3.1 Choice of indicators - Georg-August

advertisement
Sandra Kröger
Georg-August Universität Göttingen
Humboldtallee 3
37073 Göttingen
Germany
e-mail: sandra_kroeger@gmx.net
Number of words (text): 7.956
Abstract
Many scholars support the idea that the Open Method of Coordination (OMC) is fostering
learning processes. This article takes a closer look at the OMC in the field of poverty and
social exclusion, and more particularly its indicators, in order to empirically evaluate whether
this assumption is well founded. Particular attention is given to the choice of indicators, the
information they transport, the comparability and data availability and the processes leading
to the development of the indicators. It finally argues that in order to make OMCs in the
social field more meaningful, more competences must be given to the EU-level.
Keywords:
OMC, learning, indicators, poverty.
Do numbers induce learning? Assessing the Laeken indicators of the
Open Method of Coordination1
1. Introduction2
In the last few years, the Open Method of Coordination (OMC) in the field of social policy
has attracted considerable attention amongst social scientists, mostly in the context of the
European Employment Strategy (EES)3, to a considerably lesser extent in the fields of
inclusion, pensions and health. Most analyses have focused on conceptual and theoretical
issues4, fewer were concerned with in-depth analysis of the actual implementation of the
various OMCs5; equally few have analysed the theoretical assumptions of the OMC or its
concrete construction at EU level. Generally spoken, the OMC was – and mostly still is – seen
as a promising governance instrument in the absence of more binding mechanisms to bring
about “modernisation” of the so-called European Social Model (ESM) by initiating mutual
learning processes. Yet, it is argued here, in order to have an appropriate understanding of
what the OMC can potentially do for “social Europe”, it is essential to analyse the theoretical
assumptions and the technical toolbox of the OMC at EU level and the processes surrounding
their development.
The OMCs have mostly been conceptualised as enhancing steering through “learning” – a
precise definition of what “learning” should denote is mostly missing. This is certainly related
to the Lisbon Conclusions which introduced the OMC and several political EU texts since in
1
Paper originally presented under a different title at the young researchers workshop of the ESPAnet in Bath, 12 April 2005.
2
I am grateful for critical and constructive comments from Milena Büchs, Hester Kan, Stephan Lessenich,
Ramon Pena-Casa, Geny Piotty and John Veit-Wilson.
3
As examples, see Büchs (2005) and Goetschy (2003).
4
See Kröger 2005 for the inclusion process.
5
Exceptions include Büchs (2005) for the EES as well as Atkinson et al. (2002), Friedrich (2006) and Kröger
(2006) for the inclusion process.
which one can continuously find a strong focus on learning6. In the light of absent sanctionary
mechanisms within the OMCs, it is assumed that “learning” can lead to policy change – and
reform – through a shift of policy actors’ understandings of social problems and their
solutions7.
However, strong empirical support for de facto learning processes induced by the OMC
inclusion is missing. To the contrary, those who invested in in-depth empirical research
mostly conclude that the OMC inclusion has so far not delivered on both expected fronts, that
is on effectiveness and legitimacy (Idema and Kelemen, forthcoming, Kröger 2006). Indeed,
one can wonder why the tool box of the OMCs and its non-bindingness should promote
“learning” processes in a politically highly sensitive policy area where further integration was
and remains judged undesirable for reasons of institutional diversity and political and
ideological disagreements8. It often seems as if research tends to neglect that we are dealing
with a political process, in which one can find different ideas, interests and resources
available, which is embedded in other, “stronger” political processes such the EMU or the
Growth and Stability Pact (Scharpf 2002).
In the following, I will deal with the commonly agreed indicators and their development in
the context of the OMC inclusion and evaluate if they can contribute to supranational learning
processes. First, they constitute the “hardest” element of the OMC inclusion and therefore can
best be evaluated. Second, they contribute to the framing of a given social problem and
therewith are indicative of the current approach to social policy matters. Third, as will be
shown, they point to the diverse difficulties that the soft governance approach of the OMC
faces in the social field. Particular attention will be given to 1) the choice and content of
indicators; 2) the information that the indicators transport; 3) the comparability and data
The Lisbon Conclusions imagine the OMC inclusion as “periodic monitoring, evaluation and peer review
organised as mutual learning processes” (para 37).
7
See Berghman et al 2003; Jacobsson 2002 and Trubek and Mosher 2003 among many others.
8
Disagreements about how to conceive of the social sphere and how to organize it institutionally and financially.
6
availability as well as 4) the processes leading to the development of the indicators. Why are
these for issues central in the “learning” context of the OMC?
As for content, the main question is whether the choice of indicators is broad enough so as to
draw a picture of the diverse aspects of poverty. If one assumes that different aspects of
poverty interact with one another and can be mutually reinforcing, then a wide range of
indicators needs to be taken into consideration. With respect to the second point, the main
question of concern here is whether the indicators provide the information necessary to learn
about the reasons for the respective performances, or, in other words, whether the indicators
allow for the contextualisation of performances. Thirdly, in order to support learning
processes, it is clear that the data need to be comparable, available and timely. Finally, if
“learning” is to happen, it is essential that all actors concerned have the possibility to
contribute to the debate, that the process be open and transparent (Friedrich 2006). In the
empirical section, I will review in how far these four points are met by the Laeken indicators.
After a brief review of the OMC inclusion process (2), the second part will review theories of
learning and deliberation which have been used in the scientific community to conceptualise
the OMC (3). The next section will confront these theories with the empirical reality of the
commonly agreed indicators, their choice and development as well as the actors involved (4).
Finally, the discussion will review why it might not (yet) be possible to conceive of the OMC
as promoting learning processes and in how far there remain structural limitations to
supranational learning in the social policy field (5). The analysis, other than on academic
literature and policy documents, particularly draws upon in-depth interviews with involved
actors9.
9
See footnote 20.
2. Introducing the OMC inclusion
In 2000, the Lisbon Council decided to officially install a governance instrument 10, the OMC,
which was seen as respecting the principle of subsidiarity11 in social matters in the EU while
nevertheless leading member states in the direction of convergence of performances and the
„modernisation“ of the ESM through ongoing processes of exchange, comparison and
learning12 and benchmarking13. While diverging in some aspects, most OMCs have since then
integrated common features such as the writing of National Action Plans (NAPs) by the
member states, evaluating Joint Reports by the Commission and the Council, gathering data
on the basis of commonly agreed indicators, peer reviews, potentially benchmarking, and the
exchange of best practices.
