Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research What is Normal Profit for power generation? Paul Simshauser and Jude Ariyaratnam Level 6, 144 Edward Street Brisbane, QLD 4001 June 2013 Abstract One of the seemingly complex areas associated with energy-only wholesale electricity pools is at what point market power abuse is present on the supply-side. It shouldn’t be this way. If a theoretically robust measure of normal profit exists, identification of potential market power abuse is straight-forward. Such a definition readily exists and can be traced back to the ground-breaking work of financial economists in the 1960s. But using this framework in a post-2008 financial crisis environment requires careful application. In this article, we explore how the Capital Asset Pricing Model can be applied in atypical capital market conditions, and when combined with a multi-period dynamic power project financing model, pragmatic estimates of benchmark wholesale power prices can be derived. This in turn can guide policymakers as to whether price spikes or bidding above marginal cost in wholesale markets warrants any investigation at all. Keywords: Profit, Project Finance, Electricity Prices. JEL Codes: D61, L94, L11 and Q40. 1. Introduction Price spikes in gross pool, energy-only, uniform first-price auction wholesale markets typically trigger regulatory inquiry. Policy intervention may be warranted if supranormal profits are being extracted on a sustained basis through generator bidding behaviour in the presence of demonstrable barriers to entry. But episodes of transient price spikes in energy-only markets should not represent an ‘automatic’ trigger for inquiry let alone policy intervention, particularly if underlying prices are otherwise driving merchant generators to a state of financial distress. Economic theory has long demonstrated that energy-only spot electricity markets can clear demand reliably, and can provide suitable investment signals for new capacity (Schweppe et al. 1988). But such analysis typically presumes unlimited market price caps, limited political or regulatory interference, and by deduction, a largely equity capital-funded generation fleet able to withstand wildly fluctuating business cycles. Unfortunately the real world isn’t this convenient. Rarely are generators devoid of scheduled debt repayments and so theories of spot energy markets suffer from the inadequate treatment of how non-trivial sunk capital costs are financed (Peluchon, 2003; Joskow, 2006; Finon, 2008; Caplan, 2012; Nelson and Simshauser, 2013). Additionally, wholesale price caps do exist and are enforced – in some instances excessively so – by regulatory authorities (Besser et al. 2002; Oren, 2003; de Vries, 2003; Wen et al. 2004; Finon and Pignon, 2008, Joskow 2008a, Simshauser, 2010). Intensely competitive energy-only markets are known to produce inadequate net revenues to support investment in the optimal least cost generating portfolio, otherwise known as the ‘missing money’ problem (Neuhoff et al. 2004; de Vries, 2004; de Vries et al. 2008; Bushnell, 2005; Roques et al. 2005; Cramton and Stoft, 2006; Joskow, 2008b; Finon, 2008; Simshauser, 2008). In short, given substantial fixed and sunk costs associated with power generation, and low marginal production costs, persistent generator bidding at short run marginal cost does not result in a stable equilibrium (Bidwell and Henney, Paul Simshauser is the Chief Economist at AGL Energy Ltd and Professor of Economics at Griffith University. Jude Ariyaratnam is a financial analyst at AGL Energy Ltd. The authors are grateful to Rob Prest (Macquarie Capital), James Nelson (PwC) and AGL Energy Ltd’s Applied Economic and Policy Research Council for reviewing earlier drafts. However, as noted in Appendix IV, any errors or omissions remain entirely the responsibility of the authors. Page 1 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research 2004; Simshauser, 2008; Nelson and Simshauser, 2013). Generator bidding must, therefore, deviate from strict marginal cost at some point. But given an oligopolistic market environment, at what point might this cross a line and represent a potential abuse of market power that warrants investigation and possible intervention by policymakers? If a pragmatic measure of Normal Profit exists, then the combination of historic base load spot prices and futures prices for call option contracts can provide suitable guidance. Identifying a theoretically sound measure of Normal Profit is of vital importance to the industry, policymakers, and in turn, the overall efficiency and welfare of the macro economy. The allocation of resources within an economy relies quite fundamentally on such constructs, whether this is through the investment decisions of firms, or by decisions made by policymakers that influence or directly impact on investment outcomes. But Normal Profit needs to be very carefully defined. The concept of Normal Profit is unremarkable in economics but oddly enough is very rarely identified in practice. This is primarily because profit announcements by firms (and reported by the media) are dominated by accounting statistics and ratios based on the traditional measure of Net Profit after Tax. Finance theory is clear – NPAT is nothing more than a residual measure. When NPAT is determined by traditional accounting axioms, it represents the residual funds available for distribution to stockholders after all other claimants have been satisfied. NPAT does not describe the ‘pitch’ of profits generated, that is, Normal or otherwise. In order to assess the pitch of profits, a suitable benchmark must first be defined. Economic theory has long told us that this is measured by the opportunity cost of funds employed. By the 1960s, the economics profession had produced profoundly more refined quantitative definitions, viz. the marginal cost of capital or expected returns of rational investors based on a one factor, two-parameter model of risk and return. The origins of such developments can be traced back to Sharpe1 (1964) and Lintner (1965). If profits of the firm meet the marginal cost of capital, a Normal Profit has been generated. Supranormal profits are achieved when profit exceeds the cost of capital and conversely, economic losses occur when returns fail to meet expected returns. For highly capital-intensive industries like power generation, temporal issues associated with accounting results create further complications. Accounting numbers use arbitrary reporting periods (e.g. monthly, quarterly, annual) to measure NPAT. While this is both desirable and necessary for managerial and agency purposes, discrete accounting period reporting is fundamentally a static analysis, whereas for investment or policymaking purposes, Normal Profit should be considered in a dynamic context. There are no capital-intensive assets likely to deliver lifecycle economic returns within a decade, let alone a single accounting period. More commonly with capital-intensive assets, expected returns occur over multiple decades and in power generation are subject to (nominally) 5-7 year business cycles, with actual returns oscillating considerably around the mean outcome. Normal Profit, then, must be considered as a multiperiod dynamic inquiry rather than a static analysis based on a collection of half-hour price spikes during a short episode of hot weather, for example. In economics literature, from a benchmark perspective the Internal Rate of Return (IRR) of investments is the most prominently used theoretical long-run profitability concept, as Salmi and Virtanen (1997) explain. Finance literature on the other hand has a distinct bias towards net present value analysis, although as Brealey, Myers and Allen (2011) observe, IRR comes from respectable ancestry, and for our purposes, can be expected to provide conforming results under all of the conditions that we envisage in this article.2 1 Prof William Sharpe was awarded the 1990 Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences for his research in this area. See for example Brealey, Myers and Allen (2011, pp 109-115) for a discussion of the conditions where IRR calculations deviate from NPV calculations. 2 Page 2 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Normal Profit is of central importance in policymaking – if benchmarks are over-estimated consumer welfare can be adversely affected and resource allocation to other industries may be scaled-back to inefficient levels. Conversely, underestimation of Normal Profit can lead to policy settings that benefit consumers in the short run but the associated wealth transfers adversely affect industry investment, competition and innovation in the long run, and will eventually harm consumers. Neither outcome is desirable. From a policymaking perspective, as the capital intensity of an industry increases, the consequence of error (in either direction) compounds. Capital is scarce and will inevitably find its optimal use.3 The purpose of this article is to set out a theoretically robust and pragmatic approach which defines ‘Normal Profit’ in power generation which is then transposed into base electricity prices and call option prices. This requires that we define the cost of debt and the cost of equity capital for the two most prominent business combinations in merchant energy markets, and to set out a clear quantitative methodology for quantifying the long run marginal cost of power generation given prevailing capital and factor market conditions. While our application to power generation uses Australian data, the framework is equally applicable to other regions with energy-only market models such as those in Australia, Texas, New Zealand, Singapore, Alberta (Canada) and Europe amongst others. This article is structured as follows. Section 2 briefly discusses Normal Profit. Section 3 then defines the estimated cost of equity. Section 4 outlines a dynamic power project financial model which produces generalised long run marginal cost estimates for multiple technologies. Section 5 summarises the results and Section 6 applies the results to policymaking. Concluding remarks follow. 2. What is Normal Profit? Normal Profit can be defined as the firm’s total cost of production, including the opportunity cost of funds employed. The ‘opportunity cost of funds employed’ requires further clarification, however. The accounting treatment of equity costs is inadequate because it treats such resources as a ‘residual claim’. In economics, no such assumption is made – equity returns are treated as a fixed cost, just as the interest and principal repayments on debt are considered fixed costs under accounting principles. And so a firm’s total cost of production includes all costs, including the opportunity cost of capital which translates to a normal (i.e. fair) level of profit to equity investors. It goes without saying that, in practice, the mere treatment of equity resources as a fixed cost does not of itself produce a profit. Charging equity costs to a profit and loss statement is a foreign concept in financial accounting. However, the importance of incorporating equity costs as a charge against revenue has long been accepted in economic theory as a prerequisite to the survival of the firm as Thompson and Formby (p. 241, 1993) noted: …Whenever the profitability of a business is consistently below what can generally be earned in other enterprises of equivalent business risk, stockholders can be expected to seek greener pastures for their investment funds. Because additional resources and capital will tend to be withheld from an enterprise if profits fall below normal levels for sustained periods, it is appropriate to consider this minimum profitability as a cost. It is a cost in the sense that unless revenues from the firm’s operations are adequate to provide acceptable rewards to stockholders, the capital funds needed to sustain operations will dry up and the firm, in time, will wither and die. In other words, in the long run some minimal amount of profit is a condition of survival… 3 For the electricity industry, the matter is further intensified by the portfolio weightings associated with institutional investors. The typical institutional investor with an Australian investment mandate has an asset allocation of c.10% of their total Funds Under Management for ‘infrastructure class’ assets. Electricity then forms only a component part, and needs to compete with other infrastructure classes such as ports, roads and gas pipelines. Further still, power generation needs to compete with transmission and distribution infrastructure opportunities for this scarce capital. Page 3 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research In our experience, a surprising number of policymakers, regulators and microeconomics professionals (from academia and industry) misinterpret the appropriate quantitative value for the marginal cost of capital. The reason for this, we suspect, is that the theoretical construct of ‘opportunity cost’ must shift from theory to practice, all the while ensuring that in the process the result does not violate the basic axioms and constraints of credit metrics and taxation implications – all of which are important in defining the true marginal efficiency of equity and debt capital. Producing reliable estimates of a firm’s cost of capital and the level of profit which constitutes ‘normal’ is therefore an exercise best applied using financial economic principles. Turvey (2000, p.2) also notes that in power generation, the estimation of long run marginal costs requires engineering and operational research skills and rarely requires accounting skills. 