one contract type. We present and summarise a new rich dataset on the balance sheet asset and liability exposures of large European banks that submitted to the European Banking Authority’s EU capital exercise. In particular, we show that these banks transform short-term customer deposits and 1-5 year hybrid and subordinated debt liabilities into loan assets with greater than 5 years’ maturity. The value-weighted average maturity of the assets of these banks exceeds their liabilities by 2.07 years, with standard deviation 1.44 years. Given the importance of loan assets among these banks for determining interest rate risk, we describe and measure the interest rate risk of their loan portfolios. We find that their loan assets are primarily allocated to households and non-financial corporations in the Euro area. We critically assess the interest rate repricing risk in these loan portfolios under five simple methods, including the Basel Committee guidelines on interest rate risk assessment. We identify four major limitations in the Basel Committee guideline method and illustrate the size of the approximations they introduce through examples. Using these five methods, we measure the extent to which a standardised 200 basis point parallel interest rate shock affects the values of their loan portfolios. We find that simple loan-specific pricing models provide different, and presumably better, rankings of the relative interest rate riskiness of bank loan portfolios than the Basel Committee guideline method. JEL Classification: E43, G21, G28 1 Introduction Interest rate risk in financial intermediation matters because it is a source of systemic or non-diversifiable risk to the industry, and the health of the real economy depends on a well-functioning financial system. High and unpredictable interest rates in the 1980s led to widespread failures of banks and thrift institutions (see Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (1994)). The ever-increasing scale and complexity of financial institutions and their use of non-standard contracts for hedging and speculation makes proper risk assessment essential. Conceptually, one may distinguish between two major categories of interest rate risk to a financial intermediary. The first is the risk that unanticipated changes in interest rates cause a loss of income, in particular interest income. Secondly, unanticipated changes in interest rates affect the so-called “economic value” of the intermediary.1 Both of these categories affect the ability of the intermediary to fulfil its obligations as they fall due, and therefore also its liquidity and solvency. ∗ Department of Economics, University of Oxford. Corresponding author: galen.sher@economics.ox.ac.uk of Economics, University of Rome Tor Vergata. giuseppe.loiacono@students.uniroma2.eu ‡ The authors would like to acknowledge helpful discussions with Arnaud Lionnet and Stephen Bond at the University of Oxford, and with Matthias Sydow at the European Central Bank, without any implication for errors or omissions contained herein. Some of the data were collected while the authors were at the European Central Bank. The first author would like to acknowledge research support from the Oxford–Man Institute of Quantitative Finance. 1 The “economic value” of a company may be understood as changes in the ‘value’ of the company, or changes in prices and quantities that affect the ‘value’ of that company’s assets and liabilities. For a detailed discussion of ‘value’ in economics, see Hicks (1939). † Department 1 There are at least three ways that an analyst (say, a regulator) may monitor or assess the interest rate risk of a financial intermediary. Publicly listed banks and insurers disclose measures of the sensitivity of their balance sheets to shifts in the term structure of interest rates, so in the first instance an analyst may refer to these disclosures. These self-reported measures have the advantage that they may take into account the complex structure of the contracts held by an intermediary that may not be visible in its financial statements, but such measures also rely on the willingness and ability of the intermediary to make an accurate assessment. Furthermore, only one to two measures are typically disclosed, which cannot be hoped to provide a complete picture of the intermediary’s exposure to interest rate changes. As an alternative, the analyst could use regression analysis to measure the sensitivity of the stock return of publicly-listed intermediaries against changes in specific interest rates or against measures reflecting the shape of the yield curve. The principle paper in this category is Flannery and James (1984a), where the authors find that US banks’ stock returns are sensitive to interest rate changes, and that the degree of sensitivity is correlated with the degree of maturity transformation measured from the nominal contracts on their balance sheets. Flannery and James (1984b) infer the effective degree of maturity transformation based on these stock sensitivity measures. Saunders and Yourougou (1990) find that bank stock returns are more sensitive to interest rate changes than the stock returns of other companies; they also find some evidence to suggest that universal banks would be more robust to interest rate changes due to better diversification. Czaja, Scholz, and Wilkens (2009) measure the sensitivity of stock returns of German banks and insurers to level, slope and curvature changes in local yield curves, and find that bank and insurer stock returns offer a premium for those banks and insurers with greater sensitivities to the level and curvature factors. English, van den Heuvel, and Zakrajsek (2012) use high-frequency stock and interest rate data around Federal Open Market Committee announcements to measure the effect of interest rate level and slope changes in bank stock returns; studying short time intervals helps to avoid the pollutive effects of unrelated news on stock prices. The analyst could also measure the interest rate sensitivity of each item on the balance sheet, by asking the question “How would the unit prices of the major asset and liability categories change if interest rates were different on the valuation date?” This is the approach taken in our paper, and can be thought of as a ‘prospective’ assessment of interest rate risk, as opposed to the ‘retrospective’ assessments following Flannery and James (1984a). The concepts of duration and convexity as measures of price sensitivity to interest rate changes were introduced by Macaulay (1938), Hicks (1939), Samuelson (1945) and Redington (1952). Houpt and Embersit (1991) propose a duration-based method for assessing the interest rate sensitivity of banks’ economic value based on their publicly disclosed balance sheets. This model has since become known as the Federal Reserve’s Economic Value Model (EVM). Wright and Houpt (1996) evaluate the performance of this simple model for ‘thrift institutions’ against a model that uses more detailed private supervisory data, and against the Office for Thift Supervision’s internal model. Despite the limitations of publicly-available data, the authors find that the simple model provides useful information for measuring the sensitivity of banks’ economic value to interest rate changes; they also find that the biggest limitation of such models are the arbitrary assumptions that have to be made about the behaviour of depositors. Jarrow and van Deventer (1998) offer a no-arbitrage model for determining the economic value of deposit contract liabilities, and this pricing function could also be used in principle to measure its sensitivity to interest rate changes. O’Brien (2000) also offers such a no-arbitrage model, and further estimates its parameters on US bank data, providing detailed sensitivity estimates of the economic value of bank liabilities to changes in the short term interest rate. Sierra and Yeager (2004) evaluate the predictions of the EVM against the actual performance of US community banks, which do not typically engage in complex derivative transactions, and find that those banks that the EVM identifies as most sensitive to rising rates show the greatest deterioration in performance in the 1998-2000 period of rising rates in the US. Sierra (2009) finds that the ‘prospective’ sensitivities of US bank economic value to interest rates calculated from the EVM are consistent with the ‘retrospective’ interest rate sensitivities of stock prices discussed above. Entrop, Memmel, Wilkens, and Zeisler (2011) try to produce a refined EVM model calibrated to German banking data by using repeated observations of balance sheets over time. By evaluating their model using private supervisor data, they are able to argue that their model outperforms the EVM, which relies on data at only one point in time. The most important paper for estimating the sensitivity of US bank balance sheet derivative exposures is 2 Gorton and Rosen (1995), who find that interest rate derivative exposures seem to be used for hedging rather than speculation. 1.1 Basel Committee guidelines for interest rate risk assessment The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision2 temporarily releases guidance on the principles Table 1: Basel Committee guideline method for net of the management and supervision of interest asset revaluation sensitivity to parallel interest rate rate risk. To the best of our knowledge, the most shocks. recent guidance document for the assessment of interest rate risk was released in July 2004 and maturity point as- duration weighting is entitled “Principles for the Management and bucket sumption (yrs) (%) Supervision of Interest Rate Risk”. We find that (yrs) (yrs) the principles and guidance given in the docu0.083 0.042 0.040 0.080 ment are generally prudent and nuanced. How0.250 0.167 0.160 0.320 ever, the guidance provided in Annexes 3 and 4 0.500 0.375 0.360 0.720 seems to depart strongly from the sensible ad1.000 0.750 0.710 1.420 vice given in the body of the document. To the 2.000 1.500 1.380 2.760 extent that supervisors use Annexes 3 and 4 to 3.000 2.500 2.250 4.500 rank banks’ interest rate risk, these supervisors 4.000 3.500 3.070 6.140 might end up overlooking the most risky banks. 5.000 4.500 3.850 7.700 To summarise these Annexes, they argue that 7.000 6.000 5.080 10.160 a supervisor should monitor the interest rate risk 10.000 8.500 6.630 13.260 of institutions using a “standardised interest rate 15.000 12.500 8.920 17.840 shock,” which amounts to either a 2% parallel 20.000 17.500 11.210 22.420 upward or downward shift in interest rates or the Inf 22.500 13.010 26.020 1% and 99% quantile of the distribution of yield curves. Given that Annex 4 provides a more detailed example using the parallel interest rate shock, but does not provide guidance for implementing a quantile-based shock, it seems likely that supervisors would find the parallel interest rate shock easier to implement. In the example implementation provided for guidance in Annex 4, which proposes a duration-based sensitivity measure akin to that of the Federal Reserve’s Economic Value Model, shocks have a symmetric effect on value, and hence it becomes unnecessary to consider both positive and negative shocks. Since banks almost always draw funding at short durations to invest at longer durations, they tend to lose only when interest rates rise. When choosing between positive or negative shocks according to the guideline method in Annex 4, it therefore makes sense only to consider a rise in interest rates. To implement the standardised shock, the supervisor or bank analyst3 is referred to Table 1. This table provides the ‘risk’ or sensitivity estimates to be used as risk-weights in a calculation of overall portfolio sensitivity to a parallel interest rate shock. For a hypothetical security,4 the supervisor considers the remaining contractual maturity in the case of a fixed-rate security, or the time until the next repricing date in the case of a variable-rate security. This remaining maturity determines the “maturity bucket” into which the security falls, given by the first column in Table 1.5 Associated with each maturity bucket is a point-in-time assumption, where the entire cashflow from the security is presumed to fall in the form of a zero-coupon bond. The price sensitivity of such a zero-coupon bond, i.e. the percentage decrease in present value per unit increase in interest rates, is given by the 2 “The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision is a Committee of banking supervisory authorities which was established by the central bank Governors of the Group of Ten countries in 1975. It consists of senior representatives of bank supervisory authorities and central banks from Belgium, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom and the United States. It usually meets at the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) in Basel, Switzerland, where its permanent Secretariat is located” (Basel Committee Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2004). 