Merit pay - Conseil central de Lanaudière-CSN

advertisement
Merit pay
Examination of the proposal made by the
Standing Committee on Public Accounts of the
Parliament of Canada
Review of the theory, research and practice
March 2003
Merit pay
TABLE OF CONTENTS
1.
INTR0DUCTION..................................................................................... 1
2.
MERIT PAY: WHAT IS IT? ...................................................................... 1
3.
MERIT PAY: THEORY AND ORIGINS...................................................... 3
4.
CONSIDERATIONS IN IMPLEMENTING MERIT PAY .............................. 6
5.
PERFORMANCE .................................................................................... 12
6.
DETERMINING INCREASES IN PAY ..................................................... 15
7.
DISCUSSION........................................................................................ 18
8.
CONCLUSION....................................................................................... 20
BIBLIOGRAPHY ................................................................................... 21
i
Merit pay
1.
INTRODUCTION
At the recommendation of the Canadian Parliament’s Standing Committee on Public
Accounts, the Treasury Board Secretariat is asking for proposals for a feasibility study on the
implementation of a system of merit pay for unionized employees in the federal public service.
The Secretariat is also asking for information on the costs and potential benefits of such a
system. The terms of reference indicate that the study is to pay special attention to systems
based on individual appraisals.
In this context, we will focus on two aspects of merit pay. We begin by looking at what
merit pay is, and then analyse and comment on it, including a review of the literature.
2.
MERIT PAY: WHAT IS IT?
To answer this question, we consulted the findings of three U.S. experts recognized as
such in both academic and business circles: Robert L. Heneman, author of Merit Pay: Linking
Pay Increases to Performance Ratings, published by Addison-Wesley in 1992; and George T.
Milkovich and Jerry M. Newman, co-authors of Compensation, Seventh Edition, 2002, published
by McGraw-Hill Irwin.
Heneman defines merit pay in this way:
At a very specific level, merit pay can be defined as individual pay increases
based on the rated performance of individual employees in a previous time
period. Under this specific definition, salary increases are granted on the basis of
a subjective judgement of employee performance in a previous period of time.
(6)
Milkovich and Newman give the following definition:
Wage increase granted to employee as function of some assessment of
employee performance. Adds to base pay in subsequent years. (291)
Two features are common to both definitions: the individual nature of merit pay, and
performance ratings or assessment. These are the fundamental characteristics of this system of
pay. Widely used in the United States, merit pay is a form of compensation that dates back to
the early 20th century. In 1992, when Heneman’s book was published, he estimated that 80% of
companies in the United States used merit pay. He added that in the public sector, though,
1
Merit pay
Public sector employees tend to show less frequent use of merit pay plans. (8)
By 1989, merit pay was used by 37 of the 50 states, compared to only 27 out of 50 in
1975. Looking at governments, or overall public administrations, merit pay was used by 48%.
There seems to be a broad consensus among U.S. employers on the effectiveness of
merit pay. Designed to improve performance and control rising payroll costs, business surveys
indicate that it is perceived as effective. The widespread use made of it can also be seen as a
reflection of this perception. In the past 25 years, however, many studies have been done by
academics as well as by government agencies, such as the U.S. General Accounting Office, to
evaluate merit pay more rigorously. All this research tends to point to the same conclusions:
“success [in improving employee performance] is moderate,” according to Heneman, p. 10, or
again:
“does not achieve the designed goal: improving employee and corporate
performance.” (Bassett, Compensation and Benefit Review: March/April, 1994, in
Milkovich & Newman, 310)
In 1991, the U.S. government’s Office of Personnel Management mandated the
Committee on Performance Appraisal for Merit Pay, composed of academic experts and chaired
by Milkovich himself, to do a vast study to help the government review the merit pay system for
mid-level managers. It is worth citing what the experts’ committee had to say about the results
of using merit pay on performance (National Research Council, 1991):
Researchers in the applied tradition concentrate on the appraisal system and
how it functions to serve organizational ends. On the basis of the evidence in the
applied tradition, the committee presents two major findings.