3. What is the marginal cost of capital in atypical economic conditions? Among the most important variables in determining Normal Profit in capital-intensive industries like power generation is the cost of capital as Nelson and Simshauser (2013) demonstrate. The cost of debt capital is directly observable from the capital markets. The cost of equity capital is not – it is the subject of economic estimation models. The estimated marginal cost of equity capital is not a single number – for merchant power generators it will be quite different for the two most prominent business combinations (1) merchant utilities with an investment-grade credit rating, and (2) project financed merchant utilities.4 The viable level of debt within these two business combinations can be quantified through detailed power project modelling which we explain in Section 4. These lead to very different gearing levels with project financing typically ranging from 60-80% and investment-grade entities exhibiting values closer to 30-40%. The expected cost of equity is different for each business combination – the marginal efficiency of equity capital for a project finance will gravitate towards 15-16%, whereas marginal equity costs for an investment grade integrated merchant utility is typically 11-12%. In other words, the expected IRR of power project post-tax cash flows will range from 11-16% with the variation explained by the relevant business combination and consequent level of debt within the capital structure. 3.1 Estimating the cost of equity: Sharpe-Lintner Capital Asset Pricing Model Since the marginal cost of equity capital must be estimated, a brief discussion of its derivation is warranted, noting that a truly vast amount of literature on this topic exists from a mechanistic perspective. What follows is therefore focused on the key elements of its application in ‘atypical capital market conditions’ – where there is considerably less literature readily available. With any portfolio of investments, there is always some component of risk that affects all asset classes, known as ‘systematic’ or market risk. Systematic risks are those variables that affect the entire economy, albeit some assets are affected by these variables more than others. A good example of systematic risk is a rise in consumer prices. All things being equal, rising general inflation is likely to lead to higher interest rates, labour costs or both (amongst other impacts). Such movements in these economic variables generally adversely affect all firms, although for power generation, interest rate changes are amplified given the capital-intensive nature of the sector. Non-systematic risks on the other hand are those that affect a single or a small group of stocks, and can therefore be essentially eliminated at minimal cost through diversification at the investor level. An example of a non-systematic risk for power generation is mild weather, which is usually associated with adverse commodity sales. Since non-systematic risk can be virtually eliminated at almost no cost by diversification at the investor level, there is no reward for bearing We consider that these two business combinations represent the ‘book-ends’ of the feasible business models from a cost of equity perspective. 4 Page 4 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research it. However, systematic risk cannot be eliminated through diversification, and thus, stockholders must be rewarded by suitable (expected) returns for that risk. The cost of equity capital is most typically approximated through the Capital Asset Pricing Model5 (CAPM), which as noted earlier can be traced back to Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965). The model is defined as follows: ( ) (1) Where: Ke Rf Rm i = post-tax cost of equity capital = the risk free rate of return = the expected market return = the equity beta for the ith firm, which ex ante can be used as predictive, and i = ( ) (2) Where: Ri Rm 2 m = the returns from the ith firm = the returns from the stock market as a whole = the variance of market returns as a whole The intercept term (Rf ) is the risk free rate and is a purely theoretical construct. In practice however, the current yield of long-dated government bonds are used as a proxy. Regulators in the NEM typically use contemporaneous values for Rf .6 The expected return of the total market (Rm) is approximated by reference to very long run average returns from the stock market over and above long dated government rates at the time (i.e. Rm – Rf). Over the last 128 years this calculation, also known as the Market Risk Premium (MRP), has averaged 6.1% (Brailsford, Handley and Maheswaran, 2012). The crucial factor in the CAPM is the equity beta ( i) for the ith firm– which is concerned with the measure of systematic risk for a company. As equation (2) implies, a firm that has the same general risk characteristics as the aggregate stock market will return a i equal to 1.0. The generation business unit of an investment grade merchant utility, for example, would typically have i in the range of 0.95 to 1.15 as IPART (2013) explains. The higher leverage associated with project financed merchant power plants will produce markedly higher earnings volatility and therefore will have i greater than 1.0, typically in the range of 1.5 to 1.8.7 Of course, while i is mathematically defined based on equation (2), this is an historical calculation and in practice i and the CAPM must be used to define (expected) future returns.8 3.2 Applying the Sharpe-Linter CAPM in atypical capital market conditions Throughout most of the last 20 years, the CAPM could be mechanistically applied as outlined in Section 3.1 to the power generation industry and produce relatively stable and reliable estimates for over time. The collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 and the Global Financial There are other equity cost estimation models such as Fama and French’s (1997) three factor model. However in the Australian energy sector, the CAPM is most widely used. 6 For example, Rf is often determined in regulatory determinations by reference to the 30-day rolling average yield on 10-Year Australian Government Bonds. 7 The variable is based on the work undertaken by the NSW economic regulator, IPART (2013) and PWC (2013). The range for was found to be 0.95-1.15 and so we have opted to use the midpoint of 1.05 as our set point. Using the gearing levels implied in the SFG analysis, the Asset Beta value which appears later in Table 2 for generation can be expressed as 5 ) ( ⁄[( [( ) ( )]. This can then be rearranged to produce an equity beta for merchant plant such that )] where the term is the value of equity and D is the value of debt. 8 This is of course a critical shortcoming with the CAPM framework and the estimation of equity costs, but it nonetheless represents the most widely used equity cost estimation model. Page 5 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Crisis that followed has however produced atypical capital market conditions. A ‘mechanistic’ application of the CAPM anytime since October 2008 through to the time of writing in 2013 would produce results that are intuitively erroneous. Our reference to atypical capital market conditions is not a reference to economic recession. By atypical, we mean a situation whereby yields on government bonds are especially low – which implies a general state of ‘loose credit’ – while simultaneously the market for corporate debt is contracting with rising spreads. Bernanke (1983) shows that the Great Depression and in particular, the 1930-33 financial crisis in the US exhibited atypical conditions not observed in other economic recessions. The prime cause was the 1930-33 financial crisis and associated insolvency of large numbers of banks. We consider the Global Financial Crisis of 2008-09 produced outcomes in capital markets that are directionally consistent with Bernanke’s (1983) description of 1930-33. The relevance of atypical capital market conditions to the CAPM is that a mechanistic application of MRP uses a very long run data set for both variables in the MRP calculation (i.e. Rm – Rf), in our case 128 years, but simultaneously uses a contemporaneous value for the intercept Rf . This combination is problematic in atypical capital market conditions. In Figure 1, we demonstrate this by mechanistically applying the CAPM to produce estimates for a power generator from July 1997 through to June 2013 and assume MRP = 6.1% and i = 1.05, which is relevant to a generation business with an investment-grade credit rating. Notice that by following the mechanistic application of the model, the value of marginal equity costs falls once the 2008 financial crisis sets in. Figure 1: 10-Year Govt Bond Yields vs. Mechanistic CAPM Estimate Source: RBA, AGL Energy Ltd. In this instance, falling government bond yields gives the appearance that Ke is also falling. But in a financial crisis, this is an erroneous conclusion as Bernanke (1983, p266) noted in the context of the 1929-33 US episode: Page 6 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research …the idea that the low yields on Treasury [bonds]… during this time signalled a general state of “easy money” is mistaken; money was easy for a few safe borrowers, but difficult for everyone else. An indicator of the strength of lender preferences for safe liquid assets (and hence of the difficulty of risky borrowers in obtaining funds) is the yield differential between Baa corporate bonds and Treasury bonds… In Figure 2, we present historical credit spreads between Australian Government Bonds and BBB rated corporate bonds from January 2000 through to June 2013, along with Bernanke’s (1983) US Baa corporate bond spread data from the Great Depression which runs from July 1929 to March 1933. We contrast these data with the mechanistically determined average values for Ke as derived in Figure 1. The Figure 2 results are important with respect to the application of the CAPM. First, note the shape of the US Baa corporate spread data trace from the Great Depression – Bernanke (1983) explains that the sharp rise in spreads coincided with an accelerating rate of bank failures. The 1929-33 data has been aligned to the Australian BBB bond spread data by matching the peak of the bank failures as reported by Bernanke (1983) with the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008. As an aside, the correlation coefficient between the two data sets is 0.88. Note that just as 10 year government bond yields fall sharply in 2008, BBB corporate spreads rise sharply and coincide