Actuarial Sciences Equity Risk under Solvency II by: Hans Heintz & Timo van der Veen All regulations induce both intended and unintended effects. The aim of Solvency II is clear, but certain consequences of the regulation may lead to an undesirable situation. This article illustrates that regulations imposed by Solvency II may not lower the risk for policyholders as much as intended. This is particularly true with respect to the treatment of equity risk. The analysis of CEIOPS to measure equity risk, neglects a variety of factors that are important for analyzing portfolio risk in the long-term. This article argues that the duration of liabilities plays an important role in insurance companies’ risk profile, and that the requirements for equity risk should explicitly incorporate this. Literature shows that as the investment horizon increases, stocks become less risky while providing relatively high returns. This implies that capital requirements on equity must be decreasing with the duration of liabilities of a life insurance company. Introduction The main objective of Solvency II is policyholder protection by ensuring financial soundness of insurance companies. The insolvency risk of an insurance company must be reduced to at most 0.5 percent for the coming year, leading to the requirement of holding a minimum amount of capital. Investments in risky assets require higher amounts of capital than less risky investments. As the (1 year) volatility of stocks is higher than the volatility on bonds, Solvency II considers equity to be riskier than bonds. Solvency II defines risk as the probability that assets will be insufficient to cover liabilities during the following year. This definition, however, does not take the duration of the liabilities into account. This can be problematic for life insurance companies with long term liabilities. Solvency II requires them to use a mark to market valuation of assets and liabilities. Mark to market valuation introduces swings in their solvency ratios as equity prices are volatile. But there is no reason to liquidate investments in the short term if liabilities lay in the far future. It therefore seems more reasonable to require a life insurance company to meet its (future) liabilities with a probability of 99.5 percent. This seems like a nuance in formulation, but it is not. The difference will become clear at the end of this article. In his book ‘Stock for the Long Run’ Jeremy Siegel argues that in the long run stocks bear less risk than bonds, while they have a higher return. If true, Solvency II does not only introduce adverse side effects, it also misses its goal to decrease the risk for insurance companies. Solvency II might bring the insolvency risk for insurance companies to 0.5 percent for the year ahead, but this could lead to a suboptimal asset allocation if a longer time span is taken into consideration. Multiple institutions saw their capital evaporate during the financial crises of 2008. Regulators responded by increasing the capital requirements. Low supply of capital, combined with a high demand, makes capital expensive as a mean for funding. However, if capital is expensive and the capital requirements for equities 2 AENORM vol. 19 (75) May 2012 are high, equity becomes unaffordable for insurance companies. Accordingly, by implementing high capital requirements for equity, Solvency II stimulates insurance companies to reduce their investments in equity. The change of asset allocation increases several risks in the economy. The problem is that this increase in risk is not measurable, but surely affects the policyholders. Capital Requirements of Solvency II The high capital requirements do not only make equity unaffordable, they also incentivize insurance companies to change their product mix. Products with a defined benefit scheme become too expensive under the new Hans Heintz After graduating in business econometrics in 1995, Hans joined ING Barings to work within the Trading Risk department. In 2000, Hans became account manager large corporate relations at Deutsche Bank Corporate Finance. In 2006 Hans moved back to ING, where he helped to establish a new model validation department. In 2008 Hans together with three other partners founded RiskQuest, an Amsterdam based consultancy firm specialized in mathematical models for financial solutions. Timo van der Veen In August 2012 Timo graduated with a bachelors degree in econometrics and operational research at the University of Amsterdam. In September 2012 Timo started the master financial econometrics at the UvA. In the same month he joined RiskQuest to acquire empirical competence in Risk management and to write his thesis. Actuarial Sciences regulations. The market-consistent approach of Solvency II values assets at current market prices. The liabilities of defined benefit products are fixed for sometimes more than 30 years, while the assets covering these liabilities bear the risk of a sharp decline in prices every day. It therefore seems attractive to transfer this risk to the policyholder. Defined benefit products become rarer and defined contribution products may be the new norm. Danielsson et al. (2012) state that “market-consistent valuation induces excessive