CHAPTER 5: RISK AND RETURN: PAST AND PROLOGUE 1. i and ii. The standard deviation is non-negative. 2. c. 3. Investment 4. For each portfolio: Utility = E(r) – (0.5 3 2 ) Determines most of the portfolio’s return and volatility over time. Investment 1 2 3 4 E(r) 0.15 0.20 0.15 0.18 0.30 0.50 0.16 0.21 U 0.0150 -0.1750 0.1116 0.1139 We choose the portfolio with the highest utility value. 4. Investment 2. When an investor is risk neutral, A = 0 so that the portfolio with the highest utility is the portfolio with the highest expected return. 5. b. 6. V(12/31/2004) = V(1/1/1998) (1 + g)7 = €100,000 (1.06)7 = €150,363.03 7. E(r) = [0.35 40%] + [0.4 15%] + [0.25 (–20%)] = 15% 2 = [0.35 (40 – 15)2] + [0.4 (15 – 15)2] + [0.25 (–20 – 15)2] = 525.00 = 22.91% The mean has increased and the standard deviation has increased. 8. E(rX) = [0.25 (–25%)] + [0.45 18%] + [0.3 60%)] = 19.85% E(rY) = [0.25 (–20%)] + [0.45 20%] + [0.3 15%)] = 8.5% 5-1 9. X2 = [0.25 (–25 – 19.85)2] + [0.45 (18 – 19.85)2] + [0.3 (60 – 19.85)2] = 988.03 X = 31.43% Y2 = [0.25 (–20 – 8.5)2] + [0.45 (20 – 8.5)2] + [0.3 (15 – 8.5)2] = 275.25 Y = 16.59% 10. E(r) = (0.9 19.85%) + (0.1 8.5%) = 18.715% 11. a. The holding period returns for the three scenarios are: Boom: (35 – 25 + 1)/25 = 0.44 = 44.00% Normal: (25 – 25 + 0.50)/25 = 0.02 = 2.00% Recession: (10 – 25 + 0.25)/25 = –0.59 = –59.00% E(HPR) = [(1/3) 44%] + [(1/3) 2%] + [(1/3) (–59.00%)] = −4.33% 2(HPR) = [(1/3) (44 – (−4.33))]2 + [(1/3) (2 – (−4.33))]2 + (1/3) [(–59 − (−4.33))]2 = 1788.22 = 1788.22 = 42.29% b. E(r) = (0.5 −4.33%) + (0.5 4%) = −0.165% = 0.5 42.29% = 21.145% 12. a. E(rP) = (0.3 6%) + (0.7 15%) = 12.30% per year P = 0.7 25% = 17.5% per year b. Security T-Bills Stock A Stock B Stock C c. 0.7 27% = 0.7 33% = 0.7 40% = Investment Proportions 30.0% 18.9% 23.1% 28.0% Your Reward-to-variability ratio = S = Client's Reward-to-variability ratio = 5-2 15 6 = 0.360 25 12.30 6 = 0.360 17.5 d. E(r) % P 15 CAL( slope=0.360) 12.3 client 6 17.5 13. a. 25 % Mean of portfolio = (1 – y)rf + y rP = rf + (rP – rf )y = 6 + 9y If the expected rate of return for the portfolio is 12%, then, solving for y: 12 = 6 + 9y y = 12 6 = 0.667 9 Therefore, in order to achieve an expected rate of return of 12%, the client must invest 66.7% of total funds in the risky portfolio and 33.3% in T-bills. b. Security T-Bills Stock A Stock B Stock C c. Investment Proportions 33.3% 0.667 27% = 18.0% 0.667 33% = 22.0% 0.667 40% = 26.7% P = 0.667 25% = 16.7% per year 5-3 14. a. Portfolio standard deviation = P = y 25% If the client wants a standard deviation of 20%, then: y = (20%/25%) = 0.80 = 80.0% in the risky portfolio. 15. 16. b. Expected rate of return = 6 + 9y = 6 + (0.80 9) = 13.20% a. Slope of the CML = b. My fund allows an investor to achieve a higher expected rate of return for any given standard deviation than would a passive strategy, i.e., a higher expected return for any given level of risk. a. With 70% of his money in my fund's portfolio, the client has an expected rate of return of 12.3% per year and a standard deviation of 17.5% per year. If he shifts that money to the passive portfolio (which has an expected rate of return of 14% and standard deviation of 24%), his overall expected return and standard deviation would become: 14 6 = 0.333 24 E(rC) = rf + 0.7(rM rf) In this case, rf = 6% and rM = 14%. Therefore: E(rC) = 6 + (0.7 8) = 11.6% The standard deviation of the complete portfolio using the