THE ADVANCED DIPLOMA IN INTERNATIONAL TAXATION June 2014 PAPER IIF – AUSTRALIA OPTION ADVANCED INTERNATIONAL TAXATION Suggested Solutions Question 1 This question calls from some discussion regarding the twin concepts of residence and source and in particular whether any relevant case law examples in Australia might serve to assist in understanding these concepts and the extent to which they are appropriate as jurisdictional nexus rules in both the case of developed and less-developed economies. In the case of modern developed economies consideration should be given to the meaning of residence and source and some explanation of these concepts in the Australian context would be appropriate. This would include some discussion of residency rules for individuals and those applying to companies. For individuals Australia adopts four alternatives for treating a person as a resident namely Common law residency rules; Domicile (but subject to certain qualifications); Presence in that jurisdiction for more than one half of any given year of income (but subject to certain qualifications); Specific tests dealing with Commonwealth public servants. For companies a company will be treated as a resident of Australia if It is incorporated in Australia; It has its central management and control in Australia and carries on business in Australia; It has its voting power controlled by Australian residents and carries on business in Australia. Looking at these Australian definitions some commentary should be provided around the appropriateness of such tests in a modern developed economy where transactions frequently occur through electronic commerce and thus the place where a company is incorporated can be utterly meaningless. For example, a company incorporated in Vanuatu could quite readily transact extensively in Australia without triggering the central management and control test since all directors meetings and any other meetings that might be relevant could be held offshore effectively in cyberspace. For individuals the tests appear to be particularly arcane based largely around domicile and presence in Australia and again much can be done in Australia without the necessity to be physically present here. These observations suggest that existing concepts of residency and source are particularly illequipped to deal with taxation issues arising in developed economies. In relation to less-developed economies these countries are usually more concerned with source issues than residence, as they seek to demonstrate that more and more income is sourced in the jurisdiction since in many cases extractive processes are being adopted to remove commodities from such countries without triggering residency in that country. The emphasis in these countries would inevitably be in relation to the source rules and requires detailed analysis of what might trigger a source in the local jurisdiction. Although not cases as such, the recent publicity attaching to companies such as Google and Microsoft and their international structures are in many cases underpinned by ensuring that the relevant residency rules in a number of countries are not triggered and that source is maintained outside high tax jurisdictions. There are a number of recent Australian residency decisions that highlight problems for individuals including re Murray v FCT (2013) AATA 780 and re Bezuidenhout v FCT (2012) AATA 799 where certain factual matters that do not always appear to be relevant from a policy perspective seemed to carry significant weight in determining the residency issue. The Page 2 of 12 subtleties of factual differences would suggest that the residency rules are not working in a clear-cut definitive way at least not in the Australian context. The source rules in Australia remain broadly common law based and the case law has grappled with the question of source of income over many years including a recent decision re Crown Insurance Services Ltd v FCT 2011 85 ATR 905 where income was held to be foreign sourced. In that case two Vanuatu based companies entered into contracts with Australian member country companies who provided funeral benefits on the death of Australian residents. The connections with Australia seemed to be substantial but the Tribunal at first instance nonetheless found, based on relatively old principles, that the income in question was nonetheless foreign sourced. On appeal to the full Federal Court the matter was dismissed on the basis that the appeal did not raise a question of law although there was one significant dissent in the full Federal court by Jessup J who concluded that the income in question was indirectly derived from an Australian source and would be taxable as such. Again this case in particular demonstrates the uncertain manner in which the source rules operate in Australia and is perhaps an argument which could be used to endorse more blackand-white definitive rules that might give greater clarity to both taxpayers and tax administrations alike. Question 2 This question calls for a consideration of withholding tax and how it operates in Australia. To answer it properly students would need to first explain how withholding tax operates in Australia and then consider whether that manner of operation confirms or contradicts the quote. Students should point out that essentially withholding tax in Australia applies to interest, unfranked dividends and royalties. Franked dividends while technically subject to withholding tax, incur a withholding tax rate of zero on the basis that the franking of