There is some evidence that performance appraisals can motivate employees
when the supervision is trusted and perceived as knowledgeable by the
employee.
There is evidence from both laboratory and field studies to support the
assumption that the intended use of performance ratings influence results. The
most consistent finding is that ratings used to make decisions on pay and
promotion are more lenient than ratings used for research or feedback. (NRC, 3)
The committee added:
2
Merit pay
Our reviews of performance appraisal and merit pay research and practice
indicate that their success or failure is substantially influenced by the
organizational context in which they are embedded. (NRC, 4)
At first glance, it would seem that the use merit pay has limited impact on improving
performance, and that it is dependent on organizational considerations that can influence its
effectiveness.
3.
MERIT PAY: THEORY AND ORIGINS
This section looks at various aspects of merit pay. Generally speaking, this method uses
“standards” that are benchmarks for appraising an individual’s performance. Once this appraisal
is done, the individual receives an increase in pay, or perhaps an increase in the form of
benefits. The increase may be either a percentage or a flat amount. Finally, the increase may be
rolled into the employee’s basic pay, or paid as a lump sum that is not incorporated into the
basic rate of pay. So merit pay is flexible, multi-faceted and complicated to administer, as we
will see.
Merit pay is based on a certain number of theories taken from social sciences as well as
empirical research using observation and measurement of results obtained by organizations
using this method of remuneration, or illustrated by case studies. The theories are for the most
part borrowed from economics and psychology.
Briefly, the theory taken from psychology states that motivation and aptitude are the
fundamental determinants of performance:
Motivation and ability are the primary determinants of performance. (Heneman,
24)
This theory suggests using individuals’ expectations to motivate them with attractive
measures to which they attach value. For instance, using merit pay as a way to satisfy
expectations, an individual can be motivated by accurately measuring his/her performance.
Assuming that higher pay is an important objective for the individual, establishing a clear link
between pay and performance is a way of creating opportunities for that individual to improve
his/her performance. One could say that the organization relies on a “virtuous circle.”
3
Merit pay
Psychology also indicates that behaviour, including performance, is determined by its
consequences. In pay, this implies establishing a clear link (contingency) between behaviour and
reward, and to do so it is necessary for an organization to make clear what the desired
performance is and the fact that the value of raises in pay will depend on performance levels
achieved, while ensuring that an appropriate period of time is allowed for achieving the desired
performance. As well, psychology shows that it is necessary to take into account the relationship
between an individual and his/her co-workers, in part to ensure that the efforts required to
attain desired performance levels are fair – a perception that is very important in establishing
the method’s credibility. Finally, psychology contributes the idea that achieving goals is a source
of motivation in and of itself. In this respect, merit pay has to set specific goals that are
accepted by employees as challenges, and the amount of pay must then vary in accordance with
the level of difficulty associated with the goals and the results achieved. Moreover, the goals and
the raises in pay should be determined simultaneously so that the parameters at the outset are
clearly defined.
Economic theory contributes the notion of the marginal productivity of labour, which
measures the number of additional units of production that the addition of one labour unit
brings (a measure of economic performance), in light of additional costs incurred and ultimately
profitability. It is also the source of the theory of implicit contracts, summed up in the saying, “A
fair day’s pay for a fair day’s work,” which implies that performance must be measured and not
assumed (Heneman, 38). Merit pay must take into account factors that lie beyond individuals’
control and satisfy the “efficiency” criterion for pay rates that is generally founding the labour
market. This approach to pay allows an organization to reduce staff turnover and limit the
tendency to lax performance on the job.
In short, it is a method of pay based on people’s behaviour and designed to motivate
them. The whole method therefore relies on a combination of performance and reward,
meaning that very close attention must be paid to the notion of performance.