3 In this discussion, we use the word ‘supervisor’ to mean any analyst that is attempting to measure the interest rate risk of banks using the recommendations of the Basel Committee for Banking Supervision. 4 The hypothetical security could be an asset or a liability. 5 In particular, the right endpoint of the maturity bucket is determined by the smallest value in the first column of Table 1 that is greater than or equal to the remaining maturity of the hypothetical security. The left endpoint of the maturity bucket is the largest value in the first column of Table 1 that is smaller than the remaining maturity of the hypothetical security. 3 ‘duration’ number in the penultimate column of Table 1. Multiplying this duration number by the size of the standardised shock, which is 2%, gives the risk-weight measure that is shown in percent in the final column of this Table. The risk weight is an estimate of the interest rate revaluation sensitivity of the hypothetical security under a standardised interest rate shock. We can immediately observe several shortcomings of this guideline method for interest rate revaluation sensitivity. These shortcomings can be summarised as follows: 1. The method does not depend on the specific type of security. We might expect different securities with the same remaining time to maturity to have different sensitivities to interest rate changes. In particular, we have no indication of how good this guideline method is for loan contracts. 2. The method does not depend on the current yield curve. Not only is the standardised shock of 2% invariant to historical yields, but the sensitivity calculation itself is unrelated to the prevailing interest rate environment. For example, in a high interest rate environment, we might expect larger absolute changes in interest rates to be likely, and we might expect the price of a security to be more sensitive to a given absolute change in interest rates in a low interest rate environment than in a high interest rate environment. 3. The method encourages the use of a parallel upward shift in interest rates of 2%, without explicitly requiring that the supervisor investigate other scenarios. As a scenario, there is little reason to expect that a parallel upward shift in interest rates of 2% is commensurate with a desired level of riskiness, or even that it is plausible, given the well-known correlation between levels and slopes of yield curves. As a risk measurement device, a single scenario incentivises banks to reduce their exposure to just this one scenario, while potentially remaining severely exposed to other scenarios, which include parallel shifts not equal to 2% and slope changes. 4. The method provides only an ad hoc way to aggregate the sensitivity of many exposures into a portfolio sensitivity, despite the fact that the method is recommended for measuring the interest rate revaluation risk of the whole balance sheet. Indeed given these four criticisms, it is difficult to see how the method improves on so-called gap analysis, where the weighted average maturity all the assets and liabilities on the balance sheet is used as a proxy for interest rate risk. 1.2 Structure of this paper Our objectives of this paper are twofold. First, we offer a definition of maturity transformation in terms of the pricing characteristics of assets and liabilities. This theory of ‘transformation’, including maturity transformation, is presented in Section 3.1. To measure the degree of maturity transformation of large European banks, we employ a dataset collected by the authors at the European Central Bank that covers the asset and liability exposures in greater detail than currently available from major data providers. All the asset and liability exposure data were collected from the consolidated annual financial statements and Pillar III disclosures of these banks. We present and summarise the data in Section 2 and we measure the degree of transformation in Section 4.1. Having determined that the degree of on-balance-sheet interest rate revaluation risk6 is most substantially influenced by the loan asset portfolios of these banks, our second objective in this paper is to measure the interest rate revaluation sensitivity of these loan assets. To do so, we employ several methods, including conventional gap analysis,7 the Basel Committee guideline method introduced in Section 1.1, and the simple present value formulae for amortising loan contracts of Section 3.2 combined with stylised characterisations of the yield curve in Section 3.3. We present our results in Section 4, including one ranking of banks by the (2%-) interest rate risk of their loan portfolios for each of the sensitivity methods, in Section 4.4. Section 5 concludes. 6 As opposed to off-balance-sheet interest rate revaluation risk, which is discussed for example in Gorton and Rosen (1995). 7 Gap analysis is a method for measuring the interest rate risk of a bank by computing the weighted average maturity of all assets and liabilities on the balance sheet. By computing the weighted average maturity of loan assets only, we obtain an analog of gap analysis applied to the interest rate risk assessment of just the loan assets of banks. 4 Table 2: List of banks in the sample. EBA code AT001 AT002 AT003 BE004 BE005 CY006 CY007 DE017 DE018 DE019 DE020 DE021 DE022 DE023 DE024 DE025 DE026 DE027 DE028 DK008 DK009 DK010 DK011 ES059 ES060 ES061 ES062 ES064 FI012 FR013 FR014 FR015 FR016 GB088 2 Description Erste Bank Raiffeisen Bank Oesterreichische Volksbank Dexia KBC Marfin Popular Bank of Cyprus Deutsche Bank Commerzbank LBBW DZ Bank Bayern LB Nord LB Hypo RE West LB HSH Nordbank Helaba Landesbank Berlin DekaBank Danske Group Jyske Bank Sydbank Nykredit Santander BBVA Bankia La Caixa Banco Popular OPO-Pohjola BNP Credit Agricole BPCE Societe Generale RBS EBA code GB089 GB090 GB091 GR030 GR031 GR032 GR033 HU036 IE037 IE038 IE039 IT040 IT041 IT042 IT043 IT044 LU045 MT046 NL047 NL048 NL049 NL050 NO051 PL052 PT053 PT054 PT055 PT056 SE084 SE085 SE086 SE087 SI057 SI058 Description HSBC Barclays Lloyds EFG Eurobank National Bank of Greece Alpha Bank Piraeus Bank Group OTP Bank NYRT. Allied Irish Banks Bank of Ireland Irish Life Intesa Sanpaolo Unicredit Banca Monte Dei Paschi Di Siena Banco Popolare UBI Banca Banque Et Caisse DEpargne De LEtat Bank of Valetta ING Rabobank ABN Amro SNS Bank DnB NOR PKO Bank Polski Caixa Geral de Depositos Banco Comercial Espirito Santo Banco BPI Nordea SEB Svenska Handelsbanken Swedbank NLB Group NKBM Data The sample of banks we study here is the sample of banks analysed in the European Banking Authority’s 2011 EU-wide capital exercise. They form the largest European bank holding companies and are listed in Table 2. Balance sheet data for these banks is publicly available from data providers like Reuters, Bloomberg and SNL, but not at the full level of detail that these institutions report in their annual financial statements. We use data collected by the authors at the European Central Bank on balance sheet assets and liabilities as at 31 December 2011. In particular, our data segregates loan assets into countries, sectors and remaining time to maturity, which allows us to compute detailed estimates of the interest rate sensitivity of these loans portfolios. While we use the country and sector classifications to measure “net asset transformation” in Section 4.1,8 we use only the maturity data to measure the interest rate sensitivity of these loan assets. The joint distribution of loan asset values by geography, sector and maturity is not known (only the marginal distributions are known) and the risk assessment by maturity already provides a rich analysis. We describe the cross-section of loan exposures by sector and country merely as a qualitative device for assessing concentration risk. In this section we summarise these loan exposures data by maturiy, geographical location and sector. In Section 2.4 we also summarise the yield curve data used in this 8 We define net asset transformation as a more general notion than maturity transformation in Section 3.1. 5 paper. 2.1 Accounting valuation methods in European countries The loan exposure data on which this paper is based has been gathered by the authors from the financial statements of large European banks. In this section we provide an overview of the accounting methods used to value these assets and liabilities. In doing so, we gain a better understanding of the exposures underlying the summaries in Section 2, and we can compare the accounting valuation methods to the stylised economic valuation models of Section 3. 2.1.1 Introduction to accounting rules for valuing assets and liabilities In the life of a corporate entity, every event has to be recorded in the financial statements according to common standards. Accounting standards can have a significant impact on the financial system, in particular via their potential influence on the behaviour of economic agents. Published financial statements provide financial and economic signals on which decisions can be made, and on which management can be assessed. Therefore, comparability of financial statements across countries is desirable. Pursuing this aim, the IFRS Foundation – an independent, not-for-profit private sector organisation working in the public interest – developed a single set understandable, enforceable and globally accepted international financial reporting standards (IFRSs) through its standard-setting body, the International Accounting Standards Board. In Europe, the IFRS standards have not fully substituted for the national accounting standards (Generally Accepted Accounting Principles). EU Regulation 1606/2002 requires European companies at the consolidated level to comply with IFRS standards, but does not make prescriptions for nonlisted European companies. Therefore subsidiary companies, like banks that are part of larger holding companies, are still subject to national GAAP and can move voluntarily to IFRS.9 The banks that are used for the analysis in this paper complied with IFRS standards. They were chosen based on their participation in the European Banking Authority’s 2011 EU capital exercise, and are therefore the largest and most systemically important banks in Europe. For the sake of our analysis, this section focuses on IAS 39 and IFRS 9, which are the specific IFRS standards that regulate the recognition and measurement of financial assets and liabilities. 2.1.2 Explanations of fair value and amortised cost Financial assets and liabilities can be recorded on the balance sheet at either fair value or amortised cost. Fair value is the amount for which an asset could be exchanged, or a liability settled, between knowledgeable, willing parties in an arm’s length transaction [IAS 39.9]. IAS 39 provides a hierarchy to be used in determining the fair value for a financial instrument: [IAS 39 Appendix A, paragraphs AG69-82] • Level 1: Quoted market prices in an active market10 are the best evidence of fair value and should be used, where they exist, to value the financial instrument. • Level 2: If a market for a financial instrument is not active, an entity establishes fair value by using a model-based valuation technique that makes maximum use of market inputs, and with reference to recent arm’s length market transactions, the current fair value of similar instruments, discounted cash flow analysis, and option pricing models. An acceptable valuation technique incorporates all factors that market participants would consider in setting a price and is consistent with accepted economic methodologies for pricing financial instruments. A financial instrument falls under Level 2 valuation if the model inputs are substantially based on market observables. For example, in pricing debt instruments with default risk, the credit spread inputs should be based on prevailing credit spreads that are observable at the time of valuation. • Level 3: If the model inputs are not observable in the market, they should be estimated to the extent possible from historical data. Continuing the above example of debt instrument 9 The “consolidated level” refers to the group holding company, which may own whole or majority stakes in subsidiary companies. Accounting statements are often produced for both the group holding company and the subsidiary companies. 