Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 89 Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy By Chin-Ming Lin∗ Concerns over society’s aggregate well-being initiated a new trend in social regulations in the United States beginning in the 1960s. These regulations focus on fundamental aspects of the production process and on its negative externalities so that nearly every sector of the economy is affected. However, the US is quite distinct from other countries in terms of regulatory patterns. The American format of regulatory laws, the process of regulatory policy-making, and the ways in implementing regulations are more legalistic, and more adversarial than other advanced countries. Legalism in US social regulations resulted in bigger uncertainties, higher litigation and legal expenditures, and heavier compliance and opportunity costs, as well as causing firms to become defensive and alienated. As domestic regulations are increasingly becoming insufficient to deal with problems arising from globalized production, differences in American regulatory content and legal implementations from other countries will affect its competitiveness in the global economy. We argue, in this paper, that the impact of social regulations on the whole of society is not large, but the impact of higher liability and legal costs can be more pronounced for particular industries. However, as long as the higher regulatory costs do not proportionately fall on inputs of production, US companies will not be at a competitive disadvantage. ∗ Chin-Ming Lin (林欽明), Assistant Professor, Graduate Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, Tamkang University, Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Wisconsin-Madison, Specialize in Trade Policy, Economic Development and Industrial Relations. 90 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs Key words: Regulatory Policy, Adversarial Legalism, Competitiveness, Industrial Policy, Government-business Cooperation, Social Cost and Benefit, Globalization, Social Safety Legislation, Comparative Economic Systems, Corporate Social Responsibility The Rise of American Social Regulation The beginning of legislating of health protection for foods and drugs in the UScan be traced to the Progress Era, while initiatives in basic regulations on labor relations became prominent in the period of the New Deal. Furthermore, the surge of federal legislation on human rights, environmental protection, occupational safety and consumers’ product protection was around thirty or forty years ago. The prevalent trend of legalism in individual rights and preferential treatment has not been a recent phenomenon as well. As Alexis de Tocqueville observed in 1835 that in America important political issues repeatedly were transmuted into judicial questions and that politics and social life were pervaded by the vocabulary of law.1 From the end of the 1960’s to the 1970’s, we witnessed a new trend in American regulations that, as in the Progress Era and the New Deal, was meant to rebuild and revitalize the role of government in the economy. This was mainly inspired by the new political economic ideology and new administrative philosophy, but it was distinctive from the Progressive Era and the later New Deal. The crucial difference is that, with active macroeconomic management policies, fluctuations in business cycles 1 Alexis de Tocqueville, Democracy in America, ed. by J. P. Mayer and Max Lerner (Harper & Row, 1966): 248. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 91 were not so huge as in the first half of the twentieth century, and thus the overall economy did not change so much with the transformation of the post-war economic structures. Furthermore, the initiatives of the new trends in regulatory policies were not the same as those in previous periods. The former regulations were concentrated in economic issues, while the new schemes were mainly social regulations. However, there is close connection between these two schemes: it was the continuous concern in the capitalist production process in the former period which resulted in the rise of interest in another regime of regulations in the later period. However, before we proceed to discuss the characteristics of the new regulatory schemes, let us first clarify what is the distinction between social regulations and economic regulations. Economic regulations in the Progressive Era and the New Deal were mainly designed to expand governmental controls on price and supply conditions of production, the number of participants in regulated industries and conditions of entering into these industries. The government adopted relevant responsive regulatory measures for different periods respectively toward market inefficiencies due to specific sectors’ characteristics or the fluctuations induced by market competition. In earlier times various agencies for the purpose of economic regulations were established, such as the Interstate Commerce Commission (1887), Antitrust Division of the Justice Department (1890), the Bureau of Corporations of the Commerce Department (1906), the Federal Reserve Board (1913), the Federal Trade Commission (1914), the Federal Power Commission (1920), the Commodity Exchange Authority (1922), the Food and Drug Administration (1931), the Federal Home Loan Bank Board (1932), the 92 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (1933), the Agricultural Adjustment Administration (1933), the Federal Communications Commission (1934), the Security and Exchange Commission (1934), the National Labor Relations Board (1935), the Federal Maritime Commission (1936), and Civil Aeronautics Board (1938).2 Unlike economic regulations, social regulations focus on fundamental aspects of the production process and on its negative externalities. Therefore, social regulations are concerned with the qualities of goods and services and the side effects of production process that are threatening human health and even the living environment. Thus, it is not meant to protect business enterprises, but rather to restrict their activities on behalf of the public, while it is not meant to promote market competition or to protect those competitors in the market, but, on the contrary, to induce additional costs to smaller enterprises for complying with regulatory restrictions and therefore render it very difficult to survive in the market. In the 1970s the US Congress initiated many policy measures to prevent air and water pollution, to control toxic wastes and chemicals, to prevent occupational accidents and diseases, and to promote consumer safety. In order for the new regulatory legislation to pass it was necessary to coordinate with business associations, to mobilize advocacy groups, and to effectively exploit highly publicized events or relevant reports. Agencies such as the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (1970), Environmental Protection Agency (1970), the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (1970), and the Consumer Product Safety Commission (1972) are the best known of the social regulatory agencies. 2 Marc Allen Eisner, Regulatory Politics in Transition, 2nd ed. (Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 2000): 119. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 93 Nevertheless, we must note that some past policies were regulations, such as the earlier Food and Drug Administration and the Federal Trade Commission. All have promoted some social regulatory functions. However, during the 1960s and the 1970s there were indeed large expansions in social regulations. The US Congress successfully passed five consumer protection laws in the Progress Era and eleven more of such laws in the New Deal. Comparatively, Congress successfully passed sixty-two such laws in the later period. It is the same in aspects of occupational safety and working standards: five such laws were passed in the Progressive Era and the New Deal as against twenty-one in the period of 1960 to 1978. Similarly, there were seven energy and environmental protection laws in the Progressive Era and the New Deal while there were thirty-two more in the later period.3 After the New Deal, government regulation was gradually accepted by the public. Furthermore, with changes in governmental focus the regulated became less antagonistic against government policies. Actually, in many industries, firms’ stability and sustained profitability relied crucially on the sustainability of these regulatory measures. However, the relationship between government and economic units became much more tense and antagonistic with changes in political environment witnessing the rising of many public-opinion groups. The latter asserted that government should play a different role and business enterprises should be less autonomous. Influenced by left-wing mentalities, they believed that government policies should not only focus on industrial stability or business extravagance, but should set standards and stringently execute 3 These figures were adopted from David Vogel, “The ‘New’ Social Regulation in Historical and Comparative Perspective,’ in Thomas K. McCraw, ed. Regulation in Perspective: Historical Essays (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1981): 162. It was cited in Eisner, Regulatory Politics in Transition: 120. 94 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs them with respect to every aspect of the production process. Those social regulations set up in the 1960s and the 1970s extended governmental interferences into many proprietary areas of business administration. Government created many new institutions, and, at the same time, made many mechanistic innovations in adjusting administrative structures and promoting integration of sectors’ benefits. Most importantly, huge manpower resources in natural and social sciences were infused to delineate policy scope and to design appropriate methods of compliance. The trend in social regulations changed the trajectories of historical development. In the past, economic regulatory agencies were mainly responsible for distributing benefits (such as changes in routes, frequencies and rates) among a few enterprises in specific industries. These policies may have harmed consumers or obstructed many new entrants, but they were welcomed by the regulated because they actually stimulated industrial stability and raised profitability. And, of course, there were many complaints that governments abused their authority to deliver benefits to business enterprises.4 On the contrary, new schemes of social regulations covering issues across industries and economic sectors were implemented, such as air and water pollution, defects and dangers in consumer products, and occupational disasters and diseases that were not specific to any particular industry. To solve these problems, there must be a preventive standard applicable to the whole economy, not impinging on industrial stability and profitability. The transformation in regulatory focuses, along with the compliance costs, has put the regulators and the regulated in an adversarial position, as opposed to the past. 4 See, e.g., Samuel P. Huntington, “The Erasmus of the ICC,” Yale Law Journal, 61 (April 1955) : 467-509. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 95 Adversarial Legalism In the past few decades, we have heard voices of deregulation in many political arenas. Some economic regulations that restricted competition such as those in banking, maritime and air transportations, telecommunications and retail sales were discarded. But, almost no politician wished to discard any social regulation because most of these measures were deemed necessary for rectifying negative externalities. However, it is undeniable that social regulations were always in the middle of political conflicts, partly because of their incapability to function perfectly as social protection. Furthermore, the costs of compliance were always large and the procedures were tedious. In the United States, due to political confrontations, the system of social regulations, either in overcoming social problems or most of the regulatory standards, is not so different from those of other advanced democratic countries. Nevertheless, the US is quite distinct from other countries in terms of regulatory patterns. The American format of regulatory laws, the process of regulatory policy-making, and the ways of implementing regulations are more legalistic, and more adversarial, and has been coined as “adversarial legalism” by Robert Kagan.5 Adversarial legalism may not necessarily render the American system worse than other industrial countries, but it has surely resulted in higher regulatory costs, as well as less efficiency and less flexibility, which hindered necessary cooperation between government and businesses in response to 5 Cf. Robert A. Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: The American Way of Law (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2001); see also Robert A. Kagan and Lee Axelrad, “Adversarial Legalism: An International Perspective,” in Pietro S. Nivola, ed., Comparative Disadvantages: Social Regulations and the Global Economy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution): 146-202. 96 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs public demand for protection.6 We will first look at the form of American regulatory laws. Edward Rubin found that the statutes and regulations issued by the US Federal Reserve Board on bank safety and soundness fill numerous three-inch-thick binders, while Germany’s comparable statute and the Bundesbank’s implementing regulations are bound in a pamphlet that is less than 100 pages in length. Part of Rubin’s answer is that Germany’s bank regulatory officials are career employees, subject to more extensive training than American counterparts, so there is no need to restrain the former with comprehensive rules for them to make independent and reasonable judgments.7 Germany’s environmental regulations are implemented by state (lander) and municipal officials and are, perhaps, the most detailed of any nation’s except for the US. Still, they are much less prescriptive and constraining than American rules.8 Besides, the intention of Gemany’s detailed regulations is different. The detailedness of the US laws and regulations was the result of distrust of regulatory institutions by the government and advocacy groups; the ruling was designed to prevent the agency’s “capture” by the regulated firms and, furthermore, to facilitate 6 7 8 Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: 181-182. Edward L. Rubin, “Discretion and Its Discontents,” Chicago-Kent Law Review, 72 (1997): 1299. For example, a study by John Dwyer and coauthors compared experiences of controlling air pollution in Ford Motor Company’s assembly plants in Germany and the US They found that both countries’ regulations prescribed similar emissions levels for the pollutants produced during the vehicle painting process, and both required use of the best available control technology. The EPA’s regulations, however, prescribed specific emission levels for each of the three different coating processes, while the German regulations called for a single overall emission limit for the plant, which gives manufacturers more flexibility in adjusting production runs and processes, and reduces monitoring and reporting requirements. See John Dwyer, Richard Brooks and Alan Marco, “The Air Pollution Permit Process for US and German Automobile Assembly Plants,” in Robert A. Kagan and Lee Axelrad, eds., Regulatory Encounters: Multinational Corporations and American Adversarial Legalism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2000). Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 97 judicial reviews that will check unwarranted administrative decisions. In Germany, in contrast, the detailedness of environmental regulations was meant mainly to give a guidance for state and municipal governments in implementing federal laws and also to protect regulatory officials from judicial interference. When plaintiffs in German court argued that regulatory activities conflicted with their individual rights, the regulatory agencies could point at detailed rules and reply that they were only following the letter of the law. Moreover, the detail in Germany’s air pollution regulations has legal characteristics of “administrative guidance” rather than a binding law. Therefore, the regulators can lawfully depart from them in individual decisions, based on their duty to adjust regulatory requirements to particular circumstances and economic conditions.9 Unique to American environmental regulations is the strict designations by the Congress on promulgation schedules in regulatory legislations and specific dates of achieving pollution prevention goals, which always resulted in failure to fulfill deadline requirement and, therefore, in subsequent accusations by environmental groups asking for strict compliance.10 Prescriptive and deadline-laden statutes, moreover, lead to prescriptive and deadline-laden regulations and, for individual regulated firms, to permits, remediation plans, checklists for inspectors, and reporting requirements that far exceed in specificity those imposed by other countries.11 9 R. Daniel Kelemen, “Regulatory Federalism: The European Union in Comparative Perspective,” Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University (1998), 10 Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: 188. 11 Robert A. Kagan, “The Consequences of Adversarial Legalism,” in Robert A. Kagan and Lee Axelrad, eds., Regulatory Encounters: Multinational Corporations and American Adversarial Legalism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2000). 98 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs We next look at the regulatory policymaking process. In the US, any political dispute is subject to judicial limitation so that regulated enterprises or regulatory supporting advocacy groups, when they do not like specific regulatory measures, can use these to fend off regulatory policy decisions. Thus, there are some special legal formats in the US regulatory policy decision-making process. It is open to interest-group participations and, therefore, is adversarial and susceptible to judicial reviews. In the US legal and judicial decision-making process, draft legislatures have to be published first, and then public hearings could be held where advocacy groups, business organizations and other interested agencies can raise their concerns and demands. The regulators and the regulated, in many circumstances, have to negotiate in private and, in many more circumstances, this will result in dangerous political consequences. Government asks the regulatory decision-makers to provide scientific, technical and economically effective evidence to support the chosen standards. The regulatory measures are always challenged in the courts where judges criticize the fairness of decision-making process and raise their objections to legal words. Moreover, many responses by regulatory agencies to dispute by industrial and advocacy groups are often criticized as well. A study by David Vogel points out that the regulatory decision-making processes in England are less formal and less challenged judicially. The regulatory officials issue environmental prevention guidelines after consultation privately with each other, the representatives appointed by affected firms and associations, and the “responsible” environmental groups. Judicial reviews on regulatory decision-making are infrequent, and, thus, lawyers play insignificant roles in decision-making Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 99 process.12 The same contrast emerges between Germany and the US with respect to environmental regulatory decision-making processes. 13 . Furthermore, studies on occupational safety regulations in the US, France, Germany, the UK and Japan, 14 and on regulations on chemical carcinogens in pesticides, food additives and workplaces in Germany, France, the UK and the US, also confirm more stringent legal requirements and less attention to bureaucratic or economic reality in the US regulatory decision-making process. Policy implementations, they pointed out, were often criticized by other government agencies and the warring private interest groups, all engaged in legal, scientific and economic explanations from their own narrow perspectives. We found in the study by Brickman and others 15 that there is no confrontations between legislative and executive government sectors in European countries where, with traditions of governance by experts, apolitical public agencies and business groups, the “pressure for rigorous procedural and judicial controls on the bureaucracy” have been reduced. 16 In consequence, “A confidential process of consultation and accommodation permits government officials to mediate among conflicting private interests. As a result, regulators are able to make the necessary trade-offs and compromises without presenting reasoned public justifications or drawing open political fire.” As Vogel pointed out, while British enterprises were permitted and 12 13 14 15 16 David Vogel, National Styles of Regulation: Environmental Policy in Great Britain and the United States (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1986). Susan Rose-Ackerman, Controlling Environmental Policy: The Limits of Public Law in Germany and the United States (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1995). Joseph L. Badaracco, Loading the Dice: A Five Country Study of Vinyl Chloride Regulation (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1985). Ronald Brickman, Sheila Jasanoff and Thomas Ilgen, Controlling Chemicals: The Politics of Regulation in Europe and the United States (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1985). Brickman, Jasanoff and Ilgen, Controlling Chemical: 305. 100 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs assured to participate in regulatory decision making, consultations between business executives and regulatory officials were often questioned politically: Businesses would always have to manage to be assertive and “the importance given to economic considerations is in large measure dependent upon the lobbying and litigation skills to business.” Economic concerns are addressed through formal cost-benefit analyses or technical feasibility studies, but, because of some unavoidable deficiencies in methods, either the regulated may feel the regulation is too stringent or the regulation advocacy organization may think it is too lenient. These all created grounds for appeal to the courts. Lastly, we may want to look at the implementation aspect of regulations. Some US regulatory agencies pursue a flexible or sometimes accommodative enforcement style, emphasizing remedial orders more than punishment.17 Some regulatory agencies are too lenient or, due to shortage of staff or too much burden, may not want to or be unable to punish even in situations of obvious and significant regulatory violations. The regulated sometimes in political occasions would fight back the enforcement of regulations.18 Nevertheless, US regulatory officials are often under political pressure to pursue legal methods and sue those involved in regulatory violations. Thus, the regulators often measure their performance by the number of accusations and the amount of fines recovered. The Environmental Protection Agency of the federal government often checks on records of accusations by state environmental regulatory agencies to see if there is failure to seek legal sanctions against 17 18 Robert A. Kagan, “Regulatory Enforcement,” in David Rosenblum and Richard Schwartz, eds., Handbook of Regulation and Administrative Law (New York: Marcel Dekker, 1993). Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: 191. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 101 violators. 19 Several cross-national studies also found that, in many regulatory areas, the US was far more legalistic and deterrence-oriented in enforcing many regulatory measures than other advanced countries. Comparatively, regulatory officials of other democratic countries are more consistently employing a problem-solving, cooperation-seeking style in cases of regulatory violations.20 The much more stricter regulatory enforcement style was criticized by some social-legal studies, calling it formalistic or “by the book”.21 No other country authorizes or imposes such weighty criminal penalties for violations of regulatory laws. In 1988 the Congress raised the penalty for inside-trading to one million dollars for individuals and to two and half million dollars for organizations. It also doubled prison terms for violations of any securities law provisions from five to ten years.22 At the end of the 1980s and the beginning of the 1990s, Congress upgraded most criminal offenses in environmental laws from misdemeanors to felonies, thereby, increasing the potential prison sentences. According Federal or California state laws, firms that violated water pollution prevention laws that “knowingly endanger another person” could be fined by courts to the maximum penalty of one million dollars while violating individuals could be fined two and half million dollars, along with maximum prison terms 19 20 21 22 Jonathan Adler, “Bean Counting for a Better Earth: Environmental Enforcement at the EPA,” Regulation (Spring, 1998): 40-43. Steven Kelman, Regulating America, Regulating Sweden: A Comparative Study of Occupational Safety and Health Policy (Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, 1981); Graham Wilson, The Politics of Safety and Health (Oxford: Clerendon Press, 1985). Eugene Bardach and Robert A. Kagan, Going by the Book: The Problem of Regulatory Unreasonableness (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1982); Lee Axelrad, “Investigation and Remediation of Contaminated Manufacturing Sites in the United States, the United Kingdom, and the Netherlands,” in Robert A. Kagan and Lee Axelrad, eds., Regulatory Encounters: Multinational Corporations and Adversarial Legalism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2000). Harvey Pitt and Karen Shapiro, “Securities Regulation by Enforcement: A Look Ahead at the Next Decade,” Yale Journal on Regulation, 7 (Winter 1990). 102 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs of fifteen years.23 American laws also provide more heavier civil penalties to regulatory violations than other countries. For Federal Clean Air Act and the Toxic Substance Control Act, the maximum penalties to consecutive violations are authorized up to $25,000 per day. The EPA can impose administrative penalties equal to the financial “benefit” the violators gained. Some Federal environmental statutes require violators to pay for the damage to natural resources by unauthorized pollutions. These encouraged environmental officials to act like trial lawyers seeking the largest possible damage calculations.24 In 1989 the Exxon Valdez went aground in Prince William Sound, Alaska and spilled eleven million gallons of oil in the wildlife-rich waters. 25 Exxon Corporation, after spending two billion dollars in cleaning the leakage, pled guilty to criminal charges and was fined $125 million. Furthermore, the Alaskan state government and Federal government respectively also filed civil accusations against Exxon for damaging the environment which culminated in a settlement of close to one billion dollars by Exxon.26 At the same time, a number of lawyers who acquired thousands of signatures by fishermen, Indian tribes and other private organizations who claimed to be harmed by the leakage also filed suit in Federal court and gained five billion dollars of remediation. Exxon’s simultaneous exposure to criminal prosecution, governmental civil penalties, and private lawsuits for damages from the 23 24 25 26 33 U.S.C. §1319(c)(d); Cal. Water Code §§13385-13386. John Privatera, “Using CERCLA’s Natural Resource Damage Provision to Focus and Organize a State Environmental Penalty Case,” National Environmental Enforcement Journal (March 1992). Al Davidson, In the Wake of the Exxon Valdez (San Francisco: Sierra Club Books). “Judge Endorses $1 Billion Exxon Valdez Settlement,” Washington Post (October 9, 1991): A4. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 103 same accident revealed characteristics of the US regulatory laws: the uniqueness in encouraging private enforcement of public law. Legislation by the US Congress often encourage enterprise lawyers to act as “private attorneys general.” Thus, for example, the plaintiffs in Federal antitrust laws could get “treble damage” awards if they can prove in court a violation. According to the Federal Truth-in-Lending Act, the borrowers could sue the lenders for violating the complicated disclosure requirement in the laws. To encourage suits, the Federal law provides that the plaintiffs would receive a $100 minimum award, regardless of actual losses, plus their attorneys’ fees. The Act also enabled attorneys to bundle thousands of bank customers together in a class action, “raising the prospect of enormous damages suits for minor violations of the statute.”27 Social and Economic Costs of Legalistic Regulations As revealed by several studies, compared to more cooperative regulatory laws in other countries, legalism in US social regulations resulted in bigger uncertainties, higher litigation and lawyer expenditures, and heavier compliance and opportunity costs, causing firms to become defensive and alienated. These costs are borne by society as a whole, not merely by regulated firms. Many multinational enterprises thought that US regulatory policies are more legalistically unpredictable than those of the Western Europe or Japan. The uncertainties stems from several features of the US regulatory regimes. Institutional fragmentation results in an overlap of authorities and coordinating failures in many local, state and Federal regulatory units which could be controlled by different parties with diversified preferences 27 Edward L. Rubin, “Legislative Methodology: Some Lessons from the Truth-in-Lending Act,” Georgetown Law Review, 80 (1991): 233. 104 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs in regulations. Due to the political and legal openness of the American government, business groups and advocacy organizations frequently battle for regulatory changes in agencies, courts and legislatures, rendering American regulatory laws more volatile. The ever-present prospect of legal and political challenges means that the US government, compared to counterparts in other countries, often demand more specific scientific support in permit applications, demands for rule changes or new regulations. This also makes it less clear when a decision can be made and whether the studies and certifications provided will be regarded as legally sufficient.28 To comply with American regulations, many enterprises also must pay for more legal fees. Officials in a Japanese metal-producing company pointed out that the legal consulting expenditure paid by its subsidiary company in the U.S. is higher than the gross expenditure by the mother corporation and its European subsidiaries. Several other multinational companies had similar experiences such that their subsidiaries in the U.S. consulted lawyers more often and longer on a wider range of matters, because, compared to other advanced democratic countries, the American laws are usually more complicated, changeable, and difficult to master; the legal sanctions from being wrong are generally much higher; litigation is more common; and litigation in the United States is more expensive.29 The requirements of American regulatory policies on investigation reports, record-keeping, testing, employee education and certifications are usually more extensive and comprehensive. Thus, besides complying with 28 29 Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: 198-199; Kagan and Axelrad, “Adversarial Legalism: International Perspective,”: 165-167. Laura Beth Nielson, “Paying Workers or Paying Lawyers: Employee Termination Practices in the United States and Canada,” Law & Policy, 21 (July 1999): 247-282; Charles Ruhlin, “Credit Card Collection and the Law: Germany and the United States,” in Kagan and Axelrad, eds., Regulatory Encounters; Kagan, “The Consequences of Adversarial Legalism.” Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 105 actual regulatory standards, regulated firms in the US must also spend more to prove that they are complying.30 One company, at the beginning of the 1990s, reported to the regulatory agencies in the US, the UK and Netherlands that the underground tanks and pipes in those countries had deteriorated and solvents had leaked. Comparatively, the American regulatory authority demanded more detailed analyses, more paperwork and more expensive reports than its counterparts in other countries. Officials of the company pointed out that the documents they provided to the US regulatory agency would fill a four-drawer filing cabinet, compared to the less than half of a single file drawer of documentation submitted to regulatory agencies of other countries. As estimated by the company, to comply with American regulations the designing and clearing plans in two sites in the United States added $8 to $10 million out of total costs per site of an estimated $22 million, whereas the “extra” costs in investigating and clearing were negligible.31 Regulatory permitting systems are designed to slow the rush to development and technological change, pressing businesses to reconsider the negative effects before taking further steps. However, this kind of prior regulatory review may also cause a large opportunity cost to society. Whenever a new and less harmful pesticide is stalled by extra checkup, it means that the existing and more harmful pesticides could remain for a little longer. European Union’s regulatory procedure for prior reviews of genetically engineered products and new chemical substances are slower and impose longer delays on useful products than the comparable US 30 31 Dwyer, Brooks and Marco, “The Air Pollution Permit Process for U.S. and German Automobile Assembly Plants”; Kagan, “The Consequences of Adversarial Legalism.” Axelrad, “Investigation and Remediation of Contaminated Manufacturing Sites in the United States, the United Kingdom, and the Netherlands.” 106 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs systems.32 Nevertheless, for most products and manufacturing processes, the American regulatory system, compared to countries of the European Union, usually caused longer delays and larger opportunity costs. American opponents of new projects generally have more opportunities to challenge regulatory permits in the courts and, with litigation at a deliberately crawling pace, typically this results in substantial opportunity costs. The greater prospects of judicial reviews seem to show that the U.S. officials are more cautious and also more dependent on judicial reviews to control development projects. However, when we compare the difference between the U.S. and other countries, it is actually very significant. For example, when Ford applied for air pollution permits for its two plants in Germany, the time from application to approval in Germany took five and seven months, respectively; the same permit application for its plants in Minnesota and New Jersey, on the other hand, took the company more than four years.33 Another of regulatory legalism’s more intangible costs is its corrosive effects on personal and institutional relationships. Exchange and cooperation of information necessary for effective regulatory enforcements are often reduced due to adversarial postures between the regulatory investigators and the regulated enterprises.34 One of the most heralded case is EPA’s “Project XL”, announced in 1995 in a Clinton administration document, Reinventing Environmental Regulation. It authorized state regulatory agencies to reach agreement with the regulated 32 33 34 See Martine Kraus, “Licensing Biologics in Europe and the United States,” in Kagan and Axelrad, eds., Regulatory Encounters; Loro Johnson, Tatsuya Fujie and Marius Aalders, “New Chemical Notifications Laws in Japan, the United States, and the European Union,” in Kagan and Axelrad, eds., Regulatory Encounters. Dwyer, Brooks and Marco, “The Air Pollution Permit Process for U.S. and German Automobile Assembly Plants.” Bardach and Kagan, Going by the Book. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 107 businesses under which, in return for relief from highly prescriptive regulatory requirements, the enterprises institute performance-oriented pollution reduction methods that promise “superior” environmental benefits. Each enterprise had to publicize its actual records of environmental performance and update goals in light of experiences.35 However, the progress of agreements in Project XL was unbearably slow that although EP set an initial goal of fifty projects, by the end of 1997 only seven had been finally approved, with twelve under development. The reason is the shadow of adversarial legalism hang there and the regulatory agencies must guard against the charge that they are casting aside the law to accommodate a polluter. Each of the legal waivers for particular prescriptive regulations must be negotiated arduously. Negotiations between EPA and 3M broke down partly because EPA could not guarantee that, once the Project XL requirement was fulfilled, 3M would be free from civil litigations for technical violations of present regulations. 36 Furthermore, environmental groups would never easily give up the power they gained from prescriptive rules and rights to litigate and, thus, they nearly scuttled the agreement between EPA and Intel.37 What are the costs of regulations to the US on the whole? According to one estimate, the US spends over $230 billion a year, or around 2% of GDP, on legal actions with respect to tort laws, far more than any other advanced economy. But over half of the compensation does not go 35 36 37 On Project XL and other related cooperative regulatory schemes cf. Edward Weber, Pluralism by the Rules: Conflict and Cooperation in Environmental Regulation (Washington, D.C.: Georgetown University Press, 1998) Michael Dorf and Charles Sabel, “A Constitution of Democratic Experimentalism,” Columbia Law Review, 98 (1998): 384-385. Jody Freeman, “Collaborative Governance in the Administrative State,” UCLA Law Review, 45 (1997): 61-66, 73. 108 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs victims of negligence, but are eaten up by administrative costs. 