CE Delft CE Solutions for Oplossingen voor environment, milieu, economie economy and en technologie technology Oude Delft 180 Oude Delft 2611 180 HH Delft tel: 015 150 150 2611 HH 2Delft 015 2 150 151 Thefax: Netherlands e-mail: ce@ce.nl website: www.ce.nl fax:Besloten +31 15 2150 151 Vennootschap 27251086 e-mail: KvK ce@ce.nl tel: +31 15 2150 150 website: www.ce.nl Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios KvK 27251086 Discussion paper for the workshop on internalisation on March 15, 2007 Discussion paper Delft, March 8, 2007 Author(s): H.P. van Essen and B.H. Boon (CE Delft) M. Maibach and C. Schreyer (INFRAS) Contents 1 Introduction 1.1 Background of the project 1.2 Aim and scope of the project 1.3 Aim of the workshop 1.4 Reader 1 1 2 2 3 2 External cost estimates 2.1 Introduction 2.2 Overview of the general approach 2.3 Best Practice per cost category 2.3.1 Congestion and scarcity costs 2.3.2 Accident costs 2.3.3 Air pollution cost 2.3.4 Noise costs 2.3.5 Climate change 2.3.6 Other external costs 2.3.7 Summary 2.4 Cost estimates 2.4.1 Level of differentiation 2.4.2 Ranges and levels of accuracy per mode of transport 2.4.3 Putting the values into practice 2.5 Main questions for the workshop 5 5 5 10 10 12 14 17 19 21 23 26 26 27 32 34 3 Scenarios for internalisation 3.1 Introduction 3.2 Aims of internalisation and pricing policies 3.2.1 Potential aims of internalisation 3.2.2 Motives and aims in directive 2006/38/EC 3.2.3 This project 3.3 Theoretical framework 3.3.1 Optimal internalisation methods depend on the context 3.3.2 Marginal social cost pricing 3.3.3 Deviations from marginal social cost pricing 3.3.4 Differentiation of existing taxes or charges 3.3.5 Policy packaging 3.3.6 Use of revenues and earmarking 3.4 Legal background 35 35 36 36 36 37 37 38 38 38 41 42 43 44 3.5 3.6 3.7 3.8 From theory to practice - cross cutting issues in designing scenarios 45 3.5.1 Most important cost categories per mode 46 3.5.2 Options for incentive base 46 3.5.3 How to deal with existing taxes and charges? 49 3.5.4 Revenue use 53 3.5.5 What to do with air pollution? 54 3.5.6 What to do about congestion? 55 3.5.7 How to address the costs of noise? 56 3.5.8 What to do about external accident costs? 57 3.5.9 What to do about climate costs? 58 3.5.10 Special issue: Do we need a toll system for passenger cars? 60 Proposal for scenarios 61 3.6.1 Scenario 1 - Reference scenario 62 3.6.2 Scenario 2 - Differentiation of existing taxes and charges & regulation 62 3.6.3 Scenario 3 - Full internalisation of external cost 66 3.6.4 Scenario 4 - Full internalisation of intersectoral external costs only 68 3.6.5 Scenario 5 - Mix of differentiation and new taxes and charges 70 3.6.6 Scenario 6 - Current directive for road freight to a maximum 73 Next steps 75 Main questions for the workshop 75 References 77 1 Introduction This report is the input paper to the workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport in Brussels on 15 March 2007. In this chapter a brief explanation of the background of this project, its aim and its scope are provided. The aim of the workshop is also discussed. 1.1 Background of the project The benefits from transport are enormous. It contributes significantly to economic growth and enables a global market. Without transport, current day society would have a totally different structure. Unfortunately, most forms of transport do not only affect society in a positive way but also give rise to side effects. Ships for example contribute to air pollution, trains and aircraft to noise and road vehicles to congestion. Such effects of transport are generally not borne by those who caused them and hence not taken into account when they make a transport decision. If so, these effects may be labelled external effects. Associated with the external effects of noise, pollution, accidents, congestion and climate change impacts are costs. Internalisation of these effects means making such effects part of the decision making process. Generally this means that market-based instruments (e.g. taxes, charges, emission trading) are introduced or altered in order to give incentives to limit external effects. Existing taxes and charged may be differentiated, e.g. to Euro standards. In some cases existing instruments may not be able to give incentives in line with cost drivers. Then there may good reasons to introduce additional taxes or charges. Because of considerations of fairness, existing taxes or charges may be lowered or abolished in order to limit the total tax burden of transport users. Transport pricing is a sensitive subject. There is a lot of public and political resistance to the subject particularly when it comes to the increase of overall tax and charge levels. Transport users already pay a large variety of taxes and charges. A major aim behind these existing taxes and charges is to cover infrastructure costs. In most cases, internalisation of external cost has not been a major aim when current taxes and charges were introduced. They generally provide few incentives to limit external costs. Internalisation of external costs can be an efficient way to reduce the negative side effects of transport. It is an important precondition to: − Improve transport efficiency (e.g. efficient use of scarce infrastructure, energy and environmentally efficient rolling stock, efficient use of different transport modes). − Guarantee fairness between transport modes, that means fair prices considering the overall performance and potentials of the different transport modes. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 1 − Improve safety and reduce environmental nuisances in the transport sector. Over the last decade, issues related to external effects and internalisation have been extensively studied under a number of European Framework Program projects (e.g. UNITE, PETS, ExternE, IMPRINT, REVENUE, MC-ICAM, TRENEN, GRACE). With the amendment of Directive 1999/62/EC on the charging for infrastructure use of heavy duty vehicles the subject has come to the forefront of attention. Article 11 of the amended directive 2006/38/EC requires the Commission to present a general applicable, transparent and comprehensible model for the assessment of all external costs (including those caused by nonroad modes). This model is to serve as a basis for future calculations of infrastructure charges. The model must be accompanied by an impact analysis on the internalisation of external costs for all modes of transport and a strategy for stepwise implementation. 1.2 Aim and scope of the project The aim of this study is to provide an overview of market based instruments that can be applied for internalising all external costs in all transport modes and to show the impact of various approaches. Based on the enormous amount of material on these issues, this study will give a comprehensive overview of applicable options for estimating and internalising external cost of transport. The result of this study should help the Commission with the development of policy for internalizing external costs of transport by showing options for internalizing and their possible impacts. The study should, in addition, give an overview of the costs of and tolls levied on road infrastructure in all these countries. This part of the project is not covered in the workshop, however. The scope of this study is the extended European Union (EU27) plus Norway and Switzerland. Besides market-based instruments, also some more direct regulatory measures are considered, although these may not be labelled internalisation in the strict sense. 1.3 Aim of the workshop As a part of this project, a workshop will take place in Brussels on March15, 2007. At this workshop the project team will share their views on the methods for estimating external cost and internalisation scenarios with a group of policy makers, scientists and European interest group representatives. The aim of the workshop is twofold. First, to make use of the broad expertise on these issues among the invitees. Second, to gain support for the results of the project, which is deemed crucial for any further step towards policy development on internalisation of external costs. 2 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 1.4 Reader The next chapter presents an overview and assessment of various methods for estimating external cost of transport. Chapter 3 provides an overview of methods for internalising external costs of transport and a list of internalisation scenarios. From this list a selection will be made to come to a set of four to six scenarios which will be subjected to an impact assessment later on in this project. In each of these chapters, the last paragraph lists a set of issues to be discussed at the workshop. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 3 4 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 2 External cost estimates 2.1 Introduction ‘Fair and efficient pricing’ or ‘getting the prices right’ requires an accepted (scientifically and politically) measurement of external cost of transport. The strength of the internalisation approach is the dealing with quantified figures in the policy debate. At the same time this is also a weakness since there is a long way from a scientific concept to monetarised values ready for pricing instruments (or other measures). The production of unit values ready for internalisation needs a modelling approach with a clear definition of external costs, scientific consensus on basic methodology and the dealing with critical values and uncertainties. This chapter describes the major issues of external cost estimation and approaches per cost category, based on a preliminary evaluation of existing studies at EU and national level. It forms the basis for the handbook on estimating external costs which will be developed in this project. 2.2 Overview of the general approach Several attempts have been made to estimate external costs in the transport sector. At EU-level, the CAPRI project (1999) and the High Level group on transport infrastructure charging (1999) have made recommendations for best practice approaches, within a dialogue between researchers and policy experts. These have been further developed and used within the two research projects UNITE and GRACE, in order to provide cost figures. HEATCO has made recommendations for unit cost figures for externalities which can be used in transport related Cost Benefit Analysis. Within the sector of air pollution, the figures are compatible with the approach developed for the CAFE standards, with unit costs per air pollutant. The most recent recommendations have been developed in Germany, with the Methodological Convention to estimate environmental costs (UBA, 2006). At the same time several national and international studies have estimated costs for different transport modes. Although the basic approaches and methodologies are similar, the differences between the estimated figures are big. In order to transform the estimation approach into real figures, the following questions are of major importance: − The transformation requires a lot of pragmatic decisions: How accurate is accurate enough? Scientists tend to underestimate the level of costs, if uncertain cost categories cannot be quantified. On the other hand, interest groups tend to under- or overestimate specific cost categories favouring their transport mode. It has to be considered that estimating of external costs is a scientific and political approach at the same time. − The level of differentiation is a tricky issue: The more differentiation (e.g. based on bottom up procedures), the more accurate are some values, the more difficult however is it to translate them into policy measures. On the other hand top down procedures (based on national average figures) tend to simplify the approach. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 5 − There are several important uncertainties, not only with respect to the economic valuation (such as the value of statistical life or specific shadow prices for pollutants such as CO2), but also with respect to the availability of transport, safety and environmental data. a Definition of external costs and level of externality External costs are not paid by the transport users. Transport users are thus faced with incorrect incentives for transport supply and demand, leading to welfare losses. However: Defining ‘external costs’, within the transport policy discussion, there are usually two types of discussions. − The scientific discussion, focussing on welfare optimisation and efficient pricing. Within this approach, the term ‘external’ is not of major importance. Much more the term ‘marginal social cost of transport’ is relevant, which are all costs (infrastructure, congestion, accidents, environment) caused by an additional vehicle km. These costs are used as a basis for optimal infrastructure pricing. Within this logic, external costs are the difference between these costs and the marginal revenues (esp. based on variable taxes and charges paid such as infrastructure charges and excise fuel duties). − The transport accounts discussion, where external costs are the difference between the total social costs of transport and the costs already paid by the user. This view focuses mainly on cost recovery and fairness conditions and is including total infrastructure costs. As analysed within the UNITE project, these two approaches are leading to different figures (marginal, average and total costs, internal and external costs) and two different outcomes of internalisation measures. There is consensus that for the time being, transport users consider: − Prices (including all taxes and charges). Existing taxes and charges cover parts or all infrastructure costs. In some countries, total revenues from transport taxes and charges exceed the total infrastructure costs. In size the most important tax is fuel excise duty. − Their own waiting time or opportunity costs within scarce or congested infrastructure, but not the costs they impose on other transport users. − Parts or all of their own risk of accidents based on their insurance, but not the risks of other transport (or non transport) users. − No damages or nuisances to society and environment. In order to produce external costs figures as a basis for practical internalisation measures, it is useful to concentrate on the three last cost items, which means external costs of scarce infrastructure, external accident costs and external environmental costs. Under- or overpayment of infrastructure costs on the other side is a financial issue. Within the internalisation scenarios however, the link to existing charges and taxes in the transport sector has to be made. This issues is further discussed in section 3.5.3. For the three types of cost to be considered, the level of externality is differing. 6 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Table 1 Level of externality per cost component and mode Cost component Social costs Costs of scarce infrastructure All costs for traffic users and society based on the difference between the current traffic situation and an optimal situation Time costs Costs of reduced reliability All direct and indirect costs of an accident Material costs Medical costs Production losses Suffer and grief Accident costs Environmental costs All damages of environmental nuisances Health costs Material damages Biosphere damages Long term risks WTP = Willingness to pay. External part in general Part which additional demand above a certain traffic volume impose to other users External part Road Difference between marginal and average costs congestion costs External part Rail and Air Difference between WTP for scarce slots and average airport/air control charges External part Waterborne Difference between marginal and average waiting costs Part of social costs which is not considered in own risk anticipation and not covered by insurance All remaining costs Add. Costs for the health sector and WTP for fatality risk reduction WTP for fatality risk reduction (depending on insurance systems) WTP for fatality risk reductions Total damage to society and nature Total damage to society and nature Total damage to society and nature Which costs are already internalised? This question is crucial for the definition of external costs. The following arguments have to be considered. − Parts of the congestion costs are paid by waiting and delay costs of the users. Thus these costs can only be estimated if marginal costs are compared with average costs. − Parts of the accident costs are paid by insurance. Thus it is very important to consider the total volume of insurance fees related to the transport sector. − In most cases environmental costs are not ‘paid’ at all (with some exceptions for CO2, see remark made above). But the quantification of environmental costs has to consider the interrelation between the cause and effect of the externality. Noise is a good example: According to the Coase theorem, it must not be only the causer (transport) which has to pay for the externality. In addition some of the taxes and charges already paid by transport users might be considered as internalisation some of the external cost. This is discussed in section 3.5.3. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 7 b Best practice methodologies Individual preferences are the most important indicator to value externalities. For some externalities, like long term risks also collective preferences have to be considered. In order to value individual preferences, the following approaches are relevant. − The willingness to pay WTP (for an improvement). − The willingness to accept (a compensation for non improvement). Several methods can be used. For resource costs the willingness to pay (WTP) is reflected by the market price of a certain effect (damage). In order to get the real WTP, taxes and subsidies have to be extracted using factor costs. If resource costs are not available, hypothetical market situations have to be constructed. Several methods can be used; all of them have strengths and weaknesses: The stated preference method using a contingent valuation approach is directly measuring the WTP, but depends very much on the survey design and the level of information. Also indirect methods like revealed preferences (e.g. hedonic pricing where house price differentials can be used to estimate costs of noise) are therefore viable. For several environmental costs (relevant for nature), more differentiated approaches are necessary, since the stated preference approach is only useful for the valuation of individual key values such as the value of a human life. In order to estimate the willingness to pay for a long term environmental problem (e.g. global warming), it is necessary to consider different risk scenarios: These are direct and indirect costs to decrease and repair environmental damage and further costs of damages which cannot be repaired. The major recommended approach is the impact pathway approach (used by the ExternE model specifically developed for air pollution) which follows the dose-response function considering several impact patterns on human health and nature. The German methodological convention is recommending seven steps to carry out such an approach. Sometimes it is necessary to combine this approach with a standard price approach, if the damage level cannot be modelled properly. In this case, as a second best approach, the avoidance cost approach (cost to avoid a certain level of pollution) can be used. The following table is summarising the best practice approaches for different cost categories pointing out the sensitive issues. 