The four common objectives that were agreed upon for the social inclusion process at the
Nice Council in December 2000 were: 1) Access to employment and to resources, rights,
goods and services, 2) prevention of the risks of exclusion, 3) help for the most vulnerable
and 4) mobilisation of all relevant bodies. While these common objectives 14 certainly reflect a
multi-dimensional approach to social exclusion, they are very broad and leave considerable
space for interpretation and implementation.
Since its inauguration in 2000, member states have produced three NAPs (2001, 2003 and
2005), and the Commission respectively three Joint Reports (2002, 2004 and 2005). In June
10
Whereas the OMC was introduced in Lisbon, elements of it such as guidelines, benchmarking and peer review
had already been in practice for a longer time.
11
Article 3b of the Treaty on the European Union states that "the Community shall take action, in accordance
with the principle of subsidiarity, only if and insofar as the objectives of the proposed action cannot be
sufficiently achieved by the Member States and can therefore, by reason of the scale or effects of the proposed
action, be better achieved by the Community".
12
For a broad overview of the respective literature, see Zeitlin "The Open Method of Coordination in Action:
Theoretical Promise, Empirical Realities, Reform Strategy.", in: Zeitlin, Jonathan, Pochet, Philippe and Lars
Magnusson (eds.) 2005, The Open Method of Coordination in Action: The European Employment and Social
Inclusion Strategies. Brussels: P.I.E.-Peter Lang, to be found at: http://eucenter.wisc.edu/OMC/open12.html.
13
For the origins of the concept of „benchmarking“ in the economy as well as in the EU, see Arrowsmith et al.
(2004) and de la Porte, Pochet and Room (2001).
14
It should be mentioned that they are spelled out in greater detail in the respective official EU-document:
Objectives in the fight against poverty and social exclusion (EC: 2001/C 82/02).
2000, the Social Protection Committee (SPC) was established through the Council15. The SPC
is meant to be the connecting mechanism between member states, the Council and the
Commission with respect to the “modernisation” of the social protection systems. Its purpose
is therefore broader than the issues at stake in the context of the OMC inclusion It has, soon
after its coming into existence, created an indicator sub-group (ISG) which was and remains
responsible for the elaboration and further development of common indicators. The so-called
Laeken indicators were adopted by the Employment and Social Affairs Council in December
2001 and were therefore only used in the second and third round of NAPs.
While these developments are considerable achievements, there was stagnation with respect
to quantified targets (Greve 2002: 11) which would – to some degree – permit evaluation of
compliance16. Yet, “if the process is to be meaningful and credible, targets are essential”
(Atkinson et al. 2004: 66) as they are a prove of political commitment and a goal against
which to measure progress. Without quantified targets, the intended benchmarking process
also becomes impossible17. There equally has been no dynamic with respect to the further
development of the common objectives.
3. Situating the OMC in the learning literature
Many different approaches have been offered in order to come to grips with the OMC.
Nowadays, they are commonly referred to as governance literature. This literature is inspired
by theories of learning and deliberation (Cohen and Sabel 1997), of policy transfer (Dolowitz
15
See the Council Decision of 29 June 2000 on Setting up a Social Protection Committee (2000/436/EC). The
SPC subsequently gained a Treaty basis in 2003.
16
The Common Outline for the NAPs 2003-2005 of the SPC invited member states to set targets that are
ambitious but achievable, relevant, intelligible, quantified, measurable, and time specific (SPC 2003, Appendix
I).
17
Ramon Pena-Casas has pointed to me that a “pure benchmarking” process was not the aim of the exercise (and
impossible in light of the principle of subsidiarity). While this is certainly right for the implementation of the
OMC, benchmarking was and is nevertheless foreseen by the institutional equipment of the OMC/incl., and with
it, the possibility for naming and shaming to happen.
and March 1996), of networks (Kohler-Koch 2001), of diffusion, and of naming and shaming
(Trubek and Mosher 2003). Most researchers, however, have conceptualised it as a learning
instrument, particularly in the direction of ideational, cognitive and discursive learning
(Jacobsson 2002; Overdevest 2002; Tucker 2003). This concept particularly focuses on the
interactions amongst involved actors. These interactions, so the expectation, can lead to policy
change, namely by leading the concerned actors to the modification of the interpretations of
their interests.
The idea of learning can be traced back to the 1960s (Deutsch) and the 1970s (Heclo). In the
1990s, Hall has strongly influenced the academic debate, defining policy learning as a
“deliberate attempt to adjust the goals of techniques of policy in the light of consequences of
past policy and new information (Hall 1993: 278). Hall speaks of learning when policy
change occurs after such as process and differentiates into first (tools), second (setting of the
tools) and third order (paradigm or goal changed) learning. Some years later, the concept of a
directly deliberative polyarchy has been presented and has received broad attention since, also
in the OMC literature (Sabel and Cohen 1997). The authors suggest that steering political
systems might be better achieved through ongoing local learning processes than through
centralized regulation. Consequently, they propose a reconfiguration of the traditional
political (state) powers and their rights and duties, mainly shifting formal and material
responsibilities to local units while leaving the dissemination of information and the
distribution of financial means to central agencies. Competition between the different local
units about the “best model” would be supported by processes of mutual comparison and
benchmarking. A central criticism of this model concerns its blindness towards the political
character of learning in a public environment (de la Porte and Pochet 2003). Therefore, so de
la Porte and Pochet, the “DDP approach does not seem to add much value to understanding
the OMC” (de la Porte and Pochet 2003: 8).
More directly concerned with the social OMC processes in the EU, Hemerijck and Visser
identified a whole set of reasons why processes of learning might not lead to any or improved
policy change. These include the assessment that learning is neither a sufficient nor a
necessary condition for policy change; that to learn from other countries is only but one
possible factor amongst others for the change, and not necessarily the most important one;
that there is no reason to believe that learning necessarily improves performances, particularly
if ut does not rely on one’s own experiences. They also noticed that “poorly developed
evaluation methods tend to stand in the way of effective learning” (Hemerijck and Visser
2003: 17). Research has additionally shown that often fundamental political, administrative,
institutional and cultural aspects are neglected, overseen or forgotten in the analysis of
learning processes, for example problems of collective action, diverging interests, the low
predictability of outcomes, to name only a few (Barbier 2004; Kröger 2005).