38 Furthermore, the American tax laws and their attendant regulations run to 60,000 pages. The annual cost of tax compliance is estimated at $115 billion.39 We could not find comparable figures for Europe, but it is without doubt that the European economy is hindered by various levels of regulations, as evidenced by recent call for regulatory reform from many people. However, even though companies in the US may face lower administrative (legal) burdens, they do face substantial costs when working to avoid legal litigation procedures.40 Before we ponder upon the implications of social regulations for American competitiveness, it is worth noting that resource wasting from legal expenditures and wherewith the uncertainties caused by regulatory policies should not be ignored. The United States provides an enormous market for both American and foreign business; those businesses can not afford to abandon the United States even if its regulatory system is especially costly. But those “extra” costs, even though they may not harm the dynamism of the whole economy, are in fact a large burden for individual firms and a depletion of wealth for the whole society. Impacts on the economy by regulatory waste and inefficiency, just like the waste and inefficiency from military purchases and highway building by the government, are undesirable as well. It is often argued, but not mentioned at the above, that differential regulations between the US and other less-developed economies such as Mexico and China will have deleterious effects. More lenient regulations, 38 39 40 "George Bush's Second Term: The Revolution Comes Home," Economist, January 13, 2005. Ibid. See, e.g., ETUC (European Trade Union Confederation), “Note from the ETUC on Regulation, Competition and Innovation in Europe," A note from the ETUC regarding the meeting of Finance Ministers (http://www.etuc.org/a/566). Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 109 especially on environment and labor standards, may have rendered many developing countries a comparative advantage in international trade against the US and other advanced countries. On the other hand, there is also growing concern by policy-makers and private entities in developing countries about the proliferation and strengthening of standards and technical regulations, which is impacting their competitiveness. For the sake of not to involve in those dispute and to complicate our discussions, we leave such issues to other more appropriate places.41 The United States and Global Economy For the past half century the United States was increasingly integrated with the global economy. In 1950 imports and exports, when combined, constitute a ratio of 8.1% in gross domestic product (GDP). In the next two decades the ratio was rising slowly to 10.9% in 1970. But thereafter the speed of globalization rose very quickly for the past two to three decades (see Table 1). In 2003 imports and exports, when combined, constituted a ratio of 23.0% of GDP, with value of over $2.5 trillion.42 Gross value of global trade reached $6.5 trillion in 2002, wherein the U.S. exports were responsible for 11.0% and imports for 18.5%. It is indeed a very active player in international economy.43 Most of the world trade is conducted among advanced countries with similar wage structures, or among subsidiaries in different regions of the world within the same firm 41 42 43 The World Bank has increased its involvement in this field recently. Confer its related web pages for detailed portfolio of projects. Calculated from Christipher L. Bach, “U.S. International Transactions: 2003,” Survey of Current Business, 84 (April 2004), Table 1 (http://www.bea.gov/bea/ARTICLES/2004/04April/0404ITA.pdf). Calculated from trade statistics published by the WTO. Cf. its webpage on “International Trade Statistics” (http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/its2003_e/its03_bysubject_e.htm#geograph ical_regions). 110 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs (intra-firm trade). While there are examples of industries devastated by international trade (e.g., textile), the image of U.S. workers being displaced en masse by sweatshop workers in developing countries is a wholly unfounded assertion. Table 1 Openness of U.S. Economy (in current price, $billion) Total trade GDP Trade/GDP (%) 1960 48.4 526.4 9.2 1970 122.7 1,038.5 11.8 1980 563.1 2,789.5 20.2 1990 1,151.3 5,803.1 19.8 2003 2,527.6 10,987.9 23.0 Source: Calculated using data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce (http://www.bea.gov/). However, the threat brought about by globalization is real. After a period of sustained growth in wage equity (1947-1973), the wages of U.S. non-farm workers entered a period of stagnation and decline (see Figure 1). Real wages (in 1982 dollars) fell from $8.63 per hour in 1973 to $7.46 per hour in the 1990s. Decreasing real wages, along with a long-term trend of falling employee tenure, suggest greater employment insecurity. In view of the declining unionization levels44 and a contingent workforce of over 35 million, many people feel the threat of employment insecurity especially in an epoch of lean production and global market.45 Many countries’ governments, viewed from the pressure of international competition on domestic markets, are increasingly feeling less effective at protecting their people from the impact of global markets. Every 44 45 At present the unionization ratio in workforce of non-agricultural private sectors is below 10%. For wage figures cf. Eisner, Regulatory Politics in Transition, p. 202. And on the impact of globalization and lean production cf. Bennett Harrison, Lean and Mean: The Changing Landscape of Corporate Power in the Age of Flexibility (New York: Basic Books, 1994). Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 111 government is increasingly finding it difficult to extract wealth from corporations and limit their mobility given the dearth of policy tools. As William Greider notes, ”The nation state faces a crisis of relevance. What remains of its purpose and power if authority over domestic social standards is yielded to disinterested market forces? If governments are reduced to bidding for the favors of multinational enterprises, what basis 10 9 8 7 6 5 19 64 19 67 19 70 19 73 19 76 19 79 19 82 19 85 19 88 19 91 19 94 19 97 20 00 20 03 Real wage ($/hour) will citizens have for determining their own destinies?”46 Year Figure 1. Real Hourly Wages* of Production Workers * In 1983 dollars. Source: Calculated using data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor (http://data.bls.gov/). These are significant questions for those who engage in regulatory design. Regulatory policy is a means of shaping the effect of economic forces, preserving or promoting common political values, and forcing representation and accountability. And growing international integration 46 William Greider, One World, Ready or Not: The Manic Logic of Global Capitalism (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1997): 334. 112 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs will render each country’s regulatory measures less effective and will force a search for resolutions. Many of the issues raised above are worth pondering. First of all, many of the problems conventionally concerned by regulators, such as safety and health of products and environmental impact of productive activities, are difficult to address when businesses function outside country borders. Although American consumers will not be directly impacted by occupational safety and health records of other country’s enterprises, regulations are promoted, nevertheless, on the basis of a commitment that corporations should assume responsibility for the welfare of their workers. This commitment is not supposed to be obviated by the fact that the workers in turmoil are in Mexico City instead of Milwaukee. With regard to environmental protection, sustainability, biodiversity, acid rain, and global warming, these are all issues that are affected by production regardless of where they are located. These create trans-border externalities that are difficult to control with individual country’s regulatory policies or institutions. Some countries may want to circumscribe the limitations of domestic regulatory policies by the infusing of trade policies, which results in second problem. If regulatory policies were assisted by trade policies, then the goals of regulatory policies will impinge on wider goals of national income and employment. Industrial and labor associations used to promote government policies to protect their members, but now they are using trade policies to reach the goals of regulations. The use of regulations to affect the behavior of producers in other nations