8 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Table 2 Best practice valuation approaches for most important cost component Cost component Costs of scarce infrastructure Accident costs Air pollution costs and human health Air pollution and building/material damages Air pollution and nature Noise Climate change Nature and Landscape Best practice approach WTP for the estimation of the value of time (based on contingent valuation approaches). WTP for scarce slots (based on SP with real or artificial contingent valuation approaches). Resource costs for health improvement. WTP for the estimation of Value of Statistical Life based on SP for the reduction of traffic risks. Impact pathway approach using resource cost and WTP for human life (Life years lost) base. Impact pathway approach using repair costs. Impact pathway approach using losses (e.g. crop losses at factor costs). WTP approach based on hedonic pricing (loss of rents). Impact pathway approach for human health using WTP for human life. Avoidance cost approach based on reduction scenarios of GHGemissions. Repair (compensation) cost approach. WTP = Willingness to pay; SP = Stated preference approach. c Bottom up or top down estimation Bottom up approaches are more precise and accurate, with potential for differentiation. On the other hand the approaches are costly and difficult to aggregate. Thus there is a trade off which has to be handled differently depending on type of cost. The existing literature for efficient pricing recommends mainly a bottom up approach for the impact pathway approach. In practice however a mixture of top down (with representative data) and bottom up has to be combined. Most important is the definition of appropriate clusters where cost levels are similar (such as air pollution levels, traffic characteristics and population density). It is important to state that a bottom up approach is superior to derive marginal cost values, whereas a top down approach is more appropriate to derive average(d) costs (see next section). d Estimation and internalisation approaches: marginal or average costs According to theory and ongoing research, there is no doubt that marginal social cost figures are needed for optimal internalisation scenarios. In practice and related to the new Directive for HGV charging 2006/38, a separation between infrastructure costs (and recovery) and external costs is however decisive. This leads to the conclusion, that a first best approach considers the estimation of marginal external costs for scarce infrastructure (congestion and scarcity), accident and environmental costs. The link to internalisation can be shown as follows: 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 9 Table 3 Relation between marginal and average costs and links to internalisation Cost component Difference between marginal and average costs (costs per veh.km) Marginal costs above average costs: Difference is relevant to define external costs. Costs of scarce infrastructure Accident costs Marginal costs for infrastructure use unclear, Average costs as a proxy possible. Air pollution costs and human health Linear dose response function: Marginal costs similar to average costs. Air pollution and building/material damages Linear dose response function: Marginal costs similar to average costs. Air pollution and nature Linear dose response function: Marginal costs similar to average costs. Noise Decreasing dose response function, Marginal costs below average costs. Climate change Marginal damage costs similar to average costs (if no major risks included). For avoidance costs, marginal costs are higher than average costs. Marginal costs are significantly lower than average costs. Nature and landscape 2.3 Best Practice per cost category 2.3.1 Congestion and scarcity costs Practical implementation and proposed differentiation Estimation of marginal cost based on standardised curves for specific traffic clusters (urban-interurban, peak-off peak). Marginal or average costs per vkm for different type of infrastructure (urban, interurban, motorways, non motorways). Average costs per accident as a basis for liability differentiation. Marginal (averaged) costs per type of vehicle (EURO-class) and traffic and population clusters (urban, interurban). Marginal (averaged) costs per type of vehicle (EURO-class) and traffic and population clusters (urban, interurban). Marginal (averaged) costs per type of vehicle (EURO-class) and traffic clusters (urban, interurban). Marginal (averaged)costs) per traffic and population clusters (urban, interurban). Marginal (averaged) costs per type of vehicle and/or fuel. Averaged (or marginal) variable costs per type of infrastructure. It is important to distinguish between the following terms: − Congestion in the narrow sense denotes the social loss due to the fact that users do not care for the additional costs and inconvenience they cause to other users. This is relevant for non scheduled road transport. − Delays, additional journey times or increased travel costs are the effects of traffic congestion experienced by users. In scheduled transport delays can be measured against arrival and departure times published in time tables, but it is not clear in how far time tables already consider usual delays. − Reliability is based on delay information, but the inconvenience for users is not only expressed by the demand-capacity driven prolongation of travel or shipment time, but by their fluctuation. The argument behind this concept is that the traveller or shipper needs to know with a particular level of certainty 10 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 − when the trip needs to start in order to arrive on time. For the purpose of setting efficient congestion charges information on regular traffic conditions is more appropriate than information on the effects of irregular events. Scarcity denotes the economic costs to users and operators occurring when infrastructures can not be used at the desired time due to overcrowding. Scarcity thus describes the opportunity costs due to displacement or exclusion. They can not be measured directly as they describe potentially lost benefits rather than real measurable costs. Thus, slot auctioning is proposed as a means to value infrastructure scarcity. Besides these quantitative concepts congestion can be expressed by qualitative measures, such as Level-of-Service marks. Such information is, however, not helpful for price setting and will not be considered in detail in the subsequent presentation of results. Out of the above concepts the elaborations will concentrate on marginal social congestion costs and on delay valuations. a Best practice approach Most important is the analysis carried out within UNITE, GRACE, INFRAS/IWW and COMPETE. All these studies have provided methodologies and have quantified marginal external congestion costs for specific traffic situations, especially for road transport. GRACE has estimated as well scarcity costs for public transport; COMPETE has analysed the available data basis and as well additional congestion costs for indirect economic losses. Comparing the methodologies, we find consensus on the basic approach valuing mainly the value of time based on speed flow characteristics (road transport) and opportunity cost approaches for scarce tracks. Nevertheless the difference between proposed values is quite huge, depending on differentiation and traffic characteristics (e.g. corridors, lanes, cordons, etc.). The level of detail depends very much on the internalisation strategy to be applied (e.g. road or track pricing schemes). Thus it is very difficult to recommend general values of congestion costs. Our assessment of existing studies has shown however that the studies mentioned can be used to provide bandwidths. For the measurement of unit congestion costs (marginal congestion costs for specific traffic situations), the following steps are necessary: 1 Differentiation of the traffic network: urban/interurban, single/multiple lanes. This depends very much on the specific network conditions. 2 Speed flow curves for different traffic network segments. There are some curves (UK, Germany, TRENEN) available. Most realistic seem to be the German curves. 3 Transformation to congestion cost curves (mathematical step). 4 Valuation of speed losses with a valuation of time approach. There are several studies measuring the value of time. Within this context it is very important to use the willingness to pay to reduce congested situations. The analysis shows that the basic value of time in congestion might be lower than in general, but due to the fact of indirect costs, the total value of time can be higher. UNITE has used a Value of Time for road transport of 21 € 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 11 5 (1998/business) and 4 € (leisure). Other studies (such as INFRAS/IWW) have used higher values in order to consider as well possible indirect costs of congestion (especially for business and freight transport). HEATCO 2006 recommends higher time values for delays due to congestions or late arrivals in public transport. HEATCO 2006 recommends to value the time in congested situation in road transport 1.5 times higher than standards invehicle-time. For freight transport, the factor is 1.9. For public transport, it is recommended to value the delays 2.5 times higher than standard in-vehicletime. Estimation of traffic reactions by charging the external congestion costs. This step can only be carried out with the help of traffic modelling. For other modes than road transport, delay and scarcity costs are of major importance. An appropriate way to estimate scarcity costs is the willingness to pay for a specific track, which has been used within the GRACE project. b Critical aspects All steps are depending strongly on the level of differentiation and the quality of data available, specifically the speed flow relations (congestion data) and the value of time. Methodological uncertainties are on the other hand comparably low. One issue is the treatment of congestion costs due to traffic accidents. It is useful to allocate these costs within traffic accidents since they are not caused due to infrastructure scarcity, unless there is a link between the scarcity and the accident risks. 2.3.2 Accident costs External accidents costs are those costs which are not covered by risk oriented insurance premiums. Compared to the other external cost components and similar to infrastructure costs, part of the costs are paid (internalised) by the user. Therefore the level of external costs does not only depend on the level of accidents, but also on the insurance system. a Best practice approach There are two different approaches, leading to rather different results: − The top down approach (UNITE, IWW/INFRAS, OSD) estimates total and average accident costs considering national accident statistics and insurance systems. It focuses on material damages and administrative costs (usually covered by the insurance premiums), medical costs (including other insurance systems), production losses and societal valuation of risks (usually external). This approach considers all production losses and valuation of risks (as well for self accidents) as external. The values are usually rather high. There are two views to consider: In order to allocate insurance premiums, two views are to consider: The first view focuses on transport individuals and does only consider risk dependent premiums. The other view focuses on the total transport systems considering the total cost recovery. Risk balance between transport users is considered. Thus the values of the second approach are quite lower. 12 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 − The bottom up approach (UNITE, GRACE) aims at estimating marginal costs. The magnitude of the costs depend on risk elasticity (correlation between traffic levels and accidents) and on the assumption of risk values. Differently to the top down approach, it is assumed that transport users are able to anticipate and consider their own risk. Thus only third party damages are seen as external. Only the willingness to pay for relatives and friends has to be considered. Thus the values are considerably lower than those applying the top down approach. There is still no consensus on a best practice approach at scientific level. Moreover it has to be considered that the choice of approaches is very sensitive in regard to values. Although there are a lot of accurate studies available, there is no consensus of a best practice approach. We prefer the top down approach as more appropriate since it is more transparent and considers the insurance system properly. The bottom up approach seems very narrow and considers a risk elasticity (accidents by vkm). The wide range of risk elasticities found in empirical estimates however shows that an internalisation strategy based on infrastructure pricing is not a very effective strategy. b Critical aspects There are several critical aspects to consider: − Underreporting: the number of fatalities and injuries in official statistics and databases does not reflect to total number or accidents, fatalities and injuries. For some countries, figures are available. − Risk value VSL: In the GRACE project (Lindberg, 2006) the different biases are discussed. Throughout the world empirical estimates of VSL diametrically differ between different studies, ranging from a value of less than 200 000 to 30 million US dollars (de Blaeij, 2003). HEATCO made survey of the current European practice; the result is shown in the figure below. Looking at the practice in different external cost estimates (UNITE, INFRAS/IWW), an average value of 1.5 Mio € (bandwith between 1 and 3 Mio.) have been used. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 13 Figure 1 Values of accident fatalities by GDP/capita (EUR 2002 factor prices, PPS = purchasing power standard). Source: HEATCO − − − − 2.3.3 Internal and external part of risk value, linked to the two approaches shown above. This issue is very sensitive. Inclusion of risk values for relatives and friends: in most studies (UNITE, INFRAS/IWW, GRACE) a risk value for relatives and friends is not accounted for due to methodological reasons. Different early studies assume the WTP and thus the risk value of relatives and friends as a proportion of some one's own risk value (between 10-50%). Risk elasticities (different results in different case studies), relevant for the estimation of marginal costs. The values of studies (e.g. compiled in UNITE) differ widely. Cost allocation to different vehicle categories: Linked to the top down approach, there are several possibilities (causer or victim’s perspective, simplified approaches). Air pollution cost Air pollution costs are caused by the emission of air pollutants such as PM, NOx, Ozone and consist of health costs, building/material damages, crop losses and costs for further damages for the ecosystem (biosphere, soil, water). Health costs (mainly caused by PM, from exhaust emissions or transformation of other pollutants) are by far the most important cost category. Thus the state of research on these costs is much more advanced, mainly based on estimations carried out by the ExternE model funded by several EU-research projects. a Best practice approach The calculation of air pollution costs is a core external cost category and therefore a considerable amount of studies on methodology as well as studies on total, average and marginal costs is available. Within European research projects the Impact Pathway Approach established within the ExternE project is a 14 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 commonly used tool and already very advanced; ongoing research is conducted in order to update this methodology, such as NewExt (2005) or Methodex (2007). This approach can be regarded as the most advanced approach for the estimation of air pollution costs and thus is recommended as a best practice methodology. The ExternE approach is a bottom up approach originally aiming at estimating marginal costs for different traffic situations. The strength of this approach is its consistency and the consideration of different detailed input variables. However it is rather costly in order to derive average(d) and representative figures for a whole country. Thus simplified top down approaches have been developed as an alternative (especially used in Switzerland, OSD 2006). Although the dose response assumptions are similar, the final values might differ, due to the use of different air pollution concentration models and different emission characteristics (e.g. the consideration of exhaust and other particles due to abrasion and resuspension). The following picture gives an overview on the most important steps of the Impact Pathway Approach established within ExternE. Figure 2 The Impact Pathway Approach for the quantification of marginal external costs caused by air pollution and noise Impact Assessment Valuation Activity Emissions Transport and chemical conversion Concentration/ Deposition Response of receptors (humans, flora, materials, ecosystems) Physical impact Change in utility Welfare losses Monetization Costs 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 15 Each step requires inputs: − Transport flows: data required range from traffic models relevant to specific route(s), or corridor(s), to data at the aggregated level for the geographic unit considered (a country, a region, etc.). Disaggregation by vehicle technology and occupancy rates (load factors for freight) are systematically needed. − Emissions: emission factors (by technology) for all vehicle, train, plane or ship technologies are needed including the emission factors for the main upand downstream processes. For modelling the chemical transformation of the pollutants in the atmosphere, emission data bases covering all emission sources are needed for the different spatial scales. − Concentrations and impacts: in addition to transport flows and emissions, data requirements cover two main areas: i) receptor data (geographical coordinates, population density, other geo-morphological information, such as built environment pattern for urban situations, building surfaces, etc.), ii) meteorological data (mainly wind speed and direction). Impacts are derived from the application of exposure- or dose-response functions, whose knowledge is therefore a prerequisite. − Monetary valuation, finally, requires the availability of WTP/WTA, damage costs and restoration/reparation cost data. Based on most recent research by NewExt and UBA, figures for a life year lost of 50’000 to 75’000 € are recommended. Based on this procedure unit cost per air pollutant can be elaborated. Most important are the costs for PM and for NOx. CAFE has produced general figures for all EU countries. The values per tonne for PM2.5 are varying between 8’60025’000 € (low/high value for Greece) and 63’000-180’000 € (low/high value for the Netherlands. The values per tonne of NOx are for most countries considerably lower. Several studies have produced figures for the transport sector. UBA (2006), based on ExternE calculations, shows values between 92’000 € (interurban) and 450’000 € (big cities) per tonne of PM10 emission for exhaust particles and 58’000 up to 180’000 € (abrasion and re-suspension). In HEATCO 2006, unit cost values per emitted amount of PM2.5 are given for all European countries. The values range from 140’000 €2002 to 730’000 €2002 per ton of PM2.5 emitted for urban areas and from 22’000 €2002 to 104’000 €2002 for interurban areas (Germany: 400’000 €2002 per ton of PM2.5 in urban areas and 78’000 €2002 per ton in interurban areas). The approach can be used for all modes. For rail transport, the emission factors due to abrasion are very sensitive. b Critical aspects and uncertainties Critical aspects and uncertainties can be grouped according to NewExt (2005) into 5 categories. Most of these points apply for both major approaches in external air pollution cost calculation: − Data uncertainty: slope of dose-response functions, cost of a day of restricted activity, deposition velocity of a pollutant, emission factors for different vehicle categories and traffic situations. − Model uncertainties: assumption about causal links between pollutant and health impact (e.g. consideration of other emission sources), assumption 16 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 − − 2.3.4 about the form of a dose-response function (with/without threshold), choice of models for atmospheric dispersion and chemistry, underlying model parameters (e.g. meteorological input parameters). Policy/ethical choices: discount rates for intergenerational costs, value of statistical life. Interpretation of incomplete and ambiguous information. Noise costs Noise costs consist of costs for annoyance and health. The annoyance costs are usually economically based on preferences of individuals (by surveys), whereas health costs (especially due to increased risk of heart attacks) are based on dose response figures. Since marginal noise costs decrease with increasing traffic volumes, the definition and measurement of costs is quite crucial and needs differentiation. a Best practice approach As for other cost components, we can distinguish bottom up and top down approaches measuring average(d) figures for a country. From the top-down approach studies ECMT (1998) and INFRAS/IWW (2004) are the most complete ones. INFRAS/IWW (2004) and UNITE (2003) provide estimates of marginal noise costs for all modes by using a bottom-up approach. Some methodological improvements to UNITE are proposed in GRACE (2005), but these are not yet fully elaborated. The bottom-up approach was also applied in several other case studies. The bottom-up approach is developed in the ExternE-project and is generally called the ‘Impact Pathway Approach’. The starting point of this approach is the micro level, i.e. the traffic flow on a particular route. Two scenario’s are calculated: a reference scenario reflecting the present scenario with traffic volume, speed distribution, vehicle technologies, etc., and a marginal scenario which is based on the reference scenario, but includes one additional vehicle. The difference in damage costs of both scenario’s represents the marginal external noise costs of that vehicle. The top down approach is using the willingness to pay for more silence and the health effects and multiplies this unit values with the national data on noise exposure for different noise classes. Although the results of the approaches are in a similar magnitude, there are two important differences. Firstly the bottom up approach aims at estimating marginal costs which are considerably smaller for heavily frequented and loud roads. The top down approach on the contrary does not consider specifically this correlation weighing this effect out. In addition the top down approach considers exposure rates for a whole country and thus is able to produce average(d) figures. We consider both approaches as valid. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 17 The unit costs for health costs (value of a life year lost) are the same than used for air pollution costs. Total costs per person exposed vary between different traffic modes. The following table is showing the most recent figures recommended for Germany (UBA 2006a). The values of HEATCO (2006) for Germany are lower, but in the same range: for a 60 dB noise level, the values recommended for Germany are 88 €2002 per year and person exposed for road transport, 44 €2002 for rail transport and 136 €2002 for air transport. For a noise level of 75 dB, the values are 291 €2002 per year and person for road, 248 €2002 for rail and 412 €2002 for air transport. Table 4 Unit costs for noise per person Noise level € per person exposed per year Lden [dB(A)] Road > 45 30 > 50 90 > 55 140 > 60 200 > 65 260 > 70 370 > 75 460 Source UBA (2006a) Rail Air 0 30 90 140 200 260 370 30 90 140 200 260 370 460 b Critical aspects and uncertainties Besides the approach itself, the following issues are sensitive for the valuation of noise costs: − The thresholds above which noise is considered a nuisance are somewhat arbitrary. In some studies 50 dB(A) is adopted to define a reasonable level of noise, while other studies choose 55 dB or even 60 dB(A). The impact of the threshold on marginal noise costs are substantial. ECMT (1998) shows that changing the threshold from 50 dB(A) to 55 dB(A) reduces the average results for cars by almost 50%. − Different methods can be applied to value the effects of transport noise. In some cases market prices can be used (cost of illness). However, for nuisance effects no market prices do exist, and WTP-values should be used. Hedonic pricing used to be the preferred method for quantification of amenity losses due to noise. This method provides the Noise Depreciation Sensitivity Index (NDSI), which gives the average percentage change in property prices per decibel. Also the contingent valuation method is applied in some studies to value noise costs. Other valuation methods, like abatement costs and avoidance costs, are hardly used to estimate the external costs of noise. − Valuation of fatalities based on VSL or on years of life lost, similar to the uncertainties described for health costs due to air pollution. 18 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 2.3.5 Climate change Climate change costs have a high level of complexity due to the fact, that they are long term and global and the risk patterns are very difficult to anticipate. Thus there are difficulties to value the damages and allocate them to national transport modes. Therefore a differentiated approach (looking both at the damages and the avoidance strategy) is necessary. In addition long term risks should be included. a Best Practice approach The damage cost approach uses detailed modelling to assess the physical impacts of climate change and combines these with estimations of the economic impacts resulting from these physical impacts (see e.g. Watkiss, 2005). The costs of sea level rise could e.g. be expressed as the costs of land loss. Agricultural impact can be expressed as costs or benefits to producers and consumers, and changes in water runoff might be expressed in new flood damage estimates. Using a monetary metric to express non-market impacts, such as effects on ecosystems or human health, is more difficult and requires dedicated methodologies. There is a broad and established literature on valuation theory and its application, including studies on the monetary value of lower mortality risk, ecosystems, quality of life, etc. However, economic valuation, especially in the area of climate change, is often controversial. First of all there is a general lack of knowledge about the physical impacts caused by global warming. Some impacts are rather certain and proven by detailed modelling, while other possible impacts, such as extended flooding or hurricanes with higher energy density are often not taken into account due to lack of information on the relationship between global warming and these effects. Secondary impacts such as socially contingent damages (e.g. regional conflicts) are even more difficult to assess. Available damage cost estimations of greenhouse gas emissions vary by orders of magnitude due to special theoretical valuation problems related to equity, irreversibility and uncertainty. Concerning equity both intergenerational and intragenerational equity must be considered. A recent detailed assessment of damage costs is carried out by the Social Cost of Carbon project carried out by AEA Technology and the Stockholm Environment Institute on behalf of Defra, UK. The term Social Cost of Carbon (SCC) is used to denote damage cost as opposed to Marginal Avoidance Costs (MAC). The study reviews a large number of existing studies on damage cost estimates and compares these to own modelling results. An alternative approach which avoids the uncertainties associated with assessing damage costs of climate control is to assess the costs of avoiding CO2 emissions. These are often referred to as avoidance costs or mitigation costs, and are expressed as so-called shadow values. The method is based on a costeffectiveness analysis that determines the least-cost option to achieve a required level of greenhouse gas emission reduction, e.g. related to a policy target. Using a cost curve approach the costs of reaching the specified target are calculated. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 19 The target can be specified at different system levels, e.g. at a national, EU or worldwide level and may be defined for the transport sector only or for all sectors together. This approach has been applied and recommended in several studies, such as UNITE, ExternE. A most recent estimation is summarized in the Stern report. In practice the avoidance cost approach is more feasible, since the approach is more transparent and refers to climate change policy. It has to be considered however, that several decisions in regard to the transport sector are necessary, such as the reduction target (short or long term? the scope of reduction (transport or all sectors? national or international?). This leads to the conclusion that different shadow factors per tonne of CO2 should be considered. The equilibrium price of the European trading system is a possible reference value for a short term view. Most recent recommended values (for Germany and Switzerland) are compliant with the results of the Stern report: 70 € per tonne of CO2, with a range of 20 € (short term EU average, based on Kyoto targets 1) to 280 € (long term strategy and risks). HEATCO (2006) recommends a shadow price for CO2 which depends on the year of emission: for emissions between 2000 and 2009, a shadow price of 22 € per ton CO2 is recommended (with a lower value of 14 € and an upper value of 51 € per ton CO2). For emissions in the following decades, increasing shadow prices are recommended: 26 € per ton for 2010-2019, 32 € per ton for 2020-2029, 40 € per ton for 2030-2039, etc. For emissions in 2050 a shadow price of 83 € per ton CO2 is recommended. b Critical aspects and uncertainties Critical aspects determining uncertainties in valuation studies based on damage costs are: − Assessment of the physical impacts of climate change and selection of the impacts included in the analysis; this is especially true for air transport emissions in high altitudes. − Assessment of the economic impacts resulting from the estimated physical impacts and selection of the impacts valued in the analysis. − The discount rate used. − The approach to weighting impacts in different regions (called equity weighting). − The time horizon used. Critical aspects determining the accuracy of avoidance cost estimates are: − Estimation of the greenhouse gas reduction potential of technical and nontechnical options (at the vehicle level as well as at the system level, incl. e.g. possible rebound effects). − Assessment of the future costs of technical and non-technical options in various sectors to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. − The choice of the target level that is used to assess avoidance costs, with regard to the: 1 20 The recently by the Commission proposed post-2012 targets are more stringent and are likely to increase this unit estimate. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 • − 2.3.6 System to which the target is applied (e.g. all sectors or specifically for the transport sector or a country or region vs. worldwide). • The numerical value of the target level. • Political and public acceptance; formally only legally binding targets laid down in national law or international agreements can be considered as a valid indication of the (society’s) willingness to pay. • Time horizon (short term versus long term). Assumptions on the energy costs used in the assessment of avoidance costs for the technical and non-technical options. Other external costs Within external cost studies, the following costs are usually considered in addition to the costs shown above. The estimation procedures are not widely used compared to the cost categories shown above. At EU-level an ongoing project (REMEDE, 2007) is aiming at providing methodologies and values for the damages of nature, soil and water pollution. a Costs for nature and landscape Three types of negative impacts are relevant (source: OSD, 2004): Habitat loss, habitat fragmentation and habitat quality loss. The estimation procedures are − Repair cost approach for ground sealing and other impacts on ecosystems (disturbance of animals and their biotopes by noise or barrier effects, visual disturbance, etc.). (INFRAS/IWW, 2000/4). − Standard price approach for quantifying the negative effects of airborne emissions on ecosystems and biodiversity (through acidification and eutrophication). (ExternE, 1999; NewExt, 2005). − Two-stage approach for quantifying biodiversity losses: a. repair costs for reduced species diversity due to land use change and b. repair costs for negative effects of airborne emissions on ecosystems and biodiversity (through acidification and eutrophication). (NEEDS, 2005a). − Two-stage approach for habitat loss and fragmentation: a) compensation costs for habitat loss due to transport infrastructure (creating compensatory ecosystem) and b) compensation cost approach for habitat fragmentation. (OSD, 2003). The values proposed (in INFRAS/IWW 2004) vary between 10 and 40 € per m2. The costs for nature and landscape due to airborne pollutants (e.g. through acidification and eutrophication) do not belong to the cost category ‘nature and landscape’ but are covered within the cost category ‘air pollution’. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 21 b Costs for soil and water pollution The most important negative effects of traffic on soil come from the emission of heavy metals and polycyclic aromatic hydrocarbons (PAH) by different transport modes. These pollutants can lead to plant damage and decreased soil fertility along the transport infrastructure and can sometimes even pose a threat to animals or human beings. The estimation procedures are: − − − Repair cost approach for polluted areas (soil and water pollution) along transport infrastructure (dependent on the infrastructure length). (INFRAS/IWW, 2000/4). Repair cost approach for the soil and water pollution by heavy metals, organic pollutants (e.g. polycyclic aromatic hydrocarbons, PAH), de-icing salt, herbicides and other agents along transport infrastructure (dependent on the amount of emissions and the critical concentrations). (OSD, 2006). Damage costs approach: health costs for human beings due to the emission of toxic heavy metals into soil, water and air. (ExternE, 1999; NewExt, 2005). c Additional costs in urban areas In urban areas motorised traffic has different effects on non-motorised traffic participants (pedestrians, cyclists, etc.). The following two effects are quantified in certain external cost studies: − Time losses for pedestrians due to separation effects. − Scarcity problems (expressed as the loss of space availability for bicycles). Other possible effects (e.g. urban visual intrusion due to transport volume and infrastructure) are very difficult to measure and no reliable estimates are known. The measurement is based on a two-stage approach: a. damage costs due to separation effects of transport infrastructure in urban areas (waiting time for pedestrians) and b. compensation cost approach for scarcity problems due to transport infrastructure (construction of bicycle lanes). (INFRAS/IWW 2000/4, OSD, 2006) d Costs of up- and downstream processes Indirect effects of transport cause additional external effects. It has to be considered that these costs occur in other than the transport market (e.g. energy market); hence it has to be considered if these costs are already internalised in these markets. The most relevant processes considered are the following: − Energy production (precombustion): The production of all type of energy is causing additional nuisances due to extraction, transport, transmission. They depend directly on the amount of energy used. − Vehicle production, maintenance and disposal: The production, maintenance and disposal of vehicles and rolling stock causes environmental effects (emission of air, water, soil pollutants, greenhouse gases, etc.) during a long period, considering the life cycles of different transport means. − Infrastructure construction, maintenance and disposal: The construction, maintenance and disposal of infrastructure elements also lead to negative environmental effects (emission of pollutants). The methodology for the calculation of up- and downstream processes is virtually the same in all studies quantifying these costs: The costs are calculated the same way as the direct external cost categories of transport operating. However, 22 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 instead of quantifying the environmental effects of transport operating, the negative environmental impacts of all other up- and downstream processes are calculated. The main difference between the studies is the different kind of cost categories (effects) covered: some studies only cover climate change costs of upand downstream processes whereas others also cover air pollution costs and costs due to nuclear power risks. (INFRAS/IWW, 2000/4; ExternE, 1999; NewExt, 2004; Friedrich/Bickel, 2001; OSD 2006). e Critical aspects and uncertainties Research about external cost calculation often focuses on the most important cost categories such as noise costs, air pollution costs, accident costs or climate change costs. Other external cost categories - above all cost for nature and landscape, soil and water pollution and costs in urban areas - are often neglected. Methodologies for calculating these cost categories have been developed only in very few studies. Therefore, the calculation methods are far from being as sophisticated as for the most important cost categories. Another critical aspect concerning the costs for nature and landscape as well as the costs for soil and water pollution is the very complex impact patterns of the natural ecosystems. Therefore, the knowledge about the detailed impact patterns and dose-response-relationships is less developed than in other cost categories. Often, negative impacts of transport activities on the natural environment can be proved. The detailed relationship between activity and impact can hardly be quantified. As a consequence, damage costs can often not be quantified and the calculation has to be done with a repair cost approach. 2.3.7 Summary The following table is showing the main issues and cost drivers. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 23 Table 5 Overview of main issues per cost category Cost component Congestion costs (road) Cost elements Critical valuation issues Time costs/opportunity costs Add. safety and environmental costs Speed flow relations Valuation of economically relevant value of time (reliability) Scarcity costs (scheduled transport) Delay costs Opportunity costs Valuation approach as such (measurement of opportunity costs, WTP enlargement costs, optimisation model) Increasing marginal cost Level of traffic, slot capacity per infrastructure segment Accident costs Medical costs Production losses Loss of human life Valuation of human life Externality of self accidents Allocation of accidents (causer/victim related) Weak dependency; difference between marginal and average costs not proven Accident database Definition of fatalities and heavy/slight injuries very important Air Pollution Health costs Years of human life lost Building damages Costs for nature and biosphere Valuation of life years lost Valuation of building damages Valuation of long term risks in biosphere Complex: Increasing marginal cost curve Emission and exposure data (exp. PM, NOx, Ozone) 2 Cost function (costs per vkm) Increasing marginal cost 2 Data needs Main cost drivers Speed flow data Level of traffic and capacity per road segment Type of infrastructure Traffic and capacity levels, mainly depending on: − Time of the day − Location − Accidents and constructions Type of infrastructure Traffic and capacity levels, mainly depending on: − Time of the day − Location Type of infrastructure Traffic volume Vehicle speed Driver characteristics (e.g. age, medical conditions, etc.) Others Population and settlement density Sensitivity of area Level of emissions, dep.on: − Type and condition of vehicle − Trip length (cold start emissions) − Type of infrastructure − Location − Speed characteristics Not all cost drivers will be applicable as a basis for incentives. 24 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Cost component Noise costs Data needs Main cost drivers 3 Noise exposure data (persons) Long term risks of climate change Level of damage in high altitudes (aviation) Rather proportional (marginal cost close to average cost) Emission levels Costs to reduce separation effects Compensation costs to ensure biodiversity Costs to ensure soil and water quality Valuation approach as such (replacement versus WTP approach) Very low marginal cost, but high fixed costs GIS information on infrastructure Population and settlement density Day/Night Noise emissions level, depending on: − Type of infrastructure − Type and condition of vehicle Level of emissions, depending on: − Type of vehicle and add. Equipment (e.g. air conditioning) − Speed characteristics − Driving style − Fuel type (incl. biofuels) Type of infrastructure Sensitivity of area Valuation approach as such (avoidance versus damage cost approach) Complex: Increasing marginal cost curve GIS information infrastructure, emission levels Level of emissions Type of infrastructure Separation costs for pedestrians Costs of scarcity for non motorised traffic Costs of the whole energy cycle (environmental and risk effects of energy supply) Valuation approach as such (Avoidance versus WTP approach) Increasing marginal cost curve Infrastructure data in urban areas (network data, data on slow traffic) Type of infrastructure Level of traffic Valuation of long term energy risks, such as climate change and nuclear risk Rather proportional (marginal cost close to average costs) Data on energy processes and electricity mix Level of indirect energy need Electricity mix (level of non renewables Critical valuation issues Rent losses Annoyance costs Health costs Valuation of annoyances Climate change Prevention costs to reduce risk of climate change Damage costs of increasing temperature Costs for nature and landscape Additional environmental cost (water, soil) Additional costs in urban areas Up- and downstream processes 3 Cost function (costs per vkm) Decreasing marginal cost curve Cost elements Not all cost drivers will be applicable as a basis for incentives. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 25 2.4 Cost estimates Within this chapter, the most important values for different traffic situations are shown, based on a first analysis of existing values and best practice approaches. The values presented are preliminary values and will be further developed in the project. 2.4.1 Level of differentiation The level of disaggregation differs according to cost components and mode. The following table shows the most important differentiation per cost component and mode. Table 6 Overview of differentiation of unit values per cost component Cost component Congestion costs (road) Scarcity costs Accident costs Noise costs Road Passenger Car HDV Bus/Coach Costs per vehicle Costs per vkm Type of infrastructure (Interurban, urban, metropolitan) Peak – off peak - Costs per acc. Costs per vkm Type of infrastructure (urban-interurban) Costs per vkm Urban-Interurban Day - Night Rail Passenger Freight Air Passenger Freight Waterways Inland Waterways Seaports - - - Costs per train Costs per trainkm Peak-off peak Costs per acc. Costs per trainkm Costs per plane Peak-off peak Cost per ship Peak-off peak Costs per acc. Costs per pkm (cont.