volatility in solvency ratios for insurers with matched long-term liabilities. Solvency II should introduce measures recognizing the possibility of temporary adjustments in required solvency ratios, to facilitate carrying matched long-term promises.” Solvency II does introduce a symmetric adjustment mechanism1, which should cover the risk arising from changes in the level of equity prices. If the equity index (MSCI World developed index) is smaller than a weighted average level of this index, the equity capital charge will be lower than the standard capital charge.2 But according to Danielsson et al. (2012) “The proposed countercyclical premium adjustment defines a valuation concept with no economic foundations, and is thus easily manipulated. It even fails to be countercyclical, as it adjusts reserve requirements only in distress.” Although the adjustment mechanism indeed discourages fire sales of equities during an equity crash and thus pro-cyclical effects on the equity market during the first few months of a crisis, it does not prevent pro-cyclical effects if the crisis has a longer time span. The shift from equities to bonds will affect the economy. As insurance companies (used to) hold a notable share of Dutch stocks3, the portfolio shift to bonds may depress the stock market prices. This shall consequently diminish people’s wealth, which decreases consumption; moreover it decreases the investments of companies, since they will be less inclined to issue new shares and invest the revenues in capital4. There exists a variety of literature that endorses this relationship5. Please note in this context that insurance companies are highly appreciated shareholders as their long horizon makes them stable partners. Since Dutch insurers invest in Dutch companies, losing them as a shareholder is a clear loss. CEIOPS’s Model The Dutch central bank (DNB) does not deny that Solvency II gives the incentive to invest in short-term bonds. When asked6 whether this incentive would not be detrimental for the economy, DNB responded: “that might be, but we need solid insurance companies”. The assumption behind this statement is that a larger amount of short term bonds makes an insurance company more solid. We are, however, not convinced that this assumption holds in the long run. The analysis of risk chosen by CEIOPS determines the cost for holding equity. It is therefore important to assess this model. There are some complications in the measurement of risk. Besides the fact that all quantitative analyses rely on the implicit assumption that information from the past resembles information about the future, the form of the model on which the test are based will influence the outcome. It is therefore crucial to have good arguments that justify the specification of the model. This specification, again, is an unavoidable assumption in every quantitative model. For that very reason it is important to substantiate the specification of the model not only with economic theory, but also with common sense. The lack of the latter in econometric models is more often considered the reason for the financial crisis. Within CEIOPS there were three proposals for the equity charge for global equities, each proposal based on the usual Value at Risk (VaR) of different analyses. The choice for the basis7 level of capital requirement of 45% was grounded on the first proposal, supported by the majority of member states. The analysis for this proposal used the frequency distribution of the MSCI World Developed Markets Price Equity Index annual returns from 1973 to 2009. In this analysis CEIOPS has chosen to “take a rolling one-year window in order to make use of the greatest possible quantity of relevant data.” Although the possibility of distortion resulting from autocorrelation is mentioned, the model does not correct for it. This is quite strange, as it is known that if data contains autocorrelation and the model does not adjust for it, inference on the outcomes is unreliable. Another invalid assumption underlying this model is that the variance of equity is constant over time. Also note that the time interval is 1 year, so that it is assumed that the risk of equity is equal to the 1 year risk, irrespective of the investment horizon. 1. The symmetric adjustment mechanism tries to reduce pro-cyclical effects during an equity crash, by reducing the capital requirements during such a crash. 2. If the index is higher than the weighted average level, the equity charge will be higher than the standard capital charge. Moreover If the index is higher than the weighted average level, the equity charge will be higher than the standard capital. 3. Their total portfolio is worth about 300 billion Euros 4. Tobin’s q 5. See for example: Poterba, J. (2000), and Davis, M., and M.G. Palumbo. (2001). 