10 An active market in the accounting standards means a market in which transactions for the asset or liability take place with sufficient frequency and volume to provide informative ongoing prices. 6 valuation, prepayment rates may be unobservable in the market, but should be calibrated to historical prepayment rates where possible.11 According to IAS 39.46-47, financial assets and liabilities (including derivatives) should be measured at fair value, with the following exceptions: • Loans and receivables, held-to-maturity investments, and non-derivative financial liabilities should be measured at amortised cost using the effective interest method. • Investments in equity instruments should be measured at fair value, but if the range of reasonable fair value measurements is large, then such instruments, and derivatives indexed to such equity instruments, can be measured at cost less impairment. • Financial assets and liabilities that are designated as a hedged item or hedging instrument are subject to measurement under the hedge accounting requirements of the IAS 39. • Financial liabilities that arise when a transfer of a financial asset does not qualify for derecognition,12 or that are accounted for using the continuing-involvement method, are subject to particular measurement requirements. Amortised cost is calculated using the effective interest method. The effective interest rate is the rate that exactly discounts estimated future cash payments or receipts through the expected life of the financial instrument to the net carrying amount13 of the financial asset or liability. Financial assets that are not carried at fair value though profit and loss are subject to an impairment test. If the expected life cannot be determined reliably, then the contractual life is used. A financial asset or liability valued at amortised cost is subject to an impairment test when there is objective evidence to do so, as a result of one or more events that occurred after the initial recognition14 of the asset. An entity is required to assess at each balance sheet date whether there is any objective evidence of impairment. If any such evidence exists, the entity is required to do a detailed impairment calculation to determine whether an impairment loss should be recognised [IAS 39.58]. The amount of the loss is measured as the difference between the asset’s carrying amount and the present value of estimated cash flows discounted at the financial asset’s original effective interest rate [IAS 39.63]. 2.1.3 Accounting and valuation of financial assets IAS 39 requires financial assets to be classified in different categories, used to determine how a particular financial asset is recognized and measured in the financial statements. Financial assets at fair value through profit or loss This category of assets can be divided into two subcategories: • The designated category includes any financial asset that is designated on initial recognition as one to be measured at fair value with fair value changes in profit or loss. • The held for trading category includes financial assets that are held for trading purposes. All derivatives (except those designated hedging instruments) and financial assets acquired or held for the purpose of selling in the short term, or for which there is a recent pattern of short-term profit taking, fall into this category [IAS 39.9]. Available-for-sale financial assets (AFS) These are any non-derivative financial assets designated on initial recognition as available for sale or any other instruments that are not classified as (a) loans and receivables, (b) held-to-maturity investments or (c) financial assets at fair value 11 Prepayment rates are rates at which loan debtors repay their loan contracts early. In most loan contracts, debtors retain the option to repay their loans early. Early repayment can be a risk to the creditor, because it raises the possibility of poor reinvestment rates at the time of prepayment. 12 Derecognition is a term used in the accounting standards to mean the deletion of an asset or liability from the financial statements. 13 The net carrying amount in the accounting standards means the original cost, less the accumulated amount of any depreciation or amortization and less any impairments. 14 The term initial recognition is used in the accounting standards to mean the first time that an asset or liability is recorded in the financial statements. 7 through profit or loss [IAS 39.9]. AFS assets are measured at fair value in the balance sheet. Fair value changes on AFS assets are recorded directly in equity, through the statement of changes in equity, except for interest on AFS assets (which is recorded in income on an effective yield basis), impairment losses and (for interest-bearing AFS debt instruments) foreign exchange gains or losses. The cumulative gain or loss that has been recognised in equity is recognised in profit or loss when an available-for-sale financial asset is derecognised [IAS 39.55(b)]. Loans and receivables These are non-derivative financial assets with fixed or determinable payments that are not quoted in an active market, other than those held at fair value through profit or loss or as available-for-sale. Loans and receivables for which the holder may not recover substantially all of its initial investment, other than because of credit deterioration, should be classified as available-for-sale [IAS 39.9]. Loans and receivables are measured at amortised cost [IAS 39.46(a)]. Held-to-maturity investments These are non-derivative financial assets with fixed or determinable payments that an entity intends and is able to hold to maturity and that do not meet the definition of loans and receivables and are not designated on initial recognition as assets at fair value through profit or loss or as available for sale. Held-to-maturity investments are measured at amortised cost. If an entity sells a held-to-maturity investment other than in insignificant amounts or as a consequence of a non-recurring, isolated event beyond its control that could not be reasonably anticipated, all of its other held-to-maturity investments must be reclassified as available-for-sale for the current and next two financial reporting years [IAS 39.9]. Held-to-maturity investments are measured at amortised cost [IAS 39.46(b)]. 2.1.4 Accounting valuation methods for financial liabilities IAS 39 recognises two classes of financial liabilities: [IAS 39.47] Financial liabilities at fair value through profit or loss This category has two subcategories: • Designated: a financial liability that is designated by the entity as a liability at fair value through profit or loss upon initial recognition. • Held for trading: a financial liability classified as held for trading, such as an obligation for securities borrowed in a short sale, which have to be returned in the future. Financial liabilities measured at amortised cost using the effective interest method This category includes, for example, hybrid and subordinated debt securities. 2.2 Maturity data for all assets and liabilities Asset and liability maturities, where available, are classified in the financial statements into four ‘buckets’: on demand, up to three month, three to twelve month, one to five years and more than five years. Although not all banks provide all the information required for our data collection exercise, the rate of coverage on our asset and liability maturity data in 2011 is of the order 80%.15 The coverage rate of our maturity data in 2011 for loan contracts only is 82%, which compares favourably with 70% for the standard data provider SNL Financial in the same year. Our maturity data also agree closely with the SNL Financial maturity data, where they overlap. In particular, for the banks with total loans in 2011 appearing in both datasets, the ratio of our exposure to the exposure in SNL Financial is on average 97%, with standard deviation 13%, across the sample of banks.16 We provide summary information about the maturity profiles of assets and liabilities in Figures 1 and 2. The weighted average maturity gap for banks, depicted in Figure 1, is calculated by subtracting the weighted average maturity of liabilities from assets. The weights used are the total asset and liability values in each maturity bucket, normalised to sum to one. From Figure 1 it can be seen that except for two banks (Piraeus Bank Group GR033 and Svenska Handelsbanken SE086) the weighted average 15 By coverage of the data set, we mean the ratio of the number of non-missing observations across all banks, to the total number of observations that would characterise a complete data set. 16 When we compare our total loan exposures to the total “exposure at default” used by the European Banking Authority in its capital exercise, we obtain a mean of 93% and a standard deviation of 37% across all banks. 8 9 Figure 1: Average maturity gap for large European banks in 2011, based on the cashflow timing assumptions used throughout this paper. The red line shows the sample mean (2.07 years) and the green lines show plus/minus one standard deviation (1.44 years). Years -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 AT002 AT003 Weighted average maturity gap between assets and liabilities for large European banks in 2011 BE004 BE005 CY006 CY007 DE018 DE019 DE020 DE021 DE023 DE024 DE025 DE027 DE028 DE029 DK008 DK009 DK010 DK011 ES059 ES060 ES061 ES062 ES064 FI012 FR013 FR014 FR016 GB088 GB089 GB090 GB091 GR032 GR033 HU036 IE037 IE038 IE039 IT040 IT041 IT042 IT043 IT044 MT046 NL047 NL048 NL049 NL050 NO051 PL052 PT053 PT055 PT056 SE084 SE085 SE086 SE087 SI057 SI058 10 Figure 2: Asset and liability exposures according to the annual financial statements for large European banks as at December 2011. The maturity transformation activitiy from short term liabilities to long term assets is immediately evident. Eur billions -600 -400 -200 0 200 400 600 AT002 AT003 BE004 BE005 Asset and liability exposures by maturity for large European banks in 2011 CY006 CY007 demand DE018 DE019 DE020 DE021 DE023 DE024 DE025 DE027 DE028 DE029 up to 3 month DK008 DK009 DK010 DK011 ES059 ES060 ES061 ES062 ES064 FI012 3 to 12 month FR013 FR014 FR016 GB088 GB090 GB091 GR032 GR033 HU036 1 to 5 years IE037 IE038 IE039 IT040 IT041 IT042 IT043 IT044 more than 5 years MT046 NL047 NL048 NL049 NL050 NO051 PL052 PT053 PT054 PT055 PT056 SE084 SE085 SE086 SE087 SI057 SI058 Loan assets by bank and country of origin in 2011 country AT BE CY 750 DE DK Loans in EUR (billions) ES FI FR Gr 500 HU Ir IT LU MT NL 250 NO PL PT SE SI UK AT001 AT002 AT003 BE004 BE005 CY006 CY007 DE017 DE018 DE019 DE020 DE021 DE022 DE023 DE024 DE025 DE026 DE027 DE028 DK008 DK009 DK010 DK011 ES059 ES060 ES061 ES062 ES064 FI012 FR013 FR014 FR015 FR016 GB088 GB089 GB090 GB091 GR030 GR031 GR032 GR033 HU036 IE037 IE038 IE039 IT040 IT041 IT042 IT043 IT044 LU045 MT046 NL047 NL048 NL049 NL050 NO051 PL052 PT053 PT054 PT055 PT056 SE084 SE085 SE086 SE087 SI057 SI058 0 Bank Figure 3: Euro loan exposures by originating bank and country as at December 2011. maturity gap (the difference between the average maturity of assets and liabilities) is positive. The sample mean is 2.07 years and the sample standard deviation is 1.44 years, as indicated on the figure by the horizontal red and green lines. The representative bank in our sample is therefore ‘short’ the level of interest rates, meaning that parallel upward shifts in yield curves would deteriorate the solvency position, while downward parallel shifts in yield curves would improve the solvency position.17 We can see that there is substantial variation between banks, even within countries, and the largest weighted average maturity gaps appear in CY, FI, IE, MY and NL. Interest-rate sensitivity of balance sheets is similarly heterogenous across banks in our sample. We present a summary of the bank balance sheet data in Table 3. From this table, we can see that the median bank tends to fund itself at short durations from customers and the interbank market, and allocates these funds to longer-dated loans, especially to corporate and household borrowers. The median bank in our sample is therefore subject to the usual risk of parallel upward shifts in the yield curve, and to the liquidity risk associated with rolling over short-term interbank borrowings. The same stylised facts can be observed in Figure 2, where we see that banks tend to borrow in the “up to 3 month” and “demand” categories, and they tend to lend in the “1 to 5 years” and “more than 5 years” categories. In addition to parallel shifts, banks are therefore highly exposed to increases in slope of the yield curve (with the average level of the curve fixed), because such increases would tend to reduce the value of (long-dated) assets while simultaneously increasing the value of (short-dated) liabilities. Level, slope and curvature effects are all special cases of the variability we are able to simulate in this paper, although for consistency with the Basel Committee guideline method, we focus on parallel shifts in yield curves. 