-intercont.) Costs per acc. Costs per shipkm Costs per trainkm Urban-interurban Day – Night Two types of brakes Costs per airplane Hub-airportregional/hub airport Day – Night Three type of plane Costs per airplane (Landing & take-off: LTO) regional/hub airport Type of plane Costs per airplane LTO, cruise Three type of plane - Costs per vkm Costs per vkm Air Pollution Costs per vkm Urban-interurban Peak-off peak Euro standards Costs per trainkm Urban-interurban Electric Diesel Climate change Costs per vkm Urban-interurban Peak-off peak Engine capacity Vehicle weight Costs per km infrastructure Costs per vkm Costs per trainkm Urban-interurban Electric Diesel Additional external costs 26 Costs per vkm infrastructure Costs per shipkm Type of engine Costs per shipkm Type of engine 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 2.4.2 Ranges and levels of accuracy per mode of transport a 1 Total cost values Mainly two studies have estimated total external costs for Western Europe. The UIC study (INFRAS/IWW, 2004) has estimated total external costs of transport (excluding congestion costs, with climate change high scenario) of 650 billion € for 2000, being 7.3% of the total GDP in EU 17). Climate change is the most important cost category with 30% of total cost, if high shadow prices are used. Air pollution and accident costs amount to 27% and 24% respectively. The costs for noise and up- and downstream processes each account for 7% of total costs. The costs for nature and landscape and additional urban effects are of minor importance (5%). The most important mode is road transport, causing 83.7% of total cost, followed by air transport, causing 14% of total external costs. Railways (1.9%) and waterways (0.4%) are of minor importance. Two thirds of the costs are caused by passenger transport and one third by freight transport. The UNITE project has estimated total external accident and environmental costs of 120 billion €, being 1.6% of GDP. The differences stem from different methodologies for accident and air pollution costs and cautious valuation of external costs. In addition other external environmental costs like up- and downstream effects are not included. Road transport amounts to 113 billion or 94% of total cost. a 2 Unit cost values per vkm The following tables give a first overview of the range of the unit values recommended for the different cost categories and transport modes. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 27 Table 7 Road transport: unit values per cost component in €ct/vehicle-km Passenger car Cost component Noise Congestion Accidents Air pollution Climate change Nature & landscape Total Urban Interurban Urban Interurban Urban Interurban Urban Petrol Urban Diesel Interurban Petrol Interurban Diesel Urban Interurban Urban Interurban Min. 0.8 0.0 2.0 0.0 4.2 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.6 0.3 0.0 0.0 Max. Heavy duty vehicle (HDV) Min. 3.4 0.0 28 15 4.8 7.2 0.3 1.5 0.4 0.6 2.3 1.0 0.0 0.4 Max. 7.0 0.1 6.0 0.0 3.2 0.3 4.7 31 0.2 84 7.0 11 2.8 18 2.1 7.5 2.0 1.2 0.0 0.0 7.0 4.3 0.0 1.2 Peak, urban 7.7 39 23 150 Peak, interurban 3.1 38 10 103 Off-Peak, urban 5.7 26 17 73 Off-Peak, interurban 1.1 25 4.5 26 Explanations by cost category: Noise costs: Source Car/HDV: INFRAS/IWW, 2004 Min: dense traffic situations during day time Max: thin traffic situations during night time Congestion: Source: Urban Min: UNITE Case Study, Urban Max: GRACE case studies Interurban Min+ Max: UNITE case Studies Min: Off-Peak Max: Peak Accident costs: Source: UNITE case studies Min+Max: Marginal cost values from UNITE case studies Max: Marginal cost values from INFRAS/IWW, 2004 Air pollution: Source: UNITE Case Studies (D11) for different cities, Values based on EURO 2 Cars and HDVS Min: lower values from case studies (based on lower population densitiy) Max: higher values form case studies (higher pop. density) Climate change: Source: INFRAS/IWW, 2004 Min: Shadow value of 20€/t CO2 Max: Shadow value of 70€/t CO2 Nature&Landscape: Source: INFRAS/IWW, 2004 No external costs in urban and built-up areas Min: short run marginal costs Max: long run marginal costs 28 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Table 8 Rail transport: unit values per cost component in €ct/train-km Cost component Noise costs Scarcity costs (see comment below) Accident costs Air Pollution Urban Interurban Peak Rail passenger Min. Max. 27 82 1.7 5.2 Rail freight Min. 32 1.8 Max. 96 5.5 0 0 15 15 12 0 13 13 32 32 83 0 Off-Peak Urban Interurban Urban Interurban 0 0 2.5 16 11 0 13 13 5.0 42 41 0 Climate change Additional Urban external costs (nature & Interurban landscape) 0 23 0 8 Total external Urban 41 140 59 224 costs Interurban 29 123 28 140 Explanations by cost category: Noise costs: Source Rail Passenger/Rail Freight: INFRAS/IWW, 2004 Min: dense traffic situations during day time Max: thin traffic situations during night time Scarcity costs: GRACE analyses specific inter-modal corridor situation. The value of an off-peak slot is expressed as percentage of a peak slot. This value is estimated to be around 10% of the peak-slot. In an off-peak situation there are no scarcity costs. In the peak hour scarcity costs are equal to slot opportunity costs of an existing operator of a specific slot. Source: GRACE Project Accident costs: Sources: UNITE Case studies, INFRAS/IWW, CE, 2003 Min: UNITE Case studies Max: INFRAS/IWW, 2004 (in general), rail freight: ECMT, 1998, CE, 2003 Air pollution costs: Source: UNITE Case Studies (D11) Min-Max: ranges of values of different case studies, no differentiation for urban/inter-urban for rail freight transport Climate change: Source: INFRAS/IWW, 2004 Min: Shadow value of 20€/t CO2 ,electric train Max: Shadow value of 70€/t CO2 ,diesel traction No differentiation urban/interurban Nature&Landscape: Source: INFRAS/IWW, 2004 No external costs in urban and built-up areas Min: short run marginal costs Max: long run marginal costs 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 29 Table 9 Air transport: unit values per cost component in €/aircraft-km or €/LTO Cost component Noise costs Congestion costs Peak Air passenger Min. Max. Air freight Min. Unit 150 1200 150 1200 8.9 11.9 8.9 11.9 119 631 119 631 0.8 6.1 0.8 6.1 Max. € 1999 per LTO € 2000 per aircraft-km Off-Peak Scarcity costs Accident costs Air Pollution Climate change Additional external costs 0.0 0.079 0.0 0.083 (nature & landscape) Total external costs Explanations by cost category: Noise costs: Source: CE, 2002, costs expressed in € 1999 per LTO Min: 100 seater, state of the art technology Max: 400 seater fleet average 1999 Congestion costs: Source UNITE D7, costs expressed in € 2000 / aircraft-km Min: lower bound of results of selected months 1997-2000 Max: upper bound of results of selected months 1997-2000 Accident costs: No data available. Air pollution: Source: CE, 2002, costs expressed in € 1999 per LTO Min: 100 seater, fleet average 1999 Max: 400 seater fleet average 1999 Climate change: Source: CE, 2002, costs expressed in € 1999 per aircraft-km Min: 100 seater, fleet average 1999, shadow value of 20€/t CO2 Max: 400 seater fleet average 1999, shadow value of 70€/t CO2 Nature&Landscape: Source: INFRAS/IWW, 2004, costs expressed in € 2000 / aircraft km No external costs in urban and built-up areas Min: short run marginal costs Max: long run marginal costs Total costs: no total cost calculation possible due to different cost indicators 30 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 € 1999 per LTO € 1999 per aircraft-km € 2000 per aircraft-km Table 10 Inland waterways: unit values per cost component in €ct/vessel-km Cost component waterways freight Min. Unit Max. Noise costs Scarcity costs 215 625 240 360 Accident costs Air Pollution Climate change € per vessel and cm of water level €ct 1998 per vessel-km €ct 2000 per vessel-km €ct 2000 per vessel-km 40 141 Additional external costs (nature & landscape) 0 92 Total external costs Explanations by cost category: Noise costs: no sources available Scarcity costs: Source: GRACE D4, costs are expressed in € per cm of water level in the river Rhein for a vessel carrying 500 TEU Min: value for high water levels Max: value for low water levels Accident costs: no data available Air pollution: Sources: UNITE D11, €ct per vessel-km Min: marginal costs per vessel-km downstream Max: marginal costs per vessel-km upstream Climate change: Source: INFRAS/IWW, 2004, €ct/vessel-km Min: Shadow value of 20€/t CO2 Max: Shadow value of 70€/t CO2 Nature&Landscape: Source: INFRAS/IWW, 2004, in €ct 2002/vessel-km No external costs in urban and built-up areas Min: short run marginal costs Max: long run marginal costs Total costs: no total cost calculation possible due to different cost indicators a 3 Comparison Road-Rail (in €/pkm and €/tkm) Using the average load factors for road and rail transport, average costs per passenger-km and tonne-kilometer have been calculated. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 31 Table 11 Comparison Road-Rail: using average load factors 4 Noise Urban Interurban Accidents Urban Interurban Air pollution Urban Petrol Urban Diesel Interurban Petrol Interurban Diesel Climate change Urban Interurban Nature & landscape Urban Interurban Total Passenger transport (€/pkm) Passenger Car (€/pkm) Train Pass. (€/pkm) Min. Max. Min. Max. 0.5 2.2 0.21 0.63 0.0 0.0 0.01 0.04 2.8 3.2 0.00 0.10 0.2 4.8 0.00 0.10 0.1 0.2 0.02 0.04 0.2 1.0 0.00 0.00 0.1 0.2 0.12 0.32 0.2 0.4 0.00 0.00 0.4 1.5 0.08 0.31 0.2 0.7 0.08 0.31 0.0 0.0 0.00 0.00 0.0 0.3 0.00 0.18 Peak, urban Peak, interurban Off-Peak, urban Off-Peak, interurban 3.8 0.7 3.8 0.7 7.1 6.8 7.1 6.8 0.31 0.22 0.31 0.22 1.08 0.95 1.08 0.95 Freight transport (€/tkm) HDV (€/tkm Train Freight (€/tkm) Min. Max. Min. Max. 0.5 2.1 0.11 0.34 0.0 0.0 0.01 0.02 0.2 0.7 0.00 0.04 0.0 0.2 0.00 0.04 0.3 1.2 0.05 0.11 0.0 0.0 0.00 0.00 0.1 0.5 0.05 0.11 0.0 0.0 0.00 0.00 0.1 0.5 0.04 0.29 0.1 0.3 0.04 0.29 0.0 0.0 0.00 0.00 0.0 0.1 0.00 0.03 1.1 0.3 1.1 0.3 4.4 1.2 4.4 1.2 0.21 0.10 0.21 0.10 Explanations: Average load factors: Passenger car: 1.5 persons/car Passenger train: 130 passengers/train HDV: 15 tons/vehicle Freight train: 285 tons/train 2.4.3 Putting the values into practice a Value transfer mechanisms The unit values are the basis for calculating the values for the various traffic situations, modes, types of vehicle and countries. To calculate the values for member states, a value transfer is proposed. Value transfer is useful and appropriate to save expenditures for detailed estimation of external costs in specific traffic situations, vehicle types, modes of transport and countries. The following transfer mechanisms are relevant: − Transfer of dose-response functions: A transfer is possible. For some cost components a transfer needs additional information: • Congestion: Local Speed-Flow curves are useful, since traffic situations might differ between countries. • Accidents: The national insurance systems have to be considered and might lead to different levels of externalities. • Nature and landscape: The general settlement situation should be considered. − Transfer of data: If possible local data (traffic, emissions, concentrations, etc.) should be used. Value transfers are only possible if specific clusters (e.g. specific traffic situations and exposure situation) can be defined. − Transfer of unit values (VSL, VOT, etc.): The literature (UNITE, INFRAS/IWW) is proposing a value transfer based on GDP per capita (PPP adjusted). This implies the assumption that the unit values are linked with income with an elasticity of 1. 4 Congestion and scarcity costs are not included here, because of lack of data of scarcity costs on rail. 32 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 0.79 0.49 0.79 0.49 b Base year, update and dynamisation mechanisms It is useful to present figures for a most actual base year. The more disaggregated the figures are presented, the less important is a common base year, since structures can be shown in detail (e.g. Euro classes). Forecasts and changes in the future, e.g. the variation of external cost over time, depend on: − Change in dose response functions. Usually this is only the case for long term risks such as climate change. − Change in traffic patterns (volumes, structure, loading factors). This can influence averaged figures, depending on disaggregation of results. − Change in technical performance (emission category, etc.). This can also influence averaged figures, depending on disaggregation of results. − Change in income: According to the assumptions above, an increase of GDP per capita is also changing unit values. Similar to the value transfer approaches, an income elasticity of 1 can be assumed. Recent research (INFRAS/IWW, 2004) shows that a lower elasticity (e.g. 0.5) can be used as well. It has to be considered that the very sensitive unit values (such as VSL) are also depending on other factors like the change of risk aversion for individuals. c Link to internalisation scenarios How to use the values presented into practice, e.g. into concrete pricing scenarios? In order to build a bridge between external cost values and transport pricing strategies, the following leverage points are most important and will be further analysed in chapter 3. − The internalisation of congestion costs requests a road pricing scheme which differentiates at least between urban areas and interurban bottlenecks on motorways. Since the implementation of such schemes is very much depending on local network characteristics, available alternatives and political acceptability, the values presented can only provide a rough magnitude for concrete congestion based road charges (usually not per vkm, but per passage). − The pricing strategy for the internalisation of accident costs is only a small part of the policy instrument to internalise accident costs. Thus the figures presented will serve mainly as a basis for the differentiation according to type of infrastructure and for cost benefit analysis of appropriate safety measures. − The internalisation of environmental costs can be linked to km or fuel charging, differentiated according to environmental criteria. The values presented can directly provide a basis. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 33 2.5 Main questions for the workshop The following questions are of major importance for the discussion in the workshop: a How accurate is accurate enough? − Value transfer: Is it possible to use proposed values from scientific studies or is an own detailed study necessary? − Level of detail: Which disaggregation level of values is useful? b Which values are useful? − Which values do reflect external cost properly? − Which level of differentiation is useful? c Main approaches − Is there consensus that a pragmatic marginal cost oriented approach with averaged figures for typical traffic situations forms the basis for the estimation of concrete values? − Is there consensus that a bottom up approach is most appropriate for the estimation of congestion and environmental costs and a top down approach is useful for the valuation of accident costs? − What is the opinion on best practice approaches per cost category? d Dealing with critical aspects and risks − What has to be considered for the definition of critical unit costs such as VSL and shadow rates for CO2? − How should values be presented: Recommended values, bandwidths, sensitivity analysis? 34 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 3 Scenarios for internalisation 3.1 Introduction Transport gives rise to various types of external effects which pose costs to society. External effects are by definition not taken into account explicitly in decision making. There is no economic market for these effects, and therefore the market-clearing process does not lead to the most optimal outcome, from a societal point of view. The external effects of pollution, noise and climate change may be labelled intersectoral externalities when transport users inflict these to a large extent on others outside of the transport sector. In contrast, the externalities of congestion and accidents are intrasectoral externalities, imposed by transport users upon one-another 5. Pigou formulated an optimal solution to the problem of external effects, in the context of congestion: introduce a regulatory charge equal to the marginal external costs. Transport users will thus take account of the external effects on one-another and on others, and may or may not adapt their decision, depending on whether their marginal benefit is lower or higher than the marginal external costs to others. This is the basic idea behind internalisation of external costs. The step from theory to practice is not a simple one, however. External congestion cost levels may vary from minute to minute 6, transport users may not be able to take fully rationale account of such varying taxes and charges and even then, technological solutions to charge such rapidly varying taxes and charges are not straightforward either. In this chapter we discuss the ways external costs can be internalised. First, we provide an overview of the main aims of internalisation (section 3.2). This includes a discussion of the formulated aims by the European Union in Directive 2006/38. Next, we give an a theoretical framework of the methods for internalisation external costs of transport (section 3.3). In section 3.4 we discuss the legal background. The main cross cutting issues for designing the scenarios are discussed in section 3.5. Section 3.6 gives an overview of the scenarios themselves. The next steps in the project are briefly described in section 3.7. Finally section 3.8 lists the main questions for discussion at the workshop. 5 6 We will refer to this distinction in the next section. There are examples in the US, where certain lanes are tolled and others not, with charges levels being adapted according to traffic levels every six minutes. Clearly, drivers can only take account of such varying charges when they have the option of using the tolled lane or the non-tolled lane (US FHA, 2006). 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 35 3.2 Aims of internalisation and pricing policies The design of internalisation measures starts with a clear picture of the aims they might serve. We first discuss the various aims and motives that can be distinguished and then focus on the aims of internalisation as described in Directive 2006/38. 3.2.1 Potential aims of internalisation The motives for internalisation and/or the introduction of pricing policies can be various. Related to these motives may be specific policy aims. As background to the discussions, we distinguish in this section different motifs and aims of pricing policies for the transport sector (based on Verhoef et al. (2004)). Three motives for pricing policies that can be distinguished are (each with various possible policy aims): − Influencing behaviour, to: • Reduce environmental impacts. • Allow a freer flow of traffic. − Generating revenues, to: • Finance new, extension or modernisation of infrastructure (which may in turn be related to the aim of improving freer flow of traffic). • Cover (fixed) costs of infrastructure management, operation and maintenance. • Finance the general budget. − Increasing fairness, to: • Make the polluter / user pay. • Have identical taxes and charges for everyone. • Level out the income distribution. • Prevent changes in income distribution. • To level the playing field between modes. Clearly, when implementing pricing policies, a multitude of effects will occur, contributing to more than one potential aim. 3.2.2 Motives and aims in directive 2006/38/EC Although in theory, the various motifs and aims can be distinguished neatly, in practice things are more complicated. As mentioned above, implementation of pricing policies will generally contribute to more than one potential aim. The motifs and aims underlying directive 2006/38/EC also appear to be multiple. Reading directive 2006/38/EC carefully, the motif of the Commission for the amendment appears to be related with encouragement of sustainable transport, that is to influence behaviour. A fairer charging scheme is a means for that motif and not a motif in itself. 36 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 The aims of internalisation appear to be more diverse. A reduction of environmental impacts, a freer flow of traffic (or even wider: a more efficient transport system), making the user and polluter pay and level the playing field between modes are all aims that have been mentioned at one time or another. At the same time, the directive also involves the recovery of infrastructure investments and the generation of funds to provide new infrastructure. 3.2.3 This project According to welfare theory, the primary motif for internalisation is a more efficient economy. This is particularly related to influencing behaviour by providing optimal incentives. In this project this is taken as the primary aim of internalisation. The other motives may be politically relevant and will be taken into account, but less central. 