the dividend has meant that adequate Australian tax has already been paid in relation to the money that the dividend represents. The standard withholding rates in Australia are 10% for interest, 30% for unfranked dividends and 30% for royalties but these rates can be reduced to as low as zero in some cases for interest and unfranked dividends and to 5% in the case of royalties if an appropriate double taxation agreement is operative. This might include, for example, double taxation agreements which Australia has with countries such as the United Kingdom and the United States. Students should construct examples of each highlighting the net amount that is paid out to the foreign jurisdiction and in particular emphasise the fact that a failure to withhold will give rise to detrimental consequences to the payer of the interest, dividend or royalty even though they are not strictly the legally obligated party. This leads directly to the quote which suggests that withholding tax is an absurd creation since it simply increases the cost to the payer of amounts such as interest, dividends and royalties. Whether this is true or not will depend,in the case of interest and royalties, on the economic bargaining power of the parties to the transaction that has given rise to the flow of interest and royalties. If the foreign party has the superior bargaining power it will use its leverage to ensure that any tax which is extracted by Australia would be grossed up such that in net terms the foreigner is not in a position that would be any worse than if no withholding tax had applied in Australia. In other words, the withholding tax cost in such cases would be absorbed by the payer rather than the payee of the interest or royalties. If, on the other hand, the bargaining power sits with the Australian payer it will be able to shift the tax liability to the foreigner by ensuring that there is no gross-up or adjustment to reflect Australian withholding tax. Thus, the quote needs to be refined in order to take into account the bargaining power of the respective parties. The situation with dividends will probably depend on whether the company is a private or public company. Private company dividends would usually be subject to the same bargaining power issues as referred to above in the context of interest and royalties. In the public Page 3 of 12 company context the company paying the dividend will determine the size of any unfranked dividend and is unlikely to be swayed by issues concerning the pre and post-tax positions of its shareholders. The quote also refers to there being no advantage to Australia and in fact is quite damaging to the economy as a whole. This would again only be true if the cost is effectively being shifted although if the cost is not being shifted and is effectively borne by the foreigner it will increase the cost to the foreigner doing business in Australia and this in its own way may be quite damaging to the economy as a whole as it may discourage the foreigner from returning to make investments here. Thus, the appropriate comment to conclude with would appear to be that the quote can only be correct with certain qualifications. Thus, the quote should to take into account the relative bargaining positions of the parties to the transactions that create the flow of interest, private company dividends or royalties. The quote is accurate to the extent that the costs are passed back to the Australian payer and they are only partially accurate if they are not so passed back since if they are not passed back they are absorbed by the foreigner and the foreigner may then be less inclined to trade with Australia as there is an additional cost in the form of the withholding tax and this in and of itself may be quite damaging to the economy as a whole. Question 3 The first point to make in relation to this question is that HK Co is presumed to be not resident in Australia. However, this assumption needs to be more fully tested since although it is incorporated in Hong Kong, three of its five directors are resident in Australia. This may well suggest that HK Co is a resident of Australia based on its central management and control here. However this would also lead to the question of whether it carries on business in Australia and looking at the classes of income which it has disclosed, this looks unlikely. Merely purchasing goods from Australian resident associates is unlikely to trigger a conclusion that HK Co carries on business here. Accordingly, it would be reasonable to conclude that HK CO is not resident in Australia. As such, it would not be subject to tax in Australia on any of its income unless that income was sourced in Australia or it derived capital gains which arose from the disposal of taxable Australian real property(TARP). Neither of those things appear to arise on the facts as presented. As a result HK Co cannot be exposed to tax in Australia in its own right. However, a question arises as to whether HK Co is a Controlled Foreign Company as far as Australia is concerned since if it is, the passive income, tainted sales income and tainted services income of HK Co might be subject to tax in Australia under Part X of the Income Tax Assessment Act 1936. In considering this issue, it is noticeable that Aust CO is the owner of only 43% of the shares in HK Co which means that it is not a CFC based on the primary test for determining whether a CFC exists which requires at least 50%. It may however be nonetheless a CFC based on the other two tests, the first of which requires