Trubek and Mosher, occupied with the functioning of the EES, introduced an important
distinction when analysing potential supranational learning processes insofar as they
differentiate between looking at policy change once it has occurred and the possibility of
tracing change back to learning processes and analysing whether the instrument which is
expected to support learning processes is well equipped to do so. Turning to the latter
scenario, they suggest that learning can take place where public and private actors are brought
together in deliberative problem-solving settings; where policy networks are enlarged; where
decentralised experimentation is encouraged; where information on innovation is precise and
commonly available; and where actors are encouraged to compare their results with those of
the best performers in any area (Trubek and Mosher 2003).
Addressing the Laeken indicators, Mabbett defended the learning conceptualisation of the
OMC by differentiating between learning and evaluation, suggesting that “evaluative exercise
has to resolve problems of power and authority” (Mabbett 2004: 2) and thereby imposes
certain “demands on the use of indicators which a learning orientation does not” (ibid)18. The
first point broadly pertains on the issue of subsidiarity and more concretely to who should
have the authority to evaluate member states’ performances. While the Commission obtained
the task to write Joint Reports, this does not mean that it is free to write whatever it wants to
write19 (Idema and Keleman 2006). The second point has to do with the choice of indicators.
For evaluation and learning processes alike, it is not sufficient to rely exclusively on outcomeoriented indicators as these do not take into account the larger environment in which a given
performance is achieved: “The promise of benchmarking as a powerful tool of learning can be
undermined by the elevation of quantitative criteria over more complicated issues to do with
context and processes“ (Arrowsmith et al. 2004: 312; see also de la Porte, Pochet and Room:
2001: 292 and Kutsar 2000: 3).
While distinguishing learning from evaluation has analytical value to it, this must not mean
that learning is not dependent on supportive mechanisms, binding rules and common
definitions nor that hierarchies are absent in such a logic. Indeed, there are strong arguments
which speak against the conceptualisation of the OMC as a learning instrument. The first one
being that the OMC takes place in a political environment, that it is a truly political exercise
where different actors pursue different interests and goals, grounded on diverging if not
opposed ideas and equipped with diverging amounts of resources (Radaelli 2004). Nowadays,
this political environment is strongly influenced by the demands of European Monetary
Union, the process and effects of “negative integration” (Scharpf 1996) and the supply-sided
focus of labour market policies. Secondly, the structure of the process is not supportive of
enduring collective learning as it does not ensure that knowledge and experience are widely
shared, discussed and evaluated (Casey and Gold 2004; Idema and Keleman 2006). Thirdly,
18
This does not mean that in learning processes, no power hierarchies were active.
Particularly in 2001, the Commission had to deal with severe critique for its draft Joint Report from all
member states for pronouncing a too direct and harsh critique on their NAPs and policy approaches and attempt
to categorize them hierarchically.
19
there is a strong tendency to neglect that the involved actors are embedded in a larger
institutional and organizational environment and therefore not free to learn whatever they may
wish.
4. The Laeken indicators: a basis for learning20
Social indicators can be an important tool for evaluating a country's level of social
development, for assessing the impact of policy, for addressing social inequalities and their
structural grounds, dimensions and degrees of social exclusion. A lot depends on how they are
fabricated and with which intentions. In Atkinson’s words, one has to ask “what is the
objective underlying an indicator and how does this influence the definition to be adopted?”
(Atkinson 2002: 10). Within the context of the OMC, one idea sees the indicators as
establishing a common language for the discussion of social policy issues and clearly as
performance indicators (Atkinson et al. 2002: 19). Another idea is that a set of common
indicators can advance the agenda for the social inclusion process. While social indicators
certainly can add value to the analysis, evaluation and development of social policies, there
are equally a number of difficulties with respect to the usage of common indicators
particularly in a supranational context such as the EU which should not be forgotten21.
20
In what follows I will use information gathered in seven in-depth interviews with members of the ISG, six out
of which from (EU-15) member states representatives amongst which the president of the ISG and one from the
secretariat provided by the Commission. The interviews were conducted between September and November
2005. Even though not directly used here, in order to come to an appropriate picture of the process under review,
I can also draw upon information gathered in six in-depth interviews with (EU-15) members of the SPC, five out
of which from member states and one from the secretariat provided by the Commission. Additionally I have
received eight answers to an open questionnaire from EU-25 members of the SPC. This material was gathered
during the same time.
21
Kröger has listed and explained these difficulties: the question of definition, of measurement, of taking into
account time and space, of data availability, of the political character of indicators and of who fabricates them
(Kröger 2004).
During the 1970s and 1980s, the EU’s concept of poverty came quite close to Townsend‘s
(1970) notion of poverty who operated with a relative concept of poverty which was to be
measured against the given standards of a given society and the means necessary to
participate therein. By the 1990s, and due to the academic22 and political influence stemming
from French researchers and the then-in-place President of the Commission, Jacques Delors,
the concept of poverty and its focus on monetary exclusion became less influencial in the EU
while the one of social exclusion had gained in prominence and acceptance. Social exclusion
was seen as capable of grasping the multidimensional aspects of the phenomenon as well as
the relational, agency and dynamic sides to it. Furthermore it seemed to place greater weight
on the structural reasons of different forms of individual deprivation23 thereby increasingly
focusing on “barriers and processes by which people are excluded” (Greve 2002: 11) from
social, political and cultural rights, a tradition going back to the concept of citizenship as
developed by Marshall24. With the changing conceptualisation of poverty and social
exclusion, methods used to measure the related phenomena changed as well (from national
household budget surveys to multi-dimensional and intertemporal data instruments (panel
studies)).
3.1 Choice of indicators
How are these developments mirrored in the OMC inclusion? Both the common objectives as
well as the later on decided Laeken indicators provide a provisional answer, the indicators
22
Prominent authors on the definition of social exclusion include Serge Paugam, Robert Castel, Rob Atkinson,
Ruth Levitas, Ruth Lister or Chiara Saraceno. For an overview over the shift from “poverty” to “social
exclusion” and the respective debates, see Atkinson and Davoudi (2000), Todman (2004) or Goguel d’Allondans
(2003).