2.3 Geography and sector data for loan assets In this section, we provide some summary information of the geographical and sectoral distributions of the loan asset exposures in the annual financial statements of large European banks for the years 20072011. This information is directly related to the location (X) dimension of net asset transformation that we define in Section 3.1 below, and which we illustrate in Section 4.1. When considering the geographic distribution of loan exposures, we must distinguish between origination and target countries. The origination country is the country of domicile of the bank that 17 The sensitivity of security prices to interest rates is explained for the case of loan contracts in Section 3.2. 11 Table 3: Summary of the bank assets and liabilities by maturity across all banks in the sample (in millions of Euros). category liabilities liabilities liabilities liabilities liabilities liabilities liabilities liabilities assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets assets subcategory interbank interbank interbank interbank customer deposits customer deposits customer deposits customer deposits interbank interbank interbank interbank loans corporate loans corporate loans corporate loans corporate loans financial institution loans financial institution loans financial institution loans financial institution loans household loans household loans household loans household loans public sector loans public sector loans public sector loans public sector available for sale debt available for sale debt available for sale debt available for sale debt available for sale equity available for sale equity available for sale equity available for sale equity held for trading debt held for trading debt held for trading debt held for trading debt held for trading equity held for trading equity held for trading equity held for trading equity maturity up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years up to 3 month 3 to 12 month 1 to 5 years more than 5 years 12 Min. 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 17 0 0 0 117 258 0 0 22 48 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Lower Q. 1707 410 540 43 3417 1822 714 66 898 237 66 4 991 1557 4633 5521 230 321 625 947 342 1140 1688 1638 11 29 45 5 93 656 1195 631 9 14 34 25 0 4 19 2 0 1 2 0 Med. 8722 1816 3092 664 14506 5716 5556 2086 4162 947 547 152 3678 5192 15007 21343 971 1733 5194 4008 2440 3825 10103 11330 161 199 478 660 1569 1374 5848 2387 55 64 293 177 11 500 993 153 2 13 50 13 Upper Q. 20282 5699 12996 2860 55321 27616 17059 10836 17467 4110 4546 1729 13122 12533 32487 48141 5158 5023 12392 16887 10243 11527 25336 46005 1466 1808 3893 3392 4191 4972 25972 14373 297 353 936 842 1003 1397 4004 4838 71 153 358 152 Max. 280667 121359 49148 26217 537284 1453598 87785 63077 223345 204875 70322 30791 55140 199475 258139 158765 34228 116453 150700 62434 85538 170050 220060 259236 19644 6653 18177 27372 29448 205487 297715 79772 2800 3987 7950 7968 10185 25050 25251 37425 1826 1582 3780 7396 5,000 Loan asset values by sector Ba Basic and construction BI Banks and intermediation 4,000 8,000 Loan asset values by target country 6,000 Ca Capital goods EUR billions GV Government MO Mortgage MT Media and telecommunications NC Consumer non−cyclical 2,000 4,000 En Energy OF Other financial OT Other RC Other consumer retail RE Commercial real estate Tr Transport 0 0 1,000 2,000 EUR billions 3,000 CC Consumer cyclical Euro area Other European countries North America Latin America Asia Rest of the word Ba BI Ca CC En GV MO MT NC OF OT RC RE Tr (a) Country (b) Sector Figure 4: Total allocation of loan assets by (a) country and (b) sector of loan counterparty, across all banks in the sample in 2011. originated the loan contract, and the target country is the country of domicile of the loan counterparty, which may be an individual or an institution. We summarise the loan exposures of large European banks as at December 2011 by origination country in Figure 3. The heights of the bars show total loans of each bank, measured in Euros, and the colours on the plot group the banks and loans by country of domicile. Banks in the sample are domiciled in 21 countries. We can see that the banks with the largest loan exposures are in Spain, France and the UK, while those in Italy and the Netherlands are also large. If we take a “demand-side” view of economic growth under credit constraints, then these largest banks are the most important for growth in Europe. The figure also shows that the country with the most banks in the sample is Germany. We also examine the geographic distribution of loans by country of loan counterparty in Figures 4a and 5. Figure 4a shows that large European banks primarily allocate loan capital to counterparties in the Euro area and secondarily to counterparties in other European countries in 2011. In Figure 5, we see that the high-level sectoral portfolio location in 2011 is similar within the loans extended to these two regions. Within these two major regions, most loans are extended to households, followed closely by non-financial corporations. Loans to the public sector are the smallest allocation, which may be misleading because these banks could lend substantially to national and local governments by purchasing debt instruments. On a more detailed sector breakdown, Figure 4b shows that these large European banks allocate most of their loan capital to household mortgages and diversify among the other economic subsectors. 2.4 Yield curve data We use Euro area swap curves, monthly from January 1999 to March 2013 to characterise the level and movements in yield curves. The tickers and maturities, taken from Bloomberg, are presented in Table 4. We present summary statistics for the yield curve data used in this paper in Table 5. 13 Loan asset exposures by destination region and sector for large European banks in 2011 3.500 3.000 Eur billions 2.500 2.000 1.500 1.000 500 0 Euro area Other european countries Corporate North America Financial Institution Latin America Household Asia Rest of the world Public Sector Figure 5: Total loan asset exposures in our sample of large European banks in 2011, summarised by target country and sector. Table 4: Yield curve tickers and maturities in years according to Bloomberg. These maturities are used in Section 3.3 to model the level and changes of the yield curve. series EONIA Index EUR001W Index EUR001M Index EUR002M Index EUR003M Index EUR004M Index EUR005M Index EUR006M Index EUSWG Curncy EUSWH Curncy EUSWI Curncy EUSWJ Curncy term 0.00 0.02 0.08 0.17 0.25 0.33 0.42 0.50 0.58 0.67 0.75 0.83 series EUSWK Curncy EUSA1 Curncy EUSA1F Curncy EUSA2 Curncy EUSA3 Curncy EUSA4 Curncy EUSA5 Curncy EUSA6 Curncy EUSA7 Curncy EUSA8 Curncy EUSA9 Curncy EUSA10 Curncy 14 term 0.92 1.00 1.50 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00 8.00 9.00 10.00 series EUSA11 EUSA12 EUSA15 EUSA20 EUSA25 EUSA30 EUSA35 EUSA40 EUSA45 EUSA50 Curncy Curncy Curncy Curncy Curncy Curncy Curncy Curncy Curncy Curncy term 11.00 12.00 15.00 20.00 25.00 30.00 35.00 40.00 45.00 50.00 Table 5: Summary statistics for the yield curve data, in percentage points. series EONIA Index EUR001M Index EUR001W Index EUR002M Index EUR003M Index EUR004M Index EUR005M Index EUR006M Index EUSA1 Curncy EUSA10 Curncy EUSA11 Curncy EUSA12 Curncy EUSA15 Curncy EUSA1F Curncy EUSA2 Curncy EUSA20 Curncy EUSA25 Curncy 3 3.1 mean 2.47 2.52 2.45 2.59 2.67 2.70 2.74 2.77 2.87 4.09 4.07 4.22 4.35 2.92 3.04 4.46 4.43 sd 1.44 1.43 1.44 1.43 1.40 1.38 1.36 1.34 1.36 1.04 1.01 1.01 1.00 1.34 1.31 1.01 1.03 min 0.08 0.11 0.08 0.15 0.19 0.23 0.28 0.32 0.33 1.56 1.68 1.79 1.91 0.35 0.38 1.92 1.90 max 5.16 5.05 4.89 5.13 5.28 5.32 5.36 5.38 5.38 5.95 5.98 6.06 6.16 5.43 5.52 6.22 6.22 series EUSA3 Curncy EUSA30 Curncy EUSA35 Curncy EUSA4 Curncy EUSA40 Curncy EUSA45 Curncy EUSA5 Curncy EUSA50 Curncy EUSA6 Curncy EUSA7 Curncy EUSA8 Curncy EUSA9 Curncy EUSWG Curncy EUSWH Curncy EUSWI Curncy EUSWJ Curncy EUSWK Curncy mean 3.23 4.45 3.81 3.40 4.12 3.84 3.56 4.07 3.70 3.82 3.92 4.01 2.72 2.73 2.74 2.74 2.75 sd 1.26 1.05 0.80 1.21 0.92 0.82 1.16 0.90 1.13 1.10 1.08 1.06 1.53 1.52 1.49 1.52 1.52 min 0.47 1.86 1.86 0.60 1.87 1.88 0.77 1.89 0.95 1.12 1.29 1.43 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 max 5.59 6.22 5.05 5.65 5.99 5.14 5.71 5.74 5.76 5.82 5.86 5.89 5.35 5.30 5.31 5.33 5.34 Method A theory of maturity transformation and its relation to interest rate risk Consider a financial institution that enters into contractual arrangements with other parties. These contractual agreements bind the institution into making and receiving payments many years into the future. Let us imagine that there are finitely many characteristics of these future cashflows that are relevant for determining the price today of transferring these rights and obligations to other institutions. We could call this set of characteristics Ω, and we could write Ω = X × T for some finite sets X and T with T ⊂ R+ to record the fact that among these characteristics will be the contractual maturity or repricing date of each cashflow is there (T ). The financial institution N fore defined by its asset and liability cashflow streams A ∈ R : (x, t) ∈ X × T ⊂ R × R and x,t + Lx,t ∈ R : (x, t) ∈ X × T ⊂ RN × R+ respectively, where x ∈ X ⊂ RN is an indexing set18 and t ∈ T ⊂ R+ is time into the future.19 We can define the net asset stream or equity stream using a functional application of the accounting identity E , {Ex,t , Ax,t − Lx,t : (x, t) ∈ X × T }. The equity stream can be thought of as the future profit or future net cashflow in the firm emerging over time in every tradable claim x ∈ X. We can say that an institution engages in net asset transformation if ∃(x, t), (x0 , t0 ) ∈ X × T such that Ex,t 6= Ex0 ,t0 , or in words, if there are differences in its borrowing and lending across characteristics in X × T . We give a graphical representation of transformation in Figure 6 , where an intermediary is a net borrower of some tradable claims and a net lender of others. Maturity transformation is then a special case of net asset transformation and could be defined local to some x ∈ X or globally in all x ∈ X . An intermediary engages in local maturity transformation at x ∈ X if ∃t, t0 ∈ T such that Ex,t 6= Ex,t0 , which says that the intermediary transforms assets of type x ∈ X from various maturities into other P maturities,P while an intermediary engages in global maturity transformation if ∃t, t0 ∈ T such that x Ex,t 6= x Ex,t0 . We can further talk of positive or negative maturity transformation, 18 The index x ∈ X could be thought of as measurable time-invariant classifications of assets and liabilities relevant to the price of a contract. Formally, X = Ω\T . Examples are sector, geographic, and ratings-based classifications of assets and liabilities. In the context of assessing the revaluation effect of changes in asset prices or interest rates, we assume that we have a complete market so that we can treat every element x ∈ X as a tradable claim with a measurable price. We will require that X be finite, or in other words |X| < ∞. The indexing set X is relevant for grouping assets and liabilities that are traded together, have similar prices (which may or may not be related to others through substitution effects) and whose risk characteristics are therefore similar. 19 We will require |T | < ∞, which does not in principle preclude the institution from holding non-maturing assets like stocks. 