with the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008. In these circumstances, institutional investors adopted a “risk off” approach, meaning that investment funds shift from risky corporate bonds and equities towards low risk Treasury bonds or Australian Government bonds – hence the falling value of 10-year Government bonds and rising BBB spreads. Figure 2: Australian BBB Corporate Bond Spreads vs. Mechanistic Rm Source: Bernanke (1983), RBA, AGL Energy Ltd. As an economic model reliant on assumptions and data inputs to produce estimates of , when applied mechanistically, the CAPM tells us that equity investors would accept lower risk premiums in the middle of a financial crisis – as Figure 2 highlights. So when government bonds are trading at record lows, is apparently valued at historic lows. As Gray (2013b) demonstrates, such an approach erroneously suggests that the value of is the lowest at any Page 7 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research point in the last 40 years. From a practical perspective, it is difficult to imagine the conditions where corporate debt investors require substantially higher premiums while simultaneously, corporate equity investors accept the lowest risk premium on record. Indeed, Gray (2013b) explains that whether judged by Dividend Growth Models, the practice of independent experts, advice from investment banks currently raising capital or other indicator variables from finance literature9, none point toward values for at multi-decade lows. On the contrary, the weight of evidence is that is currently slightly above the long run average. None of this means the CAPM is broken – only that its application requires judgement in atypical capital market conditions. Some regulatory authorities in Australia have nonetheless persisted with applying it mechanistically.10 For our purposes, we maintain the historic MRP of 6.1% and opt to use a 10-year average of Rf over the period immediately prior to the collapse of Lehman Brothers in 2008. We also test this against an expanded value of MRP provided by conventional dividend growth models (i.e. from 6.1% to a range of 7.4-8.3%)11 to ensure that our long run average approach remains reasonable for marginal equity raisings. This approach is similar to that adopted by the independent regulator in New South Wales (IPART, 2013). 4. Generalised long run marginal cost of generation plant – PF Model The model we use to produce a theoretically sound profit benchmark and generalised long run marginal cost estimates for generating plant is a dynamic, multi-period model with all outputs expressed in nominal dollars and post-tax discounted cash flows focusing on and solving for the expected whilst simultaneously meeting binding debt sizing parameters. The model, known as the PF Model, is a variation to the coal-fired power plant PF Model in Simshauser (2009) and the combined cycle gas turbine PF Model in Simshauser and Nelson (2012), and Nelson and Simshauser (2013). Whereas those models were focused on a single technology project financing, our PF Model solves for multiple technologies, business combinations and revenue possibilities, and simultaneously solves for convergent price, debt-sizing, and equity returns . To begin with, since all outputs are expressed in nominal dollars, costs are increased annually by a forecast general inflation rate estimate (CPI) with prices escalating at a discount to our assumed CPI. Inflation rates for revenue streams and cost streams in period (year) j are calculated in the model as follows: [ ( )] , and [ ( )] (4) In this instance, is the adjustment factor of 1.0 for costs and relates to revenues and is set at 0.75. The discounted value for is intended to reflect single factor learning rates that characterise generating technologies over time.12 4.1 PF Model for base, semi-base and intermittent power plant Energy output from each power plant (i) is a key variable in driving revenue streams, unit fuel costs and variable Operations & Maintenance costs. Energy output is calculated by reference to installed capacity , capacity utilisation rate and run time t, which in the PF Model is 8760hrs for each period j. Auxillary losses arising from on-site electrical loads (such as air compressors, lighting, induced and forced draft fans and so on) need to be deducted. 9 See for example Petkova and Zhang (2005) who examine the MRP in relation to default premiums, term premiums and treasury bills and dividend yields. 10 The exceptions to this are the NSW independent regulator, IPART and the Australian Energy Market Commission. See IPART (2013) and AEMC (2012) for details. 11 See Gray (2013b) for a summary of dividend growth model results. 12 See Frontier Economics (2013) at pp31-35 for a useful explanation of learning curves as they relate to power generation technologies. Page 8 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research ( ) (5) There are two options for convergent electricity prices in the PF Model. The first option is to exogenously set unique forecast prices for each period j (e.g. from a dynamic partial equilibrium model of the relevant power system), while the second option, which is our default option and used throughout this article is a calculated price in year one which escalates electricity price at the rate of from equation (4). Additionally, ancillary services revenues have been set at 0.25% of electricity sales.13 Thus revenue in each period j is defined as follows: ( ) (6) To determine the short run marginal cost of the ith plant in the jth period, the thermal efficiency for each generation technology needs to be defined. The constant term ‘3600’14 is divided by the thermal efficiency variable to convert the result from per cent to kJ/kWh, which is then multiplied by the commodity cost of raw fuel . Variable Operations & Maintenance costs is also added to provide a pre-carbon short run marginal cost. To the extent that the plant has non-zero CO2 emissions and faces an emissions trading regime, the CO2 intensity of output for the ith plant needs to be computed along with the relevant CO2 price, . In order to define a value for plant carbon intensity , the relevant combustion emissions factor ̇ and fugitive CO2 emissions from the fuel source ̂ are multiplied by the plant heat rate. Marginal running costs in the jth period is then calculated by the product of short run marginal production costs by generation output and escalated at the rate of . ( {[( ⁄ ) ( ) ( )] | ( ̇ ̂) ⁄ ) } (7) Fixed Operations & Maintenance costs of the plant are measured in $/MW/year of installed capacity and are multiplied by plant capacity and escalated. (8) Earnings Before Interest Tax Depreciation and Amortisation (EBITDA), a frequently used accounting-based measure, in the jth period can be defined as follows: ( ) (9) Unless plant is acquired, capital costs associated with development involve a multi-period construction program. Capital costs are therefore defined as follows: ∑ ( ) (10) Ongoing capital spending for each period j is determined as the inflated annual assumed capital works program. (11) 13 14 This factor is based on average ancillary services revenues as a percentage of overall energy market revenues. The derivation of the constant term 3600 is: 1 Watt = 1 Joule per second and hence 1 Watt Hour = 3600 Joules. Page 9 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Plant capital costs give rise to tax depreciation ( ) such that if the current period was greater than the plant life under taxation law (L), then the value is 0. In addition, also gives rise to tax depreciation such that: ( ) ( ) (12) From here, taxation payable ( ) at the corporate taxation rate ( ) is applied to Interest on Loans defined later in (16), less . To the extent ( ) results in non-positive outcome, tax losses ( ) are carried forward and offset against future periods. ( ) ( ) less (13) Our debt financing model computes the interest and principal repayments on different debt facilities depending on the type and tenor of each tranche. For example, we model project financings with two facilities; (1) nominally a 5-year bullet, requiring interest-only payments after which it is refinanced with two consecutive 10-year amortising facilities. The first refinancing is set in a semi-permanent structure with a nominal repayment term of 20 years, while the second is fully amortised over the 10 year tenor. The second facility (2) commences with a tenor of 12 years as an amortising facility, again set within a semi-permanent structure with a nominal repayment term of 27 years. This second tranche is refinanced in year 13 and extinguished over a further 15 year period. Consequently, all debt is extinguished by year 27. The decision tree for the two tranches of debt was the same, so for the Debt Tranche where = 1 or 2, the calculation is as follows: { (14) refers to the total amount of debt used in the project. The split (S) of the debt between each facility refers to the manner in which the debt is apportioned to each debt tranche. We assume 35% of the debt was assigned to Tranche 1 and the remainder to Tranche 2 in a manner consistent with Simshauser (2009). Principal refers to the amount of principal repayment for tranche T in period j and is calculated as an annuity: ( [ ( ( )) | { ) (15) ] In (15), is the fixed (reference) interest rate and is the credit spread or margin relevant to the issued Debt Tranche. The relevant interest payment in the jth period ( ) is calculated as the product of the (fixed) interest rate on the loan by the amount of loan outstanding: ( ) (16) Total Debt outstanding , total Interest and total Principle for the ith plant is calculated as the sum of the above components for the two debt tranches in time j. For clarity, Loan Drawings are equal to in year 1 as part of the initial financing and are otherwise 0. In equation (14) one of the key calculations is the initial derivation of . This is determined by the product of the gearing level and the acquisition/development cost. The gearing level in turn is Page 10 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research formed by applying a cash flow constraint based on credit metrics applied by capital markets. In this instance, the variable in our PF Model relates specifically to the business combination and the credible capital structure achievable. The two relevant combinations are Vertically Integrated (VI) merchant utilities and stand-alone Project Financed Merchant (PF) businesses. ( ) ( ( ) ) | ( ) ( | ∑ ) )( [( ) (17) ] { The variables and are exogenously determined by credit rating agencies. Values for are exogenously determined by project banks and depend on technology (i.e. thermal vs. renewable) and the extent of energy market exposure, that is whether a Power Purchase Agreement exists or not. For clarity, is ‘Funds From Operations’ while and are the Debt Service Cover Ratio and Loan Life Cover Ratios. At this point, all of the necessary conditions exist to produce estimates of the long run marginal cost of power generation technologies, and a suitable benchmark for what constitutes Normal Profit. As noted at the outset of this article, in economics literature IRR is the widely used theoretical long-run profitability concept. The relevant equation to solve for the price which produces a normal profit given whilst simultaneously meeting the binding constraints of and or given the relevant business combination is as follows: ∑ [ ] ( ) ( ) ∑ ( ) ( ) The primary objective is to expand every term which contains Interest and Tax terms is as follows: ∑ [( ( ) ) ) ∑ ( ( ) ) (( ( ) ( ) ] ( (19) ) )( ) We then solve for term is on the left hand side of the equation: ( ) ( ∑ ( ( ) ) ( ) ( )] ∑ ∑ [ ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ( ) ( )) (20) such that: ∑ ∑ ) . ∑ ∑ . Expansion of the EBITDA, ( ) We then rearrange the terms such that only the Let (18) ) ( ) (( ) ( ) ( ∑ )( ( ( ) )) ( )( ) ) ( ) ) ( ) ( ) ( ) (21) ( ) 4.2 PF Model for peaking power plant Certain adjustments to the PF Model are required to accommodate long run marginal cost estimates for peaking plant. For base, semi-base