Pricing according to cost Cost-based pricing Cost of a service = value of economic means used in order to provide the service: Cost is a relative notion! Tariffs must cover some notion of cost related to service provisioning Cost definition: different incentives Replacement of equipment, introduction of new technologies, encourage or deter entry, invest in sunk costs We investigate Theoretical aspects of cost-sharing Cost-based pricing in practice 2 Theories of cost-sharing Prices based on cost N = { 1,2,...,n} = set of = stand-alone cost of subset T ⊆ N services Economies of scale, scope: The service provider must share the total cost of the services amongst the customers in a fair manner è prices based on costs Stable under competition No incentives for bypass and self-production Solutions of bargaining games Not unique!! 4 Subsidy-free prices The firm sells services in quantities xi ,i = 1,…,n The charges ri = pi xi are subsidy free if they satisfy: The stand-alone cost test ∑px i i ≤ c(A), ∀A ⊆ N i∈A The incremental cost test ∑p x i i ≥ c(N) − c(N \ A), ∀A ⊆ N i∈A If these are violated, a new entrant can attract customers Imply ∑p x i i = c(N) i∈N The corresponding prices are subsidy free 5 Subsidy-free charge example A1 x1 = 2 A2 x2 = 1 A12 = 10 In order to be subsidy-free, the revenues from product A1 and product A2 must satisfy 2 ≤ r1 (A1 x1 ) ≤ 12, 1 ≤ r2 (A2 x2 ) ≤ 11, r1 (A1 x1 ) + r2 (A2 x2 ) = 13 A possible set of charges are (6, 7) 6 7 8 Support prices = cost of producing quantities is a support price for at if it satisfies: Price are subsidy-free for all sub-quantities of x Note that these imply economies of scale, Consumers have no incentives for bypass We also need D( p) = x 9 Sustainable Prices Potential competition: incumbent sets prices to cover costs, competitor (E) tries to take part of the incumbent’s market by posting prices which are lower for at least one service We say are sustainable prices if there is no and s.t. for some i, and Necessary conditions for sustainable prices 1. must operate with zero profits 2. must produce at minimum cost 3. prices for all subsets of output must be subsidy free 10 Axiomatic cost sharing: Shapley value Cost is to be fairly shared amongst customers. Charging algorithm: function φ (N) = (φ1 (N),..., φ n (N)) dividing c(N), N ⊆ {1,…,n} Problem: find that no customer can have a valid argument against If φ j (N) − φ j (N − {i}) > 0 then customer is paying more than he would if customer were not being served He might argue this is unfair, unless customer can argue that he’s just as disadvantaged because of : φ i (N) − φ i (N − { j}) = φ j (N) − φ j (N − {i}) Same reasoning if customer benefits from customer φ j (N) − φ j (N − {i}) < 0 Unique φ : charge average incremental cost 11 Sharing the Cost of a Runway Three airplanes share a runway, require 1,2 and 3 km to land. Cost = 1$/km. Problem: How to share the cost? Adds cost Order 1 2 3 1,2,3 1 1 1 1,3,2 1 0 2 2,1,3 0 2 1 2,3,1 0 2 1 3,1,2 0 0 3 3,2,1 0 0 3 avg 2/6 5/6 11/6 12 Pricing in Practice The key principles for pricing In practice, we can identify some key principles Cost causation: service cost should be closely related to the cost of the factors consumed by the service Objectivity: the cost of the service should be related to the right cost factors in an objective way Transparency: the relation of the cost of the service to the cost factors should be clear and analytical Danger of leaving the biggest part of the cost, i.e., the common cost, unrecovered 14 Historic and current costs Historic cost: the actual amount paid to purchase the various factors (equipment, etc) Top-down models, such as FDC, use the historic costs found in the accounting records Current cost: the equipment cost if it were bought today Bottom-up models are naturally combined with current costs (the network model is built from scratch) The use of historic or current costs provides very different incentives to network service providers Examples: access service and interconnection prices 15 Types of cost from accounting Direct cost: the part of the cost attributed solely to the particular service, ceases to exist if service is not produced Indirect cost: other cost related to the service provision Indirectly attributable cost: arises from the provision of a group of services and there is a logical way to specify the percentage of the cost that is related to the provision of each service Un-attributable cost: cannot be divided straightforwardly amongst the services, -> common cost 16 Definitions related to the cost function Variable cost (VC): cost of those factors whose quantities depend on the amount of the service produced marginal cost (MC) variable cost Fixed cost (FC): the sum of all factor costs that remain constant when the quantity of the service changes 1 1 Fixed cost total volume 17 Incremental cost