a The Chinese Current Account Surplus: Where is This Growth Coming From? The Eurasia Center Kumar Bhattacharyya April 15, 2014 Over the past decade, an interesting anomaly has surfaced on the Global Economy; China has been running a massive Current Account surplus. This rise, from 68.7 billion USD in 2004, to a peak of 412.8 billion USD in 2008, to 201 billion USD in 2011, testifies to the fact that China has been running the highest Current Account surplus in the world, followed by Germany and Saudi Arabia.2 With China becoming more and more relevant in the discussion of global economic imbalances, it is necessary to understand the various factors that have resulted in this massive surplus. These factors can generally be grouped into five categories excluding currency manipulation; Industry Relocation, Measurement Errors, By-products of policies promoting growth, the Saving and Investment gap, and finally Factor market distortions. Why isn’t currency manipulation included in these factors? Because of this alarming rise, US economic policymakers and policymakers around the world have cried foul, heavily criticizing what they characterize as rampant Chinese currency manipulation being the 2. C.I.A World Fact Book. "China Current Account Balance." China Current Account Balance. N.p., n.d. Web. 02 Dec. 2013 http://www.indexmundi.com/china%2F/current_account_balance.html 5. Staiger, Robert W. "Currency "manipulation" and World Trade: A Caution." VOX. N.p., n.d. Web. 2 Dec. 2013 http://www.voxeu.org/article/currency-manipulation-and-world-trade-three-reasons-caution 1. Trachtman, Sam. "Understanding China's Trade Surplus: Going Beyond Currency Manipulation." China Research; A Center for Collaborative Research on Greater China. N.p., n.d. Web. 2 Dec. 2013. http://www.chinacenter.net/understanding-chinas-trade-surplus-going-beyond-currency-manipulation/ 6. Morrison, Wayne M. "China's Currency Policy: An Analysis of the Economic Issues."Congressional Research Service 7-5700 (2013): n. page. Print http://www.fas.org/sgp/crs/row/RS21625.pdf a prime culprit. Traditionally, currency manipulation practices distort trade, as they amount to the equivalent of a subsidy to exports and a tariff on imports. The general argument is that through currency manipulation, the Chinese were able to prevent the RMB from appreciating against the rest of the world currencies, keeping its value artificially low. Up until 2005, the Chinese RMB was pegged to the US dollar; however the Chinese changed their policies, pegging the RMB to a larger basket of currencies.5 This allowed the RMB to appreciate 34% as of June 2013 against the U.S dollar.6 There are other indications that give cause to criticize the accusation of such currency undervaluation necessary to be the sole contributor to such a high surplus. China would have to cope with devastating inflationary pressures, and while inflation has been high, it seems the level of inflation does not reflect the degree to which some argue the RMB is undervalued.1 It is highly implausible that only currency manipulation is that cause for such a high Current Account surplus. Measurement Errors The quality and honesty with which numbers are presented by the Chinese government has always been a major concern for economics all around the world. Because of this, some have argued that there has been an overestimation of China’s Current Account surpluses. The key proposition is that there were capital inflows, which would otherwise be prohibited given capital account controls, disguised in forms of export revenues or income transfers.8 This form of inflows is sometimes dubbed hot money inflows, and some third- party entities such as Bank of America have claimed that the official numbers are vastly overestimated.9 These ‘hot money inflows’ have been found to artificially increase the Current Account, but only by 2-3 percentage points in recent years, not enough to be the sole contributor. Industry Relocation Another factor that has played a huge role in China’s Current account surplus is the relocation of industries from many Southeast Asian countries to China in the wake of the ’96 Asian crises.4 In 1978, China was just barely recognizable in terms of global exports, yet by 2012 China established itself as the number one exporter in the world. Increasing by a factor of about 15, China is now responsible for 10% of all of global trade.4 The Asian ’97 crises allowed China to amp up its trade, since most of the Southeast Asian countries transferred their industry manufacturing to China, allowing China to jump from a regional exporter to a global exporter. However, it is important to note that in the processing industries with regards to China; usually 60-70% of the value of manufactured products was imported content. As an assembler, China is the last stage of the international supply chain.8 b This could give reason to speculate that perhaps Chinese exports are overvalued, another possible measurement error that could boost China’s current account even higher then what it should, in reality, be. By-Product of Policies Promoting Strong Growth It is no secret that the Chinese favor economic growth and maximum employment, and that these policies focus much more on profits than profitability. Job creation has always been a huge issue for the Chinese, as they have a massive labor surplus in the country side. The growth targets that are set, for