3.3 Theoretical framework Internalisation of external costs can be done by a wide variety of methods and instruments. In general, internalisation relates to market-based instruments, and pricing instruments in specific. Consumers receive a direct financial incentive to adapt behaviour and at the same time keep the freedom for making their own choices. There are however many different ways of implementing pricing policies, for example with regard to price structures and price levels. More generally, potential government instruments (not all internalisation methods) can be classified as follows. − Market-based instruments (pricing, emission trading). − Regulation. − Infrastructure provision. − Environmental planning. − Communication & information. These instruments differ to the extent that they allow consumers to make their own decisions and to the extent that the results can be predicted beforehand. They also differ to the extent that they may be related to particular government motives and aims. For example, communication & information may influence consumer behaviour, but cannot be related to generating revenues. The focus in the scenarios will be on market-based instruments, but other instruments will be included where appropriate, in particular regulation. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 37 3.3.1 Optimal internalisation methods depend on the context The optimal internalisation strategy depends on the underlying aims and motifs. If internalisation takes place out of equity considerations, intersectoral externalities are especially relevant, because these make up the ‘unpaid bill’ that transport imposes upon society. Charging for external congestion costs may be of less interest then. In contrast, if the improvement of economic efficiency is the goal, both intra- and intersectoral externalities should be internalised 7. If the aim of internalisation is solely generating revenues then the main considerations are minimizing transaction costs and gaining public support. The most efficient way of revenue raising is to increase existing taxes or charges, but this often faces strong public resistance. Combining aims of generating revenues with increasing fairness may help to increase public support. As stated before (section 3.2.1) the central aim of the internalisation scenarios to be developed in the current study is influencing behaviour to improve economic efficiency and reduce external effects. This implies that designing the scenarios, we need to have a close look at the impacts on welfare. These impacts are discussed in the next sections. 3.3.2 Marginal social cost pricing In theory, assuming a first-best world, Pigouvian taxes would be optimal for optimizing economic efficiency (welfare). This is often related with the principle of marginal social cost pricing. Under the REVENUE research program, ‘pure marginal social cost pricing’ has been defined as a situation where prices in transport are set equal to the short-run price relevant cost, consisting of: − The marginal producer costs (e.g. reconstruction, wear & tear, maintenance costs). − The price-relevant user cost (congestion, scarcity costs). plus − The marginal external costs (environmental costs, external accident costs). Marginal social cost pricing would, under some conditions, lead to allocative efficiency in a static perspective. 3.3.3 Deviations from marginal social cost pricing In the dynamic real world, deviations from marginal social cost pricing may be more appropriate or practical. In marginal social cost pricing, no consideration is given to the financial implications of the pricing scheme in terms of surpluses of deficits for each mode. This implies that there is no guarantee that the total revenues from marginal social cost pricing are sufficient to cover all infrastructure costs. Rothengatter (2003) remarks that marginal social cost pricing is typically orientated to optimize the use of an existing facility of which the fixed costs are bygones. Infrastructure 7 38 See Lakshmanan et al. (2001). 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 providers may not be able to recover the investments in new infrastructure and thus have no incentive for such investments. More generally speaking, the theoretical ‘first best’ solution in the form of regulatory Pigouvian charges based on marginal external cost levels may not be appropriate or feasible altogether in practice. Pigouvian charge levels may not be appropriate, because they are only optimal under certain theoretical assumptions that are not satisfied in practice. For example, it is based on the assumption that marginal social cost pricing is applied throughout the whole network considered, the whole transport sector and even throughout the economy. In addition, it is based on the assumption that governments use lump sum taxes to pursue any redistribution targets they may wish to meet. See also MC-ICAM (2001) and Lindsey and Verhoef (2001). Furthermore, marginal social cost pricing may not be practical because a tax or charge varying by all cost drivers, including time, place and all relevant vehicle characteristics may be impossible, or at least, very expensive to implement. The derivation of the optimality of marginal social cost pricing abstracted from implementation and transaction costs. Thus, when first-best conditions are not achievable or not known, or when a multitude of motifs and aims are at stake, and prices are set optimally conditional to constraints of imperfections, deviations from marginal social cost pricing may be needed. Summarizing, there may be three reasons for deviating from marginal social cost pricing: 1 Limited scope of a pricing scheme - First-best pricing is not applied throughout the whole network considered, the whole transport sector and / or throughout the economy. 2 High system requirements & costs - Pure marginal social cost pricing requires a technological system which may be too complex or expensive to implement. 3 Insufficient revenues - Revenues from pure marginal social cost pricing may be insufficient to cover total infrastructure costs. Below we sketch the main impacts of these deviations on the design and price setting. Limited scope of a pricing scheme Internalisation measures have a limited scope, unless they cover the whole economy. Regulation, like the National Emission Ceilings (NEC), or emission trading systems, like the ETS, are measures which approach a coverage of the whole economy, at least within the EU. Pricing measures generally cover a much smaller part, such as a single mode of transport or even only a part of a network. This may give rise to boundary-effects, in particular a shift from the priced modes or parts of the network to the other parts or modes. From a welfare point of view this could lead to much less positive welfare effects. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 39 The shift away from priced modes or parts of infrastructure will only be significant in cases where there is true competition. An example is the German kilometer charge for heavy duty vehicles on motorways only. After the introduction there was an increased use by heavy duty vehicles of regional roads. However, after a few months after the introduction this temporarily shift did not hold. Apparently, in this case the underlying network is not a valid alternative for the motorways. To avoid undesired side-effects because of the limited scope of a system in order to limit the negative impacts in the welfare gains, the scope needs to be chosen in such a way that there is only limited competition between the priced and the non-priced parts. For this reason this project focuses on scenarios with internalisation measures in all transport modes. High system requirements & costs Pure marginal social cost pricing requires a system that can differentiate price levels according to all cost drivers for the various external costs, e.g. the actual congestion level, the actual vehicle emissions factors for pollutants and noise, the actual fuel consumption and maybe even the actual blood alcohol level of the driver. Such a system would be too complicated from a technological point of view and the price incentives would be far too complicated for users to respond to. Therefore, any feasible pricing system will use a limited number of easy measurable parameters as a proxy for the actual cost drivers. Examples of such proxies are the Euro standard as a proxy for the actual emission factor or the distinction between peak and off-peak hours as a proxy for the actual congestion level. As long as the proxies are well-chosen and close-enough related to the cost drivers, these types of deviations from a pure marginal social cost pricing will not give rise to large negative impacts on the potential welfare gains. The same holds for implementation and transaction costs. As long as these costs are relatively small compared to the price incentives, their impacts on welfare will be limited. We conclude that welfare gains require internalisation measures that are: − Built on good proxies for cost drivers. − Not too complex so as to limit implementation and transaction cost. Insufficient revenues If the principle of pure marginal social cost pricing is applied to both infrastructure costs and external costs, the revenues of such a scheme may not be sufficient to cover the total infrastructure costs. Whether or not marginal cost based pricing suffices, may be mode dependent. In that case, one might want to use the revenues of external cost pricing of one mode to cover the fixed infrastructure costs of other modes. This could be done by introducing inter-modal funds. The issue of use of revenues and how to take account of existing taxes and charges will be discussed later in section 3.3.6. 40 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 3.3.4 Differentiation of existing taxes or charges If the aim of internalisation is influencing behaviour in order to reduce external costs, there is an alternative for the introduction of mark-ups or new taxes or charges based on external cost levels. This alternative is differentiation of existing taxes or charges, giving incentives on a revenue neutral basis. In the air transport sector such differentiation have been introduced at several airports. Existing infrastructure charges are differentiated with respect to the noise emissions of aircraft. The idea is that aircraft operators are thus incentivised to operate less noisy aircraft. This can either reduce the noise exposure of the population or free up capacity for other aircraft. Because the overall charge levels are not increased, the demand for transport may not go down. Such a revenue-neutral differentiation cannot generally be seen as internalizing external costs. Although, given the correct level of differentiation, the externalities will be taken into account, other costs will no longer be fully taken into account. Consider the example of tolls that account for the variable costs of road infrastructure. If these tolls are differentiated by increasing them at peak times and reducing them during off peak hours, during off peak hours users no longer pay the variable infrastructure costs. Other previously internal costs may become external under revenue-neutral differentiations 8. In the specific situation where the existing tax or charge was introduced to cover fixed costs, differentiation may be an improvement from the perspective of economic efficiency. The total costs will still be financed, and users of infrastructure receive incentives to adapt their behavior to account for e.g. congestion or emissions of pollutants. A practical advantage of differentiating existing taxes or charges which were introduced to cover fixed infrastructure costs is that there will be no need to discuss the use of revenues (see section 3.3.6). There are however some practical aspects that need to be taken account of. First of all, because differentiation incentives changes in behavior, periodic adjustment may be required to ensure the financing requirements. This is similar to any charge and should not be a problem. Second, there is the question to what extent public bodies can make private concessionaries differentiate their tariffs. Some current concessions allow for differentiations but do not require them. In particular when different concessionaries compete with each other, such as some port and airports may do, there may be resistance to differentiating existing taxes or charges. 8 Nonetheless, allowing for such differentiations is likely to increase welfare (abstracting from implementation / transaction costs), because it relaxes one restriction on the charge levels. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 41 3.3.5 Policy packaging It may be more effective to combine different policies in a policy package than to introduce pricing instruments in isolation. As formulated in MC-ICAM (deliverable 2, p48-49): ‘It was found in the AFFORD project that packages designed to match policy instruments to externalities sometimes performed much better than analysis of the effects of the isolated instruments suggested, and even approach first-best efficiency gains 9. (…) Optimal policy packages are likely to combine or supplement marginal cost based usage charges such as vehicle taxes, standards, or other regulations. For example, if a CO2 fuel charge provides insufficient incentive to develop and buy fuel-efficient vehicles, then a differentiated vehicle tax related to CO2 emissions might be adopted too 10. While countries currently rely heavily on fuel taxes, several factors limit how much they should, and indeed can, be used either to raise revenue or as Pigouvian tax instruments. For this reason, fuel taxes need to be used in combination with other instruments, including (of course) road pricing as well as differentiated vehicle taxes.’ In the final report it was formulated as follows (MC-ICAM, final report, p20). ‘Second best policies 11 almost by definition require policy packaging. The failure to achieve the ideal result with one policy instrument forces us to look at ways of improving the situation by the use of other policy instruments’. This includes the use of other pricing and non-pricing measures. The choice between transport instruments, or packages of instruments, depends not only on their relative efficiency but also on their equity impacts, since in general the overall objective of society concerns not only a maximization of total efficiency, but also to achieve an equitable distribution of welfare. Moreover, any major transport policy reform will be acceptable only if it is welfare increasing or welfare neutral for a sufficiently large majority of the voters. A necessary condition for voters to accept the reform is that their utility is not reduced SPECTRUM (2003). Verhoef (2002, p13) also notes that ‘the possible weaknesses that can arise from second-best taxes when applied in isolation can often be reduced when constructing a policy package of second-best measures, that is designed to cover the most important externalities and dimensions of behaviour relevant for the particular case considered. What is of importance here, of course, would be that the various charge levels employed for the individual instruments in the package be carefully chosen, simultaneously, so as to maximize the package’s eventual efficiency.’ 9 10 11 42 These are the gains of marginal social cost pricing assuming that all conditions are met. Indeed there is evidence that fuel charges do not provide sufficient incentives. In general, when purchasing a car, consumers only take account of the first three years of potential fuel savings of a fuel efficient vehicle (NRC, 2002; Annema, J.A. et al., 2001). Hence, there is reason not to internalise only by marginal cost pricing, but to design more complete policy packages. Second best means here optimal pricing from a welfare point of view, under real world conditions. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Some non-pricing measures have proven to be very effective in the past. However, also when applying these non-pricing measures it makes sense to internalise the remaining external costs. 3.3.6 Use of revenues and earmarking The introduction of mark-ups or new taxes or charges to internalise external costs, leads to revenues. The use of the revenues is an integral part of the internalisation policy. Mayeres and Proost (2001) have shown for example, that it is possible to increase society’s welfare by using the revenues of a congestion charge for financing new road infrastructure or reducing income taxes, but that by applying the revenues for public transport subsidies, welfare may go down 12. If the aim of internalisation would mainly relate to infrastructure costs and the ‘user pays principle’, the revenue from congestion charges could be used to finance new infrastructure. In CE Delft (2002) a road pricing system is developed in which investments in new road infrastructure aimed at relieving congestion are governed by the willingness to pay of users. The investment rule developed prescribes that the time to expand road capacity at a particular location is when the revenues from an optimised congestion charge levied on the new, additional capacity are precisely sufficient to fund the capital costs of that capacity. More generally, the REVENUE project has extensively researched the issue of how to use the revenues from transport pricing. REVENUE (p 38) concludes that ‘the arguments in favor or against earmarking are more or less balanced’. This conclusion was reached after studying the relation of earmarking with efficiency, equity and acceptability objectives (Revenue, Deliverable 6, 2006, p37-38). Below the considerations are repeated. Efficiency As there is no guarantee that transport projects will be the most efficient proposals, standard theory informs us that hypothecation of funds to transport budgets may result in a loss of efficiency, in that it may require that a set of projects be undertaken which does not maximize social welfare. However, this simple theory takes no account of institutional arrangements and social acceptance. Governments at the lower levels may take no account of the effects of their decisions on the rest of the system outside their area. For instance, governments may select projects that favor local rather than transit traffic. To the extent that detailed investment decisions are sensibly left to national or regional government earmarking funds to be invested in the Trans European Network may offset this inefficiency. Equity Equity considerations giving individuals with lower incomes higher weights when balancing utilities will lead to deviations from marginal social cost pricing which 12 The impact of the use of revenues on economic welfare is case specific, so this example may not be generalised. The availability of public transport generally offers mobility alternatives and helps giving a greater elasticity to the demand curve, thus making pricing policies more effective. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 43 reduce efficiency but improve equity. There is no reason to suppose in general that earmarking will improve equity in this sense, although there may be specific cases where it would. Equity arguments for earmarking more often take the form of saying that those who pay should get corresponding benefits for their money. This would only be fair in general if the existing distribution of income were fair. Even so, it would not be the most efficient way of using the revenue, which would be to undertake the most beneficial set of projects across all sectors subject to the requirement that the existing distribution of income was not changed. Acceptability The prospect of a pricing reform being implemented will be enhanced if it enjoys public acceptability. It may be thought that this is most likely if a majority of the population benefits from it. If surplus revenue is used to minimize the number of individuals that will experience a reduction in utility from the transport pricing reform, the acceptability of that reform will increase. Earmarking of surplus revenues to the transport budget is one method for ameliorating the harmful impacts of pricing reform that raises prices for certain users. As remarked above, in the end arguments for or against earmarking were judged to be more or less balanced. In section 0 we discuss the use of earmarking we choose in the internalization scenarios in this project. 3.4 Legal background In this section, a brief overview is provided of the legal background for internalisation in the various modes. It focuses on prevailing EU directives, but attention is also given to current proposals from the European Commission, and to other current international arrangements that may either enable or restrict internalisation of external effects. Specific national laws are not addressed. The purpose of this overview is to provide a general background on the legal possibilities for internalisation. This current state of affairs serves as a point of departure for the internalisation scenarios to be developed in this project. However, it is not the intention that all internalisation scenarios put forward adhere to current legislation. Some adaptations may be proposed. Directive 2003/96/EC requires minimum tax levels for energy products, including motor fuels. However, there are a few important exemptions. Regarding aviation, jet fuel is to be exempted from the minimum tax levels as set in the Directive. Energy products for private pleasure-flying may be taxed. Similarly, fuel for navigation in Community waters is to be exempted. Member States may limit these exemptions to international and intra-Community transport. In addition, in case of bilateral agreements, exemptions may also be waved. In such cases, a level of taxation below the minimum level set out in the Directive may be applied. Energy products and electricity used for the carriage of goods and passengers by rail, metro, tram and trolley bus may also be exempted. Also, energy products used as fuel for inland navigation may be exempted. 