passive portfolio would be: C = 0.7 M = 0.7 24% = 16.8% Therefore, the shift entails a decline in the mean from 12.3% to 11.6% and a decline in the standard deviation from 17.5% to 16.8%. Since both mean return and standard deviation fall, it is not yet clear whether the move is beneficial. The disadvantage of the shift is apparent from the fact that, if my client is willing to accept an expected return on his total portfolio of 11.6%, he can achieve that return with a lower standard deviation using my fund portfolio rather than the passive portfolio. To achieve a target mean of 11.6%, we first write the mean of the complete portfolio as a function of the proportions invested in my fund portfolio, y: E(rC) = 6 + y(15 6) = 6 + 9y 5-4 Because our target is: E(rC) = 11.6%, the proportion that must be invested in my fund is determined as follows: 11.6 = 6 + 9y y = 11.6 6 = 0.62 9 The standard deviation of the portfolio would be: C = y 25% = 0.62 25% = 15.50% Thus, by using my portfolio, the same 11.6% expected rate of return can be achieved with a standard deviation of only 15.50% as opposed to the standard deviation of 16.8% using the passive portfolio. b. The fee would reduce the reward-to-variability ratio, i.e., the slope of the CAL. Clients will be indifferent between my fund and the passive portfolio if the slope of the after-fee CAL and the CML are equal. Let f denote the fee: Slope of CAL with fee = 15 6 f 9 f = 25 25 Slope of CML (which requires no fee) = 14 6 = 0.3333 24 Setting these slopes equal and solving for f: 9f = 0.3333 25 9 f = 25 0.3333 = 8.33 f = 9 8.33 = 0.67% per year 17. The probability is 0.45 that the state of the economy is neutral. Given a neutral economy, the probability that the performance of the stock will be poor is 0.15, and the probability of both a neutral economy and poor stock performance is: 0.45 0.15 = 0.0675 18. E(r) = [0.1 20%] + [0.6 10%] + [0.3 5%)] = 9.5% 19. a. E(rP) – rf = ½AP2 = ½ 4 (0.25) = 0.125 = 12.5% b. 0.09 = ½AP2 = ½ A (0.25) A = 0.09/( ½ 0.0625) = 2.88 c. Increased risk tolerance means decreased risk aversion (A), which results in a decline in risk premiums. 5-5 20. a. Time-weighted average returns are based on year-by-year rates of return. Year 2002-2003 2003-2004 2004-2005 Return = [(capital gains + dividend)/price] (20 – 110 + 4)/110 = 12.73% (80 – 120 + 4.5)/120 = –29.58% (90 – 80 + 4.5)/80 = 18.13% Arithmetic mean: 0.43% Geometric mean: −2.12% b. Time 0 1 Cash flow -£330.00 -£228.00 2 £102.50 3 £378.00 Date: 1/1/02 | | | | | 330 Explanation Purchase of three shares at £110 per share Purchase of two shares at £120, plus dividend income on three shares held Dividends on five shares, plus sale of one share at £80 Dividends on four shares, plus sale of four shares at £90 per share 1/1/03 | | | | 228 102.50 | | 1/1/04 378 | | | | | | | 1/1/05 Dollar-weighted return = Internal rate of return = –6.100% 21. For the period 1926 – 2003, the mean annual risk premium for large stocks over T-bills is: 12.25% – 3.79% = 8.46% E(r) = Risk-free rate + Risk premium = 4% + 8.46% =12.46% 5-6 22. a. The expected cash flow is: (0.5 €60,000) + (0.5 €160,000) = €110,000 With a risk premium of 10%, the required rate of return is 15%. Therefore, if the value of the portfolio is X, then, in order to earn a 15% expected return: X(1.15) = €110,000 X = €95,652 b. If the portfolio is purchased at €95,652, and the expected payoff is €110,000, then the expected rate of