only 40% in circumstances where the remaining 60% are widely held such that no one else appears to control HK Co. Based on the limited information we have been given that appears to be a strong likelihood. It should also be noted that the 9% call option will be taken into account as being Aust Co’s on the basis that you look at not only the shareholding which it holds but the shareholding Page 4 of 12 which it is entitled to acquire. This would take Aust CO to 52% and accordingly HK Co would be a CFC on the basis of the first primary test anyway. It should also be noted by students that the put option arrangement will have no effect because Aust Co is a seller of the put option and as such it will be under an obligation to take those shares if they are put to it but it has no rights under this put option arrangement. The provisions dealing with entitlements only refer to entitlements to acquire and does not refer to obligations to take. In any event it would seem that HK Co either on the basis of the primary CFC test or the secondary CFC test will be treated as a CFC. Having reached that decision one the needs to analyse Part X to determine the extent to which the income of HK Co might be subject to attribution under section 456. In this context, the first point to note is that HK Co is a company resident in an unlisted country for the purposes of section 333. As such its notional assessable income includes passive income, tainted sales income and tainted services income. The first item being business income would be tainted sales income under section 447 (1)(a) since the goods in question are sold to HKCo by an Australian associate of the company. The capital gain on the sale of the shares in the Hong Kong subsidiary would be treated as passive income under section 446 (1) (k) since the disposal would be the disposal of the tainted asset being shares in a company (see the definition of tainted asset in section 317(1)). The management fees would not be treated as tainted services income since they are not fees received from a Part X Australian resident at the time that the income was derived. The dividend income would be treated as passive income as a result of section 446 (1)(a) and would not be removed from being included in assessable income by any of sections 402,403 or 404. It would be exempt through the operation of 23AJ via the application of Australian law on the basis HK Co is assumed to be a resident. Thus, it would seem that of the total revenue of $400,000 generated within HKCo, only the management fees are excluded as attributable income for the purposes of section 456. That is $300,000 of the $400,000 is to be taxed in the hands of Aust CO but with a foreign income tax offset arising in respect of any tax that might be paid in Hong Kong or Singapore (see especially s 770 – 135 (2) where a foreign tax offset can arise in respect of foreign income tax and withholding tax paid by a foreign company where an amount is attributable to the attributable taxpayer – ie Aust Co in this case - under the CFC measures. In making this calculation students should point out that some assessment should also be made as to whether the company has passed or failed the active income test see especially section 432. For the purposes of the above we have assumed that the tests being would be failed having regard to the significant amounts of passive and tainted income It should also be pointed out that these rules apply in relation to the year ended 30 June 2011. The government had previously indicated that the rules will change quite significantly but more recently these plans appear to have been abandoned. Students might also mention the repeal of the Foreign Investment Fund rules such that they would not be applicable in the year in question. Furthermore, the proposed substitute the Foreign Accumulation Fund (or FAF) rule has not been implemented. In any event if the CFC rules apply in the manner indicated above, neither the repealed FIF rules nor the proposed FAF rules are likely to have had any impact whatsoever. Question 4 This question requires the student to explain each of the six terms referred to in plain English without the use of jargon. It also requires the students to explain the relevance of each of these terms to transfer pricing and to explain what transfer pricing is likely to involve in the Page 5 of 12 context of an Australian company with subsidiaries in New Zealand Hong Kong and Singapore. Thus some of the following comments would be pertinent. What is transfer pricing and how is it relevant to you? Transfer pricing is an area of the law which deals with the way in which prices are set where related parties resident in different tax jurisdictions are dealing with one another in relation to goods or services which one party provides to another. This could be particularly relevant to your circumstances since the Australian head company will be dealing potentially with each of its three subsidiaries in New Zealand, Hong Kong and Singapore. Thus, if the Australian company were to provide services to any or all of those three subsidiaries, a question would arise as to how the price for those services was struck. This is particularly relevant because Australia is seen to be a high tax jurisdiction particularly in comparison to Hong Kong and Singapore and thus care needs to be taken to ensure that profits are not being shifted out of Australia into Hong Kong and Singapore where the tax rates are lower. This could be achieved by the Australian company providing