23
Not all scholars perceive of this shift as a positive one and Veit-Wilson came to the opposite conclusion when
stating: “The well documented change in Eurospeak terminology from poverty to social exclusion in the 1980s
reflected a deliberate politically-driven expedient shift in discourse from politically-sensitive structural causes to
politically-anodyne victim consequences” (Veit-Wilson 2003: 6).
24
Room has noted the following elements in the switch from poverty to social exclusion: 1) From financial to
multi-dimensional disadvantage. 2) From a static to a dynamic analysis; 3) From a focus on the resources of the
individual or household to a concern also with those of the local community; 4) From distributional to relational
dimensions of stratification and disadvantage and 5) From a continuum of inequality to catastrophic rupture
(Room 2000).
being the harder instrument as they are supposed to be the basis for evaluation, benchmarking
and naming and shaming. The indicators suggested in October 2001 by the SPC and endorsed
at the Laeken Council in December 2001 are divided into primary, secondary and tertiary
indicators, the last ones being a voluntary domestic exercise.
The ten primary indicators consist of: 1. Low income rate after transfers with low income
threshold set at 60% of median income (with breakdowns by gender, age, most frequent
activity status, household type and tenure status; as illustrative examples, the values for
typical households); 2. Distribution of income (income inequality S80/S20); 3. Persistence of
low income; 4. Median low income gap; 5. Regional cohesion (based on employment); 6.
Long term unemployment rate; 7. People living in jobless households; 8. Early school leavers
not in further education or training; 9. Life expectancy at birth, split by gender; 10.Self
perceived health status.
The eight secondary indicators are: 11. Dispersion around the 60% median low income
threshold after transfers (40%, 50% and 70% of median); 12. Low income rate anchored at a
point in time; 13. Low income rate before transfers; 14. Distribution of income (Gini
coefficient); 15. Persistence of low income (based on 50% of median income); 16. Long term
unemployment share within total unemployment; 17. Very long term unemployment rate and
18. Persons with low educational attainment, by age and sex25. Since the adoption of these 18
indicators in December 2001, two indicators have been added to the list: in-work poverty and
the amount of children in jobless households.
What does the choice of these indicators say about the framing of poverty and social
exclusion in the context of the OMC inclusion? Out of the ten primary indicators, seven are
income (4) or unemployment (3) related, while out of the eight secondary indicators, seven
are income (5) or unemployment (2) related. This adds up to 14 out of 18 indicators being
25
http://europa.eu.int/comm/employment_social/soc-prot/soc-incl/index_en.htm.
income or unemployment related, two to education, two to health. There are no indicators on
housing, drug abuse, early (child) pregnancy, released prisoners, ethnic minorities and
migrants, consummation or social and political activities. Atkinson et al. have noted these
gaps in coverage: “Major gaps in the areas and topics covered at this stage – recognized by
the SPC and its ISG – reflect a combination of data unavailability and absence of clear
conceptual underpinning in particular areas” (Atkinson et al. 2004: 59), particularly with
respect to housing (see also Greve 2002: 11) and homelessness.
Whereas the indicators of this OMC were continuously discussed in 2001-2002, this was the
case five times during 2003 and 2004, and four times in 200526. This decrease in importance
can largely be attributed to the increase of other OMCs, namely those in pensions (late 2001)
and health (2002), but also to the fact that the “easy” questions were resolved during the first
two years of work whereas the difficult issues remain unsolved and more or less on the
agenda27.
The discussions since 2003 have particularly focused on non-monetary / deprivation
indicators, indicators on housing and homelessness as well as for ethnic minorities and
immigrants. Other regular points of the meetings included the passage from the European
Community Household Panel (ECHP) to the EU-SILC (Statistics on Income and Living
Conditions), the review of the indicators used in the national reports, how to link the
indicators more closely to the objectives, and the preparation of the streamlined OMC on
social protection and social inclusion, beginning in 2006. Finally, it is an open question
whether the ISG should concentrate on finding and defining indicators or whether it should
also analyse the results28 which would give greater political weight to it.
26
This information stems from the official work programmes of the respective years, documents obtained
through informal contacts.
27
Interview with a member of ISG, 25.11.2005.
28
Interview with a member of the ISG, 25.11.2005.
There are different reasons why these issues have remained on the agenda instead of being
resolved. The first reason is that contrary to the ISG on employment, this indicator sub-group
opted for having a high degree of comparability, rendering consensus building more
difficult29. With respect to the deprivation indicators, it has been particularly the French
delegation speaking up against them arguing that such indicators would deter the picture
whereas other delegations consider that such indicators are the only way of getting indicators
in particular areas at all, namely for housing issues: “The French are strategically wrong in
rejecting it. Because if we don’t do it, there will be no indicators at all on, for example,
housing”30. If this area, and particularly homelessness have not become an object of
consensus yet, this mainly has to do with both a lack of a commonly accepted definition and
of data: “Indicators on homelessness and housing are important, but very difficult. First,
because there is no adequate data available and second because it is unclear how the quality of
housing should be judged (ex: lack of heating in northern and southern member states)”31.
The question of ethnic minorities and immigrants was rendered difficult by the respective
legislation of France and Portugal which do not foresee the possibility of data gathering split
up by national origin or ethnic ascription. But also, ethnic minorities vary in (quantitative)
importance in the different member states as well as their social stratification. In June 2005, a
preliminary consensus was found foreseeing strict guidelines for the future reporting on these
individuals, including their work situation32.
There is thus a strong focus on employment and income-related indicators which generally
tend to be adopted to the EES: “These indicators have a clear and distinct overlap with the
employment strategy” (Greve 2002: 11). Social exclusion as framed through the Laeken
indicators mainly appears as exclusion from the labour market and thereby exclusion from an
29
Interview with member ISG, 25.11.2005.
Interview with member of ISG, 17.11.2005.
31
Interview with member of ISG, 14.11.2005.
32
This was reported by two interviewees and also can be found in the report presented under the Luxemburg
Presidency by Marlier et al. An immigrant is now defined as someone who crossed the border and with a
different nationality (than EU).
30
own income. While both are without any doubt fundamental for the integration into society,
they do “not tell us everything we need to know about the resources or living standards of
households” (Atkinson et al 2004: 61), an argument that points in the direction of more nonmonetary indicators (Greve 2002).