and intermittent plant, the normal estimation procedure is to identify the relevant convergent electricity price that is sufficient to produce an IRR equal to . The value for is found by solving equation (21), and one of the most Page 11 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research sensitive variables is energy output , which is in turn driven by the value for . In general, values for are comparatively predictable in that base load plant have high capacity factors and intermittent plant, over time, exhibit output factors within a comparatively tight range given long-run average weather conditions. Peaking plant on the other hand exhibits fluctuating values for due to the natural volatility inherent in short-run weather patterns and temporal shocks to the demand-supply balance. This has two primary implications. First, defining a single electricity price for peaking plant is ̅̅̅̅̅ virtually meaningless in the absence of an expected fixed or ‘sticky’ . Second, attempting to define a value for is likely to render such a project unbankable due to the uncertainty over values for in application (i.e. by project bank credit committees). Consequently, peaking plant requires a distinct revenue model in its own right. In our opinion, the appropriate way to express generalised long run marginal cost estimates for peaking plant is to define the ‘carrying cost’ of plant capacity, ̅ . This requires only small modifications to the calculation of revenues in our PF Model. The result produced is a single capacity price which essentially reflects the equilibrium price of a sold call-option contract at the commonly traded NEM strike price for such instruments of $300/MWh. Equations (5) and (6) require reconfiguring as follows: , and ( ) (22) Here, the value of energy output is set to zero, which means marginal running costs will also be zero. In practice will have a non-zero value and so would also be non-zero, and under most conditions will exceed marginal running costs . This differential between and , while somewhat contentious to model, will be limited in each sub-period of j by the call option strike price, and for our purposes we assume it to be zero. Putting the typically trivial value of this to one side, revenue for the ith peaking plant is hence the product of installed capacity , the price of that capacity (which is expressed in $/MWh), being the number of hours in a year as noted earlier in equation (5), and the revenue escalation factor. The value for , which will also exactly equals ̅ , is a vitally important one as it also defines the ‘missing money’15 in an energy-only market under conditions of intense competition and perfect plant divisibility and availability as Section 6 later demonstrates. It also represents a useful benchmark in helping to establish potential presence of market power abuse and barriers to entry. 5. Model Results – Generalised Long Run Marginal Cost of Power Generation Our PF Model results rely quite crucially on the engineering estimates of capital and maintenance costs of plant. These key variables along with fuel market costs are set out in Table 1. Note that the parameters have been derived from Worley Parsons (2012), ACIL Tasman (2012) and Frontier Economics (2013) who produce these estimates for the independent market operator (AEMO) and for New South Wales’ independent economic regulator (IPART). The term ‘missing money’ was first discussed by Cramton and Stoft (2006), and later Joskow (2006), and describes a situation whereby market price caps (set low to constrain market power) adversely affect average clearing prices thus resulting in inadequate returns to investors in generation plant. Steed and Laybutt (2011) identify c.$6 billion in ‘missing money’ in the NEM from 20002010 even with a market price cap of $10,000/MWh. 15 Page 12 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Table 1: Engineering & Cost Parameters Model Variable Unit i= Black Coal Black Coal Brown Coal CCGT Wind OCGT QLD NSW VIC VIC SA QLD NSW Plant Capacity MW k 1000 1000 1000 400 400 400 400 Capacity Factor % CF 90.0 90.0 90.0 85.0 85.0 85.0 85.0 Auxillary Load % Aux 6.0 6.0 7.0 3.0 3.0 3.0 3.0 Thermal Efficiency % ζ 39.0 39.0 28.0 50.0 50.0 50.0 50.0 Raw Fuel $/GJ F 1.00 1.42 0.40 5.00 7.00 8.00 8.50 Variable O&M $/MWh v 1.28 1.28 0.10 4.08 4.08 4.08 4.08 Fixed O&M $/MW f 52,768 52,768 36,700 10,188 10,188 10,188 10,188 Combustion Emissions kg CO2 /GJ ġ 90.2 90.2 92.0 50.6 50.6 50.6 50.6 Fugituive Emissions kg CO2 /GJ ĝ 8.7 8.7 8.7 18.6 18.6 18.6 18.6 Carbon Price $/t CP 7.50 7.50 7.50 7.50 7.50 7.50 7.50 Capital Cost $/kW X 2,500 2,500 3,000 1,200 1,200 1,200 1,200 Capital Works $ '000 x 5,000 5,000 5,000 2,000 2,000 2,000 2,000 Useful Life Years L 40 40 40 30 30 30 30 Sources: Worley Parsons (2012), ACIL Tasman (2012), Frontier Economics (2013) CCGT CCGT CCGT NEM 200 37.5 1.0 n/a n/a 12.23 40,750 7.50 2,000 1,000 25 NEM 450 n/a 1.0 35.0 8.00 10.19 4,075 50.1 5.7 7.50 783 1,000 30 In addition to these parameters, we also require financial and economic parameters, which are presented in Table 2. Table 2: Financial Economic Parameters Model Variable Unit Inflation % CPI Risk Free Rate % Rf Market Risk Premium (Rf-Rm) % MRP 2.5 5.8 6.1 Generation Asset Beta # βa 0.73 Equity Beta Factor VI # βVI 1.05 Equity Beta Factor IPP # βIPP 1.58 Tax Rate % τc 30.0 Effective Tax Rate % τe 21.3 5Yr Interest Rate Swap % RT 3.6 12Yr Interest Rate Swap % RT 4.5 PF Credit Spread (5 Yr) bps CT 250 PF Credit Spread (12 Yr) bps CT 300 BBB Credit Spread (5 Yr) bps CT 180 BBB Credit Spread (12 Yr) bps CT 225 BBB Credit (FFO/I) times δVI 4.0/5.0 BBB Credit (FFO/D) times ωVI 0.2 DSCR & LLCR times δIPP 1.8-2.2 Sources: PWC (2013), Gray (2013a, 2013b), Simshauser and Nelson (2013). In Figure 3 we present the stylised cost of capital for merchant generation. Debt costs are largely based on 7-12 year bond pricing for varying credit quality. Note the range for project finance runs from about 50-67.5% (and by chance the results are currently equivalent to bond pricing +/15 basis points). We consider the cost of equity to be largely sticky at our long run calculated value for for any credit quality below BBB and do not contemplate credit ratings beyond Adue to inherent industry risk, otherwise varies according to our Asset Beta. This is based on judgement, and a lack of practical evidence to the contrary. Note that the Weighted Average Cost of Capital is notionally minimised at a BBB credit rating. Page 13 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Figure 3: Stylised cost of capital for merchant generation Combining the parameters in Tables 1 and 2 with equations (3) – (22) in our PF model produces generalised long run marginal cost estimates for multiple plant types in total dollars and on a unit cost basis – the latter being more useful for any subsequent comparative analysis. In Figure 4, we present the model results on a unit cost basis under the financing conditions historically activated by merchant power producers using project finance to either develop or acquire a power project for each technology i. Figure 4: PF Model generalised long run marginal cost estimates – Project Financing At the bottom of each bar in Figure 4 the “per cent” result relates to the gearing level achievable under energy market equilibrium conditions. So for example, the Black Coal Queensland (QLD) plant has 65 per cent debt within the capital structure. The bars are comprised of the individual cost elements of the plant, starting with Unit Fuel Costs , Unit Carbon Costs ( ) through Page 14 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research to the Unit Cost of Equity, all of which is expressed in dollars per Megawatt Hour ($/MWh). At the top of each bar is the PF Model’s calculated unit price in which the IRR of the project exactly equals the cost of equity while simultaneously meeting all binding credit metrics specified in equation (17) using the Table 2 parameters. To be clear, is also the generalised long run marginal cost or entry cost for each individual technology. Note also that these unit costs also represent market equilibrium or the ‘centre of gravity’ for base load futures contract prices over the long run given an optimal stock and mix of plant. The unit cost of an Open Cycle Peaking (OCGT) plant is expressed as the ‘carrying cost of capacity’ or ̅ for reasons identified in Section 4.2. Our alternate business combination results are presented in Figure 5 and arise from producing generalised estimates for plant that have been financed ‘on-balance sheet’ by an entity with an investment-grade credit rating. The structural changes to unit costs in this instance are limited to capital and taxation, and this is primarily due to binding constraints in equation (17). For ease of comparison, we have included the headline Project Finance results from Figure 4 as the black diamond markers in Figure 5. What this analysis illustrates is that there is no marked benefit in either structure, with the exception of wind plant.16 Note however that wind farms are assumed to be backed by an investment-grade Power Purchase Agreement, and thus use different credit metrics (i.e. a DSCR equal to 1.35x which enables substantially higher gearing) and a constant value for (i.e. equivalent to the horizontal section of the curve in Figure 3). Figure 5: PF Model generalised long run marginal cost estimates – Balance Sheet Financing From this one would conclude that all wind turbines should be project financed rather than financed on-balance sheet. However, our PF Model has one significant limitation in this regard – it does not model portfolios of plant at the enterprise level. In practice, credit rating agencies treat half of the PPA’s present value as ‘synthetic debt’ on the balance sheet of the counterparty who writes the instrument. This in turn has a real opportunity cost to vertically integrated firms – since their level of total corporate debt must be modified downwards accordingly, and so the apparent gains from writing PPAs over balance sheet financings are partially illusory. 16 Although as Nelson and Simshauser (2013) argue, greenfield merchant power project financings are not currently plausible. Page 15 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research 6. Application to policymaking Understanding Normal Profit and the long run marginal cost of production is clearly important for investment decision-making. In our experience, firms in the energy industry use a framework that is consistent with that presented in Sections 3 and 4 and extend the revenue lines with power system simulation modelling and so it is not necessary to elaborate further. However, the investment decisions of firms in fixed power assets in the energy industry are influenced quite fundamentally by policy settings – again in our opinion, more so than many other industries given the role of electricity in the economy and the political economy of electricity tariffs. As such, understanding Normal Profit is important as it will frequently form a pivot point in policy formulation and regulatory settings. Industry and consumer groups, and in some instances politicians themselves, have sought to change NEM market policies, rules and regulations based on perceived levels of supranormal profits gained or economic losses incurred in both the wholesale and retail markets. 