It would seem that the relationship between pay and performance is in fact solidly
established. Heneman identified 42 empirical studies on this question covering 31,081
individuals, 67.9% of whom came from professional, management or scientific circles. He
concludes:
4
Merit pay
In some 40 of 42 studies that looked at the relationship between pay and
performance in organizations with merit pay, there was a positive relationship
between current merit increase and previous performance. (Heneman, 47)
He adds:
The actual positive relationship between pay and performance appears to be
robust. (Heneman, 47)
He qualifies the term “robust,” however, by adding that:
The magnitude of the relationship between pay and performance in these
studies is not large. (Heneman, 48)
From this he concludes:
In summary, the perceived relationship between pay and performance under
merit plans appears to be moderate. (Heneman, 48)
Although these studies were reviewed and analysed ten years ago, they still provide
revealing empirical evidence of what this method can do. The conclusions cited above are still
just as relevant: the use of merit pay has a limited impact on employees’ performance. But this
does not mean that it is no longer of interest to organizations that favour this approach. For
according to Heneman, it is still true that:
The rationale behind merit pay is not the product of idle speculation. Instead,
the concept of linking pay to performance is well grounded in theories form
economics and psychology. Moreover, the tests of these theories, which have
been conducted through empirical research, have for the most part, been
supportive. In short, the rationale behind merit pay has been clearly established.
(Heneman, 58)
The theoretical considerations and the rationale for merit pay are convincing, according
to Heneman. What remains to be tested is its implementation in an organization. Ultimately,
results are rather modest, and the implementation phase is crucial, says Heneman, if the
method is to really achieve the organization’s objectives:
The entire merit pay process must be carefully managed for merit pay to have
the desired results. (Heneman, 58)
5
Merit pay
Based on their review of the literature, Milkovich and Newman conclude:
Although there are exceptions, generally linking pay to behaviors of employees
results in better individual and organizational performance. (Milkovich &
Newman, 292)
One of the influential critics of this idea of individual performance appraisal is Edward
Deming, the leading expert in continual improvement and total quality management. As
Milkovich et Newman report:
…[Deming] … launched an attack on appraisals because, he contended, the
work situation (not the individual) is the major determinant of performance. »
(Milkovich & Newman, 355)
4.
CONSIDERATIONS IN IMPLEMENTING MERIT PAY
In the discussion so far, we have seen which theories underpin merit pay and noted the
limits identified through empirical research. In his conclusion, Heneman warns practitioners
about the need to implement merit pay carefully in order to properly control the expected
results.
The first consideration is economic: merit pay must first be implemented during a period
of price stability.
Periods of either rising or declining product and services prices can make the
feasibility of merit pay difficult.» (Heneman, 64)
A period of price volatility can undermine the incentive value of merit pay, because it
makes it hard to properly adjust merit pay increases to variations in prices. Just think of what
would happen if the raises paid didn’t keep up with variations in prices.
The second consideration is the need to ensure that the organizational setting or
institution is in favour of merit pay. One of the findings clearly shows that the setting influences
the conditions of implementation:
6
Merit pay
… merit pay is used more frequently in the service sector than in the
manufacturing sector. (Heneman, 69)
Research indicates that this finding stems from the fact that it is easier to assess
performance in the service sector. At first glance, therefore, it might seem that the government
sector is well-suited to the introduction of merit pay. But the research points to the conclusion
that it is harder to introduce merit pay in the public service sector than in the private sector.
Perry (1976); Rainey (1979); Silverman (1983); and Scott, Hills, Markham, and
Vest (1986) describe some of the situational characteristics found more often in
the public sector than in the private sector, which limits the effectiveness of
merit pay plans. These constraints include among other things, limited merit pay
budgets, limited discretion on merit pay decisions, accountability to conflicting
constituencies and a long history of pay based on longevity rather than
performance.
These constraints, which have led to limited success of merit pay plans in the
public sector (Heneman, 70)
Howard Risher, a professor at the University of Pennsylvania’s Wharton School of
Business, examined the U.S. federal government’s experience with merit pay, and came to the
following conclusions:
Merit pay has been tried by many public employers including the federal
government. The track record is not a good one. In some public agencies,
attempts to introduce merit pay almost trigger an armed revolution. One of the
reasons that merit pay has not been accepted in government is that it has been
used as a reason to deny increases to poor performers. In contrast, in the
corporate world the emphasis is on recognizing and rewarding the better
performers with above average. (Risher, 334)
It is therefore very important to examine the institutional environment and the
organization’s objectives in introducing merit pay. Note as well that between 1979 and 1989,
merit pay only affected between 10% and 16% of unionized employees in the United States.