15 t At t5 t4 + − t3 + + − − − t1 − − + x1 x2 x43 t t t t t t t t Lt + t2 t Et + negative none positive x x5 Figure 6: A graphical representation of (net) asset transformation by a financial intermediary. The intermediary is a net borrower at some contractual maturities (t1 , t2 , t4 ) and in 1 some markets (x1 , x2 , x4 ) while being a net lender at other maturities and in other markets. Figure 7: Examples of positive and negative maturity transformation for a financial intermediary. The top, middle and bottom rows give the values of assets, liabilities and net assets by maturity. where positive maturity transformation refers to assets that are ‘on average’ longer in maturity than liabilities. We don’t define these notions explicitly, but provide some examples of positive and negative maturity transformation in Figure 7. From balance sheet data, we typically find that banks engage in positive maturity transformation, while insurers engage in negative maturity transformation. As a complement to maturity transformation, if we use the term sector to refer to the more abstract X dimension of future contracts, we can similarly define local and global (in t ∈ T ) sector transformation. In an economy where all claims indexed by (x, t) ∈ X × T ⊂ RN × R+ are traded in perfectly competitive markets populated by agents with weakly monotonic preferences, we have a unique pricing kernel for tradable claims and hence a discount factor B : RN × R+ → R+ satisfying ∂B ∂t ≤ 0 for all t ∈ R+ . In this case, the value of assets at time zero, which is the price that another institution would have to pay to obtain these future cash inflows, is given by X B(x, t)Ax,t , x,t 1 with the values of liabilities andPequity at time zero similarly defined. The solvency position of the financial institution is given by x,t B(x, t)Ex,t , and the financial institution is said to be solvent at time zero on a market-consistent basis if and only if X B(x, t)Ex,t > 0. x,t Note that the definition of At is sufficiently general that it could depend on the pricing function B, which would arise, for example, if the firm purchased a floating-rate note, payments on which depended on realised interest rates. The value of equity is then the value of assets of liabilities. In ´ t less the value the case where we can express the pricing function as B(x, t) = exp − 0 r(x, s)ds for some integrable function r : RN × R+ → R and for all x, we can interpret r , r(x, t) : (x, t) ∈ RN × R+ as the set of yield curves implied by the discount function B. For the balance sheet items that are valued on a market-consistent basis, the financial institution reports their value at the valuation date, Ex,t Bx,t . If the per-unit pricing function B were to move 16 to some B 0 , and if the quantity function Ex,t were to remain constant, then the market-consistent 0 valuation of the balance sheet item would become Ex,t Bx,t , implying a percentage change of 0 0 0 Ex,t Bx,t − Ex,t Bx,t Bx,t Bx,t = − 1 ≈ log . Ex,t Bx,t Bx,t Bx,t (1) By assuming a distribution for B 0 , either through assuming a distribution for the set of yield curves r when this exists, or through assuming a distribution for the pricing function B 0 directly, we have a distribution for this percentage change in (1) above. The interest rate risk or asset price risk then arises from the revaluation effect of unanticipated changes in interest rates or per-unit asset prices, and the intermediary’s exposure to such risk depends on the allocation of the intermediary’s net assets across all (x, t) claims. 3.2 Interest rate risk of loan securities and portfolios As we see in Section 4.1, the most important component of the bank balance sheet for assessing interest rate revaluation risk,20 ignoring off-balance sheet instruments, are the loan assets, because of their long maturity. In assessing interest rate revaluation risk of banks, we therefore focus on the interest rate risk of these loan assets. Assessing the interest rate revaluation risk of the whole balance sheet in the spirit of the EVM for European banks would be a useful exercise, but it is beyond the scope of this paper. In our study of these loan assets, we assume that all loan assets are fixed-rate amortising loans. Variable-rate loan contracts exist and are less price sensitive to interest rate changes. However, since our loan exposures by maturity are categorised by time to “next repricing date”, rather than by time to contractual maturity, variable-rate contracts behave like fixed-rate contracts maturing on thir next repricing date. However, to the extent that these loan exposures by maturity in fact include heterogenous contract types,21 the pricing and risk methods associated with fixed-rate amortising loans may not be appropriate. In Section 1.1 above we discuss the Basel Committee guidelines for assessing interest rate revaluation risk. In this section, we offer simple alternative methods for assessing interest rate revaluation risk based on methods for pricing such amortising loan contracts. The pricing functions we propose here are well known present value functions.22 The simplest such pricing function is the formula for the present value of a fixed-term annuity of 1 per year for τ years, at constant annual continuously-compounded interest δ: 1 − e−δτ . δ This formula corresponds to a present value under a flat yield curve, with level δ at every maturity. We can generalise this formula to the case where yield curves are not flat. If we let {f (m)} be the forward curve,23 the present value of the same fixed-term annuity is ˆ τ ˆ u p({f (m)}, τ ) , exp(− f (m)dm)du. p(δ, τ ) , 0 0 Using p(δ, τ ) and p({f (m)}, τ ), we have pricing functions for individual loan contracts. However, if we would like to compare banks, we need to be able to price portfolios of loan contracts too, so that we can compute interest rate sensitivities. The price of a portfolio defined by a (possibly countable) set P of shares {φi }, where perhaps i φi = 1, is24 20 The revaluation or repricing risk that we use interchangeably throughout this paper simply means the percentage change in value of a contract or portfolio of contracts given a change in interest rates or yield curves. 21 Heterogeneity in loan contracts in the form of collateral or embedded options, for example for default and prepayment respectively, would be key sources of pricing heterogeneity and hence heterogeneity in interest rate risk. Prepayment risk is defined in Footnote 11. 22 More sophisticated pricing functions like those using risk-neutral valuation would be an interesting extension to this paper. 23 For explanations of the terms forward curve and zero curve, see Section 3.3 and Svensson (1994). 24 In the case where f (m) = δ ∀m, we have X p({φi }, δ, {τi }) = φi p(δ, τi ). i 17 p({φi }, {f (m)}, {τi }) , X φi p({f (m)}, τi ). i For the purposes of calculating sensitivity to interest rate revaluation, we do not require that {φi } be normalised to sum to one. In particular, we could use Euro-denominated exposures in place of {φi }, because the normalisation constant cancels out in the sensitivity measures below. We seek to measure the percentage change in value of a loan, or portfolio of loans, given a change in interest rates or yield curves. We could consider using an analytic derivative25 to compute this sensitivity, which also motivates the Basel Committee guideline discussed in 1.1 above. However, such a derivative would only be valid, and an accurate approximation, for infinitesimally small changes in yield curves. If, as per the Basel Committee guidelines, we were to seek the effect of a 200 basis point interest rate shock, which is fairly large, then we would not expect the derivative to provide a good approximation. A more exact approach would be to compute the present value under two interest rate scenarios – one before, and one after the shock. This exact approach would capture the non-linearities in exposure. For example, increases and decreases in interest rates of equal magnitude would not be expected to produce equal decreases and increases in present values, respectively. If we assume a flat forward curve, the change in present value takes the form log p(δ1 , τ ) − log p(δ0 , τ ), where δ0 is the constant annual continuously compounded interest rate before the shock, and δ1 is the same rate after the shock. This expression can be interpreted as a percentage change in the present value of a loan contract and is directly analogous to (1) above. If we assume an arbitrary shape to the forward curve, the change in present value takes the form log p({f (m)}1 , τ ) − log p({f (m)}0 , τ ), and if we consider a portfolio of loan contracts, the change in present value takes the form log p({φi }, {f (m)}1 , {τi }) − log p({φi }, {f (m)}0 , {τi }), where the weights {φi } are assumed invariant to the interest rate change, and where the normalisation constant for {φi } cancels. 3.3 Characterising interest rate movements We can characterise the shape of the yield curve at any point in time by the forward curve or the zero curve. The zero rate at any given maturity is the yield to maturity one could obtain on a zerocoupon bond of that maturity, and the zero curve is the collection of such zero rates at all maturities. The zero-coupon bond underlying a zero rate may be hypothetical, for example a Treasury security or corporate obligation that does not exist in the market at that particular maturity. Zero curves are inferred from the yields to maturity on a set of coupon-paying bonds, the prices of which can be observed in the market, through a process known as bootstrapping.26 The forward curve at any maturity is defined as the increase in yield to maturity one could obtain today by marginally extending one’s holding period from that maturity. If the zero curve is defined by {z(m)}, then the forward curve is defined by {f (m)|f (m) , limh→0+ ((m + h)z(m + h) − mz(m)) /h = d (mz(m)) /dm ´ m ∀m}, and similarly, the zero curve can be obtained from the forward curve pointwise by z(m) = 0 f (u)du/m. In this paper, our yield curves are given by the Euro area interbank and swap rates discussed in Section 2.4. At every month-end, we therefore have 34 points that characterise the shape of the 25 Note that we would need a directional derivative in the case of a general forward curve. In this paper, we only consider directional derivatives in the direction of a constant function, or in other words, we only consider parallel shifts in the yield curve for consistency with the Basel Committee guideline method for interest rate sensitivity assessment. In Section 4.3 we show that parallel shifts are not plausible from historical data on Euro yield curves. 26 The process of bootstrapping involves transformation and interpolation. For a discussion, see Svensson (1994). 18 yield curve. A particular yield curve parametrisation allows use to reduce this dimensionality. A Nelson-Siegel model of the yield curve takes the form f (m) = β0 + β1 e−m/τ1 + β2 z(m) = β0 + (β1 + β2 ) m −m/τ1 e τ1 τ1 (1 − e−m/τ1 ) − β2 e−m/τ1 , m (2) where the four parameters to be specified are β0 , β1 , β2 and τ1 (Nelson and Siegel, 1987). If we assume for convenience that the forward curve is closely approximated by the interbank swap curve for which we have data, then we can estimate at each month-end these four parameters by choosing them to minimise some distance measure between the 34 observed and fitted values of f .27 We also consider the so-called Svensson model of the yield curve, which takes the form f (m) = β0 + β1 e−m/τ1 + β2 z(m) = β0 + (β1 + β2 ) m −m/τ1 m e + β3 e−m/τ2 τ1 τ2 τ τ1 2 (1 − e−m/τ1 ) − β2 e−m/τ1 + β3 (1 − e−m/τ2 ) − e−m/τ2 , m m (3) where the six parameters to be estimated are β0 , β1 , β2 , β3 , τ1 and τ2 (Svensson, 1994). By specifying one of these parametric forms of the yield curve, i.e. Nelson-Siegel or Svensson, one can obtain the pricing functions and sensitivities discussed in Section 3.2 above. In particular, by varying the β0 parameter, one can obtain the effect of parallel shifts in the yield curve on the price of a loan contract or portfolio of loan contracts. We show below that our results using Nelson-Siegel or Svensson models are qualitatively similar. By estimating the parameters of the Nelson-Siegel and Svensson models at each month-end under a squared error loss function, we obtain a characterisation of the yield curve at every point in time. The parameters of these models can loosely be interpreted in terms of level, slope and curvature effects, although the interpretation in the Svensson model is more difficult. For interpretation, we therefore focus on the Nelson-Siegel model, where β0 can be interpreted as the level of the yield curve, β1 as the premium of the short term rate over the long term rate (i.e. the inverse of the slope of the curve), and β2 as the premium of the medium term rate over the long and short term rates (i.e. the ‘humpedness’ or curvature of the yield curve). By examining also the month-to-month changes in these beta parameters, we can learn about shape changes in the yield curve through time. We present the kernel density estimates for month-to-month changes in β0 in Figure 8. We can see that in both yield curve models, changes in the level of yield curves are roughly symmetric and clustered around zero. We explore changes in the yield curve further in Section 4.3. 