44 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 The rail directive 2001/14/EC allows for rail infrastructure charges to be differentiated with respect to environmental characteristics. Mark ups that lead to additional revenues are however not allowed in the absence of comparable charges for competing modes. If this is the case, it is up to Member States to decide on how to use the revenues. Directive 2006/38/EC allows for tolls and user charges for road vehicles over 3.5 tonnes to recover infrastructure costs. These costs may include expenditures related to the infrastructure designed to reduce noise nuisance, accidents or to relate to particular environmental elements. Mark ups up to 25% (15%) above infrastructure costs are allowed for regions with acute congestion or environmental problems, under the condition that these are invested in crossborder (domestic) priority TEN projects. Member States are free to determine the use to be made of the revenue of the general charge, though are recommended to be used benefiting the transport sector. Differentiations of charge levels are allowed (in fact required as of 2010 on the basis of Euro class) but the variation in charge levels is restricted. The Directive explicitly does not restrict Member States to introduce regulatory charges to combat time and place related traffic congestion or to combat environmental impacts, including poor air quality. In addition, there are Directives that provide standards for emissions of pollutants are applicable to road vehicles, vessels, aircraft and locomotives. Next to these Directives, there are several proposals for Directives that are of relevance. First of all, there is a proposal relating to passenger car related taxes (COM(2005) 261). According to the proposal, by 2008 at least 25% of the total revenue from annual circulation taxes and registration taxes shall come from a carbon-dioxide based element in the tax structure. This share should be 50% for 2012. By 2016, it is proposed, all registration taxes should be abolished. Second, there is a proposal for the inclusion of aviation in the EU emissions trading scheme. Starting from 2011 airlines would have to purchase allowances for all emissions of aircraft above the historic emission levels of 2004-2006. The Commission is about to propose special tax arrangements for commercial gas oil, aiming at narrowing excessive differences in tax levels between Member States, in order to reduce distortions of competition and environmental damage in the transport haulage by reducing ‘fuel tourism’. In addition, the taxation of fuel used for aviation in generally prohibited through bilateral air service agreements. 3.5 From theory to practice - cross cutting issues in designing scenarios The previous sections have provided an overview of the theoretical and legal background of internalisation scenarios. Before proposing particular scenarios, we discuss several cross-cutting issues: − Most important cost categories per mode (section 3.5.1). 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 45 − − − − − Options for incentive base and non-pricing measures (section 3.5.2). How to deal with existing taxes and charges (section 3.5.3). Use of revenues (section 3.5.4). Approaches for different external costs (section 3.5.5 to 3.5.9). some mode-particular issues (section 3.5.10). The considerations provided in these discussions, enable us to be more brief in the discussion about the proposal for the scenarios to be studied. 3.5.1 Most important cost categories per mode Based on 2.4.2, the table below gives a rough indication of the most important cost categories per mode of transport. This may serve as the basis for selecting the external effects that are most important to address in the different scenarios. Table 12 A rough indication of the most important categories per mode of transport Congestion Scarcity Accidents Climate Air pollution Noise Additional ext. costs (nature & landscape) RoadHDV X Roadcars X X X X X X X X X X X RoadLDV X X X X X X Rail Shipping Aviation X ? X X X X ? X X X X X ? ? Note that especially the costs of congestion, air pollution and noise and their size differ to a large extent to the specific location and time of the day and/or vehicle characteristics. For local / urban transport, those cost categories are much more important. 3.5.2 Options for incentive base Pricing measures that aim at influencing behaviour give incentives to users change behaviour leading to reduction of external costs. To be effective and efficient, these incentives need to be based on good proxies for the true cost drivers (see section 3.3.3). Table 13 gives an overview of options for the incentive bases for the various cost categories. In addition, in the third column an indication is given of the correlation between the proxy provided by the incentive base with the marginal cost level. The fourth column lists the most relevant nonpricing options. As indicated in the table, fuel use and kilometres driven alone have a low correlation to most external costs. The main reason behind this is that the external costs induced by a kilometre driven or a litre of fuel used depend very much on other parameters that have a large impact on the marginal external cost level, in particular the vehicle characteristics (e.g. Euro-standard), location and 46 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 time of the day. As an example, the difference in external air pollution cost of a Euro-5 car on rural road and Euro-0 diesel car in a dense urban area is enormous; the same is true for the difference between the noise cost of a noisy train or aircraft at night in an urban area and a relatively silent one in an area with a low population density. For any specific pricing instrument, the incentive base needs to be kept as simple as possible to avoid unnecessary complexity of the pricing scheme. Systems that are too complex may stay closer to marginal social cost pricing, but generally also face the problem of high implementation and transaction costs. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 47 Table 13 Options for incentive base and their correlation with marginal cost levels Cost component Options for the incentive base of pricing measures Accident costs a b c d e Noise costs Air pollution f a b c d e f g a b c d Climate change e f a b c d e Additional environmental cost (water, soil) Additional costs in urban areas Congestion costs (separate cost category) a b c d a b c a b c d Scarcity 13 48 a b c d Fuel use Kilometers driven (road/rail) 13 Number of LTO’s (aviation) or port visits (shipping) a/b + time of the day d + location (accident risk) + vehicle type e + driver/carrier characteristics Fuel use Kilometers driven Number of LTO’s (aviation) b/c+ time of the day (day or night) b/c + location (number of people exposed, population density, urban/non-urban) b/c + vehicle noise emission class combination of c,d and e Fuel use Kilometers driven/sailed Number of LTO’s (aviation) or port visits (shipping) b/c + location (number of people exposed, population density, urban/non-urban) b/c+ Euro-standard & fuel type combination of d and e Fuel use + CO2 content of the fuel Kilometers driven (road) Kilometers flown/sailed Vehicle: average vehicle fuel efficiency (class) c+d Kilometers driven Number of LTO’s (aviation) or port visits (shipping) Quality Management Certification Location Kilometers driven Time of the day Location Fuel use Kilometers driven b + Time of the day and location (peak/off-peak, based on average congestion level in peak hours) Times or days of entering a certain congestion zone Kilometers driven Number of port visits (shipping) Number of paths/slots (rail/aviation) b/c + Location + Time of the day Correlation with marginal cost level (current situation) Low Low Low Low Medium High Low Low Low Medium Medium Most relevant other instruments − − − − − − − − Low/Medium High Low Low Low/Medium − Medium − Medium High High Medium Medium Low Medium Low Low Low Low ? Low Low High − − − − − Liability regulation Insurances Regulation for vehicles, drivers, etc. Speed limits Noise emission standards for vehicles Non building zones Regulation of operations (aviation) Limits to noise levels or annoyed people Speed limits Emission standards Environmental zoning Limited access for certain vehicles Speed limits − Emission trading CO2 emission standards for (new) vehicles Fuel regulation (e.g. biofuels) Speed limits − Regulation − Various types of urban transport policy (esp. infrastructure policy for non-motorized transport) New or extension of existing infrastructure − − Medium Low Medium Medium High − Auctioning of slots/paths LTO = Landing and Take-Off. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 For most cost categories a good proxy for the cost driver is a combination of distance with one or more other parameters (some vehicle characteristics, location or time of the day). The main vehicle characteristics that can be used are the Euro standard and for some modes (i.e. rail and aviation) the noise emission class. To differentiate to location, a feasible way is to use a few categories, e.g. for road, the type of infrastructure (urban, rural motorways), in combination with the distinction between ‘normal’ and ‘sensitive’ areas. Differentiation to time of the day can be done by defining time windows, e.g. day/night, peak/off-peak. For congestion more than two rates (like high peak, peak, busy hours, off-peak) or even rates that change continuously with the time of the day, stay closer to the actual cost driver and therefore are preferable from a theoretical point of view. However, for practical reasons, all congestion schemes introduced so far in Europe use only very few rates. For congestion, an alternative for a combination of distance and time of the day as a proxy, is the number of days or times a congestion zone is entered (like used in the London Congestion Charge). For aviation and waterborne modes, for some cost categories the number of visits to a port or airport may be more relevant than the distance because of the relative large share of costs that are related to these parts of the trips. For the costs of climate change, the actual fuel use (in combination with the carbon content of fuel) is the optimal incentive base, because it is an excellent proxy for the greenhouse gas emissions. Pricing fuel with a CO2 based fuel tax gives incentives to reduce greenhouse gas emissions in all possible ways. Distance related charges are also a good proxy, but they do not give incentives for buying fuel efficient vehicles or applying a fuel efficient driving style and make it harder to distinguish between the various types of fuel in particular biofuels. For other cost than climate, fuel consumption is poorly correlated with the actual marginal cost. 3.5.3 How to deal with existing taxes and charges? In the current situation, transport users pay various taxes and charges. This raises the question to what extent external costs may be regarded as being internalised by the already existing taxes and charges. In this section we discuss how internalisation policies should take account of existing taxes and charges. We first briefly discuss what type of charges and taxes are currently levied on the transport sector. Next, how account should be taken of these charges is discussed from a theoretical point of view. Finally, the implications for this study are addressed. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 49 Existing taxes and charges in the transport sector The main types of existing taxes and charges are listed in Table 14. Table 14 Overview of existing taxes and charges and main option for entirely new ones Mode Road-HDV Road-cars Rail Water Aviation Existing taxes and charges Infrastructure charges: − User charges (fixed) − Tolls on motorways − Tolls on all roads Fuel excise duty Circulation tax Congestion charge VAT Fuel excise duty Circulation tax Vehicle purchase tax Toll Parking fees Congestion charge VAT Infrastructure charges Diesel excise duty Electricity tax VAT Harbour dues Dues for locks and bridges Fuel excise duties (in a few specific cases) LTO charge En-route charge Noise surcharges Emission charges Fuel excise duties (in a few specific cases) For the purpose of this study we categorize the existing taxes and charges that are imposed on the transport sector in five classes. Taxes and charges may: 1 Be levied to regulate / limit environmental effects. 2 Be levied to finance mitigation measures. 3 Be levied to cover marginal production costs. 4 Be levied for the general budget or to finance infrastructure measures and be differentiated on a revenue neutral basis to provide incentives for cleaner, safer or more efficient transport. 5 Be levied for the general budget or to finance infrastructure measures without any relation to the environmental performance of transport. Congestion charges are a clear example of the first type of charges. An example of the second type are noise surcharges levied at airports to finance insulation of houses. Tolls on concession roads generally cover the costs of providing infrastructure, and are an example of the third kind. Differentiated excise duties with respect to low sulphur fuels provide an example of the fourth type. VAT on fuels can be taken as an example of the fifth type. 50 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Obviously, internalisation should, in some form, take account of existing taxes and charges levied to regulate external effects (first type mentioned above). It appears plausible that also existing charges and taxes of the second and fourth type should be accounted for. What to do with taxes that are fully unrelated to the environmental performance of transport, is not directly clear. When can an existing tax or charge be regarded as internalising external cost? Whether account should be taken of existing charges and taxes when internalising external effects depends on the aims and motives for internalisation. Aim: A more efficient economy If the aim of internalisation is a more efficient economy, internalisation in transport translates to ensuring that the marginal costs of a trip are charged. This will lead to the optimal level of transport, where only trips for which the marginal benefits exceed the marginal costs are taken. The marginal costs of a trip relate both to the marginal external effects, but also to the marginal producer costs. In this context the most relevant marginal producer cost are the marginal infrastructure cost. To the extent that existing marginal taxes and charges, such as excise duties, exceed the marginal producer costs, they should be taken into account when setting the marginal charge level for internalisation. This approach is theoretically first best, but may be hard to implement because it requires full knowledge of the marginal infrastructure cost. Moreover, the cost drivers for marginal infrastructure cost differ from those for the various types of external cost. It should be noted that setting taxes and charges at marginal social cost level is not about average charge or tax levels, but about the marginal tax and charge level in each specific traffic situation. Consequently, charge structures, are of particular interest in order to give the right incentives to change behaviour. Current taxes and charges that are levied for other purposes than internalisation of external effects are generally not aligned with the main cost drivers behind the external costs, and will not provide incentives for cleaner or safer transport. Fuel excise duties for example do not correlate well with marginal external costs (except for climate, see section 3.5.2). Therefore they cannot be regarded as internalising these cost. As we can see from the overview of section 3.5.2 also most other existing taxes and charges are not well aligned with the cost drivers of the various types of external cost. Existing marginal taxes and charges, fuel excise duties in particular, are not well correlated with the marginal infrastructure cost either. Therefore to come to marginal social cost pricing, taxes and charges need to be reformed in order to reflect better the cost drivers of both marginal infrastructure and marginal external cost. However, designing infrastructure taxes and charges that are better aligned with the marginal infrastructure cost is clearly beyond the scope of this study. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 51 Therefore, in this study we will assume that marginal infrastructure cost are related to fuel excise duties. To the extent that fuel excise duties exceed the marginal infrastructure costs, they could be lowered if additional taxes and charges are introduced for internalising external cost. In cases where also tolls are present, fuel excise duties could be reduced further when internalisation measures are taken. Aim: Fairness If fairness is the motive, polluters should pay for the costs they impose on the economy. If the aim of internalisation is fairness or the making the polluter pays, internalisation does not necessarily relate to introducing marginal charges at the marginal cost level. Instead, one may argue that the total external costs should be paid for by the polluters. How to deal with existing taxes and charges in this study? For this study and in the context of Directive 2006/38, we assume as primary motive for internalisation the aim of a more efficient economy (see section 3.2). Marginal cost pricing has been at the heart of the European policy debate since many years. Therefore, marginal taxes and charges that are not related to the marginal infrastructure costs 14 will be taken account of to the extent possible in setting optimal charge levels to internalise external effects. The foremost example of a variable existing tax or charge that should be accounted for is fuel excise duty. Fuel excise duty is an important fiscal instrument with high revenues which are usually not earmarked. In many countries fuel excise duties are to some extent implicitly related to producer costs, i.e. to cover (part of the) infrastructure costs. In this study we deal with fuel excise duties in the following way. If the revenues of fuel excise duties of a mode exceed the variable infrastructure costs of that mode we will assume that the external climate costs are (partly) internalised by the fuel excise duties. To make this more transparent, we label this part of fuel excise duties in the scenarios as CO2 taxes. The revenues from both the remaining fuel excise duties and the CO2 taxes are fiscal revenues for the state budget. The minimum levels for fuel excise duties according to Directive 2003/96/EC are 30.2 cents per liter of diesel and 35.9 per liter of petrol. For comparison, a CO2 shadow price of 70 Euro/tonne corresponds to 16 and 18 cents per liter, respectively. Table 15 gives an overview of various external cost estimates for CO2 expressed and how this relates to a rate per liter fuel. 14 52 The marginal infrastructure costs are the additional infrastructure cost induced by an extra vehicle kilometre. Hence they relate to variable operation and maintenance costs. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Table 15 Various shadow prices of CO2 expressed in Euro per liter fuel CO2 shadow price Euro/tonne 10 20 50 70 150 280 Petrol Euro-ct/l Diesel Euro-ct/l 2.28 4.56 11.40 15.96 34.20 63.84 2.63 5.26 13.15 18.40 39.44 73.62 Another example relates to infrastructure charges for rail. In general, these are based on marginal cost pricing and we may assume that charges are in line with marginal infrastructure costs. However, in some countries mark ups are applied to raise sufficient revenue for financing the infrastructure. These mark ups will be accounted for in setting marginal charge levels to internalize external effects of rail transport. How to deal with fixed taxes and charges is less straightforward. Welfare economics and theory on marginal cost pricing does not provide guidance. However, we may return to secondary motives for internalisation such as fairness. One may argue that based on this motive, account should be taken of fixed environmental taxes and charges. For this project we propose the following. Fixed taxes and charges of the third and fifth type, such as undifferentiated vignets or circulation taxes, will not be taken into account when designing internalisation scenarios. This means that these charges that are unrelated to external effects will not changed when internalising new taxes or charges to internalise external costs. Fixed taxes and charges of the other three types will be considered on a case by case basis. Note that setting a general rule for this subject in practice will be difficult. The EU decision making process requires unanimity between Member States with regard to fiscal reforms while it requires the qualified majority when it comes to transport charges. A complicating factor for the modeling exercise is that current charging and taxing structures vary widely between Member States. 