An employee’s degree of autonomy in his/her work is fundamental:
7
Merit pay
... an employee must be responsible for performing a whole piece of work. ...
a distinct start and finish to the service being generated by the employee, ... to
have a noticeable impact on performance. (Heneman, 81 and 82)
To this should be added the trust that prevails in the organization, and its human
resources management practices. In a very detailed table, Heneman lists the institutional
arrangements that make merit pay more or less feasible. (Table 3-2, p. 85)
Despite these reservations, if the government considers that it should proceed, there are
an impressive number of considerations, limitations and precautions that influence the feasibility
of merit pay.
8
Merit pay
Institutional Arrangements Contributing to the Feasibility of Merit Pay
Merit Pay More Feasible
Under these conditions
Service Sector
Private Sector
Middle stages of organizational life cycle
Flexible specialization technologies
Competitive culture
Non unionized
Moderate base rate
Well-defined job characteristics
High discretion in work performed
Low politics
Merit Pay Less Feasible
Under these conditions
Manufacturing Sector
Public Sector
Early or late stages or organizational life cycle
Mass production technologies
Egalitarian culture
Unionized
High or low base rate
Poorly defined job characteristics
Low discretion in work performed
High politics
When the federal government is considered in light of the institutional arrangements
favouring the introduction of merit pay, it is clear that most of the conditions are absent. Of
course part of government’s mission involves by definition the delivery of services comparable to
the private sector’s. However the role of many departments, including some of the most
important, is to redistribute national revenue: this is the case with Finance, or Human Resources
Development Canada, which administers transfer payments to the provinces and pays benefits
to individuals (Old Age Security, Employment Insurance). Other departments offer consulting
services or grant programmes for individuals or business (research), and yet others are control
or collection agencies or departments (revenue, customs, public security). In short, government
is a complex organization with numerous activities and ultimate purposes. It is virtually
impossible to find as large an organization in the private service sector. Furthermore, the federal
government is organizationally mature, its operations regulated by standards and fundamentally
subject to the authority of parliament. The government’s organizational culture refers to
egalitarian standards, because “opportunities” are governed by the concept of merit, and pay
progression is generally the same throughout the country, depending in many cases on the
length of service. The performance of work is, at first glance, hierarchical and clearly supervised.
Many jobs offer little discretion in the performance of the work, and little room for initiative and
autonomy. For a number of reasons (staffing, regional equity, nature of duties, specialization,
unionization), pay levels, especially basic pay levels, are certainly higher than in many
9
Merit pay
organizations or businesses in the private service sector. All this indicates that merit pay is not
an obvious solution. And in fact, the National Research Council’s work in the United States
(1991) found that merit pay in the federal government was
... a matter of continuing controversy and periodic amendment.
(NRC, 160)
There are many reasons for this. But noting that merit pay was developed by private
sector organizations, the NRC considered that there was a problem related to the very nature of
merit pay and organizational differences between the private sector and the federal government.
The federal government faces special, if not entirely intractable, problems that
work against any easy transferability of private-sector experience. (NRC, 160)
The NRC added:
Where private-sector practice relatively easily accepts manager-employee
exchanges about performance objectives, both individual and organizational,
such a practice in the public sector could be perceived as opening the civil
service to partisan manipulation. (NRC, 161)
In the opinion of NRC’s research team, merit pay in the private sector is more successful
in what it called “high-commitment organizations” (161), where the following conditions make
appreciable results possible:
± merit pay is an integral part of a comprehensive management system; it is not an
add-on, but a systemic component that underpins and complements the
organization’s management philosophy;
± there is an emphasis on the need for managers to be discrete and flexible in fulfilling
their responsibilities;
± the organization and its employees share common values, and there is a high level of
trust;
10
Merit pay
± the standards for success are valued by the organization as a whole as well as by the
individuals in it;
± and finally, the turnover in management is low.