4 4.1 Results Observed maturity transformation by European banks in 2011 We provide a graphical representation of the maturity transformation undertaken by our sample of banks in Figure 9. From the figure we can see that the median bank in 2011 obtained financing mostly from customer deposits and instruments valued at amortised cost, while investing mostly in loans. The maturity mismatch on bank balance sheets is also evident: within the loan category, the median bank allocated more capital to longer-dated assets, but within the deposit category, the median bank obtained more funding from shorter-dated liabilities. The median bank also obtained a signicant share of funding in the amortised cost category from the 1-5 year horizon, which indicates hybrid and subordinated debt instruments. 27 In principle, we should apply a ‘bootstrap’ procedure to determine the zero and forward curves implied by the Euro swap curve data, and then we should fit the parametric yield curve model to this forward curve. This is a work in progress and should not affect the results significantly, since the various parametrisations are shown in this paper not to have a noticeable affect on the sensitivity calculation. 19 Kernel density of month−on−month changes in beta0: Svensson 80 0 0 20 50 40 60 Density 100 Density 150 100 200 Kernel density of month−on−month changes in beta0: Nelson−Siegel −0.02 −0.01 0.00 0.01 0.02 −0.04 N = 166 Bandwidth = 0.0006728 −0.02 0.00 0.02 0.04 N = 166 Bandwidth = 0.001099 Figure 8: Kernel densities of month-on-month changes in β0 under the Nelson-Siegel and Svensson models. Net assets for the median bank in 2011 by maturity and subcategory remaining maturity, or time to next repricing maturity not disclosed undetermined more than 5 years net assets (EUR) 20000 1 to 5 years 10000 0 −10000 3 to 12 month up to 3 month demand amortised cost available for sale central bank customer deposits held for trading held to maturity interbank loans asset / liability subcategory Figure 9: A graphical depiction of maturity transformation in the 2011 European banking data. Each cell in the matrix gives the median net asset (asset minus liability) exposure across all banks in the sample. This figure is the empirical analog of the theoretical chart 6. 20 Table 6: Percentage change in the value of an individual loan contract for various shock sizes, maturities and methods. Subtable (a) uses the Basel Committee guideline method, (b) uses the simplest flat yield curve loan pricing model, (c) uses a model based on Nelson-Siegel forward rates calibrated to historical parameters, and (d) uses Svensson forward rates also calibrated to historical parameter values. In each subtable the rows give the size of the shock, which is a parallel shift in the level of the forward curve, and the columns give the remaining maturity of the loan contract. (b) Flat rate δ = 3.2% (a) Basel Committee guideline -3.0% -2.0% -1.0% -0.5% 0.0% 0.5% 1.0% 2.0% 3.0% 1 2.1 1.4 0.7 0.4 -0.0 -0.4 -0.7 -1.4 -2.1 3 6.8 4.5 2.2 1.1 -0.0 -1.1 -2.2 -4.5 -6.8 10 19.9 13.3 6.6 3.3 -0.0 -3.3 -6.6 -13.3 -19.9 15 26.8 17.8 8.9 4.5 -0.0 -4.5 -8.9 -17.8 -26.8 20 33.6 22.4 11.2 5.6 -0.0 -5.6 -11.2 -22.4 -33.6 30 39.0 26.0 13.0 6.5 -0.0 -6.5 -13.0 -26.0 -39.0 (c) Nelson-Siegel (β0 , β1 , β2 , τ1 ) = (3.2, −.7, 4.5, 73)% -3.0% -2.0% -1.0% -0.5% 0.0% 0.5% 1.0% 2.0% 3.0% 4.2 4.2.1 1 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2 0.0 -0.2 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 3 4.4 3.0 1.5 0.7 0.0 -0.7 -1.5 -2.9 -4.4 10 14.5 9.6 4.8 2.4 0.0 -2.3 -4.7 -9.3 -13.8 15 21.5 14.1 7.0 3.5 0.0 -3.4 -6.8 -13.4 -19.8 20 28.2 18.5 9.1 4.5 0.0 -4.4 -8.8 -17.2 -25.3 -3.0% -2.0% -1.0% -0.5% 0.0% 0.5% 1.0% 2.0% 3.0% 1 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2 0.0 -0.2 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 3 4.4 2.9 1.5 0.7 0.0 -0.7 -1.5 -2.9 -4.4 10 14.1 9.3 4.6 2.3 0.0 -2.3 -4.5 -9.0 -13.4 15 20.5 13.5 6.7 3.3 0.0 -3.3 -6.5 -12.8 -18.9 20 26.5 17.4 8.5 4.2 0.0 -4.1 -8.2 -16.1 -23.7 30 37.3 24.1 11.7 5.8 0.0 -5.6 -11.1 -21.5 -31.3 (d) Svensson (β0 , β1 , β2 , β3 , τ1 , τ2 ) = (2.1, 1.1, 1.8, 5.5, 65, 855)% 30 41.1 26.7 13.0 6.4 0.0 -6.2 -12.3 -23.8 -34.7 -3.0% -2.0% -1.0% -0.5% 0.0% 0.5% 1.0% 2.0% 3.0% 1 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2 0.0 -0.2 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 3 4.6 3.1 1.5 0.8 0.0 -0.8 -1.5 -3.1 -4.6 10 18.7 12.4 6.2 3.1 0.0 -3.1 -6.1 -12.1 -18.0 15 29.2 19.3 9.6 4.8 0.0 -4.7 -9.4 -18.7 -27.9 20 38.0 25.1 12.4 6.2 0.0 -6.1 -12.2 -24.1 -35.7 30 49.9 32.8 16.1 8.0 0.0 -7.9 -15.6 -30.8 -45.4 How good is the Basel Committee interest rate sensitivity guideline for loans? Effect of loan-specific pricing The Basel Committee guidelines outlined in Section 1.1 do not take into account the type of security for which an interest rate risk assessment is being performed. In particular, the guidelines may or may not be suitable for typical loan contracts. We investigate the performance of the Basel Committee guideline method for interest rate revaluation sensitivity by comparing it to our alternative simple loan pricing models of Section 3.2 with parametric forward curves specified in 3.3. The results are summarised in Table 6. Under all methods, positive interest rate shocks (increases in the level of the forward curve) result in decreases in the value of a loan contract with any maturity, and decreases in interest rates result in revaluation increases. Larger absolute interest rate shocks result in large absolute changes in value. The Basel Committee guideline method, like any duration-based sensitivity method28 , produces sensitivities that are symmetric about zero: positive and negative interest rate shocks of equal absolute size have an equal absolute revaluation effect; in other words, for any given loan maturity, the percentage decrease in loan price from an interest rate increase is the same as the percentage increase in loan price from an interest rate decrease of equal absolute size. We can see that all the alternative simple loan models, however, are able to capture the asymmetric revaluation effect of interest rate changes. At short maturities and for small shock sizes, these asymmetric effects are negligibly small, while at longer maturities and at larger shock sizes we note that loan prices are more sensitive to decreases in interest rates. It is not surprising, therefore, that the Basel Committee guideline method sometimes overstates, and at other times understates, the interest rate sensitivity of loan prices. From the regulator’s point of view, we might be most concerned with situations where the Basel 28 For an introduction to duration-based sensitivity measurement, see Kaufman (1984). 21 Committee method understates the revaluation sensitivity to interest rate increases.29 Against the flat rate and Nelson-Siegel models, the Basel Committee method is prudent for maturities up to 30 years, in that it overstates the loan price sensitivity to interest rate increases.30 This is comforting since we would expect the remaining maturity of most loan contracts to be less than 30 years. However, when compared to the Svensson model, the Basel Committee method is only prudent for loan contracts of up to 10 year maturity, beyond which it understates the loan price sensitivity to interest rate increases. For banks with a substantial proportion of loans in the 10-30 year maturity category, we might expect the Basel Committee method to understate the loan price sensitivity to interest rate increases. While prudential regulators presumably favour the conservativeness of a method, investors would like an accurate assessment of the risk, with overstatements and understatements being equally harmful. Relative to the alternative loan models, the Basel Committee method overstates the revaluation gains from interest rate decreases at shorter maturities and understates these revaluation gains at longer maturities. The Basel Committee method for interest rate revaluation sensitivity is therefore generally conservative for shorter-maturity loans, and understates risk for longer-maturity loans. 4.2.2 Effect of current yield curve The Basel Committee guideline method for assessing interest rate revaluation sensitivity does not account for the prevailing yield curve at the time of the sensitivity estimate. For example, we might intuitively expect a 2% change in interest rates to be more serious when interest rates are low; conversely, we might expect a 2% shock not to be very serious in a high interest rate environment. We investigate this by comparing the sensitivities from the Basel Committee guideline method to the sensitivities from our simplest flat rate loan model of Section 3.2, noting that the latter does depend on a reference or prevailing rate of interest. We present a graphical summary in Figure 10. From the figure, we see that the Basel Committee method overstates the risk of a 2% parallel upward shift in the yield curve for loan maturities up to 27 years, relative to the simplest loan model. This observation agrees with those of the preceding section: although the Basel Committee method does not take into account the specific form of the loan contract, it gives a conservative assessment of the interest rate risk for loans with remaining maturity up to 27 years. However, we note that the prevailing level of the yield curve does noticeably affect the sensitivity of the price of a loan contract. When forward rates are flat and high, say 5%, the Basel Committee method conservatively assesses the risk of a 2% parallel upward shift in yield curves (forward rates) for loans with remaining maturity up to 40 years. When yield curves are flat and low, say .1% or 1%, the Basel Committee method understates the risk associated with 30-year loans. From the preceding section, we know that the Basel Committee guideline method is generally conservative for shorter-maturity loans, and understated for longer-maturity loans. In addition to these stylised facts, we also observe for interest rate increases that the Basel Committee guideline method is less conservative, or more understated, when interest rates are low than when interest rates are high. The Basel Committee method, which does not allow for the prevailing level of interest rates, is less appropriate for supervision in low interest rate environments. 4.2.3 Effect of portfolio aggregation Regardless of the type of security and the current level of the yield curve, the Basel Committee guideline method for interest rate revaluation sensitivity does not provide a unique method for portfolio aggregation. Suppose that a bank holds two loans of different remaining maturties, one with 1 year and the other with 10 years. The Basel Committee method provides senstivities for each of these contracts individually, but not uniquely for a portfolio of both. Two natural methods suggest themselves for computing the interest rate revaluation sensitivity of the portfolio with the Basel Committee method. 29 We note in Section 4.1 that European banks’ on-balance-sheet positions in 2011 are net positive at long maturities and net negative at short maturities. This finding is very typical of banks’ role as maturity-transformers. However, it exposes them to increases in interest rates, since such increases would cause the value of (long-term) assets to drop by more than the offsetting rise in the value of (short-term) liabilities. Off course, the regulator might anticipate that rational market participants should rationally compensate for overstatements/understatements in the Basel Committee guideline method, and if there are no informational obstacles to the market participants doing so, such a regulator might be equally averse to both over- and understatements of interest rate sensitivity. 30 This statement should be qualified by the specific parameter assumptions that have been made here on δ, β , β , β , τ . 0 1 2 1 See the discussion of Figure 10. 22 Percentage change in price given a 2% parallel upward shift in interest rates 0 −10 Method percentage Basel guideline loan model 0.1% −20 loan model 1% loan model 3% loan model 5% loan model 7% loan model 9% −30 −40 0 10 20 30 40 50 remaining loan maturity Figure 10: The effect of a 2% increase in interest rates at all maturities on the price of a loan contract with remaining maturity between 1 and 50 years, according to the Basel Committee guideline and the simple formula log p(δ + .02, τ ) − log p(δ, τ ) based on the present value function p(δ, τ ) = (1 − e−δτ )/δ, where τ ∈ [1 : 50] is the remaining loan maturity and δ ∈ {.001, .01, .03, .05, .07, .09} is the level of the flat yield curve before the shock. 