services to the Hong Kong and Singapore subsidiaries for less than the true proper price which should be attached to the provision of such services. Such activity could apply equally in relation to goods where Australia might transfer goods to its subsidiaries particularly in Hong Kong and Singapore for less than what might be considered to be the true proper price. New Zealand is not excluded from this although the circumstances would have to be somewhat different since New Zealand’s headline tax rate is not all that different to Australia’s in most instances. This is not suggest that all transactions will attract the application of transfer pricing rules but care needs to be taken to ensure that any pricing is properly documented and justified. Internationally transfer pricing rules and regulations have been developed and as part of those a number of methods for determining the appropriate price to charge between related parties have been established. While there are a number of different acceptable methods, two of them are the comparable uncontrolled price and transactional net margin method. In Australia these rules are now covered in Division 815 of the 1997 Income Tax Assessment Act which is very expansive in its view of transactions which can be covered by Transfer Pricing. Business restructurings in particular appear to be more broadly covered by the Australian TP rules than would seem to be the case in other comparable jurisdictions. What is the comparable uncontrolled price? The comparable uncontrolled price is the price that would be charged by parties in a comparable transaction in the same or similar circumstances to the circumstances that are being tested. Thus, if we are asking about goods that are being transferred from the Australian company to the Singapore subsidiary, we would look for a comparable transaction between parties who are not related in relation to the same or similar product in the same or similar circumstances (but obviously not including the circumstances that the parties are related). This might be a sale of the goods from the Australian company to a foreign company to which the Australian company is not related (referred to as an internal comparable) or it might be a sale of goods from another Australian company to a foreign entity (referred to as an external comparable) in the same or similar circumstances (but again where one of those circumstances is not that the parties are related). If there is a significant difference in the price such that in the comparable transaction a much higher price is charged, the Australian revenue would have substantial support for an adjustment to be made to increase the price charged by the Australian company and thereby to increase the amount of tax that would be paid in Australia by the Australian company. This methodology is not without its problems – the main difficulty being identifying comparable transactions as it is not always easy to establish the same or similar circumstances Page 6 of 12 particularly in international arrangements where circumstances are almost always different in some respects. The question is whether the difference is so substantial as to defeat comparability such that it can no longer be described as a comparable uncontrolled price. What is the Transactional Net Margin Method? This is an alternative to the comparable uncontrolled price and looks not so much to the price charged in relation to a particular transaction but to the overall net margin achieved on a category of products. Thus, following the example above, the transactional net margin method would look less to the exact price charged and more to the percentage margin achieved by the Australian company from the transactions relating to the goods sold to its Singapore subsidiary. Again this calls for some comparability because we would be comparing the net margin achieved by this company with net margins achieved by others in the same or similar circumstances. It would be fair to say that the degree of comparability required in this context would not be as onerous as that which would apply in the context of comparable Uncontrolled pricing. Thus, if the net margin achieved by this company was in the order of 2.5% overall profit, but comparable transactions have achieved 6%, the Australian revenue would again have substantial ammunition to make an adjustment to increase the net margin achieved by the Australian company in the circumstances. Of course, some explanation may be offered for why there is such a large discrepancy and in certain circumstances this would be taken into account and may even constitute a full explanation. What is functional analysis? As part of the process of establishing the proper price to be charged between the related entities (e.g. the Australian and Singapore companies), independent parties will often undertake a functional analysis. This essentially means that they determine in relation to a specific transaction, or series of transactions, what the parties to those transactions have done in the sense of what assets have been utilised in relation to that transaction, what functions have been performed by each of the parties and what risks have been assumed or undertaken by each of the parties. By separately identifying and then evaluating the functions, assets and risks associated with the transaction, or series of transactions, an independent party is then in a position to better evaluate the contribution which each party has made and accordingly the price that should be struck in relation