comes into direct conflict with the national commitment to free trade and the rules of the World Trade Organization. With respect to regulations, the restriction of imports of some products with specific additives, for example, was Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 113 designed to comply with the rulings of the Consumer Product Safety Commission, avoiding such things as “social dumping” by prohibiting the sale of hazardous toy. However, in view of trade system which is pursuing liberalization, such behavior is regarded as non-tariff barrier succumbing to pressures from domestic interest groups. The two anomalies mentioned above reveal the insufficiency of domestic regulations in dealing with problems arising from globalized production. And from discussions of the last section, we realized that the various costs imbued in stringent enforcement of regulations become a heavy burden for American regulatory units. Thus, we may want to ask if increasing international economic integration will offset the effects of American social regulations that were meant to encourage businesses to be conscious of and responsible for social development, and, therefore, affect American competitiveness in the global economy. Implications of Social Regulations to American Competitiveness We learned from the above that the compliance costs to American enterprises of social regulations are very large. However, it is hard to discern, from the micro level, if the United States is overall in an inferior position compared to other advanced countries with respect to the economy as a whole. Nevertheless, we are sure that, along with civil liability-related costs, the United States is at the high end of the cost spectrum for regulatory implementations. However, we may not want to think too hard about this issue, but rather to focus on how badly the American economy was affected by social regulatory measures, especially in respect of global markets. What concerns us here is that, in order to fulfill requirements of social regulations, American producers will face steep increases in costs that offset advantages in other aspects. 114 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs Trade performance is mainly determined by the relationship between a country’s saving and investment. If domestic saving is insufficient for investment demands, then foreign savings would be needed. The rise in foreign investment will, on one hand, increase domestic production which in turn needs more input from abroad, and, on the other hand, raise domestic consumption demand caused by rising income, which also needs more imports to fill the shortage of domestic production or to satisfy diversified consumer demands. Thus, there should be no evidence that regulatory proceedings affect overall saving and investment, so long-run as aggregate trade flows have little to do with the issues of legal processes. Of course, it is undeniable that legalistic regulations can and do affect the trade performance of individual firms or even industries. This might lead to aggregate trade effects in the very short run. Such effects, however, are soon canceled out by adjustments in exchange rates. A more relevant matter is whether differences in regulatory content and legal implementation affect domestic living standards. This is what many people mean by competitiveness. In other words, how well does a nation live when its trade is balanced? Other things being equal, it is better to balance trade with a higher exchange rate than with a lower one, because a stronger dollar allows one to purchase imports more cheaply.47 However, even with a higher exchange rate, we still can not ignore the costly litigations involved in social regulations and the rising enforcement costs thereof. If, with reasonable estimation, the U.S. legalistic regulatory system has imposed an additional “tax” of about 4 percent to 5 percent of 47 This is not meant to cut into the debate on optimal exchange rate. Of course, with a higher nominal exchange rate, i.e. a devalued dollar, it seems more palpable for the US to attain current trade balance. But a higher purchasing power for the Americans, i.e. a higher real exchange rate, appears to be more desirable for improving welfare. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 115 GDP,48 does it mean that given the United States having fixed its legal system, or carved its costs down to some levels similar to those in other countries—U.S. living standards would rise by 4 or 5 percent? It is not likely. First, other countries spend money on compensating victims, too, though they rely on government compensation mechanisms. Second, other societies, too, spend money on lawyers. Legal expenditure buy some social benefits. Viewed from the point of equilibrium, once a country has made a law, it can have some deterrent effects even though the law is not strictly enforced. So it is better than no laws.49 It is not easy to do cost-benefit analysis on social regulations. Even though we could accurately estimate the costs private businesses spend on complying with the rules and other relevant legal expenditure, it is difficult to objectively estimate the social benefits from the regulations. Now suppose, as we argued in the above, the adversarial legalism is so prevalent that the United States only receives fifty cents of social benefits 48 49 Studies on the 1990s estimate that the country spends approximately $100 billion on lawyers each year, or about 1.5 percent of GDP. Cf. Richard H. Sander, “Elevating the Debate on Lawyers and Economic Growth,” Law and Social Inquiry, 17 (Fall 1992), p. 665. Furthermore, if the Tillinghast estimates for 1989 are more or less correct, then the U.S. liability system has imposed an additional “tax” of about $117 billion annually, or approximately 2.6 percent of GDP; cf. David R. Tillinghast, “Post-Acquisition Restructuring of Foreign-Owned U.S. Corporate Groups,” Bulletin for International Fiscal Documentation, 45 (July-August 1991): 347-355. If compensations for victims and their attorneys but not counting compliance costs imposed by government regulations are included, the United States could have spent a total of 3.5 percent of GDP. But the total figure could be closer to 4 percent or 5 percent, because the above estimates do not count the time that business people must divert from their regular activities to legal problems. See Robert D. Cooter, “Law from Order: Economic Development and the Jurisprudence of Social Norms,” in Mancur Olson and Satu Kähkönen, eds., A Not-So-Dismal Science: A Broader View of Economies and Societies (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000): 228-244. He raised an example. When the government of Berkeley, California issued an order to require owners of pets to clean the roads polluted by their pets (the “pooper-scooper” law), people became less tolerant toward those who spoil their dogs because, after all, it is easier to ask others to “abide by the law,” than to say “don’t be impolite.” Afterwards, most pet owners did their duty to take care of the wastage of dogs and the roads became much more cleaner (p. 242). 