3.2 Restriction to performance indicators
The SPC, and later the Council, have opted for indicators that address final outcomes and thus
integrate a static definition of social exclusion while not addressing the processes leading to it
(Greve 2002: 11) nor structural reasons. This choice has to do with the respect of the principle
of subsidiarity33: “The aim of the EU indicators is to measure social outcomes, not the means
by which they are achieved” (Atkinson 2002: 8). Atkinson et al. bring in another argument :
“Focusing on outcomes may also foster a co-operative attitude between the different national
bodies – ministries, agencies, etc. – that have competencies in these areas, whereas as far as
inputs are concerned they may be more inclined to see competition for resources as a zerosum-game” (Atkinson et al. 2004: 51-52). While this argument may have some validity to it,
it should not be overemphasised as the degree of politicisation of the OMC and its public
visibility are very low.
More importantly, outcome indicators do not represent the result of public policies alone, but
reflect a multitude of interconnected developments in economy and society; isolating the
effects of single policies is therefore hardly possible. This is a strong argument for indicators
of policy inputs and outputs, and of policy processes, without which the Laeken indicators
will “hardly themselves furnish the comparative policy-relevant information that such
learning – and the sharing of good practice – will properly require” (Room 2004: 6).
It is noteworthy that originally, the Social Affairs Council had foreseen both „performance indicators“ and
„policy indicators“ (Friedrich 2006).
33
If the indicators themselves do not furnish this information, maybe the NAPs, the texts which
the governments have handed to the Commission on a biennal basis, can compensate for this
shortcoming? So far, these have turned out to be governmental reports instead of critical
review of passed policies or strategic planning of future policies (Idema 2004). As
importantly, there are two additional shortcomings: for once, the indicators presented in the
annex to the NAPs do not necessarily correspond to the policy measures presented in the text
and vice versa. Second, the information about a policy provided by the general text as well as
the annexed so-called good practices is by far insufficient to understand what the policy is
about, how it functions, how it is financed, which actors are involved and so on (Kröger
2006). In other words: there is an important mismatch between the indicators and the text
which is supposed to contextualize them.
This is not to say that they are without any value: the indicators chosen may very well enable
the member states and the EU alike to evaluate whether member states are moving in the
same direction or not, as well as, in theory, serve as a tool for naming and shaming processes.
Indicators may equally “serve to combat the tendency for national and European social
policies to be developed in parallel universes” (Mabbett 2004: 15). It just will not be possible
to say why member states moved in a given direction or another. Yet for learning processes,
this explanation is rather essential. The secretariat of the Commission and some national
representatives are aware of this shortcoming and see room for indicators that are more
responsive to political action: “There is room for policy or process or input measurement as
well”34.
34
Interview with member of the ISG, 21.10.2005.
3.3 Comparability and data availability
In order to learn in a supranational context, it is essential that the available data be
comparable. For comparable data to exist, situations of poverty and social exclusion need to
be somewhat comparable. However, what might be considered as producing social exclusion
or as a state of exclusion at one given point in time in one given region of the world (or the
EU) by no means corresponds with a definition given at another region of the world (or the
EU) at the same time: “People in different countries thus experience unemployment or
poverty in very different social contexts. It is therefore possible that comparability across
countries may, paradoxically, require the questions to differ across member states” (Atkinson
et al. 2002: 177; de la Porte and Pochet 2003: 26).
Some examples can be instructive. Employment rates may be lower in Italy than in the United
Kingdom; this does not necessarily have to mean that less people have a paid job in Italy than
in the UK as informal networks may work in favour of some sort of labour market integration
in Italy. A homeless rate of 3% would be a scandal in the Scandinavian countries as many
people would probably die in the cold of the winter whereas in Spain or Portugal, even though
still politically a scandal, it does rarely threaten people’s lives and therefore might not be as
big a priority: “What counts as unacceptable housing in Finland in the winter may be accepted
in Cyprus or Portugal”35. Having two friends in rural Ireland may be all one can hope for in
the Green Island, whereas it may be a sign of social isolation in Greece. Some member states
have rather well developed minimum assistance schemes allowing the unemployed to
continue to live in dignity whereas others don’t. In short, the question of comparability in a
supranational context is closely linked to the concept of adequacy which “often varies from
country to country, as it depends on specific cultural, social, environmental, and economic
factors, such as the climatic differences between the North and the South of Europe”
(Atkinson et al: 2002: 159). And evidently, the diverging traditions and institutions as well as
35
Interview with member of the ISG, 21.10.2005.
the different climates not only render the interpretation of the data more difficult, but also the
agreement on common indicators. One interviewee has focused on the cultural differences
making comparison difficult: “Furthermore, there is research evidence that quite small
changes in the wording of questions on self reported health (even in the listing of questions)
can produce different results. The other problem is that cultural differences determine answers
more than underlying health status and this makes cross country comparisons difficult”36.
Again, the interpretation of the data, necessary for learning processes, needs accompanying
information about policies, budgets and laws, supposedly provided in the NAPs. As of now,
there have been important differences between the year of data gathering and the policies
described in the NAPs leading to a situation where “countries will be reporting on the
position some years in the past” (Atkinson et al. 2002: 183) and rendering learning processes
difficult, meaning that the presented performances largely cannot be explained by the
presented text. Also, the definition of an indicator “may have changed in the meantime even if
there has been no change in policy” (ibid; see also Kutsar 2000: 3).
The problem of timely data has largely been acknowledged by the member states leading to
the introduction of the EU-SILC which is expected to solve it but will take another decade
before producing data that can be compared over time. Finally, some data just do not exist
(yet), a challenge acknowledge by all interviewees, particularly with respect to homelessness,
disabilities and illiteracy: “The data poses quite a bit of a problem”37.
3.4 The consultation process
The literature on governance, deliberation and learning emphazises the importance of the
exchange of arguments in order to come to viable solutions and an acceptable shared
understanding of the common good (Sabel and Cohen 1997). Another more functional
36
Interview with member of the ISG, 21.10.2005. As an example, the interviewee cited the notoriously good
humour of the Irish, who could still answer that everything is fine while being sick against the rather pessimistic
character of the Germans with a tendency to exaggerate sufferings.
37
Interview with member of the ISG, 21.10.2005.
argument reads that the more (and different) actors will be involved in the policy-making
process, the more effective the problem-solving strategies should be. This is why it is
important to evaluate the sort and degree of participation and consultation in the process of
indicator fabrication.