to those transactions or the profit that should be earned. Such a functional analysis is normally conducted by an independent third party adviser such as the advisory accounting firm but there is no reason why such a functional analysis cannot be conducted internally by the group provided that realistic assumptions are made about the functions, assets and risks that are being contributed/adopted by the various parties. To give one example, an Australian company may be a manufacturer utilising significant patents in its manufacturing process. That might well give rise to a circumstance where the Australian company will need to be compensated for the use of those patents as part of the price which is struck between it and its Singapore subsidiary. If on the other hand the patents were owned by the Singapore company but were being used by the Australian company under some type of licensing arrangement where no fee was being charged by the Singapore company for that licensing arrangement, that circumstance would tend to suggest that a higher allocation should be made towards the Singapore company to provide it with an adequate return since the functional analysis suggests that the Singapore company is contributing more in the way of intellectual property. A further and different example is that if all insurance risk sits with the Australian company that is an aspect of the functional analysis which would suggest that the Australian company needs to secure a larger return since it is taking greater risks. Page 7 of 12 Obviously once the functions, assets and risks have been identified allocating numbers will be a challenge but it will be based on principles of comparability. What is a Cost Contribution Agreement? In order to circumvent the likelihood of any challenge to the pricing established between related parties it would be possible and in fact in many cases desirable for the group to establish a cost contribution agreement whereby in relation to certain aspects of the group’s activities each member of the group contributes to the cost of the development of, for example, assets which are owned by the group and are to be available for the benefit of all group members. In this way the argument relating to transfer pricing that might be brought by a revenue authority at some stage down the track is effectively negated because the parties have agreed in advance to a formula for contributing to costs. Effectively this is pre-empting any transfer pricing argument by effectively allocating costs in advance to different companies within the overall group. Care needs to be taken here as a CCA would need to meet many threshold tests before it was accepted by for example the Australian Taxation Office. In fact this could entail almost as much work as a full blown functional analysis in order to demonstrate that the cost allocations are appropriate. Nonetheless, the existence of such a CCA will be helpful as a starting point and if well founded with good supporting documentation can go much further in satisfying the SATO and possibly other revenue authorities at the same time. Thus, in your case, a cost contribution agreement would be entered into and signed by each of the four companies in the group with specific recognition of costs which are to be paid by different members. If one member is to pay a disproportionate amount in relation to assets which will be used by other companies within the group, compensating adjustments will be made upfront. In my experience, Cost Contribution Agreements are not that common in Australia but they do have utility and in the appropriate circumstances can work to avoid any subsequent arguments with revenue authorities. They appear to have greater acceptance and use in the United States. What is an Advance Pricing Agreement? This is an arrangement that is very different to the Cost Contribution Agreement, as it involves not only the corporate members of the broad group but also one or more revenue authorities who are in effect bound to the terms of the APA which has been entered into. The idea is that all the parties agree to a set formula for determining pricing in relation to related party transactions within the group and will not object to the use of that formula on certain assumptions. Importantly the agreement is limited in time – it will usually last up to 5 years but can in appropriate circumstances be longer. The ATO (and most other revenue authorities for that matter) will inevitably make it clear that it will only accept the terms of the APA if the assumptions which underpinned the making of the APA remain current. This might, for example, include an assumption that the Australia to US dollar exchange rate remains within certain bounds. It might also be based on an assumption that insurance risk is taken on by the Australian company rather than the three subsidiaries. If these assumptions are invalid after two years it is incumbent on the taxpayers to return to the relevant revenue authorities and advise them of the change in circumstances so as to give the revenue authorities the opportunity to revise whatever they think might be appropriate in relation to the Page 8 of 12 pricing between the parties. This would apply equally to the companies themselves in the sense that they might also seek to revise the pricing based on the changed assumptions but that rarely arises in practice. APA’s are expensive to negotiate and time-consuming and accordingly are not normally relied upon except for large corporate group’s where there is often a substantial