6.1 Wholesale market benchmark Severe price spikes in gross pool, energy-only, uniform first-price auction wholesale markets typically form a trigger for regulatory inquiry. For policymakers, intervention may be warranted if supranormal profits are being extracted on a sustained basis through generator bidding behaviour in the presence of demonstrable barriers to entry. But episodes of transient price spikes in wholesale markets should not represent an ‘automatic’ trigger for inquiry let alone policy intervention given the nature of energy-only markets. The reason for this is quite simple. There is no stable equilibrium in energy-only markets given a market price cap and a reliability constraint due to the substantial fixed and sunk costs associated with power generation. This can be demonstrated theoretically and through power system simulation modelling. Proposition I: In an intensely competitive energy-only market with a uniform first-price auction clearing mechanism and perfect plant divisibility and availability, aggregate revenues for the optimal plant mix and for any number of optimal plant technologies will fall short by at least the carrying cost of peaking plant capacity, ̅ . Let the ith plant have marginal running costs of and total fixed and sunk costs (including the opportunity cost of capital) of ̅ . Let price in period be set on the basis of a uniform, first price clearing auction such that the short run marginal cost of the marginal plant sets price. The intercept between plant n and n+1 occurs when: ̅ ̅ (23) Rearranging this becomes: ̅ ̅ ( ) (24) Under any optimal plant mix for any number of optimal plant technologies, aggregate revenues will always fall short by at least ̅ . We provide a mathematical proof for Proposition I in Appendix II and present a static partial equilibrium analysis in Figure 6 and applied results in Table 3 using our modelling outcomes from Section 5. This helps to explains the importance of our approach to modelling peaking plant and in particular, the use of equation (22) which solves for ̅ . The concept that power system revenues will fall short by fixed capacity costs ̅ when clearing prices are set to marginal cost has long been understood by energy economists and can be traced back to Electrcitie de France’s then Chief Economist Marcel Boiteux, and his groundbreaking article on peak load pricing in electricity wholesale markets (Boiteux, 1949). The framework developed by Central Electricity Generating Board of England & Wales’ Chief Economist, Tom Berrie, provides an especially useful static partial equilibrium model of a power Page 16 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research system which demonstrates this – although note that we have added a third (Price Duration) chart to Berrie’s (1967) two-chart framework using our Section 5 results from Figure 4. Figure 6: Static Partial Equilibrium Model (ex-carbon): Victorian Region FY13 Page 17 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Figure 6.1 illustrates the Marginal Running Cost Curves of the three generating technologies for base (brown coal), semi-base (CCGT) and peaking (OCGT) duties. The y-axis intercept for each technology represents the fixed and sunk costs ( ̅ ), and the slope of the curves represents marginal running costs ( ). The x-axis measures plant capacity factor from equation (5). Note intercepts and identify the point at which the most efficient plant switches to the next technology, given the rich blend of fixed and variable costs in line with equation (24). Figure 6.2 illustrates a Load Duration Curve. This is a representation of the 17,520 half-hourly electricity load points in a year but ranked in descending order rather than as a time-series, with the y-axis measuring electricity load (MW) and the x-axis measuring ‘time exceeded’.17 Figure 6.3 is the corresponding Price Duration Curve, that is, the spot price set in each half-hour period in Figure 6.2 under the conditions of a gross pool, energy-only, uniform first-price auction clearing mechanism, with the y-axis measuring price and the x-axis also measuring ‘time exceeded’. The Figure 6 static partial equilibrium model assumes firms are free to install perfectly divisible plant capacity with perfect plant availability (and hence no requirement for a reserve plant margin) in any combination that satisfies differentiable equilibrium conditions. The model also assumes a perfect transmission system and hence no constraints on the economic order of plant dispatch. Table 3 sets out all energy production and cost results and notes that the system average spot price of $55.43/MWh (i.e. the average of results in Figure 6.3) falls short of system average cost of $66.04/MWh by the amount equivalent to ̅ – that is, $10.60/MWh (per Figure 4). Table 3: Static Partial Equilibrium Results given Perfect Plant & Transmission System Availability Plant Type Capacity Production Fixed Costs (MW) (GWh) ($m) Brown Coal 4,853 38,167 1,957 CCGT 1,544 9,067 267 OCGT 3,191 1,968 290 Total 9,588 49,202 2,514 Average Spot Price Diff (Avg Unit Cost less Avg Spot Price) Running Costs ($m) 200 363 172 735 Total Costs ($m) 2,157 630 462 3,249 Avg Unit Cost ($/MWh) 56.52 69.50 234.61 66.04 55.43 10.60 CF j i (%) 90 67 7 59 Once the assumptions of perfect plant divisibility and availability are relaxed, Average Unit Cost can be expected to rise, and Average Spot Price can be expected to fall, as discrete power plant blocks are added (i.e. lumpy plant entry) and requisite excess capacity (i.e. additional OCGT plant) is purposefully added to ensure power system reliability constraints are met. Simultaneously, a Value of Lost Load or Market Price Cap is introduced (i.e. the spot price that applies during shortages) and in the NEM is $13,100/MWh. This offsets some, but not all, additional costs and only if the optimal number of blackouts occurs annually within the reliability constraint as Simshauser (2008) demonstrates. 6.2 Discussion The key issue arising from the quantitative plant-specific results in Section 5 and the aggregate industry result from Section 6.1 is that even with the perfectly optimal plant mix and a zero reserve margin, no plant has any prospect of earning Normal Profits when conditions reflect intense competition. From a policymaking perspective, the question that follows is does this actually matter? After all, traditional welfare economics commences with the presumption that economic efficiency is maximised when prices are set at marginal cost. However, the model of perfect competition also assumes constant or decreasing returns to scale and that clearing prices result in Normal Profits to efficient firms. 17 In this instance, live FY13 half-hourly load data from the Victorian region has been used. Page 18 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research In industries with increasing returns to scale, where fixed and sunk costs are non-trivial, and where marginal costs are very low (or zero in the case of renewable energy18), clearly a problem exists as Figure 6 and Table 3 demonstrate. Varian (1996) notes that under such conditions, persistent uniform pricing at industry short run marginal cost is not economically viable. In a terminal industry, this may not warrant further consideration. But the electricity industry is not terminal as evidenced by the level of plant availability in the NEM. While it is true that electricity demand has contracted marginally over the past 3-4 years, longer run projections exhibit mild but nonetheless positive growth. Furthermore, existing plant is aging and will one day need replacement, and new plant will be required to meet renewable policy objectives. Accordingly, policymakers cannot ignore how fixed and sunk costs are treated by policy changes. It is not the role of policymakers to deliver profits to power companies. Nor however is it their role to set policies that constrain the ability of firms to earn Normal Profit over the business cycle. How does this translate into practice? Section 6.3 provides a useful applied example but in summary, spot price outcomes in an intensely competitive energy-only market with a reliability constraint cannot be considered a pragmatic benchmark for which to devise policy settings. Generators persistently bidding at marginal running costs will result in prices that clear below system average cost as Figure 6 and Table 3 demonstrate. Simshauser (2008) demonstrated that when the assumptions of perfect plant divisibility and availability are relaxed, there is not a stable equilibrium that will calibrate supply to demand in a manner consistent with stated reliability standards in the long run (absent extremely high market price caps). Further, as Bidwell and Henney (2004, p22) explain, even with high wholesale market price caps, a stable financial equilibrium could only be reached if the physical power system is operating ‘near the edge of collapse’. At some point generator bidding must deviate from short run marginal cost or blackout-induced Market Price Cap events must increase in frequency. Benchmarks for policymaking must therefore turn to plant and fleet-wide generalised long run marginal cost estimates, respectively. 6.3 Application to wholesale markets Mountain (2013) concludes that the imposition of carbon pricing from 2012 improved the profitability of all generators, with wholesale prices more than doubling and gains extracted after power generators exercised market power in the NEM. The analysis compared spot prices over a nine month period before and after the carbon policy change – nine months being the limit of data available at the time. This type of analysis can be reproduced – Table 4 draws on the relevant spot market data from the independent market operator, using Victorian region data as an example.19 Table 4: Victorian average spot prices Period-on-Period Change (FY12 vs. FY13) Month Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec Jan Feb Mar Avg FY13 Spot Incl. CO2 ($/MWh) 73.46 55.76 53.48 51.27 77.18 52.18 54.27 53.59 52.31 58.17 CO2 Price Average Carbon FY13 Adj. FY12 Spot Spot Price Intensity Excl. CO2 Pre- CO2 Difference ($/t) (CO2 /MWh) ($/MWh) ($/MWh) ($/MWh) 23.00 1.166 46.65 29.49 17.16 23.00 1.182 28.57 29.95 -1.38 23.00 1.213 25.58 26.98 -1.40 23.00 1.225 23.09 23.61 -0.52 23.00 1.244 48.57 26.58 21.99 23.00 1.258 23.25 22.18 1.07 23.00 1.237 25.81 24.03 1.78 23.00 1.187 26.29 25.85 0.44 23.00 1.221 24.24 23.70 0.54 23.00 1.215 30.23 25.82 4.41 Source: AEMO. 18 While many renewable energy technologies have zero or negligible fuel costs, Biomass plant is a notable exception. Mountain (2013) analyses production-weighted spot prices for all generation plant types. Here, we focus on the time-weighted spot price in Victoria and compare these with our estimates of brown coal plant costs. Mountain’s (2013) FY13 production-weighted price is $58/MWh and FY12 is $26/MWh – which is consistent with the result in Table 4 (results in columns 1 and 5). 19 Page 19 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research The time-weighted average spot price for the first nine months of FY13 in Table 4 is $58.17/MWh and the Carbon Adjusted FY13 spot price (column 5) averages $30.23/MWh. This adjusted price has been derived by stripping the estimated carbon impact (i.e. CO2 price x Average Carbon Intensity) from FY13 spot prices, such that $58.17 – ($23/t x 1.215t) = $30.23MWh.20 The final column compares the adjusted FY13 spot price with the FY12 spot price, which results in a difference of $4.41/MWh. This differential is identified as a gain to the profitability of generators since wholesale price rises exceeded carbon costs.21 Mountain (2013) concluded that such an outcome is not consistent with a competitive market, while the Energy Users Association of Australia added that the regulator should be granted greater scrutiny over generator bidding.22 There are many reasons why a regulator might be granted greater scrutiny over generator bidding – but our Table 4 analysis does not comprise one of them as it over-simplifies a very complex set of spot market outcomes. It ignores the role and effects of (1) short run weather on aggregate demand, (2) generator outages on aggregate supply, and (3) volumetric losses of individual plants – all of which are known to be non-trivial. Above all though is the suitability of the initial benchmark. Using this analysis in Table 4 is, in our opinion, wrong in economics for the reasons outlined in Section 6.2. Using a Period-on-Period unit price benchmark that is demonstrably below system average cost, or worse still, equal to system short run marginal cost in an industry with substantial fixed and sunk costs runs a high risk of producing a Type II error as Figure 6 and Table 3 demonstrate. Table 3 noted that the perfectly optimal plant mix for Victoria would produce aggregate annual costs (including Normal Profit) of $3,249 million. The FY12 spot price from Table 4 was $25.82 and annual output from Table 3 was 49,202GWh meaning that total spot revenues earned by plant was $1,270 million. As a result during the ‘base year’ of the analysis, generators incurred economic losses (compared to spot prices) of at least $1,900 million.23 Regardless, a nine month period is too short to draw meaningful conclusions on the levels of industry competition and profits of a fleet of capital-intensive power stations with useful lives spanning several decades. The Table 4 analysis lacks a pragmatic and theoretically robust Normal Profit benchmark. The application of Sections 3 and 4 along with the parameters from Section 5 can however provide suitable insights. We have re-run the PF Model under conditions of a zero carbon price for the relevant base plant in Victoria. We also analyse the financial viability of highly efficient new entrants in the PF Model whereby the unit price is set as an input equivalent to the FY12 value in Table 3 rather than that derived by equation (21). Figure 7 illustrates these results. This assumes the carbon price was passed-through at the industry’s average carbon intensity for the reasons explained Nelson, Orton and Kelley (2012). One implication of this is that all brown coal generators are incurring losses on carbon costs because their CO 2 intensities of 1.28t – 1.55t/MWh are above the average intensity of 1.215t/MWh. 21 See in particular Mountain (2013, p.24). 