It is possible to distinguish three types of consultation, namely institutionalised consultation
of the member states and the Commission, semi-formal consultation of external academic or
statistical experts (such the OECD or the Atkinson-group, see below) and informal
consultation of NGOs (Friedrich 2002).
Consultation of the member states happens nine to ten times a year in the official meetings of
the ISG in Brussels. The OMC inclusion, however, need not be at the centre of attention at
every meeting (other issues being the OMC on pensions and health, for example). These
meetings last half a day to a day and normally, there are several items on the agenda.
Particularly since enlargement38, it is thus easy to imagine that not all delegations can speak
up for all items: ”Out of 25 member states, maybe ten speak up during a meeting” 39.
According to all interviewees, these tend to be particularly Luxemburg, Belgium, France,
Italy and the United Kingdom40. Particularly the EU-10 member states are reported to be
“silent”. This state of the art, however, is not reported to reflect coalition building of EU-15
vs. EU-10 member states41.
With respect to the second group, the degree of participation had a lot to do with Frank
Vandenbroucke, the former Belgian Federal Minister of Social Affairs and Pensions who had
made the indicators one of his top-priorities for the Belgian Presidency of the EU (second half
of 2001). Besides single experts from the OECD, other DGs or Eurostat, it was particularly
38
Note, however, that the EU-10 member states participated in the ISG as guests since 2003.
Interview with member of the ISG, 25.11.2005.
40
Member states that were mentioned once are Finland, Poland, Hungary, the Netherlands and Germany.
41
Note, however, that the ISG interviews were all conducted with EU-15 members of the ISG.
39
academic advise that Vandenbroucke encouraged and supported, and this resulted, in autumn
2000, in the setting-up of a group of high-level academic experts, called the ‘Atkinson group’,
after its chair Tony Atkinson42. The Atkinson group was in regular contact with the ISG and
drafted the final report for the SPC43; it also opened up discussion to a broader academic
network. Throughout the consultation process, the academic experts met clear rules of
participation and were actively encouraged to participate by the Belgian Presidency (Friedrich
2002). The visible highlight of Vandenbroucke’s efforts – besides the adoption of 18
indicators at the Laeken Council – was an international conference on “Indicators for Europe.
Making Common European Objectives Work”, in mid-September 2001, organized by the
Belgian Presidency. It seems, however, that since the adoption of the Laeken indicators,
consultation has involved less academic advise than in the first two years: “The first Atkinson
report (2001/2002) has strongly influenced the ISG as the ISG only came into place, then.
Now, the work of the ISG has strongly influenced the second report (Marlier et al. 2005). The
great value is that it puts on the table what the ISG is doing”44.
No formal participation rules existed for NGOs and attitudes from officials towards their
participation seems to differ largely. While European NGOs showed political interest in
influencing the indicators, they met considerably fewer facilitating conditions to participate
than the academic experts45 which stands at odds with the common objective no. 4.
(“mobilisation of all relevant bodies”) and with the aim to foster the exchange of good
practice which are rather based on the ground where NGOs operate than at governmental
levels. Apparently, some degree of access was possible upon request, but without (clear) rules
42
Members were Tony Atkinson, Bea Cantillon, Eric Marlier, and Brian Nolan.
Its work was published a year later (Atkinson et al 2002).
44
Interview with secretariat ISG, 21.10.2005.
45
But it should also be mentioned that such a development seems rather unlikely as people / representatives
coming from “civil society” and / or working in NGOs – let alone the excluded – simply lack the technical
know-how necessary for the construction of such indicators, most of the times. Yet, this should not be used as an
argument for their exclusion from the process.
43
of participation (Friedrich 2002). Both the EAPN46 and the FEANTSA had informal access to
the ISG and discussed several papers and the interim report: “FEANTSA, they try to
participate all the time, trying to influence the process, wanting to make contributions. They
have been in the ISG” – to the difference of EAPN47. They equally contributed with own
evaluations and reports and organized several round-tables. Yet, the scope of the impact of
their participation remains at best unclear. The perception of who established the contacts
between the subgroup and the NGOs, either the ISG’s secretariat or the NGOs, also differs.
Whereas official actors have stressed the role of the secretary, NGOs have a more critical
view with respect to the demand of their participation (Friedrich 2002).
The degree of ‘openness’, i.e. the extent to which non-public actors were incorporated into the
definition process, thus varied significantly. It is fair to conclude that the Laeken indicators
have been developed by quite closed groups. The influence of NGOs was limited48 and of
socially excluded people inexistent, whereas academic expert participation was extensive and
important for the final output, as the adoption of Atkinson’s proposal to use three levels of
indicators as well as the adoption of the suggested methodological principles proves. One can
wonder whether an increased consultation of NGOs would have meant a different set of
indicators in the end; but without clear modes of consultation, this option was excluded from
the beginning.
As Atkinson et al. have argued, it is essential to “intensify the efforts to engage a wide range
of social actors”, particularly not viewing the excluded as passive participants, but as active
actors: “Those suffering from social exclusion should co-determine how exclusion should be
46
Amongst social NGOs, EAPN enjoys by far the greatest support of the Commission who is financing it to a
large degree. Zeitlin goes as far as to state that “EAPN has been granted a semi-official place in the Social
Inclusion process” (Zeitlin 2005: 17).
47
Interview secretariat of ISG, 21.10.2005.
48
Note that no „excluded“ people were invited to participate in the elaboration of the commonly agreed
indicators.
measured” (Atkinson et al. 2004: 63-64)49. Such an approach would not only increase the
input legitimacy of the EU, but also profit from valuable knowledge coming from “experts on
their own matter”.
There are diverging acknowledgements of the nature of the discussions. While some
interviewees stated that there is a tendency towards consensus building and finding ways of
coming together, others estimated that “in the ISG, bargaining takes place more often” (than in the
SPC)50. The latter evaluation meets the findings of Jacobsson and Vifell, analysing the functioning
of various social and economic committees of the EU. They have found some evidence for
cooperative deliberation in general discussions; things where different when it came “down to
the formulation of recommendations or the exact definition of indicators, the discussion in the
committees or in the bilateral consultations with the Commission, takes the form of pure
negotiations and bargaining. Member States try to anticipate the recommendations and
influence the exact wordings to make them nationally acceptable” (Jacobsson and Vifell
2004: 20). Not only does bargaining replace arguing, but also, according to these authors, do
power relations replace good arguments in sensitive issue areas (ibid.).