It is not at all obvious that these conditions are met in the federal government’s
administration. More could be said, but on the face of it, the values of public managers and of
government itself are not all that close to those of the private sector, where competitive values
in particular are a motivation for many employees and clearly favor the implementation of merit
pay. Moreover, can such a value be introduced in the public sector without introducing
dangerous trends such as discrimination among employees, or individual conduct influenced by
the lure of power and personal gain that is incompatible with the mission of a public
administration? It’s very risky.
To return to the evaluation of merit pay in the U.S. federal government, the internal
assessment by managers raised a paradox that is worth noting:
... a study by Clark et Wachtel (1988) ... In this study of 4,000 federal managers
90 percent favored the concept of merit pay; however, 74 percent felt that the
current system was unfair. (Heneman, 88)
This section suggests that the introduction of merit pay, particularly in the public sector,
is not obvious. The U.S. experience in this regard shows that at root, the concept itself,
stemming from the competitive environment and management philosophy of the private sector,
and more especially the U.S. private sector, does not correspond to the characteristics of the
public sector. Hence the need for costly adjustments, failing which the consequences are
unintended adverse effects on employee motivation, their perception of the fairness of merit pay
and their trust in it.
We will come back to some of these points in our conclusion.
11
Merit pay
5.
PERFORMANCE
In this section, we will look more specifically at the central concept in merit pay, namely
performance and the performance appraisal process.
The definition of performance can vary from one organization to another. There are,
however, some points in common: it is focused on the individual, and is related to certain
characteristic roles and duties deemed essential by management in the organization. So from
one organization to the next, there are similarities and differences. It is generally defined in
terms of standards that vouch for its measurement. The textbooks call these:
-
absolute standards:
1) expected and actual outcomes;
2) individual personality traits;
3) behaviour, i.e., the way in which a person performs his/her work and duties.
These are so to speak the general standards valued by the organization.
-
comparisons:
1) ranking an employee in relation to the one who has contributed most to the
organization;
2) in smaller organizations, an employee is frequently ranked in relation to each of
the other employees.
We can anticipate that there will already be a certain amount of subjectivity in the
standards selected, which the research tries to control for. For instance, it seems that it is
possible to reduce subjectivity by linking the standards to an employee’s job description or the
strategic corporate mission, or by using feedback techniques to better define and delimit the
standards.
Furthermore, since the standards are used by an individual to assess an employee’s
performance, there is again a substantial margin of subjectivity.
12
Merit pay
According to specialists like Heneman, Milkovich and others, the advocates of merit pay
have to make sure that the measurement of performance and performance appraisal meets
criteria that make it less subjective. For instance, these authors recommend:
-
that performance should measure properly what is wanted, that there must not be
confusion about the source of merit pay (such as giving both a promotion and raise
in pay at the same time, or making partial use of seniority as a criterion for
determining a raise, or using merit pay to retain high-performing employees, or
trying to “reward” “standard” performance rather than the best performance);
-
that to allow adequate assessment, the content of performance be clearly defined,
notably with respect to the relation between the job and the standards;
-
that appraisals be consistent over time;
-
that appraisals be accurate, i.e., that the outcome of the appraisal be fairly related to
performance;
-
that appraisal errors such as the following be minimized:
.
the halo effect:
when the appraiser tends to rate someone highly
because of the predominance of a specific characteristic
that the appraiser favours;
.
the horn effect:
the opposite of the halo effect;
.
first impressions:
when the appraiser develops an opinion at the very
start of the process that affects the results of other
subjects evaluated subsequently.
There are other biases to be avoided as well, such as appraisals focussing on performance
results towards the end of the period instead of performance over the entire period; mistakes
due to being very strict or very lenient, or dropping both extremes; and the danger of repeating
previous mistakes in the annual appraisal.
As we can see, appraisal is subject to numerous biases. The impact of these biases has
been examined, and Heneman did a statistical estimate of their impact on the validity of
assessments:
Even though different methodologies were used, the results were very similar
and suggest that the upper bound of validity performance ratings is about .60,
with a value of 0 representing no validity and a value of 1.00 representing
perfect validity. What this value of .60 indicates is that about 36% of the
13
Merit pay
variability in the indicators being used to assess validity is due to performance
ratings.