budget available for such activities. What is Unitary Tax Methodology? Unitary Tax Methodology is essentially the adoption of a formula for determining the allocation of profits across a group of related companies that reside in different tax jurisdictions. Thus, in your case if it could be established, for example, that the profit of the whole group in dealing with the outside world (i.e. without regard to internal transactions) was $A2,000,000, then that figure would be split between the four countries based on a formula. The exact formula would be the basis of considerable debate but it historically has had regard to sales in each jurisdiction, property located in each jurisdiction and the respective payroll size in each jurisdiction. Thus, to put it simply if half the workforce was in Australia, half the sales took place there and half the assets were located here, half the profit would be taxed here. Under the formula different weightings can be given to each aspect of the formula and there is no universal agreement on what to include in the formula to start with. There are many problems with this. Most countries oppose its use as being too arbitrary and does not pay regard to where profits are really generated. Even if you accept the formula – where do sales take place when electronic commerce is involved/do you measure employees by sheer number or weighted according to levels of pay. Getting international agreement on an appropriate formula looks unlikely. This methodology has not been accepted in Australia as a valid method for dealing with TP and is unlikely to be so accepted in the near future. Question 5 The Australian Fringe Benefits Act (FBT) was introduced in 1986 as a Federal tax to supplement the Federal income tax in Australia. The main reason it was introduced was because it was felt that certain fringe benefits which were conferred by employers on employees were not being caught or at least not being caught adequately by the framework of the income tax legislation. The main examples included the availability of cars provided by employers to employees which were used in part for private purposes and the making of home loans by employers to employees at discounted interest rates. The way the FBT has been structured is that it is a tax imposed upon the employee in respect of the global fringe benefits which are provided to all its employees. It is divided into categories with two of the categories being the examples given above, i.e. cars used partly for private purposes and discounted interest rate loans for housing purposes. There are a series of other categories which can apply and the final category is residual fringe benefits referring to fringe benefits not otherwise covered. The particular category relevant to a particular circumstance will have its own specific valuation rules which will then give a value for that category of fringe benefit. That value grossed up at the top marginal tax rate is then included in the fringe benefits that are subject to tax in the hands of the employer. The valuation rules can be quite complicated particularly for cars where different valuation methodologies can be adopted. A good answer will touch on some of these valuation methodologies. Page 9 of 12 The reason there are so many classifications is because different types of fringe benefits call for different types of valuation methodologies and may have attached to them different qualifications/exemptions. There are many exemptions, qualifications and exemptions built into the system including a particular a qualification that to the extent that the employee contributes to the cost of the fringe benefit, the value of the fringe benefit assessed to the employer is reduced. Furthermore, to the extent that the cost of the fringe benefit would have been deductible to the employee had the employee purchased the fringe benefit, a commensurate reduction in the value of the fringe benefit included in the fringe benefits assessment of the employer will apply. This “otherwise deductible rule” is designed to ensure parity of treatment between fringe benefits and ordinary income tax. There are complexities in the operation of the fringe benefits tax which could be avoided. One in particular is the different year end for fringe benefits tax as opposed to income tax and GST. The latter are calculated by reference to the year-end 30 June whereas the FBT is calculated by reference to the year-end 31 March. This appears to be a rather strange anomaly and complexity could be avoided by shifting the FBT year-end to 30 June. A perceived complexity relates to the fact that FBT is levied on the employer rather than the employee and this appears to be odd as the tax appears to be levied on the provider of the benefit rather than the recipient. Whilst this might be odd in policy terms, it is a clever and relatively unique way of dealing with the issue. It is clever in particular because by levying the tax against the employer where there are say 10,000 employees, the whole situation is in effect summarised in one composite return without the need to check countless other returns. Of course some cross-referencing to the individual employees concerned may be necessary, but nonetheless the task of the revenue authorities is considerably eased by this device. Although the two exemptions/qualifications mentioned above seem sensible, many of the other exemptions/qualifications that apply under the FBT Act are not always justified and could be reviewed with the intention of simplifying the