return, E(r), is: 110,000 95,652 = 0.15 = 15.0% 95,652 The portfolio price is set to equate the expected return with the required rate of return. c. If the risk premium over T-bills is now 16%, then the required return is: 5% + 16% = 21% The value of the portfolio (X) must satisfy: X(1.21) = €110, 000 X = €90,909 d. 23. For a given expected cash flow, portfolios that command greater risk premia must sell at lower prices. The extra discount from expected value is a penalty for risk. In the table below, we use data from Table 5.3 and the approximation: r R – i: Large Stocks: Small Stocks: Long-Term T-Bonds: T-Bills: r 12.25% 3.12% = r 18.43% 3.12% = r 5.64% 3.12% = r 3.79% 3.12% = 9.13% 15.31% 2.52% 0.67% Next, we compute real rates using the exact relationship: r 1 R R i 1 1 i 1 i Large Stocks: Small Stocks: Long-Term T-Bonds: T-Bills 24. r = 0.0913/1.0312 = 8.85% r = 0.1531/1.0312 = 14.85% r = 0.0252/1.0312 = 2.44% r = 0.0067/1.0312 = 0.65% Assuming no change in tastes, that is, an unchanged risk aversion, investors perceiving higher risk will demand a higher risk premium to hold the same portfolio they held before. If we assume that the risk-free rate is unaffected, the increase in the risk premium would require a higher expected rate of return in the equity market. 5-7 25. b. 26. Expected return for your fund = T-bill rate + risk premium = 5% + 8% = 13% Expected return of client’s overall portfolio = (0.6 13%) + (0.4 5%) = 9.8% Standard deviation of client’s overall portfolio = 0.6 14% = 8.4% 27. Reward to variability ratio Risk premium 8 0.57 Standard deviation 14 28. Average Rate of Return, Standard Deviation and Reward-to-Variability Ratio of the Risk Premiums for Small Common Stocks over One Month Bills for 1926-2003 and Various Sub-Periods 1926-1943 1944-1963 1964-1983 1984-2003 1926-2003 Risk Premium(%) Mean SD 18.40 60.00 17.84 29.86 13.61 35.30 9.08 25.69 14.64 38.72 Reward-toVariability Ratio 0.3066 0.5975 0.3855 0.3535 0.3780 Table 5.5 (for comparison) 1926-1943 1944-1963 1964-1983 1983-2003 1926-2003 Risk Premium(%) Mean SD 7.15 29.07 14.74 18.38 2.76 17.29 9.08 16.79 8.46 20.80 Reward-toVariability Ratio 0.2460 0.8018 0.1596 0.5408 0.4071 a. For the entire period (1926-2003), small stocks had a lower reward-tovariability ratio (0.3780) than large stocks (0.4071). However, in two of the four sub-periods, small stocks performed better than large stocks. b. In general, yes. 5-8 29. Average Real Return, Standard Deviation and Reward-to-Variability Ratio for Real Returns for Large Stocks for 1926-2003 and Various Sub-Periods Real Return(%) 1926-1943 1944-1963 1964-1983 1984-2003 1926-2003 Mean 8.16 13.39 3.51 10.96 9.03 SD 28.20 19.44 16.80 16.86 20.56 Reward-toVariability Ratio 0.2895 0.6887 0.2091 0.6496 0.4391 Except for the period 1944-1963, reward-to-variability ratios for real rates are higher than those for excess returns. 30. Average Real Return, Standard Deviation and Reward-to-Variability Ratio for Real Returns for Small Stocks for 1926-2003 and Various Sub-Periods Real Return(%) 1926-1943 1944-1963 1964-1983 1984-2003 1926-2003 Mean 18.99 16.48 13.84 11.04 14.99 SD 57.93 30.15 33.77 24.59 37.48 Reward-toVariability Ratio 0.3278 0.5467 0.4099 0.4491 0.4000 As is the case with large stocks, reward-to-variability ratios of real rates for small stocks are generally higher than those for excess returns. This suggests that both portfolios have similar correlations with inflation. 5-9