... it suggests that about 64 percent of the variability in standards being used to
assess validity are due to factors other than performance ratings.
Therefore,
most measures of performance are less than perfect representation of the
employee’s ultimate performance contribution to organization. (Heneman, 131,
132)
To control variability in results, both Heneman and Milkovich and Newman suggest ways
of improving their reliability. Some of these have already been mentioned here:
-
rigorous, exact definitions of standards – ones that do not lend themselves to overinterpretation, that are clearly related to performance, to the organization’s mission
and to the duties set out in job descriptions;
-
employee involvement in the process;
-
training for appraisers aimed at achieving a more uniform understanding and
application of the appraisal system;
-
an appraiser’s “diary” for noting the evolution of the assessed employee’s
performance as it happens;
-
developing appraisers’ skills, improving their abilities and accountability;
-
establishing guidelines for appraisals;
-
offering employees an opportunity to understand and influence decisions stemming
from the appraisal.
All these suggestions are demanding, in that an organization using merit pay has to have
the resources required to try to guarantee the process an acceptable level of credibility.
6.
DETERMINING INCREASES IN PAY
Once the process is established and the appraisal done, its credibility in the eyes of
employees will, despite all the precautions taken, depend partly on the resulting increases in
pay. This raises the whole question of determining the size of total payroll that the company or
14
Merit pay
government considers appropriate for the company or government, as the case may be, given
the economic and financial constraints underlying any pay policy.
Merit pay specialists consider that to produce results and be accepted by employees, the
system requires the creation of something they call “Just-Noticeable Differences” (JND):
The concept of “Just-Noticeable Differences” refers to the minimum pay increase
that employees would perceive as making a difference with regard to their
attitudes and behaviours. (Heneman & Ellis, 1982, p. 149)
The “minimum” aspect of the pay increase is important, because:
If merit increases are not large enough to have a JND, they may not produce
increases in future performance. (Heneman, 158)
This refers back to concepts borrowed from psychology that we examined earlier.
Defining a difference that is perceived by the employee as sufficient motivation to improve
his/her performance creates a serious problem for the distribution of the pay budget, if only
because of variations in individuals’ perceptions of what the “Just-Noticeable Differences” should
be.
Generally speaking, once the performance appraisals are completed, the distribution of
the pay budget is determined by applying a chart of pay increases based on performance levels.
Note that in the two examples given here, there is no pay scale per se. This does not mean that
such a scale is not used in the organization. There are usually minimum and maximum rates of
pay that are used as guidelines for compensation, and there may also be a median salary, as in
this illustration:
15
Merit pay
-
maximum
$50,000
-
median
$45,000
-
minimum
$40,000
From here, pay is adjusted on the basis of the chart of increases.
INCREASES CHART
Example 1 (Milkovich, Newman)
Level
1
2
3
4
5
Performance
Exceptional
Very
Satisfactory
Somewhat
Unsatisfactory
satisfactory
Increase
7%
unsatisfactory
6%/5%
3%/4%
1%/2%
0%
Example 2
The chart in this example is more complex. It first ranks employees into groups – quartiles, in
this case – based on the quantified results of their appraisal, or on an employee classification
system. It also takes into account the performance level achieved by employees in each quartile.
So an employee could be classified in the second quartile and receive an individual performance
rating of “fully satisfactory,” while another employee in the same quartile might be rated as
“needs improvement.” Finally, the chart indicates the frequency of performance appraisals. For
instance, an employee classified in the second quartile who obtains a performance rating of
“fully satisfactory” will be reassessed between 15 and 18 months after the first appraisal. An
employee may also move from one quartile to another, usually on an annual basis. This chart is
taken from Heneman (174).