instance, are derived solely from the effort of job creation and to increase output. Also, the exchange rate policy does play into these policies that promote strong growth. It can be argued that there were two parts to Chinese exchange rate policy; exchange rate protection for the export sector by currency undervaluation, and to maintain a stable exchange rate. This exchange rate policy, along with the idea that China built up foreign exchange reserves as a form of self-insurance inevitably led to large current account surpluses as a by-product.4 The Saving and Investment Gap The Household savings rate is startling. The average saving rate for urban households in Chinas has increased from 15 percent in the early 1990’s to over 30 percent in recent years.11 This high savings rate is a result of multiple factors, including an increasingly elderly population, the nonexistence of government pension and welfare plans, and the incredible cost of healthcare due to a lack of government subsidies.11 A high savings rate, by definition, causes a high current account surplus, as Chinese reserves are growing and are not being spent.1 Factor-Market Distortions A relatively new theory that could explain the currency account surplus in China is the existence of Factor-Market distortions, particularly the distortion of Labor. These cost distortions generally push factor prices, and therefore production costs, to lower levels then they would otherwise be in a free market environment. One key element that is relevant in China is that outside the property sector, the government artificially determines land prices.8 These cost distortions, because they push factor prices below the 8. Yiping, Huang. "Causes and Remedies of China's External Imbalances." China Center for Economic Research, Working Paper Series E2010002 (2010): n. page. Print. http://en.ccer.edu.cn/download/6802-1.pdf 9. News, Bloomberg. "China Trade Surplus Seen by BofA at One-Tenth Customs Figure."Bloomberg.com. Bloomberg, 21 May 2013. Web. 02 Dec. 2013 http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2013-05-20/china-trade-surplus-seen-by-bofa-at-one-tenth-official-figure.html 4. Corden, Max. "China's Exchange Rate Policy, Its Current Account Surplus and the Global Imbalances." The Economic Journal 119 (2009): 1-12. Print http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/store/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02319.x/asset/j.14680297.2009.02319.x.pdf?v=1&t=hoesc9he&s=127aec4d907a4e68bed6bc62391a9547984146dc b market price, actually end up acting as a major subsidy to both production and investment. c On the flip side, these very low factor prices act as a heavy tax on the laborers. This tax hits the households the hardest. Because of the low wages being paid out to the laborers, household income is reduced and there is a depression on consumer spending. This boosted investment and depressed consumption imply an imbalance that is already well known to exist within China; the imbalance between investment and consumption, which leads to an imbalance between domestic and external demand.8 In the labor market, China’s Hukou system (household registration) results in migrant workers often are paid below their marginal product simply because they are not eligible for the few benefits or labor protections that are made available to registered residents. This takes the form of cheap labor being readily available and causes depressed consumption, which widens the saving and income gap, creating further boosts to the external sector surplus.8 These contributions to social welfare by employers makeup a large portion of the payroll, and should urban employers make such contributions, the payroll would potentially rise by 35-40 percent.8 So, essentially, employers that deal with migrant workers that do not benefit from these social welfare systems built into their payroll lose that percentage, and it is thus added to the profit of the employer. Conclusion This is but a short analysis of the entire puzzle of the Chinese Current Account surplus, yet in order to understand this phenomena one must understand all of the parts of the puzzle. The Current Account surplus continues to grow in China, and there seems little reason for it to change. Change means uncertainty, a risk that many think the Chinese government is not willing to take. As long as China continues to see high growth as well as advancement in an array of other sectors, China will be unwilling to address the growing imbalances in the global economy that are just under the surface. c4. Corden, Max. "China's Exchange Rate Policy, Its Current Account Surplus and the Global Imbalances." The Economic Journal 119 (2009): 1-12. Print http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/store/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02319.x/asset/j.14680297.2009.02319.x.pdf?v=1&t=hoesc9he&s=127aec4d907a4e68bed6bc62391a9547984146dc 11. Chamon, Marcos; Liu, Kai; Prasad, Eswar (2010) : Income uncertainty and household savings in China, Discussion paper series // Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit, No. 5331 http://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/51714/1/66890092X.pdf 8. Yiping, Huang. "Causes and Remedies of China's External Imbalances." China Center for Economic Research, Working Paper Series E2010002 (2010): n. page. Print. http://en.ccer.edu.cn/download/6802-1.pdf