Asking the ISG-members if they had observed learning effects, answers diverged quite
importantly. Two interviewees were rather sceptical, stating that “many member states don’t
have learning as their first interest”51 or that no discussion is taking place and that things that
are not reported at the meetings are completely neglected 52. Three interviewees particularly
mention the positive effects in the domestic context, accelerating the discussions around the
49
And they go on to cite the EAPN: 'The best indicators are those which gauge changes in the everyday lives of
people living in poverty and social exclusion. Such indicators can only be defined through a participatory
method which involves a close cooperation between them and researchers' (EAPN, cited in Atkinson et al.
2002:187).
50
Interview with member of ISG and SPC, 27.10.2005.
51
ibid.
52
Interview with member of ISG, 25.11.2005.
definition of indicators and improving the system of data gathering, particularly but not only
in the new member states. Several interviewees stated that there is a structured comparison of
the different systems leading to an increased knowledge about other social systems. However,
there was also a critical voice estimating that by now, there are so many information that the
risk exists of getting lost in it.
4. Discussion
The aim of this article was to see whether the Laeken indicators of the OMC inclusion can be
seen as fostering social learning and deliberation in a supranational environment. It became
clear that if at all, these indicators may serve to support learning processes in the fields of
employment, unemployment and income, but not in other areas as indicators are either simply
missing and not supported by adequate information on policies nor process indicators. The
latter ones so far have not been introduced into the process as they conflict with the principle
of subsidiarity, leaving the means with which to achieve certain policy goals up to the
member states. I have also shown that for different reasons – lack of available and timely
data, lack of critical assessment of the domestic policies and performances in the NAPs by
governments, important institutional, cultural and geographic differences to name some of
them – comparability of the indicators is not assured (yet). Yet without comparability of the
data, learning must remain quite vague. Finally, I have attracted attention to the consultation
process where analysis shows that not all actors concerned have been consulted in sufficient
degrees, a central precondition for learning to happen.
Concluding, let me turn to some more general remarks about the issue of supranational
learning in the field of social policy. One of the basic ambiguities inherent in the OMC is that
policy coordination needs to follow a top-down logic if seriously attempting to counterbalance economic integration and that the learning processes which indicators are supposed to
support require more of a bottom-up logic and would seem to necessarily include a broader
range of actors and indicators produced on the ground (Room 2004)53. For learning to happen,
there would need to be a greater commitment of key actors and much more space would need
to be dedicated to peer review and the contextualisation of best practices (Schludi 2003: 7) as
performance benchmarking does not allow to know causal relationships between policies and
performances and therefore do not foster learning processes. Instead, this kind of
benchmarking tends to be concerned (ideally) with target setting and quantitative
measurement, encouraging participants to manipulate the evidence.
It seems as if, in order to give the inclusion indicators greater weight, the issue of subsidiarity
must be addressed. A soft policy coordination instrument such as the OMC inclusion is not
capable of addressing questions of power nor of distributional nor judicial justice and suffers
under the absence of binding regulations (Scharpf 2002). If the EU is to become a social actor
capable of counter-balancing the negative and disintegrating effects of globally marketised
economies, then it is misguided in treating member states as if they were at the centre of
attention (Room 2004: 12). In this sense, there is a need to complement the soft elements of
the OMC with more coercive mechanisms in order to ensure some degree of compliance. If
interested in fostering learning processes, member states should also ensure that these
processes are not working in favour of individual ad-hoc and interrupted learning effects, but
in organizational and institutional learning (Casey and Gold 2004).
It might be time to question more widely the learning assumption of soft governance modes –
very difficult to operationalize for empirical research anyhow (de la Porte and Pochet 2003)
53
Which is encouraged by the Commission, but not respected by the governments.
and see it instead as part and expression of the political process: might both the member states
and the Commission not accentuate this component so much in order to reassure themselves
continuously that no compentencies are being taken away and that the EU is doing something
in the social field (Idema and Kelemen 2006) while in reality not much learning has occurred
so far through the social OMCs (ibid; Kröger 2006)?
References
Arrowsmith, James, Sisson, Keith and Paul Marginson, 2004, „What can ‘benchmarking’ offer the
open method of co-ordination?“, in: Journal of European Public Policy, Vol. 11(2), 311–328
Atkinson, Rob and Simin Davoudi, 2000, “The Concept of Social Exclusion in the European Union:
Context, Development and Possibilities”, in: Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 38, no.
3, 427-448.
Atkinson, Tony, 2002, “Social Europe and Social Science”, unpublished manuscript of the 13th
ESRC Annual Lecture, to be found at: http://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/users/atkinson/.
Atkinson, T., Cantillon, B., Marlier, E. and Brian Nolan, 2002, Social Indicators: the EU and Social
Inclusion, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Atkinson, Tony, Marlier, Eric and Brian Nolan, 2004, “Indicators and Targets for Social Inclusion in
the European Union”, in: Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 42, no. 1, 47-75.
Barbier, Jean-Claude, 2004, ‘Open methods of coordination’ and national social policies: what
sociological theories and methods?”, Paper presented at the RC19 international conference,
Paris, 2-4 Septembre 2004.
Büchs, Milena, 2005, "Dilemmas of post-regulatory European social policy coordination". The
European Employment Strategy in Germany and the United Kingdom, Ph.D
dissertation.
Casey, Bernard H. and Gold, Michael, 2005, Peer review of labour market programmes in the
European Union: what can countries really learn from one another? Journal of European
Public Policy, 12: 1, 23-43.
de la Porte, Caroline, Pochet, Philippe and Graham Room (2001) “Social benchmarking, policy
making and new governance in the EU”, in: Journal of European Social Policy, Vol. 11 (4),
291–307.
de la Porte, Caroline and Philippe Pochet (2003) "The OMC Intertwined with the Debates on
Governance, Democracy and Social Europe." Research on the Open Method Of Co-Ordination
and European Integration prepared for Minister Frank Vandenbroucke, Minister for Social
Affairs and Pensions, Belgium, http://eucenter.wisc.edu/OMC/Papers/delaportePochet.pdf
Dolowitz, D. P. and Marsh, D. (1996) “Who learns What from Whom: a Review of the Policy
Transfer Literature”, in: Political Studies , XLIV, 343-357.