16
Merit pay
Complex Merit Guide Chart (Table 5.5)
Performance Levels
Position
in range
Unsatisfactory
(Quartile)
4th
rd
3
nd
2
st
1
0%
0%
0%
0%
Needs
Fully
Above
Clearly
Improvement Satisfactory Expectations Outstanding
0%
3-5%
5-7%
7-9%
15-18 M
12-15 M
9-12 M
0-3%
5-7%
7-9%
9-11%
15-18 M
12-15 M
9-12 M
9-12 M
0-3%
7-9%
9-11%
11-13%
12-15M
9-12 M
9-12 M
6-9 M
0-15%
9-11%
11-13%
13-15%
9-12M
9-12 M
6-9 M
6-9 M
M = Months
This chart has four dimensions. First, employees are placed in a quartile, which generally
corresponds to job duties and responsibilities – it’s more or less a classification “system.” Next,
performance is rated at one of five levels. Once this is done, the rate of increase leaves the
employer some discretionary leeway: for instance, an employee in the second quartile who
obtains a “fully satisfactory” performance rating would receive an increase ranging from 7% to
9%, meaning that a number of employees in the same classification (quartile) with the same
rating could receive different increases. Finally, to complete the system, the length of time
before the next appraisal date varies, depending on the classification (quartile) and performance
level achieved.
Before concluding this section, note that these charts are applied in a framework of
controlling the payroll, which may entail periodic changes in the parameters used to determine
total annual payroll increases so as to reflect the financial situation of the business or
organization. Another way of controlling the total payroll would be to pay the amounts resulting
from the application of such charts without including them in basic pay.
7.
DISCUSSION
17
Merit pay
The theory and teaching presented in textbooks and the research literature clearly
indicate that merit pay is complex and demands a series of precautions to ensure that it works
and produces the main desired result, i.e., that it encourages employees to constantly improve
their performance on the job. Although we have reviewed all that has been written on merit pay
in the United States, given the intensive and extensive use made of it there, it is still relevant to
examine it in relation to public and private organizations in Canada. Anyway, the research is
repeated in Canadian publications.
The reference paper prepared by the Treasury Board Secretariat doesn’t make clear what
the Standing Committee on Public Accounts’ fundamental objective is. What does this
recommendation seek to do?
We have already seen that specialists who have studied merit pay at length have pointed
out that an organization must have a clear goal, and that in most private-sector businesses, this
goal is to recognize and “reward” the best employees, the ones whose performance is superior.
An examination of the situation in the public sector in the United States shows that in practice,
this objective is not achieved, notably because of the institutional framework. What is more, one
of the conclusions reached by the Experts’ Committee of the National Research Council at the
end of its study was that:
In order to motivate employees and provide them incentives to perform, a merit
plan or any pay-for-performance plan must theoretically (a) define and
communicate performance goals that employees understand and view as doable;
(b) consistently link pay and performance; and (c) provide payouts that
employees see as meaningful. These conditions seem straightforward, and the
notion of pay performance thus becomes deceptively simple. Our reviews of
research and practice indicate, however, that selecting the best pay-forperformance plan and implementing it in an organizational context so that these
conditions are met is currently as much an art as a science. We cannot
generalize about which pay-for-performance plans work best – especially for the
federal government, with its considerable organizational and workforce diversity.
(NRC, 165)
Considering, on the one hand, that conditions of pay for employees in the federal public
service are governed by collective agreements, and that on the other hand, the diversity of
federal government activities is far greater than that of even the largest companies in the
private sector, the conclusions of the NRC experts provide a very serious warning about the
feasibility of such a proposal.
18
Merit pay
In this paper, we have looked at the multiple facets, the difficulties in implementation
and the precautions to be taken to minimize mistakes in both the design and application of merit
pay.