concepts Short-Run Incremental Cost (SRIC): cost of providing a variable amount of the service in the short run assuming that all other services are provided at the same levels (=VC) Long-Run Incremental Cost (LRIC): cost difference of not providing the given service assuming that the facility provides the other services at the same levels as before but can reoptimize its operation (in the long-run), forward looking includes the direct fixed cost of the service LRIC(A) ≈ VC B VC A FC A FC B FCC AB VC C FC C true fixed common cost VC A SRIC(A) VC A FC A Note: cost(S-A) ≤ cost(S) – (VC(A)+FC(A)) hence LRIC(A) = cost(S)-cost(S-A) ≥ VC(A)+FC(A) 18 Stand-alone cost Stand-alone cost (SAC): The cost of building a facility from scratch that provides the single service at the given quantity higher because no economies of scale and scope lower because optimized to offer this service LRIC, SAC need bottom-up models to be correctly estimated VC A VC B VC A FC A SAC(A) ≈ VC C FC B FCC AB FC C FCC(A,B,C) FC A FCC(A,B) FCC(A,B,C) In practice we use top-down models 19 Pricing in practice In practice, we lack a function that can tell us the cost of producing or not any given bundle of services. All we know is the current cost of various factors involved in production Common cost cannot be directly attributed to any particular service, so far as the accounting records show. Only a small part of the total cost concerns factors that can be are uniquely related to a single service This is a major problem when trying to construct cost-related prices direct costs C B indirect common cost from accounting records A VC B VC A FC A FC B FCC AB VC C FC C true fixed common cost 20 Methodologies for constructing prices The Fully Distributed Cost (FDC) approach: make each service pay for part of the (historic) common cost Problem: ad-hoc division of the common cost ! since the common cost is large, prices can be ``cooked’’ LRIC (or IC) (Subsidy-free prices): construct prices by calculating the long-run incremental cost of a service in a network designed to be forward looking Hard to compute the true long run incremental cost IC Needs bottom-up models of the network, current costs, modern equivalent assets Problem: The sum of the incremental costs of the services leaves some common cost unaccounted for 21 Methodologies for constructing prices (2) LRIC+ : add common cost (or the cost that is not covered) to the LRIC prices in a proportional fashion Reasonable approximation of subsidy-free prices since LRIC(A) ≤ LRIC+(A) ≤ SAC(A) Problem: prices not necessarily truly subsidy-free according to theory since we don’t analyze each possible subset of services Better approximation than FDC since incremental cost is better approximated than just direct cost Uses current costs instead of historic, bottom-up models, approximates prices in a competitive market 22 The Fully Distributed Cost approach FDC divides the total cost that the firm incurs amongst the services that it sells All the cost of factors that are not uniquely identified with a single service go to a common cost pool (directly attributable costs) Next, one defines a way to split the common cost among the services 23 Evaluation of FDC § Advantages: § Covers total cost, easy to compute (top-down model) and audit, practical, covers past investments, transparency. § Disadvantages: § There is no reason that the prices constructed are in any sense optimal (competitive) or have any stability property. They hide potential inefficiencies of the network such as excess capacity, out-of-date equipment, bad routing, inefficient operation and resource allocation. § Here is where the refinement of the activity model helps. The definition of activities helps to link a larger part of the common cost to particular services, so improves the subsidy-free properties of the resulting pricing scheme 24 The LRIC, LRIC+ approach Two services A, B LRAIC: Long-run average incremental cost A : average variable cost if variable cost not linear Costs are computed per unit of the service using a bottom up model var. cost A fixed cost A var. cost B fixed cost B common cost A,B LRIC(A) + LRIC(B) < total cost LRIC+(A) + LRIC+(B) = total cost LRIC(A) = FC(A) + VC(A) LRIC+(A) = LRIC(A) + CC(A,B) x LRIC(A)/(LRIC(A)+LRIC(B) 25 Evaluation of LRIC+ Prices promote the correct economic signals to the network operator for improving efficiency Approximate better a competitive market But need bottom-up models which are harder to implement Don’t necessarily cover the actual cost of the network 26 Ordering of the various cost definitions Which cost definition to use for regulation? In a competitive market MC, IC make more sense Low prices (LRIC) in wholesale of the incumbent help competitors High prices in retail (FDC) promote entry by competitors MC Low LRIC LRIC+ LRIC+ FDC LRIC+ SAC High 27 Practical approximations How