6. In “het Financieele dagblad Monday 10 December 2012” 7. Basis in the sense that there is no adjustment from the symmetric adjustment mechanism AENORM vol. 19 (75) May 2012 3 Actuarial Sciences Optimal Asset Allocation Consider a stylized example: suppose that each year a certain asset either has a return of 20 percent with a probability of 95 percent or a return of -50 percent with a probability of 5 percent. If an insurance company has liabilities for the next year, the capital requirement must certainly be 50 percent. But if the insurance company has a liability to meet 30 years from now, the capital requirement of 50 percent is not adequate. Using the binomial distribution one can calculate the probability that more than 5 crashes occur in 30 years. This probability is less than 0.58 percent and even if 5 of these crashes occur the annualized return is 3.7 percent (i.e. the monetary value of assets has grown with 200 percent in 30 years). Of course the return of an asset is not distributed as mentioned, but this example does show some important characteristics in the measure of risk that are left out in the analysis of Solvency II. Jeremy Siegel (2006) argues that in the long run stocks bear less risk than bonds, while they have a higher return. Bonds are risky in real terms, because they give a negative return if the inflation turns out to be higher than the interest rate of the bond. Currently, Dutch Government Bonds already have negative real yields, i.e. capital invested in bonds will erode if the inflation keeps at the current low level of 1.7%. Siegel uses historical data from the US to display (see figure 5) the best and worse after-inflation returns for stocks, bonds and bills from 1802 to 2006 over holding periods ranging from 1 to 30 years. Stock returns are measured by dividends plus capital gains or losses available on a broad capitalization-weighted index of U.S small and large stocks. Diebold (2012) argues that time-varying volatility can play a crucial role in portfolio management: “The amount of shares in an optimal portfolio depends on variances and covariances of the assets in the portfolio. In particular, if an investor wants to minimize portfolio return volatility subject to achieving target return ‘µp’, she must minimize w’∑w subject to w’µ = µp, where ‘w’ is the vector of portfolio shares, µ is the conditional mean vector of returns and ‘∑’ is the conditional covariance matrix of returns. If ∑ is time-varying, then so too are optimal portfolio shares”. So if the volatility changes due to an adjustment in measuring the volatility with respect to time, the optimal allocation changes as well.9 Figure 2: Although the annualized standard error is high for short time periods such as a year, if the holding period is 25 years the standard deviation is cut by half. Campbell and Viceira (2002) find that the volatility of equity decreases as the horizon increases (see figure 1). Hence the risk for equity measured in annualized standard deviations is decreasing in the holding period. On basis of these conclusions we think it is more appropriate to use an alternative conduct in the measurement of capital requirements. One in which the basis capital requirement is decreasing in the average liability duration of the insurance company. Conclusion Figure 1: This figure shows the best and worse afterinflation returns for stocks and bonds from 1802 to 2006. Solvency II intends to protect policyholders. However, mark-to-market accounting and the application of the Solvency II capital requirements may have counterproductive effects by stimulating life insurers to opt for less volatile investments, irrespective of their liability structure or duration. This may lead to an excess demand for fixed income instruments, as currently observed in recent Dutch Government Bond issues. In real terms, yields are negative and expose the investor to inflation risk. As a consequence, life insurers will make less strong guarantees and hence opt for defined 8. 0.33 percent 9. This part of the paper of Diebold, however, was written to argue that if the volatility changes from time to time, you should adjust the portfolio dynamically. 4 AENORM vol. 19 (75) May 2012 Actuarial Sciences contribution plans rather than defined benefit. In fact, investment risk is shifted to the policy holders. The combination of mark-to-market accounting and measuring portfolio risk as short term volatility is, in our humble opinion, not appropriate. Literature shows that at a longer horizon equity prices are less volatile and that the equity returns exceed those of other asset classes. Hence, we argue that Solvency II should take the investment horizon into account as well. This horizon is largely based on the duration of liabilities. References Campbell, J. and VICEIRA, M., 2002, Appendix to ‘Strategic Asset Allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long-Term Investors’. Oxford University Press, USA. Davis, M., and M.G. Palumbo, 2001, A Primer on the Economics and Time Series Econometrics of Wealth Effects, Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series No. 09. Diebold, F.X. 2012, 100+ Years of Financial Risk Measurement and Management. Jon Danielsson, Roger Laeven, Enrico Perotti, Mario Wüthrich, Rym Ayadi, Antoon Pelsser, 2012, Countercyclical regulation in Solvency II: Merits and flaws: http://www.voxeu.org/ar-ticle/countercyclicalregulation-solvency-ii-merits-and-flaws. Poterba J., 2000, Stock Market Wealth and Consumption, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(2), pp. 99-119. Siegel, J., 2006, Stocks in the long run Mc Graw Hill. AENORM vol. 19 (75) May 2012 5