These are some of the important points to be considered:
a) Merit pay individualizes pay increase and pay levels for the same or comparable jobs
– something that does not correspond to the values of equality and fairness
promoted by unions.
b) It is a pay method that is not based primarily on workers’ concerns, namely
protecting their purchasing power, pay equity and general increases in levels of pay.
c) It is a method of pay that is ill-suited to the realities observed in workplaces – for
example, how is performance defined in workplaces that are governed by standards
set by all kinds of legislation and regulations, such as correctional services, or food
inspection, or customs? In these types of work, employees’ initiative is limited and
government objectives are prescribed by law, making the situation very different
from what exists in the private sector.
d) The administration of merit pay in such a huge organization would require
considerable efforts and strict controls. The employer would have to take steps to
avoid bungling, take into account very different diverse situations and do its best to
achieve a certain degree of homogeneity and consistency in the decisions made by
thousands of managers in order to ensure the reliability of merit pay. All of this with
the goal of trying to get employees to see merit pay in a positive light and maintain
an acceptable level of trust. The task is demanding, and indeed hard to accomplish.
In this regard, here is what Brown has to say (1990):
For incentive pay, they are the costs of measuring output and setting up
(and updating) the relationship between prices and pay. For merit pay, there
are the costs of obtaining sufficiently careful ratings from supervisors and of
convincing workers that these ratings should be taken seriously. (180-5)
19
Merit pay
CONCLUSION
Merit pay is not at all consistent with union principles, which are based on equal
treatment, an open, transparent pay system and pay increases determined in accordance with
workers’ needs, i.e., to preserve and improve their purchasing power. Tying pay solely to
individual performance, as recommended by the experts in designing and implementing an
effective merit system, introduces a significant risk for both outcomes and for the treatment
required to administer the system. Pay increases would vary from one period to another, and in
an organization whose labour force is largely unionized, it could expected that this would rapidly
cause dissatisfaction and even resentment. Information circulates in a union organization; in
fact, a union has a duty to spread and share information, because it is absolutely crucial to
decision-making, especially during collective bargaining.
Such a system would certainly result in differences in pay within our union. There are 51
penitentiaries across Canada, and more than 5,500 members in our union. There would be
hundreds of supervisors doing performance appraisals, and given the difficulties inherent in
administering this system, we would most certainly be swamped with demands for reviews of
appraisals. Apart from such “procedural” considerations, we have already pointed out a
workplace regulated by standards as strict as those in correctional services does not lend itself
to the implementation of merit pay.
The review of the literature, the evaluation of the experts whose work we
consulted and the National Research Council’s conclusions regarding the experience in the U.S.
federal public service all lead us to conclude that we cannot agree to modifications or changes in
the principles and practices that now govern the pay structure in the federal public service.
From its earliest days, the labour movement has never wavered from a
fundamental principle on pay that has served workers well: to keep wages out of competition.
Merit pay introduces a factor of competition among workers within a given company or
organization that is inevitably harmful to collective interests and solidarity.
Claude Rioux
Economist
for the Confédération des syndicats nationaux
Document discussed and adopted by the UCCOO-SACC-CSN National Committee
20
Merit pay
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Heneman, Robert L. (1992), Merit Pay Linking Pay Increases to Performance Ratings, AddisonWesley, 298 p.
Milkovich, George T. and Newman, Jerry M. (2002), Compensation, Seventh Edition, McGraw Hill
Irwin, 682 p.
National Research Council (1991) Pay for Performance: Evaluating Performance Appraisal and
Merit Pay, National Academy Press, 210 p.
Ehrenberg, Ronald G. (1990) “Do Compensation Policies Matter?” Industrial Labor Relations
Review, Vol. 43, Special Issue. pp. 3-5 to 12-5
Brown, Charles (1990), “Firms’ Choice of Method of Pay” Industrial Labor Relations Review, Vol.
43, Special Issue. pp. 165-5
Schwab, Donald P. and Craig A. Olson, “Merit Pay Practices: Implications of Pay-Performance
Relationship” Industrial Labor Relations Review, Vol. 43, Special Issue, p. 237-5
Institut de recherche sur la rémunération (1996), Rémunération variable. Description et
tendances, Vol. 1, Québec
Risher, Howard (1999), “Are Public Employers Ready for a “New Pay’’ Program?” Public
Personnel Management, Vol. 28, No. 3, p. 323
Thériault, Roland and Saint-Onge, Sylvie (2000), Gestion de la rémunération. Théorie et
pratique, Gaétan Morin, 780 p.
21
Download