116 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs for every dollar of liability bills,50 this would imply, from calculations in the above, that for gross costs to the economy of 3.5 percent or 4 percent, the United States has net social costs of about 2 percent of GDP (or about $50 a person). That is, the country would be better off as a society by that per-capita amount, if it did not have this burden. And this would be true regardless of whether or not other countries’ liability costs and benefits are better balanced. It should be noted that as far as regulations are concerned, we can not ignore the deadweight loss involved.51 There are good as well as bad regulations. Specifically, the interaction effects of some regulation may exacerbate the deadweight loss of other regulations. The classical example of this is a tax on two complementary goods. And in other cases, the effects may cancel out. A classical example of this is the polluting monopolist: regulations designed to increase monopoly production offset regulations designed to reduce pollution. So it is not realistic to simply add the separately calculated effects of different regulations. But, it appears very difficult to come up with anything that can work around this problem. Thus, viewed from the average value, the impact of social regulations on the whole of society would not be large, but the impact of higher liability and legal costs can be more pronounced for particular industries. Here the key question is whether the higher costs fall on inputs or on product design. Input costs might be higher for certain US industries because of various regulations or liability-related costs. And regardless of 50 This seems an ad hoc assertion, but from the above-mentioned estimate that over half of the regulatory compliance compensation are eaten up by administrative costs, it is reasonable to assume that net benefit to the economy is at most half of the total spending. See note 38. 51 I would like to thank an anomalous referee for point out this. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 117 whether the higher costs are offset by social benefits, they hurt US exports abroad, while also making it easier for foreigners to sell their goods in America.52 However, in the case where the legal costs fall on product design, foreigners must meet US standards, whether imposed by regulation or by liability suits, and thus American firms face no disadvantage. As for US exports, if American firms are able to differentiate their products for the home and for foreign markets (rightand left-side drive on automobiles, for instance), then the variations in product standards should make no significant difference. There are two important qualifications to these results, however. First, if it costs US firms money to make different product designs, whether because of higher R&D expenses or other development costs, then the differences in law that lead to variations in design do put US exports at a disadvantage (unless foreign firms seeking to export their design to the U.S. market suffer corresponding costs). The second, and perhaps the potentially more important, qualification is that the US legal process may create uncertainties that stifle innovation, thereby harming exports, reducing the US equilibrium exchange rate, and thus damaging living standards. The general aviation industry appears to be a clear case in point. Another is the pharmaceutical industry. But there should be no broad base for impact on innovation. In short, legal differences affecting input costs can put US companies at a competitive disadvantage, at home or abroad, but differences affecting product design are less likely to have this consequence. For example, a study by Robert Litan, using data from 1978 through 1984, could not discern a statistically significant effect of differences in liability 52 Though foreign-owned businesses in the United States presumably do not get this advantage unless they purchase all of their basic inputs abroad. 118 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs costs on export performance across industries.53 On the other hand, if Americans are more likely to be familiar with the complexities than foreigners are, the more costly legal process here acts as an invisible entry barrier to foreign investors. This would have the effect of protecting US firms from competition. Conclusions Transition in the United States from economic regulations in the past to social regulations revealed general perceptions of the public and advocacy groups not to favor business but instead to cherish society’s welfare. However, policy making and enforcement of social regulations brought to the American legalistic society anomalously large legal and compliance costs that are deemed unnecessary. This changed the formerly interdependent and friendly relationship between government and businesses into one of frequently accusing each other in the courts. On the other hand, we witnessed a change from government-assisted enhancement in competitiveness in favor of industrial benefits into a dilemma where industries face unpredictable regulatory costs, with uncertainties in effects on competitiveness in the global economy. Compared with other countries’ more cooperative and accommodative style in regulatory enforcements, the American social regulations are much more prescriptive and detailed in processes, and are thereby often challenged in the courts by the regulated enterprises. The formality of procedure and severity of punishment in US regulatory measures are also associated with more conflicts, such as disputes in penalties, civil suits for remediation and encouragement to 53 Robert E. Litan, “The Liability Explosion and American Trade Performance: Myths and Realities,” in Peter H. Schuck, ed., Tort Law and the Public Interest: Competition, Innovation, and Consumer Welfare (New York: Norton, 1991): 127-150. Implications of American Social Regulations for Its Competitiveness in the Global Economy 119 both government and the business to be plaintiffs in the courts. A large amount of social, as well as economic, costs were incurred culminating in unpredictability of judicial decisions, fast accumulation of legal expenses, costly regulatory compliances, and implicit opportunity costs to society. Furthermore, as regulated enterprises have become more defensive and adversarial towards the regulatory agencies, information costs arising from evidence gathering and tedious litigations are also not negligible. Increasing integration of the United States in the global economy, along with declining government effectiveness in the face of globalization, pressured American regulatory decision-makers to think seriously about limiting their policies. Many regulations initially raised as a safeguard for workplace security and health are regarded by free traders as non-tariff barriers. With additional costs the American public and private sectors incurred on regulatory policies, people begin to question whether American competitiveness has been impaired. Nevertheless, viewed from living standards of the American people, the net social costs caused by regulatory policies should not be very large to the overall economy. However, the costs would be a big burden for individual enterprises. They may be placed in a competitive disadvantage if regulatory costs fall on inputs of production. But when the costs fall on product design, given there being differences in export designs and no deterrence to innovation, it is less likely to have negative consequences. Finally, suppose perverse or unnecessary legal and regulatory costs exist and do have at least some deleterious impact on specific industries. One possible solution is executive branch review of major regulations to ensure better cost effectiveness. This process has been subject to speculation that it would only fuel the litigation fire. The cost-benefit test, 120 Tamkang Journal of International Affairs however, could be backed by judicial review to safeguard its fairness. As to the proposal to put a “social tariff” on incoming goods, ostensibly to level the playing field between the United States and foreign competitors (such as those raised by Ralph Nader from the left, or Pat Buchanan from the right), this would amount to making value judgments on the appropriate level of regulation abroad, since the United States would be punishing foreigners for being less stringent than itself. Moreover, the social tariff only affects imports and thus really masks protectionism. It does nothing to help U.S. exports and sales in third markets, but rather would hurt U.S. exports, since it would raise the U.S. exchange rate.