do we compute fixed costs, variable costs, etc? Easier to use top-down models than bottom-up: use the existing cost accounting records of the firm Usually directly attributable cost is a very small percentage of the total cost Need better understanding of the operation of the firm and the causation of costs to allocate indirect costs => the activity based model helps in “constructing” the cost function and answering questions about the incremental cost of a service, the fixed costs associated with subsets of services, etc. Allows in practice an approximation for the LRIC of services (within ≈15% of the bottom up calculations) 28 Activity-Based Costing approach Activity-Based Costing (ABC) approach defines intermediate activities that contribute to the production of end products Each activity cost can be computed from accounting information about the amounts of input factors that are consumed by each activity Þ A large part of the common cost is attributed to the activities and so be subtracted from common cost Refinement of the FDC approach: By reducing the unaccounted-for common cost, it reduces the inaccuracy that stems from the ad-hoc cost splitting Useful for LRIC+ approximations since it allows the calculation of the incremental and fixed costs 29 Activity-Based Costs (I) Bottom level: the input factors consumed by the net operator, such as labor, power, cost of infrastructure and bandwidth Activity level: processes that must run in order for the network to operate and produce services. An activity has a well-defined purpose, such as the maintenance of certain equipment, the network management, the links’ operation Next level defines the allocation of the activity costs to the network elements such as routers, links Service level: Services such as calls, IP connectivity 30 Activity-Based Costs (II) Hides inefficiencies of the network provider (e.g. if a network element is underutilized) No incentive for the provider to improve his efficiency unless he were only allowed to recover the cost of a network element in proportion to its actual utilization Activity-based pricing is not really suitable for determining the long run incremental cost of a service If a service is not produced, the facility can be reorganized to provide the remaining services at a lesser cost (long-run IC) Nevertheless it provides some lower approximation 31 Εφαρµογή ABC, LRIC+ σε δίκτυα Επιµέρους υπηρεσίες δικτύου Α Β ........... N Κοινό εντός του Δικτύου κόστος (ISFC- Increment Specific Fixed Cost) Συνεργασία µε Σάνδρα Κοέν Επιµέρους υπηρεσίες πρόσβασης a ........... b n Κοινό εντός της Πρόσβασης κόστος (ISFC- Increment Specific Fixed Cost) Κοινό κόστος µεταξύ πρόσβασης και Δικτύου (FCC – Fixed Common Cost) Η κάθε υπηρεσία είναι ένα Increment To Δίκτυο και η Πρόσβαση είναι ευρύτερα increments Μεταξύ των υπηρεσιών του δικτύου υπάρχουν κοινά κόστη Μεταξύ των υπηρεσιών της πρόσβασης υπάρχουν κοινά κόστη Μεταξύ των Increments του δικτύου και της πρόσβασης υπάρχουν κοινά κόστη 32 Εφαρµογή ABC, LRIC+ σε δίκτυα LRIC+ υπηρεσίας Incremental cost (σταθ. + µετβλ.) υπηρεσίας (IC) + Αναλογία κοινού εντός του σχετικού increment κόστους (ISFC) + Αναλογία κοινού µεταξύ των Increments κόστους (FCC) ICΝι ........... Κοινό εντός του Δικτύου κόστος (ISFCΝ) ........... Κοινό εντός της Πρόσβασης κόστος (ISFCΑ) Κοινό κόστος µεταξύ πρόσβασης και Δικτύου (FCC) 33 Εφαρµογή ABC, LRIC+ σε δίκτυα Αναλογία κοινού εντός του increment κόστους (ISFC) ICNi ISFCNi = ISFCnetwork ∑ ICNj n ICΝι ........... Κοινό εντός του Δικτύου κόστος (ISFCΝ) ........... Κοινό εντός της Πρόσβασης κόστος (ISFCΑ) Κοινό κόστος µεταξύ πρόσβασης και Δικτύου (FCC) 34 Εφαρµογή ABC, LRIC+ σε δίκτυα Αναλογίου κοινού µεταξύ των Increments κόστους (FCC) FCCNi = ICΝι ∑ n ICNi + ISFCNi FCC ICNj + ISFCN + ∑ ICAj + ISFCA ........... Κοινό εντός του Δικτύου κόστος (ISFCN) n ........... Κοινό εντός της Πρόσβασης κόστος (ISFCA) Κοινό κόστος µεταξύ πρόσβασης και Δικτύου (FCC) 35 Εφαρµογή ABC, LRIC+ σε δίκτυα Σταθερό + µεταβλητό κόστος υπηρεσίας (IC) Αναλογία κοινού εντός του increment κόστους (ISFC) Αναλογίου κοινού µεταξύ των Increments κόστους (FCC) ICΝι ........... Κοινό εντός του Δικτύου κόστος (ISFCΝ) ........... Κοινό εντός της Πρόσβασης κόστος (ISFCΑ) Κοινό κόστος µεταξύ πρόσβασης και Δικτύου (FCC) LRICNi+ = ICNi + ISFCNi + FCCNi 36 An application (1) A factory produces souvenirs from wood and bronze The only factors directly attributed to the souvenirs production are the amounts of wood and bronze and Common cost: Other factors used in producing souvenirs, such as the labor and electricity A single accounting record for each, no info on how to attribute these costs to the souvenirs production Problem: How to define the cost of each product? 