22 See in particular the EUAA Media Statement “Power generation prices need closer monitoring” – released 27 June 2013. Available at www.euaa.com.au. 23 In reality, hedge contracts struck at higher values in preceding periods would have reduced these loses materially. On the other hand, the Victorian region is currently oversupplied and as such economic losses would have been greater than implied given the additional capital stock deployed. 20 Page 20 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Figure 7: Comparison of generalised long run marginal costs with Table 4 FY12 spot prices The horizontal line in Figure 7 represents the FY12 actual spot price of $25.82/MWh. This is then compared with brown coal and CCGT plant entrants under the two business combinations, project finance (PF) and a vertically integrated entity (VI) using BBB credit-rated debt. The first two bars show the brown coal result for PF and VI, while the second two bars show the equivalent results for a CCGT plant. The final two bars illustrate the financial out-workings that coal plant (i.e. the lowest cost entrant excluding CO2) would face if exposed to a convergent electricity price of $25.82/MWh. From inspection of the final two bars in Figure 7 it is evident that the Brown Coal PF plant is completely bankrupt and unable to pay its interest expense, let alone the principal. There are no equity returns whatsoever. The Brown Coal VI plant, due to its substantially lower gearing level, is theoretically able to withstand such a price and, assuming its BBB credit rating is held constant, retains its financial stability. In reality the credit rating will have been stripped (meaning debt covenants will have been breached requiring remedy), no taxation will be paid (due to the plant making sizable taxation losses) and the running cash yield would equate to 1.8% compared to 10.0% when the plant is earning a Normal Profit. Our quantitative results in Figure 7 make it clear that quasi-rents (partial contributions to fixed costs) commence when prices exceed $28-$35/MWh. But at any price below $53/MWh, brown coal generators are incurring ‘economic losses’. For a CCGT plant with gas supplied at $5/GJ, short run marginal costs are not recovered until prices exceed $40/MWh, let alone fixed cost recovery. Our generalised cost estimates paint a radically different picture to that expressed in Table 4 in which competition is thought to be inadequate with generators extracting windfall gains. How should a policymaker react to such conflicting information? Real world events that occurred in the period immediately preceding the carbon tax provide the appropriate guidance. The two largest brown coal plants in Victoria, Loy Yang24 and Hazelwood25 were both recipients 24 AGL Energy acquired 100% of the 2200MW Loy Yang power station and coal mine in June 2012. The implied enterprise value was $3.1 billion or $1410/kW. AGL Energy raised $1.5 billion from the debt and equity capital markets of which $1.2 billion was Page 21 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research of emergency recapitalisations in June 2012 – of $1.2 billion and $650 million respectively. Absent this, in our professional opinion (and noting that the first author is the former Chairman of Loy Yang during FY09-FY10), both plants would have experienced financial collapse. Structural adjustment assistance packages were issued to brown coal plant by the Commonwealth Government in an attempt to moderate the most acute effects of the carbon price implementation.26 Yet in spite of this, ex post emergency recapitalisations were still necessary. Loy Yang for example incurred an equity write-off of c.$400 million or 40+% of the postacquisition equity value of $950 million – and this was after accounting for structural adjustment assistance. The third largest brown coal plant in Victoria, Yallourn also incurred write-downs of $245 million.27 These write-offs at the three largest brown coal plants occurred because of a legal obligation Company Directors have to ensure that asset values are reported as fair and reasonable under Sections 295-29728 of Australia’s Corporations Act 2001 (Cth). Our observation is that these outcomes were not a surprise to the industry. Table 4 noted that spot electricity prices in the pre-carbon environment were $25.82/MWh. They had in fact averaged about $27 throughout FY11 and FY12, and as a result, many plants were in the early stages of financial distress. That the incumbent plants lasted almost two years without defaulting on project debt was due to commodity hedge contracts signed in prior years under considerably more favourable market circumstances. However, as these hedge contracts progressively matured and were replaced with lower value hedge contracts, emergency recapitalisations became essential. Using the Table 4 FY12 spot price result of $25.82 as an efficient benchmark and concluding subsequent changes represented evidence of inadequate competition and windfall gains, while those prices were simultaneously driving generators to a state of financial collapse, is not credible. Figure 7 demonstrates that our Table 4 analysis uses the wrong benchmark over the wrong timeframe and as a consequence, draws the wrong conclusion. During FY13, the carbon price could be said to have been transmitted at a pass-through rate of 116% of the average industry CO2 intensity29 - but only after holding all other variables strictly constant. That is, given a carbon price of $23/t, and emissions intensity of 1.215t/MWh, one might expect an increase of ($23/t x 1.215t =) $27.94/MWh whereas FY13 spot prices increased by $32.35/MWh to $58.17/MWh. So under these conditions, generator losses could be said to be lower than in FY12 provided their output levels are held constant (although data from the independent market operator reveals a substantial contraction in brown coal production, from 39,856 GWh to 34,112 GWh).30 Figure 8 illustrates the comparative impact with the PF Model run using a $23/t carbon price. used to recapitalise the project’s existing debt tranches. There is little doubt that when those debt tranches matured, refinancing would have only been partially successful and additional equity injections would have been required. 25 The parent entity of Hazelwood power station, GDF Suez, injected $650m of ‘rescue capital’ into its project debt structure using an intercompany loan during the last week of June 2012. Hazelwood had been unable to secure bank funding. For further details, see the Australian Financial Review at http://www.afr.com/p/national/rescue_for_power_station_xk639CP4CyQuJIp9ndewYP 26 See Mountain (2013) for details of the structural adjustment assistance. 27 See CLP Group Financial Results (27 February 2012) for details. Available at https://www.clpgroup.com/. 28 Sections 296 and 297 in particular require the application of Australian Accounting Standard AASB136 – Impairment of Assets. Failure to account for a fair and reasonable carrying value of fixed assets exposes Company Directors to penalties under the Corporations Act 2001 (Cth), which include monetary fines and jail terms. 29 While the CO2 average intensity of the Victorian region is 1.215t/MWh, the fleet average CO2 intensity of the brown coal fleet is closer to 1.37t/MWh as Simshauser and Doan (2009) demonstrate. Accordingly, the fleet pass-through rate could be thought of as 103% rather than 116%, again holding all other variables strictly constant. 30 The apparent price premium of $4.41/MWh, when applied to the nine-month FY13 energy output of 34,112 GWh results in an apparent ‘windfall gain’ of $150 million. However, the loss of output from FY12 to FY13 (of 39,856 GWh less 34,112 GWh) at the so-called break-even pass-through price of ($58.17 less $4.41/MWh) results in an even greater offsetting loss of $309 million. This result further undermines the Table 4 analysis. Page 22 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Figure 8: Generalised long run marginal costs vs. Table 4 FY13 carbon-inclusive spot prices In this instance, the Normal Profit benchmarks change substantially, with brown coal plant rising to $85-88/MWh, and CCGT plant at $72-$74/MWh. In a post-carbon price analysis, once again, there is no evidence that windfall profits are being extracted. The final two bars in Figure 8 focus on CCGT plant as they represent the optimal plant for base duties given a price on carbon. The CCGT PF plant in Figure 8 is in manifest breach of its financing covenants – unable to repay its full interest cost let alone principal repayment. The CCGT VI is however able to financially withstand the lower price as was its Brown Coal VI counterpart in Figure 7 – although again the firm would be stripped of its investment grade credit rating and would be in breach of debt covenants. The running cash yield of the plant is just 0.2% compared to 11.2% when the plant is producing Normal Profits. One potential criticism of the analysis thus far is that the examination of market power occurs ex post. However, analysing the price of call option contracts from the futures market provides ex ante guidance. In particular, if market power abuse is present then we would expect to see sustained increases in the price of $300 call option contracts across the three-year forward curve at levels above our unit estimate for ̅ . But as with our analysis of base prices, year-ahead futures prices for $300 call options in Victoria during 2013 were $4.35/MWh – less than half of our unit value for ̅ of $10.47/MWh. Once again, there is little evidence of windfall gains. 