number and content of such exemptions/qualifications. Question 6 Division 855 ITAA 1997 now provides a comprehensive code to deal with the taxation of capital gains derived by foreign residents. Essentially, a foreign resident can disregard a capital gain or loss unless the relevant CGT asset is: a direct interest in Australian real property being real property situated in Australia (this would include a lease of land if the land is situated in Australia); a direct interest in a mining, quarrying or prospecting right, if the minerals, petroleum or quarry materials are situated in Australia; an indirect interest in either of the above two assets. This would arise in circumstances where the asset is itself at least 10% of the shares in a company or a unit in a unit trust and the underlying company or unit trust has its underlying value principally derived from interest in Australian real property or mining quarrying or prospecting rights; a direct interest in a CGT asset that has been used as any time in carrying on a business through a permanent establishment in Australia; or a direct interest in an option or write to acquire an asset referred to above. Special rules also apply for individuals who are Australian residents but have become nonresidents or for foreign resident beneficiaries of fixed estates. There are also special rules dealing with what happens when a foreign resident becomes an Australian resident. If the asset is not covered by one of the preceding paragraphs any capital gain or capital loss derived from a CGT event that arises in relation to the asset is disregarded. Page 10 of 12 The effect of this is that Australia’s domestic laws are severely restricted in terms of the extent to which CGT arises for foreign residents dealing with Australian assets. If that asset is not in any way connected with Australian real property or mining etc rights and is not an asset used in an Australian business, broadly speaking no Australian capital gains tax will arise. This limits the scope of the operation of Australia’s double taxation agreements. The double tax agreements will only come into play if Australia otherwise asserts its right to tax a capital gain and since the domestic law severely restricts the circumstances in which capital gains are taxed where they are derived by a non-resident, the likelihood of a DTA applying is limited. Nonetheless in appropriate circumstances it is possible that the business profits article in a DTA could operate to exclude Australia’s right to tax a capital gain where the capital gain is derived by a foreign resident who is resident of the DTA partner country, the gain is treated as a business profit under the DTA and the foreign resident entity does not have a permanent establishment in Australia. In those circumstances, Article 13 of the DTA is likely to preclude Australia’s right to tax. However, if the asset involved is real property in Australia which would therefore ordinarily be subject to tax under division 855 the business profits article in the DTA is likely to be overridden by a specific real property article in the DTA which may well restore Australia’s taxing rights by virtue of the fact that the real property is situated in Australia. In other words the likelihood of such a case arising where Australia’s right to tax is precluded by the treaty in circumstances where it is allowed under the domestic law is remote. It is worth noting that the cases where treaties have blocked Australia’s right to tax capital gains arose under the previous provisions which were much broader in allowing Australia to tax foreign residents then the current Division 855 – see in particular Virgin Holdings and Undershaft Number 1 and 2. Question 7 This statement is reflects to a large degree the problems identified in the application of the GST The concept of supply has been the subject of considerable judicial comment see Reliance Holdings Luxotica Qantas and AP Group all of which in various ways grapple with the supply concept and in particular whether it is possible to break a composite supply into its smaller components and whether non- performance can amount to a supply. Some discussion of the terms of the definition would be appropriate. Similarly discussion of the statutory definition of consideration would be useful highlighting some of the key parts of s 915 of the GST Act 1999. Some reference to AP Group and related cases on whether consideration must come from the recipient of the supplier would be helpful. An explanation of the three types of supply and the consequences flowing from a supply being characterised as one or the other is expected and overlap issues and grey areas should be discussed. Case discussion could explain the facts of Qantas where the issue that arose for consideration before the High Court ultimately was whether a supply had been made in circumstances where there was a no-show by a consumer, a flight previously paid for was not taken and the monies were forfeited to the airline. The court ultimately held a supply had taken place but it is not entirely clear even at this stage as to exactly what the supply was. A further example is the litigation that went before the full Federal Court in AP Group where supplies made by car dealerships allegedly to certain manufacturers was in dispute. These two cases in particular highlight some of the complexities that can arise under the GST particularly in the context of what constitutes supply and to a lesser extent what constitutes consideration. Page 11 of 12 Page 12 of 12