37 An application (2) FDC: We must find a way to split the common cost This approach can give prices that are far from being subsidy-free For instance, suppose we take Þ The bronze souvenirs cost that must be recovered is that is probably greater than the stand-alone cost for producing the same quantity 38 An application (3) Incremental cost approach: computes the difference of the cost of the facility that produces both types from the cost of the facility that produces a single type Problems: accounting records hold only the actual cost and must be evaluated is greater than hence inaccurate computation of 39 Two solutions 1. Bottom-up approach: Construct and from scratch, by building models of fictitious facilities that specialize in the production of a given product 2. Top-down approach: starts from the given cost structure and tries to allocate the cost to the various products but attempt to reduce the unaccounted-for common costs How? Refine the accounting information, by keeping more information on how common cost is generated Use the activity-based model 40 More on activity based costing and FDC The FDC approach revisited Formally, suppose service is produced in quantity and has a variable cost that is directly attributable to that service. There is a shared cost that is attributable to all services. The price for the quantity of service is defined to be its cost, i.e., The price per unit is defined as The s may be chosen in various ways: as proportions of revenue, variable costs, quantities supplied, or revenue, i.e., proportional to or Clearly, once the coefficients are defined, then the construction of the prices is rather trivial and can be done automatically using accounting data 42 FDC example (I) Consider, as above, a facility that produces wooden and bronze souvenirs, with the cost function c(y w , y b ) = s f x f + sl (x 0l + α w y w + α b y b ) + swθ w y w +sb θ b y b , where is the per unit cost of the fixed factor , is the per unit cost of the labor factor, are the per unit costs of wood and bronze respectively, the fixed amount of labor that is consumed independently of the production, and are coefficients that relate the levels of production of the artifacts to the amount of consumed labor that is directly attributed to the production, and and relate these levels of production to the amount of raw materials consumed ü Note that are fixed costs, whereas is the variable part of the cost 43 FDC Example (II) Consider first the case of simple FDC pricing without activity definitions and no explicit accounting info on how labor effort is spent In this case the common cost is the remaining part and the FDC prices are of the form [ pw (y w ) = s θ w y w + γ w s x + s ( x + α w y w + α b y b ) w f [ f l l 0 ] (1) ] pb (y b ) = sbθ b y b + (1 − γ w ) s f x f + sl ( x 0l + α w y w + α b y b ) (2) 44 FDC Example (III) Now suppose two activities defined, related to the production of the artifacts. In each activity, there is exact accounting of the labor effort required for the production of each artifact Now and the common cost is reduced to The resulting FDC prices are (3) (4) 45 Observations (I) The prices in the simple FDC approach less accurately relate prices to actual costs Suppose, i.e., wooden artifacts are extremely easy to construct and the greater part of labor effort is spent on bronze artifacts. Let there be equal sharing of the common cost, so Þ Then the price of wooden artifacts in (1) subsidizes the production of bronze artifacts as it pays for a substantial part of the labor for making them ü This cross-subsidization disappears in (3) 46 Observations (II) Suppose that the facility is built inefficiently and that the amount of building space is larger than would be required if new technologies were used This fact is hidden in both (1) and (3). However, if one develops a bottom-up model for the facility, the corresponding factor in this model will be less, say This will reduce the corresponding prices in (3) Thus with the activity-based approach one can trace the reason for the price discrepancy between the top-down and the bottom-up model, as being due to the second term, and hence one can trace the inefficiency in the existing system 47 Observations (III) Consider the price of wooden artifacts. The variable part of the price in (3) is a better approximation of the longrun incremental cost of producing the amount of wooden artifacts than the variable part in (1) The reason that it may not be equal to the long-run incremental cost is that if only one artifact is produced, then the common cost could be reduced (perhaps a smaller facility is needed, or one secretary will suffice rather than two). Unfortunately this reduction can’t be extracted from the accounting data One must construct a `virtual' model of the facility specialized in constructing only bronze artifacts, to subtract the corresponding total production costs This again shows the weakness of the top-down 48 models that are the basis of FDC pricing