6.4 Retail Markets A pragmatic approach to the measurement of Normal Profit in power generation also has an important relevance to retail electricity markets since the cost of power generation forms an important part of the overall headline retail tariff. An example to illustrate the application of our constructs to policymaking involved the determination of an ‘electricity price cap’ for rival retailers in New South Wales. In determining the generalised long run marginal cost of power generation, considerable effort was expended by the independent regulator on arriving at suitable engineering plant and fuel cost estimates, along with credible evidence on the cost of capital from the capital markets. However, once the data had been collated, two incompatible variables were (inadvertently) fused in determining the relevant cost of capital, viz. the use of an investmentPage 23 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research grade credit rating and associated credit margins from the corporate bond market, and the use of gearing levels more suited to a project finance. Table 5 presents an analysis of our global database of project financings which covers 1953 transactions, 3,772 tranches of debt commencing from the first power project financing in 1981 through to the time of writing in mid-2013, across 89 countries. Of these, only 7.6% of transactions had a parent company guarantee and only a portion of these parent companies would have investment grade credit ratings.31 The implication here is that project financings will not involve credit-rated debt, and so project debt margins will, ceteris paribus, be higher than that associated with investment-grade bond issuance. This was the result of misinterpreting the capital structure constraints facing the business combinations. Table 5: Analysis of project finance deal metrics (real 2013 AUD) Period Issuance (A$m) Global - 89 Countries 1981-2006 555,703 2007-2013 490,103 Total 1,045,806 Australia 1994-2006 2007-2013 Total 8,913 16,513 25,426 Deals (#) Tranches (#) Tenor Avg Spread (Yrs) (bps) 784 1,169 1,953 1,441 2,331 3,772 10.4 12.1 10.9 133 262 187 32 28 60 49 44 93 10 6 8 113 287 244 The impact of such a decision in policy formulation can be readily quantified through analysing its impact on the Weighted Average Cost of Capital, which we define in Appendix III. In this instance, the capital structure was assumed to comprise 50% debt at a spread of 260bps. The spread for a BBB corporate bond was appropriate at that time based on observed data, but the gearing level was not. As Figure 5 demonstrated earlier, a black coal plant in NSW could only sustain gearing levels of about 32% and retain an investment-grade credit rating. The PF Model is able to compute the generalised long run marginal cost after relaxing the credit rating constraint, and impute an estimate given a 50% gearing level – the results of which are illustrated in Figure 9. Note that the differential between the two scenarios equates to $4.29/MWh, and in a market with total consumer load of 20,100 GWh pa, had a c.$88 million consequence. To be sure, once the issue was highlighted to the NSW regulator, the framework was suitably modified at the next pricing reset. 31 Our database shows all transactions listed in Reuters from 1981 through to June 2013. However, our data on guarantors only covers 1080 transactions. Of these 1080 transactions, 70 or 6.48% involved a guarantor – and it was not clear that those guarantors necessarily had a credit rating in any event. Page 24 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Figure 9: Generalised long run marginal cost – with and without credit rating constraints 7. Concluding Remarks Policymakers and regulators governing competitive power markets, particularly those based on a gross pool, energy-only market designs as exists in Australia, Texas, New Zealand, Singapore, Alberta (Canada) and Europe amongst others, face an interesting dilemma. Our Proposition I and associated static partial equilibrium model in Section 6 demonstrates that under conditions of intense competition, perfect plant availability and divisibility with no transmission constraints, energy-only markets result in clearing prices which are not economically viable in the long run. When these simplifying assumptions are relaxed, things get worse, not better. One option, operating a power system on ‘the edge of collapse’ as Bidwell and Henney (2004, p22) explain, is not politically viable. This means that bidding must, by definition, deviate from strict (short run) marginal cost at some stage. The judgement of the regulator is to determine whether deviations represent a sustained departure in the presence of barriers to entry and are a potential abuse of market power, or whether it merely represents quasi rents and a partial inter-temporal contribution towards substantial fixed and sunk costs. All too often, regulatory inquiry is static and ignores the essential time dimension. Policymakers in Australia and the regulator in Alberta (respectively) clearly understand this balance: Without affording electricity generators the opportunity to submit dispatch bids or rebids above marginal cost, new capacity would fail to enter the market and the market would become vulnerable to periods of inadequate supply. Wholesale market price volatility and the ability of electricity generators to- from time to time- offer electricity into the market at prices above marginal cost (sometimes even as high as the market price cap) is entirely consistent with the design of the NEM… (AEMC, 2013, p. 65) …wholesale price volatility and price polarity (periods of low prices interspersed with shorter periods of high prices) are an expected outcome in an electricity market such as Alberta’s and consistent with effective competition. In fact, these price signals promote innovation and economic efficiency… (MSA, 2012, p.1). Page 25 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Two important inputs to the judgement required of policymakers and regulators were presented in Sections 3 and 4 – the cost of equity and the long run marginal cost of generation plant, which culminate in a theoretically robust measure of Normal Profit as a suitable ‘benchmark’ for which to gauge activity over the business cycle. We found that when using the CAPM in atypical capital market conditions, a mechanistic approach will produce intuitively erroneous results. Longer-run average values were found to provide for more credible outcomes but should nonetheless be tested against best-estimates for marginal capital raisings to ensure they are reasonable. There is a wealth of investment banking experience available to policymakers and regulators to draw upon if in doubt. It is also important to ensure that the capital structure of the reference ‘business combination’ is tractable – if the credit spreads on debt are based on an investment grade company, the gearing level selected must also reflect the credit constraints of such a credit rating. Our PF Model focused on two business combinations and found that there was little difference in the ultimate long run marginal cost estimate, although the differences in the thresholds for bankruptcy were marked. This analysis was then applied in an ex post analysis of base energy prices against pragmatic estimates for the long run marginal cost of base plant, and an ex ante analysis of call option prices against the carrying cost of peaking plant, using Victoria as a case in point. Prima facie it may be tempting to argue that our Normal Profit benchmark is overstated because it ignores the fact that the actual plant mix is different from optimality, or that existing plant is aged/depreciated or holds special resource endowments (such as long-dated fuel contracts at below market rates). On the other hand, existing plant owners may argue that our benchmark understates the real costs of existing businesses which were developed or acquired at higher cost (i.e. when turbine prices were higher in real terms) or fail to account for the industrial/labour market constraints. Neither set of arguments holds in the long run. If profit benchmarks are raised to inefficient levels and new entrants do not enter and compete away the available supranormal profit over the business cycle, then material barriers to entry may exist and policy intervention may be warranted where market power is being exercised. On the other hand, if profit benchmarks are set to suboptimal levels, neither incumbents nor entrants will find it profitable in the long run which has implications for reliability and an inevitable (and typically unwelcome) price correction of significance over time. Ultimately, a pragmatic Normal Profit benchmark must be forward looking, not only with respect to the cost of capital, but of what capital needs to be deployed to meet incremental demand or replace retiring plant. 8. References ACIL Tasman, (2012), “Fuel cost projections”, Report to AEMO, ACIL Tasman Publication, Brisbane. Available at www.aemo.com.au AEMC: Australian Energy Market Comission, (2012), “Rule Determination – National Electricity Amendment (Economic Regulation of Network Service Providers) Rule 2012”, AEMC Publication Sydney. Available at www.aemc.gov.au AEMC: Australian Energy Market Commission (2013), “Final Rule Determination: potential generator market power in the NEM”, AEMC Publication, Sydney. Available at www.aemc.gov.au Berrie, T. (1967), “The economics of system planning in bulk electricity supply”, Electrical Review, 22(2): 425-428. Page 26 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Besser, J., Farr, J. and Tierney, S. (2002), “The political economy of long-term generation adequacy: why an ICAP mechanism is needed as part of standard market design”, Electricity Journal, 15(7): 53-62. Bidwell, M. and Henney, A. (2004), “Will Neta ensure generation adequacy?”, Power UK, 122:10-26. Boiteux, M. (1949), “La tarification des demandes en pointe: Application de la theorie de la vente au cout marginal”, Revue Generale de l’Electricite, Translated by H. Izzard in Journal of Business, Boiteux, M. 1960, ‘Peak load pricing’, Journal of Business, 33(2): 157–80. Brealey, R., Myers, S. and Allen, F. (2011), Principles of Corporate Finance, Second Edition, McGraw Hill, Sydney. Bushnell, J. (2005), “Electricity Resource Adequacy: matching policies and goals”, Electricity Journal, 18(8): 11-21. Cramton P. and Stoft, S. (2006), “The convergence of market designs for adequate generating capacity with special attention to the CAISOs resource adequacy problem”, Cambridge, MA: Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research. Cannavan, D., Finn, F. and Gray, S. (2004), “The value of dividend imputation tax credits in Australia”, Journal of Financial Economics, 73(2004): 167-197. De Vries, L. (2003), “The instability of energy-only electricity markets”, Research Symposium: European Electricity Markets, The Hague, September 2003. de Vries, L. (2004), “Securing the public interest in electricity generation markets, the myths of the invisible hand and the copper plate”, PhD Dissertation, Delft University of Technology, The Netherlands. de Vries, L. And Heijnen, P. (2008), “The impact of electricity market design upon investment under uncertainty: the effectiveness of capacity mechanisms”, Utilities Policy, 16(2008): 215-227. Finon, D. (2008), “Investment risk allocation in decentralised markets: the need of long-term contracts and vertical integration”, OPEC Energy Review, 32(2): 150-183. Finon, D. and Pignon, V. (2008), “Electricity and long-term capacity adequacy: the quest for regulatory mechanisms compatible with electricity markets”, Utilities Policy, 16(2008): 143-158. Fama, E. and French, R. (1997), “Industry costs or equity”, Journal of Financial Economics, 43(1997): 153-193. Frontier Economics, (2013), “Input assumptions for modelling wholesale electricity costs - draft report prepared for IPART”, Frontier Economics Publication, April, Melbourne. Gray, S. (2013a), “Evidence on the required return on equity from independent expert reports”, SFG Consulting, Mimeo., Brisbane. Gray, S. (2013b), “The required return on equity since the global financial crisis”, SFG Consulting, Mimeo., Brisbane. Hathaway, N. and Officer, R. (2004), “The value of imputation tax credits”, available at http://www.agl.com.au/Downloads/050427_App-1-Imputation-Tax-Credits%E2%80%93Hathaway-andOfficer_Corporate_Government-Submissions.pdf IPART: Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal, (2013), “WACC Methodology”, IPART publication, Sydney. Available at www.ipart.nsw.gov.au Joskow, P. (2006), “Competitive electricity markets and investment in new generating capacity”, AEIBrookings Joint Centre for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper No.06-14. Page 27 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Joskow, P. (2008a), “Lessons learned from electricity market liberalisation”, The Energy Journal, 29(2): 942. Joskow, P. (2008b), “Capacity payments in imperfect electricity markets: need and design”, Utilities Policy, 16(2008): 159-170. Lintner, J. (1965), “The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investment in stock portfolios and