Commission of the European Communities (2001) European Governance, White Paper,
COM (2001) 428 final, 25.07.2001, Brussels.
Commission of the European Communities, 2002, Nr. Kommissionsvorschlag: 13926/01,
Gemeinsamer Bericht über die soziale Eingliederung - Teil I: Die Europäische Union,
einschließlich Zusammenfassung, Brüssel.
Commission of the European Communities, 2003, 773 final, Joint Report on Social Inclusion,
Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, the European
Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions.
European Council, 2001, „Objectives in the fight against poverty and social exclusion” (EC: 2001/C
82/02).
European Council, 2000, “Council Decision of 29 June 2000 on Setting up a Social Protection
Committee” (2000/436/EC).
Friedrich, Dawid, 2002, "The Open Method of Co-ordination: Bringing the Union Closer to the
People? Participation in the process of defining indicators for the OMC on social inclusion",
Masters thesis at the MSc programme "European Social Policy Analysis" (MESPA) at the
University of Bath, UK .
Friedrich, Dawid, 2006, Policy Process, Governance and Democracy in the EU: the Case of the Open
Method of Coordination on social inclusion. Policy & Politics, 34 (2), 367-383.
Goetschy, Janine, 2003, “The European Employment Strategy, Multi-level Governance, and Policy
Coordination”, in : Zeitlin, Jonathan and David M. Trubek (eds.), Governing Work and
Welfare in a New Economy : European and American Experiments, Oxford : OUP.
Goguel d’Allondans, Alban, 2003, L’Exclusion sociale. Les métamorphoses d’un concept (19602000), Paris : L’Harmattan.
Greve, Bent, 2002, “Is a supranational strategy for social inclusion possible?” Research papers from
the Department of Social Sciences, Institut for Samfundsvidenskab og Erhvervsøkonomi,
Research paper no. 06/02.
Hall, Peter, 1993, Policy paradigms, social learning, and the state: The case of economic
policy making in Britain. Comparative Politics, 25 (3), 275-296.
Hemerijck, Anton and Visser, Jelle, 2003, Policy learning in European Welfare States,
unpublished manuscript, October 2003.
Idema and Kelemen, 2006, New Modes of Governance, the Open Method of
Coordination, and other Fashionable Red Herring. Forthcoming in
Perspectives on European Politics and Society.
Jacobsson, Kerstin, 2002, „Soft Regulation and the Subtle Transformation of States: The Case of EU
Employment Policy“, 2002/4, SCORE (Stockholm Center for Organizational Research),
Stockholm.
Kerstin Jacobsson and Åsa Vifell, 2004, “Towards Deliberative Supranationalism? Analysing the role
of committees in soft co-ordination, Preliminary chapter for Linsenmann, Meyer and Wessels
(eds.), Economic Governance in the EU, Palgrave Macmillan.
Kohler-Koch, Beate, 2001, “European Networks and Ideas: Changing National Policies?”, in:
European Integration Online Papers, 6 (6).
Kröger, Sandra, 2004, “The commonly agreed indicators in the context of the OMC/incl.: Challenges
and limitations”, Paper prepared for the French-German workshop on „Governance, Law and
Technology“, Centre Marc Bloch, Berlin, 7 December 2004.
Kröger, Sandra, 2005, “Coming to grips with soft governance: a conceptual framework for
analysing the Open Method of Coordination in the field of poverty and social exclusion”,
Paper prepared for the Summer School 2005 of the Postgraduate Programme »The Future of
the European Social Model«, University of Göttingen, 18th to 21rst July.
Kröger, Sandra, 2006, "When Learning Hits Politics Or: Social Policy Coordination Left to the
Administrations and the NGOs?" in: European Integration online Papers, 10 (3).
Kutsar, Dagmar, 2000, “Problems of Comparability of Sociodemographic Indicators between
Developed Countries and Countries in Transition”, Paper prepared for the seminar
„Brainstorming on Social Indicators”, Strasbourg, 14-15 September 2000, Council of Europe
and Friedrich Ebert Stiftung.
Mabbett, Deborah, 2004, “Learning by numbers: The role of indicators in the social inclusion
Process”, Paper prepared for the ESPAnet Conference, Oxford, 9-11 September 2004.
Marlier, Eric et al, 2005 Taking Forward the Social Inclusion Process, report written for the
Luxemburg Presidency.
Radaelli, Claudio, 2004, “Who learns what? Policy learning and the open method of
Coordination”, paper prepared for the ESRC seminar series: Implementing the Lisbon
Strategy “Policy learning inside and outside the open method”, European Research
Institute, University of Birmingham, 26 November 2004.
Room, Graham, 2004, “Benchmarking Indicators, Policy Convergence and Political Choice”, Paper
prepared for the ESPAnet Conference, Oxford, 9-11 September 2004.
Room, Graham, 2000, “Social exclusion, solidarity and the challenge of globalisation”, in:
International Journal of Social Welfare, 9 (2), 103-119.
Sabel, Charles and Joshua Cohen, 1997, “Directly-Deliberative Polyarchy”, in: European Law
Journal, vol. 3, no. 4, 313-340.
Scharpf, Fritz, 1996, Negative and positive Integration in the Political Economy of European
Welfare States. In: Marks, Gary et al, Governance in the European Union, (London:
Sage), 15-39.
Scharpf, Fritz W., 2002, “The European Social Model: Coping with the Challenges of Diversity”, in:
Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 40., nr. 4, 645-670
Social Protection Committee, 2003, Common Outline for the NAPs / inclusion 2003-2005, Brussels.
Todman, Lynn C., 2004, “Reflections on Social Exclusion: What is it? How is it different from U.S.
Conceptualizations of Disadvantage? And why Americans might consider integrating it into
U.S. social policy discourse”, unpublished manuscript.
Trubek, David M. and Joshua S. Mosher, 2003, “New Governance, Employment Policy, and the
European Social Model”, in: Zeitlin, Jonathan and David M. Trubek, (eds.), Governing Work
and Welfare in a New Economy. European and American Experiments, Oxford/New York:
Oxford University Press, 33-58.
Tucker, Christoph M., 2003, “The Lisbon Strategy and the Open Method of Coordination: A New
Vision and the Revolutionary Potential of Soft Governance in the European Union”, Paper
presented at the 2003 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association,
Chicago, 28 – 31 August 2003.
Download