23 −6 −8 −10 −12 % change in portfolio value −4 −2 The first is to use a weighted average of the Basel Committee interest rate revaluation sensitivities of each asset, based on the prevailing weights of each asset in the portfolio. We call this a weighted average sensitivity method for assessing the interest rate revaluation sensitivity of the portfolio. The is the approach recommended in Annex 4 of the Basel Committee guidelines (Basel Committee Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2004), but it is not the only possible approach. Under this method, the portfolio sensitivity is a linear combination of the sensitivities of the securities in the portfolio. An alternative method, which we call the weighted average maturity method, is to compute the Basel Committee interest rate sensitivity of a single hypothetical security with maturity equal to the weighted average maturity of all the securities in a portfolio, again using portfolio weights.31 We examine the performance of these two methods for applying the Basel Committee Portfolio sensitivity to a 2% parallel increase guideline method to portfolios of loan contracts as we allocate less to the 10−year asset using Figure 11. Consider the case where a bank Sv (2.1,1.1,1.8,5.5,65,855)% holds only two loan contracts: one with 1 year N−S (3.2,−.7,4.5,73)% flat yield curve 3.2% and the other with 10 years remaining maturity. basel w.a.m. basel w.a.s. The horizonal axis in Figure 11 represents the weight placed on the 1-year loan, and the various lines show the sensitivity of the portfolio value to a 2% increase in the level of the yield curve under the various methods, including those discussed in Sections 1.1 and 3.2. We see that all methods are able to capture the greater price sensitivity of the 10-year loan than the 1-year loan. We have already analysed above the sensitivites at the left and right endpoints of Figure 11, where we found for individual loan contracts with maturities less than 10 years that the Basel Committee method is relatively conservative. The Basel 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Committee method performs aggregation by linear interpolation between these two sensitivities, weight in 1 year loan (= 1 − weight in 10 year loan) while all other methods display some convexity. In particular, although the two Basel Commit- Figure 11: Effect of portfolio aggregation under the tee portfolio methods agree exactly at the left Basel Committee guideline method for interest rate and right endpoints, the weighted average matu- revaluation senstivity as compared to the alternarity method is more conservative everywhere in tive models. The labels in the legend correspond, between, which shows that the Basel Committee from top to bottom, to Svensson, Nelson-Siegel guideline sensitivity for individual loan contracts and flat forward curve models calibrated to historis convex in the remaining maturity of the loan. ical parameters; following these, we have the Basel This convexity is borne out by the other loan- Committee weighted average maturity method and pricing methods too. Perhaps surprisingly, while the weighted average sensitivity method. the two Basel Committee methods for portfolio sensitivity overstate the sensitivity for individual loans, they understate the sensitivity for some portfolios of loans. Even the weighted average maturity method, which is more conservative than the weighted average sensitivity method, understates the risk for portfolios with greater weight in the 1-year loan than in the 10-year loan. Portfolios of the 1- and 10-year loans that place just a small weight in the 10-year loan are much more price-sensitive to parallel upward shifts in yield curves than the Basel Committee methods indicate. For supervisory purposes or for risk self-assessment, we would therefore be most worried about using the Basel Committee method for banks whose loan portfolios have a short weighted average maturity, but a non-negligible allocation at long maturities. 31 To make these definitions more formal, consider the case where we have a portfolio consisting of 1 − φ in the 1 year loan and φ in the 10 year loan. Let the Basel Committee interest-rate sensitivity of a loan with remaining maturity τ be ∆(τ ). Then the weighted average sensitivity method computes (1 − φ)∆(1) + φ∆(10) as the interest rate sensitivity, while the weighted average maturity method computes ∆ ((1 − φ) · 1 + φ · 10). Since ∆(·) will be a convex function for most securities other than zero-coupon bonds, we would expect the latter method to produce lower portfolio sensitivities than the former. 24 Table 7: Frequency of ≥ 2% increase in the level of historical (forward or zero) yield curves over an l−month period for various values of l. Subtables (a) and (b) are computed by estimating Nelson-Siegel and Svensson parametric forms respectively at each month-end in the sample, and by then examining the longitudinal distribution of β0 . In each subtable, the first row shows the number of times where an l−month change in β0 meet or exceeds 2%, the middle row shows the number of longitudinal observations on which this count is based, and the final row shows the frequency obtained by dividing the first row by the second. (a) Nelson-Siegel number ≥ 2% number observations frequency (%) 1 1 166 0.60 3 3 164 1.83 6 5 161 3.11 9 5 158 3.16 12 6 155 3.87 15 6 152 3.95 18 2 149 1.34 24 6 143 4.20 (b) Svensson number ≥ 2% number observations frequency (%) 4.3 1 4 166 2.41 3 6 164 3.66 6 14 161 8.70 9 19 158 12.03 12 22 155 14.19 15 29 152 19.08 18 36 149 24.16 24 33 143 23.08 How representative is a 2% parallel yield curve shock? In Table 7 we show the frequency of large parallel shifts in the yield curve, under the Nelson-Siegel and Svensson models, over various time horizons. Under the Nelson-Siegel model, such large moves in the yield curve are rare even over 24 months, while under the Svensson model they are much more frequent. The most relevant time horizons for our purposes are up to 3 months, in which time we may expect a bank to be relatively unable to make major portfolio adjustments in response to sharp yield curve changes. Based on time horizons of up to 3 months, we might estimate that a 2% parallel upward shift in yield curve occurs with probability between 0.6% and 3.7% in any one month, which corresponds to something between a 1 in 14 year event and a 1 in 2 year event. This gives an idea of the ‘severity’, or lack thereof, of a 2% shock to the level of the yield curve. In addition, we would like to investigate the extent to which it is reasonable to shock the level of yield curves without also varying other shape parameters of the yield curve. In particular if slope and level changes tend to occur together, then the revaluation effect of a level shock only may under- or overstate the revaluation effect of a shock to both levels and slope. We present an initial investigation of these relationships between changing parameters in Table 8, where the subtables correspond to different time horizons over which we might measure the change in parameters. The correlations are stable between tables. They show that changes in the level and slope of the yield curve, as parametrised by β0 and −β1 , exhibit a strong positive contemporaneous correlation over 1, 3, 6, 9 and 12 months.32 Increases in the level of the Euro yield curve are associated with simultaneous increases in the slope of the yield curve over all of these time horizons, and the absolute size of the correlation decreases with the time horizon. Similary, level and curvature show a strong negative association, suggesting that yield curves flatten when they shift upward, and the absolute size of this association increases with the time horizon. We therefore note, that regardless of the severity of the interest rate shock one would like to apply (for example a 2% level change), association between level, slope and curvature are highly prevalent historically. We regard these relationships as evidence against the plausibility of a parallel yield curve shock. These relationships should be used in a proper assessment of interest rate risk. It is well known that correlation is not a very satisfactory measure of dependence. In a sense, correlation only captures a type of ‘linear’ dependence, which might ignore important and measurable ‘non-linear’ relationships. As a robustness check on our correlation estimates, we provide scatterplots of the levels and month-on-month (l = 1) changes in the β parameters of the Nelson-Siegel model in 32 β and β are negatively associated, so that β and −β are positively associated, and hence increases in level are 0 1 0 1 positively correlated with increases in slope. 25 Table 8: Correlations between l−month changes in Nelson-Siegel parameters. Of particular interest in this paper are the correlations between the β parameters, because these parameters can be interpreted as level, slope and curvature. (a) l = 1 β0 β1 β2 τ1 β0 1.00 -0.82 -0.59 0.28 β1 -0.82 1.00 0.34 -0.39 (b) l = 3 β2 -0.59 0.34 1.00 -0.23 τ1 0.28 -0.39 -0.23 1.00 β0 β1 β2 τ1 β0 1.00 -0.75 -0.63 0.24 (c) l = 6 β0 β1 β2 τ1 β0 1.00 -0.64 -0.69 0.32 β1 -0.64 1.00 0.29 -0.55 β1 -0.75 1.00 0.33 -0.46 β2 -0.63 0.33 1.00 -0.18 τ1 0.24 -0.46 -0.18 1.00 β2 -0.76 0.29 1.00 -0.28 τ1 0.31 -0.55 -0.28 1.00 (d) l = 9 β2 -0.69 0.29 1.00 -0.33 τ1 0.32 -0.55 -0.33 1.00 β0 β1 β2 τ1 β0 1.00 -0.54 -0.76 0.31 β1 -0.54 1.00 0.29 -0.55 (e) l = 12 β0 β1 β2 τ1 β0 1.00 -0.48 -0.81 0.35 β1 -0.48 1.00 0.27 -0.57 β2 -0.81 0.27 1.00 -0.29 τ1 0.35 -0.57 -0.29 1.00 Figure 12.33 On the scatterplots, we also provide the contours of a Gaussian kernel density estimator, and we scale the points by the value of τ1 .34 From the two upper plots in Figure 12, we note the negative associations between shape parameters, saying that high levels are associated with high slopes and high curvatures, not to be confused with the correlations in Table 8. We also note the clustering of points given by the two or three modes of the kernel density contours and the clustering of low and high values of τ1 . The lower two panels give the scatterplots for month-on-month changes (l = 1) in the beta parameters. From the lower-left panel we note that the strong linear dependence, measured in Table 8 by the strong correlation between β0 and β1 , captures virtually all of the bivariate relationship between the changes in these two parameters. Thus the positive correlation observed between the level and slope of the yield curve sufficiently characterises the general statistical relationship between them. 4.4 Rankings of European banks by loan portfolio riskiness in 2011 From Table 9 we see that the method by which we measure the interest rate risk of banks affects which banks emerge as most risky. We see that the ranking of the banks is not sensitive to the three forms of the yield curve, although the percentage change in portfolio value under a Svensson yield curve (and hence pricing) model produces higher sensitivities than under a Nelson-Siegel model. The two methods for calculating the portfolio riskiness under Basel Committee guidelines give different rankings of the banks, and the weighted average sensitivity guideline method agrees very strongly with the weighted average maturity from “gap analysis”. Given our reservations about the Basel Committee guideline methods for portfolios of assets, and given the lack of additional information they provide over simple gap analysis, neither of these rankings based on guideline methods is satisfactory. 33 Recall that this model has been estimated separately for each month-end yield curve by minimising a squared error loss function. 34 For the scatterplots of month-on-month changes in betas, the value of τ used to size the points on the scatterplot 1 is the second and later value corresponding to the pair of betas used for differencing. 