capital budgets”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 47(Feb): 13-37. MSA: Market Surveillance Administrator, (2012), State of the Market Report 2012, MSA Publication, 10 December 2012. Monkhouse, P. (1993), “The Cost of Equity under the Australian Imputation Tax System”, Journal of Accounting and Finance, November, pp. 1-18. Mountain, B. (2013), “The impact of emission prices on electricity prices in the National Electricity Market”, Carbon Market Economics Publication, Melbourne. Available at www.carbonmarkets.com.au Accessed 20 June 2013. Nelson, T., Orton, F. and Kelley, S. (2012), “A literature review of economic studies on carbon pricing and Australian wholesale electricity markets”, Energy Policy, 49(Oct): 217-224 Nelson, J. and Simshauser, P. (2013), “Is the Merchant Power Producer a Broken Model?”, Energy Policy, 53(Feb): 298-310. Neuhoff, K. and De Vries, L. (2004), “Insufficient incentives for investment in electricity generation”, CMI Working Paper 42, Cambridge. Newbery, D. (2006), “Market Design”, EPRG Working Paper No. 0515, University of Cambridge. Available at http://www.eprg.group.cam.ac.uk/category/publications/working-paper-series Officer, R. (1994), “The cost of capital of a company under an imputation tax system”, Journal of Accounting and Finance, May, pp. 1-17. Oren, S. (2003), “Ensuring generation adequacy in competitive electricity markets”, University of California Energy Institute – Energy Policy & Economics 007, University of California, Berkley. Peluchon, B. (2003), “Is investment in peak generation assets efficient in a deregulated electricity sector?”, Research Symposium: European Electricity Markets, The Hague, September 2003. Petkova, R. and Zhang, L. (2005), “Is value riskier than growth”, Journal of Financial Economics, 78(2005): 187-202. Roques, F., Newbery, D. and Nuttall, W. (2005), “Investment incentives and electricity market design: the British experience”, Review of Network Economics, 4(2): 93-127. PwC: Pricewaterhouse Coopers, (2013), “Guidance on the cost of capital for new plant entry to the National Electricity Market”, PwC Report to AGL Energy Ltd, Sydney. Salmi, T. and Virtanen, I. (1997), “Measuring the Long-Run Profitability of the Firm; A Simulation Evaluation of the Financial Statement Based IRR Estimation Methods”, Acta Wasaensia, No.54, University of Vaasa, Finland. Available at http://www.uwasa.fi/~ts/smuc/smuc.html . Schweppe, F., Caramanis, M., Tabors, R. And Bohn, R. (1988), Spot pricing of electricity, Kluwer Academic Publishers, London. Sharpe, W. (1964), “Capital Asset Prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk”, Journal of Finance, 19(Sept): 425-442. Page 28 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Simshauser, P. (2008), “The dynamic efficiency gains from introducing capacity payments in the National Electricity Market”, Australian Economic Review, 41(4): 349-370. Simshauser, P. (2009), “On emissions trading, toxic debt, and the Australian power market”, The Electricity Journal, 22(2): 9-29. Simshauser, P. (2010), “Vertical integration, credit ratings and retail price settings in energy only markets: navigating the Resource Adequacy problem”, Energy Policy, 38(11): 7427-7441. Simshauser, P. and Doan, T. (2009), “Emissions trading, wealth transfers and the wounded-bull scenario in power generation”, Australian Economic Review, 42(1): 64-83. Simshauser, P. and Nelson, T. (2012), “The second-round effects of carbon taxes on power project finance”, Journal of Financial Economic Policy, 4(2): 104-127. Standard & Poors, (2011), “Adjusted Key US and European Industrial and Utility Financial Ratios, Standard & Poors Publication, August 30 2012. Available at www.standardandpoors.com/ratingsdirect Steed, J., & Laybutt, C. (2011). Merchant Utilities: Who gets the missing money? Sydney: J.P. Morgan Securities Australia. Thompson, A. and Formby. J. (1993), Economics of the Firm: Theory and Practice, Prentice Hall. Turvey, R. (2000). “What are marginal costs and how to estimate them?”, Technical Paper 13, Centre for the Study of Regulated Industries, University of Bath. Wen, F., Wu, F. and Ni, Y. (2004), “Generation capacity adequacy in the competitive electricity market environment”, Electrical Power & Energy Systems, 26(2004): 365-372. Worley Parsons (2012), “Cost of Construction – New Generation Technology”, Report to AEMO, Worley Parsons Publication, Melbourne. Available at www.aemo.com.au Page 29 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Appendix I: CAPM and Gamma – accounting for investor level taxation effects The CAPM outlined in equation (1) defines the cost of equity capital on a post-tax basis under a classical taxation system, that is, after corporate taxes and before investor-level taxes. With dividend imputation credits available to investors in Australia, the expected can be reduced to take into account the tax paid on behalf of stockholders.32 Monkhouse (1993) and Officer (1994) adjusted the Capital Asset Pricing Model to capture the effect of dividend imputation credits in assessing the effective post-tax cost of equity capital. The Officer (1994) adjustment to the CAPM model is as follows: [ ( ) ] ( [( ) ) ( )] (A1) Where: i = the effective corporate taxation rate = gamma, the utilization rate of imputation credits The corporate taxation rate in Australia at the time of writing was 30%. However, the use of the full value of in equation (A1) runs a high risk of an erroneous result for capital-intensive assets such as power stations due to their particularly large tax depreciation base. That is, it may overstate and induce Type I investment errors by firms, or may result in an overly generous profit benchmark for policymaking and regulation. The better view is to use the effective rate of Taxation , and this can be readily estimated by dynamic financial models of power station assets. Our PF Model finds values of 21.3% for coal plant and 22.8% for CCGT plant. In order to apply the imputation credit adjustment , a reasonable assessment of the mix and number of ‘Australian Taxpaying’ shareholders is required, because dividend imputation credits can only be utilized by Australian taxpaying entities. Considerable debate exists as to the value of . For example, Hathaway and Officer (2004) found the market places a positive value on franking credits for Australian firms. Using ATO data and company Franking Account Balances, they found that from 1988-2002, about $265 billion had been paid in company taxes while Franking Account Balances totalled $77 billion. Accordingly, 71% of theoretical franking credits had been accessed and 50% of distributed credits had been redeemed by taxpayers, thus concluding = 0.5. Cannavan, Finn and Gray (2004, p.193) on the other hand found that while the value of franking credits was initially valued at about 50% for high-yielding firms, following the introduction of “the 45-day rule” in 199733, they found the value effects of imputation credits to be negligible, implying a zero value. Gray (2013a) also reviewed a series of Independent Expert valuation reports for publicly listed companies and found no evidence of Gamma being used by practitioners over the past five years. In our analysis, we therefore explicitly assume = 0 and ignore equation (A1) and continue our analysis using equation (1). However, should taxation law be changed at some point in the future such that Gamma once again becomes valued, it would be appropriate to use equation (A1) in the Australian context. 32 The dividend imputation system was introduced in Australia in 1987 to avoid the double taxation of equity returns. Prior to imputation, individual investors receiving the dividend stream were taxed twice; once as company profits and once more as dividends (i.e. as income in the hands of the individual investor). Following its introduction, credit was given to shareholders for the tax levied on their dividends at the company level. As a result, corporate tax may be considered a mixture of company and personal tax (Monkhouse, 1993). 33 The 45 day rule effectively meant that the trade of franking credits by foreign investors could only occur if scrip was held for 45 days around the date of dividend entitlement. Page 30 Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Appendix II: Mathematical Proof of Missing Money in Energy-Only Markets “Under any optimal plant mix for any number of optimal plant technologies, aggregate revenues will always fall short by at least ̅ ” Proof by mathematical induction: ̅ ̅ ( ) ( ) ̅) ( ̅ ̅ ( ̅ ̅ ) ̅ ̅ ̅ ̅ ̅ ( ) ( ( ̅ ) ̅ ( ̅ ̅ ̅ ) ( ) ̅ ̅ ) ̅ ̅ ̅ ( ) ∑( ) ̅ ∑( ) ̅ ∑( ) ̅ ̅ ̅ ̅ ̅ ( ̅ ) ̅ Page 31 ̅ ( ̅) Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Appendix III: Levelised Cost of Electricity Model There are two methods for producing generalised long run marginal cost estimates for a given generation plant technology, fully dynamic multi-period power project finance models and Levelised Cost of Electricity models. With dynamic power project finance models, a vastly greater number of inputs are used by comparison to Levelised Cost models, which in turn generates a more accurate result, and typically, a lower result. However with considerably more computations involved, the risk of error is also heightened. Dynamic power project finance models discount post-tax future cash flows to the expected cost of equity as outlined in equation (1). Levelised Cost of Electricity models (see below) on the other hand discount pretax, pre-financing cost and production streams to the expected WACC as outlined in equation (A2). In some modelling exercises, pre-tax and pre-financing cash flows are discounted at Weighted Average Cost of Capital to produce estimates of the long run marginal cost of power generation. In this instance, equation (3) needs to be rearranged to produce a pre-tax estimate of , the cost of debt needs to be introduced, and both the cost of equity and debt need to be weighted according to their intended deployment, as follows: {( ) ( ) – ( ) )} ( {( ) )} (A2) Where Ei Di Vi = is the value of equity of the ith firm = is the value of debt of the ith firm = Ei + Di The estimation process for RT and CT is comparatively straight forward. For a project finance, the primary variables required are debt tenors, the corresponding interest rate swap rate and the credit spread offered by relevant project bank syndicate – all of which is invariably issued in local currency in Australia. For bond issues the primary variables are the tenor, the [bank bill rate], the credit spread, and any adjustment to account for exchange rate swaps for bonds issued in foreign currency. Levelised Cost Models involve a dramatically reduced number of variables, using pre-tax and pre-financing capital and operating cash flows, discounted by the output of the plant using the pre-tax WACC outlined in equation (4). The general form can be expressed as follows: ∑ [( ) (( ) ( ) )]⁄∑ Page 32 [( )( ) ( ) ] (A3) Working Paper No.38 – Normal Profit AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Appendix IV: Declaration of the Authors The authors of this working paper were employed by AGL Energy Ltd at the time of writing. While the working paper represents the views of the authors, the research was completed as part of AGL’s public policy development. This is influenced by AGL’s core business activities which include developing, owning, and operating electricity generation; developing and producing coalseam gas; and retailing electricity and gas to more than 3.5 million customers in Australia. Earlier drafts of the paper were reviewed by the AGL Applied Economic and Policy Research Council and comments made by Council members were gratefully received by the authors. The role of the Council is not to endorse working papers but provide constructive review. In this context, all opinions, statements, errors and omissions are those of the authors and should not in any way be attributed to the Council and its members. Members of the Council are Elizabeth Nosworthy, Prof. Christine Smith, Prof. Stephen Gray, Dr. Judith McNeill, Keith Orchison, Tony Brinker and Carlo Botto. Page 33