A Note on How to Compute Unlevered Betas for Highly Levered Companies Abstract The expected cost of capital is usually obtained by estimating its individual components, the cost of debt and the cost of equity, and computing a WACC. Unfortunately, in the presence of risky debt, the standard methodology produces a systematic overestimation. This bias is increasing in leverage and volatility of assets. In this paper, we propose a novel methodology to compute the expected return on assets by estimating the unlevered beta from a time series of assets returns constructed on the basis of Merton (1974)’s model. Keywords: Cost of Capital, Leverage, Beta, Contingent Pricing, WACC, Merton JEL Classification: G12, G13, G31, G32 1. Introduction The cost of capital is a topic of paramount importance for corporate finance, with applications to capital budgeting, valuation, incentive compensation schemes… Unfortunately, the literature does not offer adequate or practicable recommendations for highly levered firms. This note makes a straightforward contribution in the determination of the cost of capital of such firms. In computing the weighted average cost of capital (WACC), it is common practice to use the promised yield of debt contracts, which is far from the expected return (πΎπ· ) of debt of highly levered firms. The promised yield, usually measured by the internal rate of return, is the highest of all possible returns. If default is possible, it is not an average of possible returns. Under the latter assumption, using the promised return of debt in the computation of WACC is not correct, because WACC should measure the expected return required by the providers of the capital. This common error has been addressed by Cooper and Davydenko (2007), who propose a method of estimating πΎπ· to be used in the computation of the WACC. They obtain πΎπ· by making use of Merton (1974)’s model. For ease of exposition, they assume the absence of taxes, in which case WACC equals the expected return (πΎπ΄ ) on assets or, more precisely, the expected return of equity holders were the firm not levered. We also assume taxes away and use Merton´s model. A key input in Cooper and Davydenko (2007)’s model is the expected return (πΎπΈ ) on equity (πΈ), which they propose to estimate by a standard application of CAPM, that is, using the historical beta of equity returns. This amounts to assuming a constant expected return on equity (πΎπΈ ), which is structurally inconsistent with Merton (1974)’s model. In the latter, πΎπΈ varies constantly with the value of assets (π΄). Moreover, πΎπΈ tends to infinity as the present value of debt (π·) tends to π΄. Therefore, the more needed is the methodology, the more inaccurate are the results. An alternative approach proposed to obtain πΎπ΄ is to compute it from an estimate of the beta of assets (π½π΄ ), which equals the weighted average of the beta of equity (π½πΈ ) and the beta of debt (π½π· ). However, the estimation of π½π· is problematic for two reasons: (i) the lack of liquidity of the most debt instruments, and (ii) the variability of π½π· due to changes in the π΄. Typically, π½π· is assumed null, which is grossly inadequate for highly levered companies. The problem with the previous approaches is that they rely on the common assumption that π½πΈ , πΎπΈ , π½π· and πΎπ· remain constant. Merton’s model contradicts this assumption as it identifies equity with a long call option on the assets of the company, and debt with a portfolio comprising those assets and a short call on them. This paper proposes a novel approach that, instead of computing π½π΄ as an average of π½πΈ and π½π· , directly estimates π½π΄ from a time series of assets returns, which can be constructed using Merton (1974)´s model. After π½π΄ has been estimated, πΎπ΄ can be computed using the CAPM. Briefly, we propose a methodology of estimating πΎπ΄ that comprises the following steps: (i) creating a time series of asset values, (ii) computing the corresponding series of asset returns, (iii) estimating the beta of assets, and finally (iv) calculating πΎπ΄ , the expected return on assets. 2. Construction of a time series of assets returns In order to construct the time series of asset values, we compute π΄ at each single observation time using Merton´s model. The steps are as follows: 1. A time series of equity volatility ππΈ is obtained. There are different possibilities to achieve this: a simple exponentially weighted moving average historical volatility, or a version of GARCH models, or the so-called realized volatility. We would not discard the use of implied volatility of equity options, although we are aware that assuming log returns on equity as normal is inconsistent with the following step 3. 2. Debt payments are mapped into a single pair of tenor π and payment π·π . 3. Assuming that assets returns are normally distributed, and given the market value πΈ of equity, its volatility ππΈ , and the risk free rate ππ , we can compute both the value π΄ of total assets and its volatility ππ΄ by solving numerically the following twoequation system: πΈ = π΄ N(π1 ) − π·π π −ππ π N(π2 ) (1) πΈ ππΈ = N(π1 ) π΄ ππ΄ (2) where π1 = π΄ ln π· + ππ π π ππ΄ √π + ππ΄ √π 2 and π2 = π1 − ππ΄ √π. Equation (1) is Merton (1974)’s formula for the valuation of the equity of a company. Equation (2) was obtained from (1) by Jones, Mason & Rosenfeld (1984) using Ito’s formula. The above system of equations is routinely solved by rating agencies to obtain the risk-neutral default probability 1 − N(π2 ) or N(−π2 ), which is them mapped into a realworld default probability. The rationale of equation (2) can be grasped by considering, on the one hand, that multiplying the values πΈ and π΄ of equity and assets by their corresponding percentage variability, ππΈ and ππ΄ , yields the dollar variability of each, πΈππΈ ππΈ and π΄ππ΄ , and, on the other hand, that delta N(π1 ) = ππ΄ is the ratio of dollar changes in πΈ and π΄. Although we obtain both π΄ and ππ΄ for each observation time, only the time series of π΄ needs to be used to estimate the unlevered beta π½π΄ , from which the expected return πΎπ΄ on assets can be computed using the CAPM. Moreover, any version of APT can be used to estimate the expected return on assets from the time series of π΄. 3. Possible Extensions The approach explained in the paper could be complemented in several ways. First, given the importance of equity volatility ππΈ for this model, different estimation procedures could be explored, discussing strengths and weaknesses of each. Second, the model could be extended by allowing rollover of debt maturity. Third, it would be interesting to run an empirical test comparing the time series of assets values estimated with the proposed methodology against the historical asset values in those cases in which market value of debt is available. Another relevant experiment would be the comparison between traditional equity betas unlevered using Modigliani and Miller (1958)’s framework with those obtained using our approach. 4. Conclusions In this paper we suggest a novel methodology, based on Merton (1974)’s model, to directly compute the expected return on assets without estimating the expected returns of debt and equity. This method aims to solve the typically overseen instability of those components. References Cooper, I. A. and S. A. Davydenko (2007). "Estimating the Cost of Risky Debt." Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 19(3): 90-95. Jones, E. P., S. P. Mason, and E. Rosenfeld (1984), Contingent Claims Analysis of Corporate Capital Structure: An Empirical Investigation, Journal of Finance, 39, 61125. Merton, R. C. (1974), On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates, Journal of Finance, 29, 449-70. Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1958). "The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment." The American Economic Review XLVIII(3): 261-297.