26 0.08 0.00 0.25 0.50 −0.01 tau1 beta2 beta1 tau1 0.25 0.04 0.50 0.75 0.75 0.00 −0.02 0.00 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.00 0.02 beta0 0.04 0.06 beta0 0.02 0.03 0.00 tau1 0.25 0.50 0.75 −0.01 month−on−month change in beta2 month−on−month change in beta1 0.01 tau1 0.00 0.25 0.50 0.75 −0.03 −0.02 −0.06 −0.03 −0.01 0.00 0.01 0.02 −0.01 month−on−month change in beta0 0.00 0.01 0.02 month−on−month change in beta0 Figure 12: Relationships between level, slope and curvature parameters, and their month-to-month changes, for the Nelson-Siegel model of yield curves, when applied to the Euro swap curve data. 27 Table 9: Rankings of the sample banks, in Column 1 by the value-weighted average maturity of their loan portfolio, and in Columns 2-7 by the percentage decrease in the value of their loan portfolios due to a 2% parallel upward shift in yield curves. Columns 2-3 give the Basel Committee guideline method under weighted-average sensitivity and sensitivity of weighted-average maturity, defined in Section 4.2.3. Column 4 uses the simple loan formula with flat yield curve. Columns 5-6 use the Nelson-Siegel parametric form of the yield curve, which agrees analytically although not computationally with the simple loan formula when β1 = β2 = 0. Column 7 uses the Svensson parametric yield curve with parameters calibrated to historical averages. The methods for Columns 4-7 are defined in Section 3.2. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 Loans weighted avg maturity (yrs) DK011 9.39 NL050 9.28 PT055 8.30 NL049 7.93 GB091 7.72 BE004 7.65 IE037 7.64 SE087 7.47 NO051 7.21 NL047 7.06 CY006 6.99 ES061 6.81 MT046 6.72 PT054 6.70 IE038 6.66 ES059 6.24 DE025 6.10 FI012 5.97 PT053 5.94 DE021 5.74 ES062 5.73 GB090 5.54 PT056 5.54 CY007 5.52 IT044 5.50 SE084 5.32 ES064 5.31 DE019 5.23 IT043 5.22 DE020 5.08 ES060 5.06 IT042 4.93 FR014 4.87 FR013 4.75 IT041 4.72 DE018 4.63 HU036 4.61 IT040 4.57 DE024 4.46 AT003 4.32 DE023 4.25 DE029 3.90 DE027 3.83 SI057 3.76 FR016 3.76 SI058 3.72 GB088 3.71 AT002 3.48 DE028 3.45 SE085 3.14 IE039 2.78 GR032 2.65 DK010 2.49 NL048 2.43 PL052 2.40 DK008 2.18 BE005 2.17 GB089 1.96 GR033 1.13 DK009 1.05 SE086 0.36 Basel guideline w.a.s. (%) Basel guideline w.a.m. (%) Simple δ = 3.2% (%) N-S β0 = 3.2% (%) DK011 -12.48 NL050 -12.34 PT055 -11.08 NL049 -10.62 GB091 -10.39 BE004 -10.29 IE037 -10.28 SE087 -10.04 NO051 -9.70 NL047 -9.56 CY006 -9.47 ES061 -9.22 PT054 -9.11 MT046 -9.05 IE038 -9.03 ES059 -8.48 DE025 -8.34 FI012 -8.17 PT053 -8.13 DE021 -7.84 ES062 -7.82 CY007 -7.61 PT056 -7.56 GB090 -7.56 IT044 -7.54 ES064 -7.29 SE084 -7.25 IT043 -7.20 DE019 -7.17 DE020 -7.06 ES060 -6.95 IT042 -6.81 FR014 -6.70 FR013 -6.57 IT041 -6.53 HU036 -6.42 DE018 -6.42 IT040 -6.36 DE024 -6.27 AT003 -6.09 DE023 -5.85 DE029 -5.53 DE027 -5.45 SI057 -5.36 SI058 -5.33 FR016 -5.25 GB088 -5.24 AT002 -4.96 DE028 -4.95 SE085 -4.54 IE039 -4.20 GR032 -4.01 NL048 -3.77 PL052 -3.72 DK010 -3.71 DK008 -3.44 BE005 -3.42 GB089 -3.16 GR033 -1.78 DK009 -1.77 SE086 -0.67 BE004 -13.26 DK011 -13.26 GB091 -13.26 IE037 -13.26 NL047 -13.26 NL049 -13.26 NL050 -13.26 NO051 -13.26 PT055 -13.26 SE087 -13.26 CY006 -10.16 CY007 -10.16 DE019 -10.16 DE020 -10.16 DE021 -10.16 DE025 -10.16 ES059 -10.16 ES060 -10.16 ES061 -10.16 ES062 -10.16 ES064 -10.16 FI012 -10.16 GB090 -10.16 IE038 -10.16 IT043 -10.16 IT044 -10.16 MT046 -10.16 PT053 -10.16 PT054 -10.16 PT056 -10.16 SE084 -10.16 AT003 -7.70 DE018 -7.70 DE023 -7.70 DE024 -7.70 FR013 -7.70 FR014 -7.70 HU036 -7.70 IT040 -7.70 IT041 -7.70 IT042 -7.70 AT002 -6.14 DE027 -6.14 DE028 -6.14 DE029 -6.14 FR016 -6.14 GB088 -6.14 SE085 -6.14 SI057 -6.14 SI058 -6.14 BE005 -4.50 DK008 -4.50 DK010 -4.50 GR032 -4.50 IE039 -4.50 NL048 -4.50 PL052 -4.50 DK009 -2.76 GB089 -2.76 GR033 -2.76 SE086 -0.72 DK011 -9.24 NL050 -9.18 PT055 -9.11 NL049 -8.87 SE087 -8.79 MT046 -8.77 NO051 -8.75 IE037 -8.74 BE004 -8.65 GB091 -8.65 ES061 -8.48 NL047 -8.36 CY006 -8.36 ES059 -8.33 IE038 -8.32 SE084 -8.20 ES062 -8.20 PT056 -8.15 GB090 -8.15 DE021 -8.12 DE019 -8.03 ES064 -8.00 PT053 -8.00 DE025 -7.95 DE023 -7.95 ES060 -7.93 IT044 -7.92 FI012 -7.88 IT042 -7.81 FR014 -7.77 CY007 -7.76 IT043 -7.72 IT041 -7.69 FR013 -7.64 DE018 -7.48 FR016 -7.41 IT040 -7.38 HU036 -7.36 DE020 -7.22 GB088 -6.94 DE024 -6.87 AT003 -6.78 SI057 -6.66 DE029 -6.62 AT002 -6.61 SI058 -6.54 DE028 -6.44 DE027 -6.34 DK010 -6.27 SE085 -6.09 GR033 -6.05 SE086 -3.36 PL052 -2.78 DK008 -2.70 GB089 -2.60 DK009 -2.41 BE005 NA GR032 NA IE039 NA NL048 NA PT054 NA DK011 -9.24 NL050 -9.18 PT055 -9.11 NL049 -8.87 SE087 -8.79 MT046 -8.77 NO051 -8.75 IE037 -8.74 BE004 -8.65 GB091 -8.65 ES061 -8.48 NL047 -8.36 CY006 -8.36 ES059 -8.33 IE038 -8.32 SE084 -8.20 ES062 -8.20 PT056 -8.15 GB090 -8.15 DE021 -8.12 DE019 -8.03 ES064 -8.00 PT053 -8.00 DE025 -7.95 DE023 -7.95 ES060 -7.93 IT044 -7.92 FI012 -7.88 IT042 -7.81 FR014 -7.77 CY007 -7.76 IT043 -7.72 IT041 -7.69 FR013 -7.64 DE018 -7.48 FR016 -7.41 IT040 -7.38 HU036 -7.36 DE020 -7.22 GB088 -6.94 DE024 -6.87 AT003 -6.78 SI057 -6.66 DE029 -6.62 AT002 -6.61 SI058 -6.54 DE028 -6.44 DE027 -6.34 DK010 -6.27 SE085 -6.09 GR033 -6.05 SE086 -3.36 PL052 -2.78 DK008 -2.70 GB089 -2.60 DK009 -2.41 BE005 NA GR032 NA IE039 NA NL048 NA PT054 NA 28 N-S (β0 , β1 , β2 , τ1 ) = (3.2, −.7, 4.5, 73)% (%) DK011 -9.21 NL050 -9.15 PT055 -9.07 NL049 -8.84 SE087 -8.75 MT046 -8.73 NO051 -8.71 IE037 -8.70 BE004 -8.61 GB091 -8.61 ES061 -8.44 NL047 -8.32 CY006 -8.31 ES059 -8.29 IE038 -8.28 SE084 -8.16 ES062 -8.16 PT056 -8.11 GB090 -8.10 DE021 -8.07 DE019 -7.98 ES064 -7.95 PT053 -7.95 DE025 -7.91 DE023 -7.91 ES060 -7.89 IT044 -7.87 FI012 -7.84 IT042 -7.76 FR014 -7.73 CY007 -7.71 IT043 -7.67 IT041 -7.64 FR013 -7.59 DE018 -7.44 FR016 -7.37 IT040 -7.34 HU036 -7.32 DE020 -7.18 GB088 -6.89 DE024 -6.82 AT003 -6.73 SI057 -6.62 DE029 -6.57 AT002 -6.57 SI058 -6.49 DE028 -6.39 DE027 -6.30 DK010 -6.22 SE085 -6.05 GR033 -5.99 SE086 -3.32 PL052 -2.76 DK008 -2.68 GB089 -2.59 DK009 -2.40 BE005 NA GR032 NA IE039 NA NL048 NA PT054 NA Sv (β0 , β1 , β2 , β3 , τ1 , τ2 ) = (2.1, 1.1, 1.7, 5.5, 65, 855)% (%) DK011 -12.06 NL050 -12.02 PT055 -11.96 NL049 -11.78 SE087 -11.71 MT046 -11.70 NO051 -11.68 IE037 -11.68 BE004 -11.60 GB091 -11.59 ES061 -11.46 NL047 -11.35 CY006 -11.35 ES059 -11.33 IE038 -11.32 SE084 -11.22 ES062 -11.22 PT056 -11.18 GB090 -11.17 DE021 -11.14 DE019 -11.07 ES064 -11.05 PT053 -11.04 DE023 -11.00 DE025 -10.99 ES060 -10.99 IT044 -10.96 FI012 -10.93 IT042 -10.88 FR014 -10.83 CY007 -10.82 IT043 -10.78 IT041 -10.76 FR013 -10.70 DE018 -10.55 FR016 -10.50 IT040 -10.46 HU036 -10.44 DE020 -10.28 GB088 -10.01 DE024 -9.91 AT003 -9.81 SI057 -9.71 AT002 -9.65 DE029 -9.63 SI058 -9.58 DE028 -9.46 DK010 -9.38 DE027 -9.31 GR033 -9.27 SE085 -9.03 SE086 -5.67 PL052 -2.90 DK008 -2.82 GB089 -2.72 DK009 -2.54 BE005 NA GR032 NA IE039 NA NL048 NA PT054 NA 5 Conclusion In Section 4.1 we are able to show that large European banks tend to transform short term customer deposits and amortised cost instruments at 1-5 year maturity like hybrid and subordinated debt into long term loan assets, as expected. Given the earlier work discussed in Section 1, in which the effective maturity of core deposits is estimated to be less than three years, the interest rate revaluation risk of these banks is significantly determined by their loan asset portfolios. Examining the loan asset values more closely, we find in Section 2.3 that the banks with the largest loan asset porfolios in 2011 are domiciled in the UK, France and Germany, and these banks extend loans primarily into Euro-area countries and then into non-Euro European countries. Ranking the banks by their loan asset portfolio repricing sensitivity to a 2% parallel shift in interest rates in Section 4.4, we find that the three riskiest banks across most methods are Nykredit (DK), SNS Bank (NL) and Espirito Santo (PT). It must be emphasised that these rankings are independent of balance sheet size and do not account for offbalance-sheet instruments like interest rate derivatives, but they provide a useful starting point for the bank analyst and supervisor. In measuring the interest rate repricing risk of these banks, we employ several methods and critically evaluate the Basel Committee guideline method for interest rate sensitivity. We show how this guideline method is simplistic and we illustrate the size of the deviation from simple alternative pricing models through the use of examples. The guideline method is conservative for loan individual loan contracts with short maturities (less than 10-15 years) and in medium-to-high interest rate environments. However, the guideline method understates risk for portfolios of loans even at short maturities and for individual loan contracts with longer maturities, and these understatements are exacerbated in low interest rate environments. Further work should be done to investigate the sensitivities of the Basel Committee guideline method, and the simple alternative methods presented here for loan contracts, to the cashflow timing assumptions, and especially the timing assumption in the 5+ maturity bucket. Furthermore, we show that the 2% parallel shift in yield curves that is typically used as the socalled “standardised interest rate shock” is atypical of historical Euro yield curve movements. More work should therefore be done to determine the appropriate shocks to apply to interest rates, especially for supervisory purposes. In particular, it is inappropriate for supervisors to rely on monitoring only one interest rate scenario because it is fairly easy for banks to allocate their asset and liability maturities so that exposure to any one scenario is zero, while exposures to other scenarios might be large. References Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2004): “Principles for the Management and Supervision of Interest Rate Risk,” Discussion Paper July, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Basel, Switzerland. Czaja, M.-G., H. Scholz, and M. Wilkens (2009): “Interest rate risk of German financial institutions: the impact of level, slope, and curvature of the term structure,” Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 33(1), 1–26. English, W. B., S. J. van den Heuvel, and E. Zakrajsek (2012): “Interest Rate Risk and Bank Equity Valuations,” FEDS Working Papers, (2012-26). Entrop, O., C. Memmel, M. Wilkens, and A. Zeisler (2011): “Estimating the Interest Rate Risk of Banks Using Time Series of Accounting-Based Data,” Available at SSRN 982070. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (1994): “The Banking Crises of the 1980s and Early 1990s: Summary and Implications,” Discussion paper, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. Flannery, M., and C. M. James (1984a): “The Effect of Interest Rate Changes on the Common Stock Returns of Financial Institutions,” The Journal of Finance, 39(4), 1141–1153. Flannery, M. J., and C. M. James (1984b): “Market Evidence on the Effective Maturity of Bank Assets and Liabilities,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 16(4), 435–445. Gorton, G., and R. Rosen (1995): “Banks and derivatives,” NBER Working Paper Series, 5100. 29 Hicks, J. (1939): Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory. Clarendon Press, Oxford. Houpt, J. V., and J. A. Embersit (1991): “A Method for Evaluating Interest Rate Risk in US Commercial Banks,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, (August), 625–637. Jarrow, R. a., and D. R. van Deventer (1998): “The arbitrage-free valuation and hedging of demand deposits and credit card loans,” Journal of Banking & Finance, 22(3), 249–272. Kaufman, G. (1984): “Measuring and managing interest rate risk - A primer,” Economic Perspectives, 8, 16–29. Macaulay, F. (1938): Some Theoretical Problems Suggested by the Movements of Interest Rates, Bond Yields, and Stock Prices in the United States since 1856, NBER. Columbia University Press, New York. Nelson, C. R., and A. F. Siegel (1987): “Parsimonious modeling of yield curves,” Journal of Business, pp. 473–489. O’Brien, J. (2000): “Estimating the Value and Interest Rate Risk of Interest-Bearing Transactions Deposits,” FEDS Working Papers, (2000-53). Redington, F. (1952): “Review of the Principles of Life-Office Valuations,” Journal of the Institute of Actuaries, 78, 286–340. Samuelson, P. (1945): “The effect of interest rate increases on the banking system,” American Economic Review, 35(1), 16–27. Saunders, A., and P. Yourougou (1990): “Are Banks Special? The Separation of Banking from Commerce and Interest Rate Risk,” (42), 171–182. Sierra, G. E. (2009): “Can An Accounting-Based Duration Model Effectively Measure Interest Rate Sensitivity?,” Available at SSRN 1488884. Sierra, G. E., and T. J. Yeager (2004): “What Does the Federal Reserve ’ s Economic Value Model Tell Us About Interest Rate Risk at US Community Banks?,” 86(December), 45–60. Svensson, L. E. O. (1994): “Estimating and Interpreting Forward Interest Rates: Sweden 1992-1994,” IMF Working Papers 94/114, International Monetary Fund. Wright, D. M., and J. V. Houpt (1996): “An Analysis of Commercial Bank Exposure to Interest Rate Risk,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, 82(2), 115. 30