3.5.4 Revenue use Some of the internalisation measures proposed in the scenarios will lead to revenues. These revenues can be used in many ways, as was discussed in section 3.3.6. In this section we explain the choices we make in this project. In order to model the impacts of the various scenarios, we need to make assumptions on how the revenues are spent. Whether this is done by earmarking or not, is more a political issue, related to aacceptability, than that it is relevant for modelling the scenarios. The assumptions made are described within the various scenarios. Some more general considerations are discussed below. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 53 First of all, as was described in the previous section, the revenues from CO2 taxes are used to lower existing fuel excise duties to the extent they exceed marginal infrastructure cost. For other cost categories the revenues will be spent differently. Revenues from congestion charges are assumed to be applied for investment within the modes or for intermodal funds. Taxes and charges related to other external effects are used for investments to reduce the external effects (e.g. noise screens and insulation, research into new technologies) and rewarding the best in class 15. Other options for using revenues are redistribution per capita or allocation to the general budget. Redistribution of revenues per capita, e.g. via a lowering of labour taxes, comes out as most efficient according to many studies and modeling work. Allocation to the general budget, in contrast, is sometimes worst in respect of welfare gains. 3.5.5 What to do with air pollution? The Euro-standards for road vehicles have proven very effective in reducing the emission of air pollutants. In other modes, such standards have been introduced more recently. We propose to further tighten the Euro-standards, for road vehicles and locomotives, and also Euro or other international standards for vessels and aircraft. In addition to the standards, financial incentives are now used in some countries to: − Speed up the introduction of new/cleaner vehicles in the fleet. − Use of most recent technology in critical areas (urban areas, sensitive areas such as alpine transit). In theory, the differentiation of circulation taxes, road user charges and tolls could be used for this purpose. Registration taxes are not suitable, since (almost) all newly sold cars adhere to the latest Euro-standards. At the moment, in the road sector, there are good arguments for such financial incentives. However, by 2020, the differences in emissions and external costs between cars from different Euro-standards are likely to be small. Differences in costs may be more attributable to the location where is driven (e.g. driving in a densely populated area versus a rural environment) than the vehicle that is driven (e.g. between a Euro-5 and a Euro-7 car). For this reason, the need for incentives in fixed charges (such as user charges and circulation taxes) for cleaner cars may be small. However, if a system is in place that levies charges dependent on location (either for congestion or infrastructure or a combination), incentives to limit the use of cars in certain areas 15 54 There is some recent scientific literature on greening taxes and use of revenues that addresses this issue. Some model results indicate that from an economic efficiency perspective, rewarding the best companies may be superior to lowering labor taxes. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 may be provided. The charges may then also be differentiated according to Eurostandards. In other modes than road, the (Euro-)standards currently in place are not so severe yet. It appears significant technical improvements are still feasible. Based on the progress made for road vehicles, we propose to continue the approach of standards for these sectors. In addition, there may be reason to differentiate existing taxes and charges with respect to the emission of pollutants (e.g. differentiated harbour dues, differentiated LTO charges), or even to introduce regulatory charges, potentially differentiated to location. Potential revenues could be earmarked for research into cleaner technologies, or to subsidise retrofit applications. This may be especially relevant for the non-road modes, because the lifetime of locomotives, vessels and aircraft is generally much longer than for road vehicles. There is no real argument for direct earmarking. Bonus-Malus is sufficient. Only in a wider sense (e.g. to promote public transport or rail alternative in sensitive regions (the Swiss and the London idea). This may be especially relevant for the non-road modes, because the lifetime of locomotives, vessels and aircraft is generally much longer than for road vehicles. 3.5.6 What to do about congestion? Congestion problems on the road can basically be split into two categories: 1 Congestion in urban areas. 2 Congestion at major corridors. These two categories may require different solutions. Congestion around urban areas may best be addressed by city toll (aera licencing/cordon charge, e.g. London or Stockholm). The examples so far show that urban congestion can be decreased significantly, if alternatives (e.g. public transport) are available. Tolls may be differentiated according to time of day (e.g. peak and off peak). The experience so far show however that there is no real acceptance of road users, due to the following reasons. Firstly the alternatives (e.g. public transport) in peak hours are usually worse than during the day. Road users tend to pay for a bad quality instead of a good alternative (double payment of congestion costs). Secondly the system is getting more complication with regard to transparency and enforcement. To improve accessibility and provide alternatives, revenues may be earmarked for investments in the transport sector, including the financing of public transport alternatives. The second type of congestion is related to congestion at major corridors outside of city centres. This can be bottleneck congestion related to the passing of a certain point or construction work (i.e. a bridge or tunnel). Alternatively, congestion on a link between large cities may arise. If such bottlenecks or 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 55 arteries become congested, there is by definition a capacity problem that cannot be solved by alternative links 16. Real life examples show that there are two possibilities. The one is optimal capacity management by differentiating a congestion toll according to time of day, in order to guarantee optimal traffic flows with low congestion risk. This value pricing can be used for specific lanes combined with incentives to increase load factors. The examples in the US show that high occupancy lanes function if there are transparent pricing systems, enough lanes and a willingness to pay of the users. The second possibility is increasing capacity. The congestion toll is a pre- or postfinancing instrument of the capacity increase. This increase can be a new lane (also priced with value pricing) or a new bypass. We therefore propose to levy tolls at such links, with a recommendation to earmark revenues for road infrastructure investment. Especially in mountainous areas, it may be relevance to invest in alternatives that have minimal impact on the environment. In general, the investments of the funds should be based on cost benefit analysis, including options within the road sector as well as investment in other modes. In addition to the instruments discussed so far, a transit bourse has been proposed to solve congestion problems in alpine regions. Such a system is a cap and trade system for limiting the number alpine transits. The impact of such a system can be similar to a bottleneck congestion toll mentioned above. The implementation cost of a transit bourse will probably be much higher than of a congestion toll. For these reasons we do not elaborate a transit bourse system in the scenarios. 3.5.7 How to address the costs of noise? Especially in the road, rail and aviation sector, noise costs may be substantial. The costs of noise relate both to the vehicle used and the location / time of day where it is used. For the road sector, the marginal costs of noise may be very limited in situations where the total costs are high, i.e. in urban areas. The reason is that there is already a lot of noise in urban areas. For this reason, including the marginal costs of noise in marginal pricing schemes may not be very effective in reducing the exposure to noise in areas where total noise problems are largest. Alternatively, noise may be better addressed by regulation and standards. Different to air pollution there is a direct link to the use of revenues, since infrastructure or home based noise measures (noise walls, windows) are appropriate and effective. This link should be considered for all modes. For road transport, a noise charge and sensitive corridors is useful. A differentiation according to noise levels however is not feasible since the differences are small and driving styles play an important role. 16 56 An exception might be Alpine corridors, where railways alternatives might be viable. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 For railways, a differentiation of track pricing (considering esp. brake systems) are useful. Several countries are using such a noise bonus for silent brake systems. In the aviation sector, landing charges differentiated to noise emissions and / or time of day are widely applied. In some situations, surcharges are levied to finance insulation or property acquisition. 3.5.8 What to do about external accident costs? Accident costs are odd external effects of transport. In principle, accident costs are covered by insurances. However, a large part of the costs associated with accidents are non financial, and are often not covered by insurances, see also Chapter 2. Depending on the liability laws, even parts of values of human life’s are paid by compensation for bereaved. This is especially the case within the US law. Vehicle kilometres are not the best cost driver to base internalisation on. For the government to develop a pricing scheme that adheres closely to the true cost drivers is not straightforward. An alternative would be to charge the insurance company involved a lump sum at the level of the estimated external costs for each accident. In all countries, insurance is obligatory. Insurance companies have detailed information on cost drivers and differences in the risk rates between drivers. Insurance companies are expected to pass on the costs to their clients through higher insurance rates. The insurance companies are better able to differentiate these costs according to the accident risk involved with different drivers, driving times, routes etc. Drivers thus receive further incentives to reduce their risks. Insurance companies may then judge whether it is worthwhile to switch to payas-you-drive schemes 17, providing optimal incentives at the margin, or that the costs of introducing such schemes do not weigh up against averaging. A disadvantage of this proposal is that insurance companies are faced with increased uncertainties. On top of their current expenditures on the internal accident cost there will be additional payments to the governments for each accident to cover the external costs. It is however the core business of insurance companies to deal with such uncertainties. Clearly, such a scheme involves revenues for the government. The earlier discussed options for revenue use once more apply. More specifically, part of the revenues could be invested to augment a fund for compensation and safety of infrastructure use. Parts could be redistributed to the insurance holders per capita. 17 Which may be connected to potentially existing kilometer charging schemes for infrastructure costs to limit transaction and implementation costs. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 57 The main alternative to this scheme would be to apply an average charge, potentially differentiated with respect to location (type of road) and time of day, on top of an existing toll scheme for road. For the other modes, alternatives are not straightforward. For railways there could be an additional charge to the infrastructure charge. For aviation, the enlargement of the liability system seems to be most appropriate. For maritime transport and inland waterways, the costs of fatal accidents are small. Accidents in the maritime transport sector may involve oil spills into the sea and substantial damage to the environment. Whether additional instrumentation to reduce these externalities is required will be discussed at a later stage in the project. 3.5.9 What to do about climate costs? With the use of fossil fuels, carbon dioxide is emitted into the atmosphere. This contributes to climate change. From a fairness perspective, it can be argued that all modes should be treated the same and receive the same incentive (per ton of CO2) to reduce the emission of carbon dioxide. Two notes however. The climate impacts of aviation and shipping differ substantially for the impact of CO2 emissions alone. Related to aviation are the emissions of NOx at altitude and contrail formation. Both have a net warming effect on climate. On the other hand, related to shipping are the emissions of sulphates. Even though these remain in the atmosphere for only a limited amount of time, they have a substantial cooling effect. How to deal with this? Neglecting for the moment the non-CO2 climate effects, we propose on the basis of the fairness argument to provide the same incentives across all transport modes to reduce emissions of CO2. There are two options for this. 1 A CO2 tax could be levied upon fuel, based on the carbon content of fuel. The charge would thus be lower for diesel than for gasoline. The charge per ton of CO2 would be the same across all transport modes, and could be based on external cost estimates. A disadvantage of this approach is that there may be some possibilities to fuel up outside of Europe, thus avoiding the charge. This holds especially for maritime transport. Another potential problem is that the levying of such a charge may not be allowed for all modes. For aviation, many bilateral air service agreements exist that preclude such charges. For inland waterways, the Mannheim convention can pose a problem. It should however be taken into account, that before 2020 such legal arrangements may be adapted. 2 A connection could be made with the EU ETS. In line with the proposal for the aviation sector, and in line with the current practice for the electricity used for electric trains, all transport modes could be included in the EU ETS. The advantage of this approach is that the incentive to reduce CO2 emissions in the transport sector will be in line with incentives in the other sectors. A disadvantage is that level of the incentive may be below or above the external 58 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 costs of CO2 emissions, dependent on the shortage on the EU ETS market and the emission reduction opportunities available to all parties. In addition, inclusion of all transport modes in the EU ETS is not straightforward. It is important to make a good choice for the actors to be included, so to limit transaction costs. For example, transaction costs may become unacceptably large if all passenger car owners would be made to trade on the EU ETS market 18. It must further be noted that inclusion of all modes in the EU ETS may not end the discussion of level playing field across modes. A similar allocation method for all modes, such as auctioning may provide, would be further required. Because of the difficulties with fuel taxes for aviation and maritime transport, (both legislative and with respect to economic distortions), we propose to include these sectors in the EU ETS. For some scenarios, the other sectors will also be included in the EU ETS, for others a CO2 tax or charge on fuel will be proposed. As discussed in section 3.5.3, especially in the road mode, excise duties already impose marginal costs on transport users that are partly in line with the external climate effects. The excise duties may therefore be revised when internalisation measures are imposed. For a CO2 tax or charge, we refer to section 3.5.3. With regard to emissions trading, the excise duties may be lowered so that the total revenue from fuel excises is reduced by the revenue from any auctioned allowances under emissions trading. Total revenues for the government will so remain unchanged, and the charging scheme is closer to marginal cost based pricing. When a CO2 tax or charge or emission trading is implemented, we propose account is taken of the potential of biofuels to limit the net CO2 emissions of fuel. With regard to the non-CO2 climate impacts of aviation 19, we propose that additional flanking instruments are introduced. Closer regulation of flight paths can reduce the formation of contrails. In additional, standards for new aircraft may reduce the emissions of NOx at altitude. In addition to the proposed cross-cutting measures, one could imagine specific incentives to influence the vehicle purchasing decision and the supply of fuel efficient passenger cars. A CO2 tax on fuel or inclusion in the ETS may provide the correct incentive at the margin, but there is evidence that at least car owners may not make fully rational decisions with regard to fuel efficiency of vehicles on purchase. Generally, only the first three years of fuel use are taken into account. If longer periods are taken into account, people are more likely to opt for more fuel efficient cars. A differentiation of registration taxes, or if these are abolished, circulation taxes may be a good instrument, in line with the Commissions proposal. 18 19 There are several potential alternatives, each with its merits. Fuel suppliers are for example an option. For maritime transport, it is more complicated. The science behind these non-CO2 climate effects of shipping is not at a stage in which concrete policy recommendations can be made. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 59 Next, it is also important the fuel efficient cars are introduced and being put on the market. The current agreements between car makers and the Commission have this aim. Regulation of CO2 emissions of new cars may be a useful instrument. In addition, special incentives may be given to lease cars, such as currently employed in the UK 20. The argument for such special treatment is that it has been shown that the person that picks a new lease car has very little concern on the fuel costs of the car. For other modes instruments to incentivice the production and use of more fuel efficient vehicles are more difficult to introduce, because there is more variety in the potential performance of vehicles, albeit aircraft, vessels or trucks. In additional, there may be less need for such a scheme, since generally the lifetime costs of vehicles are more rationally taken into account in the commercial sector than in passenger car market. 3.5.10 Special issue: Do we need a toll system for passenger cars? In theory, setting a charge at the marginal social cost level would be optimal. This would require investments in charging systems. To be able to account of situation differences in external costs (related to e.g. time of day and location) a fairly sophisticated charging scheme would be required. The question we want to pose is whether a kilometre charging scheme that applies on all roads and that can be differentiated to time and location would be worth setting up, based on considerations of external costs only. Without going into details here, to decide whether such a system may be called for, we discuss briefly for which external effects such a system may be required. For air pollution, congestion, accidents and noise the external effects may differ by time and location. However, above we have argued that the costs of air pollution may be relatively small by 2020. Similarly, for congestion in urban areas, toll rings or cordons may be more appropriate. These may of course be differentiated to time, and are by definition differentiated by location. Similarly, bottleneck congestion and congestion on major arteries may best be regulated by specific tolls. For accidents we propose to use a very different charging scheme, introduced via insurance companies. The impacts of noise vary substantially according to time of day and location. However, the marginal costs of noise are very low for passenger cars in urban areas, given the number of cars that already drive there. 20 60 In the UK, income tax is levied on a share of the sales price of a lease car. This share has been made dependent on the fuel efficiency of the car. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Based on these considerations, it may not be worthwhile to introduce sophisticated (and relatively expensive) systems for kilometre charging that apply to the whole network for the purpose of reducing external effects. From other perspectives, such as a fairer charging system for the use of infrastructure, there may be good arguments to introduce such a system. If such a system is indeed introduced for such reasons, it may also be used for differentiated charges with regard to internalisation of external costs. 3.6 Proposal for scenarios In this section we present the scenarios as a starting point for the workshop. They are not meant as a final list, but as a starting point for discussion. The final definition of the scenarios that will subjected to the impact assessment will be chosen after the workshop, in order to make fully use of the ideas and suggestions made at the workshop. The scenarios describe the changes in price levels and price structures and other internalisation measures that are implemented by Member States. To some extent they are hypothetical, because they assume that all Member States implement a similar set of internalisation measures. Following the contract with the Commission, four to six scenarios will be worked out in detail and be subjected to an impact analysis. The project team is responsible for a precise definition of the different scenarios. Under guidance by the Commission, the scenarios will then be inserted into a variety of models (TRANSTOOLS, TREMOVE and ASTRA) to assess the impact the different scenarios may have on the economy (transport cost, government income, employment, welfare and competitiveness), transport sector (modal split, transport cost, safety and congestion) and environmental impacts and cost. We now turn to a discussion of the different scenarios we propose. Some scenarios are based on complex pricing mechanisms that are closely aligned with external cost drivers. Related to this are differences in the extent to which new measures are introduced, or existing charges and taxes are differentiated. Scenarios also differ in the way they take account of fairness considerations, there is one scenario in which intrasectoral external effects are not internalised. Some scenarios are more directed toward setting correct charge levels, other are primarily aimed at charge structures. The playing field between effectiveness, equity, marginal cost pricing, secondbest circumstances and use of revenues is complex. With the set of proposed scenarios, we aim to cover a reasonable spread in possibilities. In the proposal for the scenarios we have been considering to what extent existing models can take account of the differentiations and instruments proposed. In the back of our mind we have also considered the current legal 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 61 background and restrictions this might pose to the introduction of instruments 21. Nonetheless, not for all of the proposed instruments, impacts can be modelled with the existing models. Similarly, not all of the proposed instruments may be feasible within the current legislative context. We have chosen not to restrict us too much by these criteria, because legal contexts may be changed and the inability to model a certain instrument does not mean it cannot be an cost effective instrument. Comments with regard to the appropriateness of the proposed scenarios are very welcome, as are suggestions for adaptations and alternatives. The scenarios we propose are: − Scenario 1 - Reference scenario. − Scenario 2 - Differentiation of existing taxes and charges & regulation. − Scenario 3 - Full internalisation of external cost. − Scenario 4 - Full internalisation of intersectoral external costs. − Scenario 5 - Mix of differentiation and new taxes and charges. − Scenario 6 - Current directive for road freight to a maximum. Note that all scenarios 2 - 6 describe the changes with respect to the business as usual scenario, Scenario 1. 3.6.1 Scenario 1 - Reference scenario To be able to model the impacts of internalisation, a reference scenario is required. We propose as a reference scenario to assume that all existing taxes and charges remain unchanged within all modes. No additional internalisation measures are introduced. 3.6.2 Scenario 2 - Differentiation of existing taxes and charges & regulation The second scenario we propose is based on existing taxation and charging schemes and regulation. We propose to adapt existing instruments to make them more in line with the cost drivers of external effects. It thus addresses the structure of existing charges and taxes, and not so much the levels. The scenario does not propose new mark ups or charges. The additional burden on the transport sector only depends on the costs that are associated with adhering to strengthened regulations. Moreover, by using existing instruments, transaction and implementation costs may be kept to a minimum. Because this scenario is based on existing charges that may be levied for other reasons than internalisation, e.g. infrastructure cost recovery, the proposed transformation of the existing instruments will be revenue neutral for each instrument. It can thus be ensured that the aims of the existing instruments are not harmed. Clearly, strict revenue neutrality cannot be guaranteed because of 21 62 In additional, especially for the aviation and maritime transport sector, we are aware that some of the proposed instruments may distort competition. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 the unpredictability of infrastructure users’ reactions. Periodic adaptation of the charges may therefore be required. There are two related practical aspects that warrant attention: 1 Should the level of differentiation be based on marginal external cost estimates or should more pragmatic differentiations be applied? 2 In case of the first option, what to do if current charge levels are too low to base differentiation upon? We propose a pragmatic solution to these issues. In general, the level of differentiation should have a basis in the external cost estimates, but may be required not to exceed the limits of e.g. 25% and 250% of the average charge level. Instruments per mode Passenger cars and LDV For CO2, we assume a regulatory scheme that reduces the average CO2 emissions of new passenger cars. Registration taxes or circulation taxes 22 will be differentiated with respect to CO2 emissions of new cars, in line with the current EC proposal. In addition, CO2 taxes or charges on fuel are introduced based on the external climate costs. The charges reflect the differences in climate impact of diesel, gasoline and biofuels. Existing fuel excise duties are lowered by the same rates, but not below the level of marginal infrastructure cost 23. Emissions of noise and air pollution are addressed through vehicle standards. Circulation taxes are differentiated to Euro standard to speed up fleet renewal. Existing toll schemes are transformed so to provide incentives to spread traffic over the day. A differentiation of existing instruments with respect to accident risk is not feasible. HGV Emissions of noise and air pollution are addressed through vehicle standards. Existing tolls, fixed infrastructure user charges and circulation taxes are transformed so to differentiate between Euro standards and to provide incentives to spread traffic over the day. CO2 taxes or charges on fuel are introduced based on the external climate costs. The charges reflect the differences in climate impact of diesel and biofuels. Existing fuel excise duties are lowered by the same rates, but not below the level of marginal infrastructure cost. 22 23 In addition to differentiating registration and circulation taxes with respect to fuel efficiency, the EC proposal also proposes to abolish purchase taxes for internal market reasons. his might also be implemented by labelling part existing fuel duties as being related to the external cost of climate impact. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 63 A differentiation of existing instruments with respect to accident risk is not feasible. The same holds for climate costs 24. Rail A distinction will be made between electric and diesel trains. External effects related to electricity production should be addressed within the energy sector. The costs of regulation are expected to be passed on in the price of electricity. Euro-standards and noise standards will be further tightened. To provide incentives for retrofit applications, infrastructure charges will be differentiate to Euro-standard and noise standard. Account will be taken of location (noise & air pollution) and time of day (noise), according to the possibilities that the rail directive provides. Scarcity costs will be addressed in accordance to the possibilities the rail directive provides (i.e. by mark-ups). We assume that revenues generated will be used for rail infrastructure investments. Inland shipping There are few existing taxes and charges that can be differentiated. Harbour dues will be differentiated to air pollution. Euro-standards will be further tightened. Sea shipping Similar to inland shipping. Standards will be further tightened, harbour dues are differentiated. Aviation Aviation will be included in the ETS, in line with the current proposal. Infrastructure charges are further differentiated according to the noise emissions of aircraft, time of day and the NOx emission level during LTO. NOx and noise standards for new aircraft will be further tightened. 24 64 With respect to the climate effects of HDVs, it is difficult to design a levy point on the basis of which existing charges might be differentiated. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Table 16 Overview of internalisation measures in scenario 2 Scenario 2 Road passenger cars and LDV Road HDV Climate Differentiation of vehicle purchase tax & circulation tax Regulation of CO2 emissions of new cars Fuel excise duty partly replaced by CO2 tax Fuel excise duty partly replaced by CO2 tax Rail - Inland shipping - Maritime shipping - Aviation ETS Air Pollution Differentiation of circulation tax to Euro standard Stricter vehicle emission standards Noise Stricter vehicle noise emission standards Other - Accidents - Congestion and scarcity Differentiation of existing tolls to spread traffic over day Differentiation of circulation tax, toll and fixed user charges to Euro standard Stricter vehicle emission standards For diesel: differentiated infrastructure charges to Euro standard and location Stricter vehicle emission standards for diesel Stricter vehicle noise emission standards - - Differentiation of existing tolls to spread traffic over day Differentiated infrastructure charges to noise standard, time of the day (day/night) and location (urban/non-urban) Stricter vehicle noise emission standards - - - Mark-ups to existing infrastructure charges to spread traffic over day - - - - - - - Differentiation of LTO charge to noise emission category Stricter aircraft noise emission standards - - - Differentiated harbour dues to vessel size, Euro standard and location (urban/non-urban) Stricter vehicle emission standards Differentiation of harbour dues to ship size, emission class and location (urban/non-urban) Stricter vehicle emission standards Differentiation of LTO charge to emission class and airport location Stricter aircraft emission standards 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 65 3.6.3 Scenario 3 - Full internalisation of external cost In contrast to scenario 2, under this scenario new charges are introduced, to adhere as much as possible to marginal cost pricing. The disadvantage is that transaction and implementation costs are likely to be higher, because the charging structure is more sophisticated. The advantage is that by the introduction of new instruments, we can adhere closer to the cost drivers that cause the external effects. We assume implementation of a variable kilometre charging scheme for road infrastructure 25 that can also be used for charging for external effects, and enables charge levels to be differentiated to time of day, location and vehicle characteristics. Accident costs For all modes, insurance companies will be charged a lump sum per accident (depending on severity) to cover external accident costs. We assume that insurance companies will raise their insurance rates by the same amount, differentiated to the main cost drivers. We also assume that half of the revenues of these lump sum charges will be invested in mitigation measures, and the other half will go to the general budget. For aviation and maritime transport, we assume all proceeds will be invested into mitigation. Because of the international nature of these sectors, flows to general budgets may be very difficult to achieve. Revenue use We propose two variants. In scenario 3A, revenues from congestion charges will be fed into intermodel funds. Based on cost benefit analysis, the most cost effective infrastructure investments will be selected. Revenues from road may thus be reinvested in the road sector. Revenues from charges for environmental effects will in the first place be used to reduce existing variable taxes and charges that are unrelated to marginal costs (in particular fuel excise duties but not below marginal infrastructure cost levels). Remaining revenues will be invested in research, mitigation and subsidies for retrofit technology. Under the second variant, scenario 3B, all revenues will in the first place be used to reduce existing variable charges that are unrelated to marginal costs (e.g. excises and circulation taxes). Remaining revenues will be directed at the taxes on labour. Such taxes are known to disturb the economy significantly. Charging externalities and lowering disturbing taxes should increase economic efficiency substantially. Below, the instruments per mode for both scenarios are further presented. 25 66 We further assume that simultaneously with the introduction of this infrastructure charging scheme, existing charges such as registration and circulation taxes and fuel excise duties are reduced so the net governmental revenue remains unchanged. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Instruments per mode Passenger cars, LDV and HDV The kilometre charging scheme takes full account of the external costs of congestion, air pollution, noise and ‘other’ external costs. In addition air pollution and noise emission standards for new vehicles are tightened. Just like in scenario 2, we assume a regulatory scheme that reduces the average CO2 emissions of new passenger cars. Registration taxes or circulation taxes will be differentiated with respect to CO2 emissions of new cars, in line with the current EC proposal. In addition, climate costs are internalised through a CO2 tax on fuel, based on carbon content and shadow cost level. Existing fuel excise duties are lowered by the same rates, but not below the level of marginal infrastructure cost. Rail The rail infrastructure charge will take full account of the external costs of congestion / scarcity, air pollution, noise and other external costs, in line with rail Directive. In addition air pollution and noise emission standards for new vehicles are tightened. External costs of electricity production will be dealt with upstream. On diesel, a CO2 tax will be imposed. Just like in scenario 2, scarcity costs will be addressed in accordance to the possibilities the rail directive provides (i.e. by mark-ups). We assume that revenues generated will be used for rail infrastructure investments. Inland waterways A CO2 tax on fuel will be introduced. In addition, an air pollution charge is levied. This is based on the amount of fuel taken on board and the engine standard of the vessel 26. Euro-standards for air pollutants will be tightened. Sea shipping Maritime transport is included in the EU ETS. Harbour dues will be increased based on fuel intake and engine characteristics, this relates especially to potential sulphur emissions. NOx standards for engines will be tightened. Aviation Aviation is included in the EU ETS. A LTO charge based on NOx and noise emissions is introduced. The LTO NOx charge will be increased to take account of the climate impact of NOx emissions at altitude. NOx and noise standards for aircraft / engines will be tightened. Air traffic control measures are taken to reduce contrail formation. Congestion/scarcity will be dealt with by a governmental levy. 26 If this unfeasible because of evasion, the alternative is to add a surcharge on the harbour dues to account for air pollution, based on the emission class of the engine. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 67 3.6.4 Scenario 4 - Full internalisation of intersectoral external costs only This scenario is very similar to scenario 3, with the difference that it does not address intrasectoral external costs that users of the same mode impose onto each other. This means that congestion and accident costs are not internalised. Revenues from charges are used as in scenario 3B. 68 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Table 17 Overview of internalisation measures in scenario 3 (for scenario 4 the same table applies, with the last two columns left blank) Scenario 3 Climate Air Pollution Noise Other Accidents Road passenger cars Differentiation of vehicle purchase tax & circulation tax Regulation of CO2 emissions of new cars Fuel excise duty partly replaced by CO2 tax Fuel excise duty partly replaced by CO2 tax For diesel: CO2 emission factor based charge (partly replacing fuel excise duty, if present) Charge per km, differentiated to Euro standard and type of infra (motorway, urban, other) and mark-ups for mountainous areas Stricter vehicle emission standards Same as cars Charge per km, differentiated to noise standard and type of infra (motorway, urban, other) and mark-ups for mountainous areas Stricter vehicle noise emission standards Same as cars Charge per km, differentiated to type of infra (motorway, urban, other) and mark-ups for mountainous areas Same as cars Charge per accident for insurance companies Same as cars Same as cars For diesel: charge per km, differentiated to Euro standard and location Stricter vehicle emission standards Mark-up per km, differentiated to noise standard and location (urban/non-urban) Stricter vehicle noise emission standards - Charge per accident for insurance companies Inland shipping CO2 emission factor based charge - Rate per km or harbour visit, differentiated to vessel size Charge per accident for insurance companies Maritime shipping ETS - Rate per harbour visit, differentiated to ship size Charge per accident for insurance companies - Aviation ETS Rate per km or harbour visit, differentiated to vessel size, Euro standard and location Stricter vehicle emission standards Rate per harbour visit, differentiated to ship size, emission class and port location Stricter vehicle emission standards Rate per LTO, differentiated to emission class and airport location Stricter aircraft NOx emission standards Mark-ups to existing infrastructure charges to spread traffic over day - Rate per LTO, differentiated to noise emission category Stricter aircraft noise emission standards - Charge per accident for insurance companies Governmental levy Road HDV Rail 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 Congestion and scarcity Congestion charge or Cordon charge 69 3.6.5 Scenario 5 - Mix of differentiation and new taxes and charges This scenario is somewhere in the middle between scenario 2 and 3. It introduces less new instruments than scenario 3, but more than scenario 2. In contrast to scenarios 3 and 4, this scenario does not presuppose a kilometre charging scheme for road infrastructure costs. For climate costs, we assume that the whole transport sector is included in the ETS 27. Excise duties are adjusted so that the total revenue from the revised excise duties and any auctioned allowances under the EU ETS is equal to the old revenue from excises. External accident costs are addressed by a lump sum for insurance companies per accident. The revenues will be used first to invest in safety measures related to infrastructure. Additional revenues will be used to lower labour taxes. Congestion on the road is addressed by cordon charges in major urban areas with congestion problems. Corridor congestion charging on bottlenecks 28 (and potentially in mountainous areas). Revenues into TENS and additional infrastructure, intermodal funds (to finance infrastructure with best cost-benefit analysis). Accident costs are internalised the same way as in scenario 3 (via insurance companies). In addition to these measures, we assume that (Euro-)standards for air pollution and noise are further tightened for all modes. Instruments per mode Passenger cars, LDV and HDV ETS for climate costs. Congestion on the road is addressed by cordon charges in major urban areas with congestion problems. Corridor congestion charging on bottlenecks (and potentially in mountainous areas). Revenues into TENS and additional infrastructure, intermodal funds (to finance infrastructure with best cost-benefit analysis). Euro-standards for air pollution and noise emission standards are further tightened. Rail ETS for climate costs and lowering of excise duties (where present). Revenues invested in infrastructure. (Euro-)standards for air pollution and noise are further tightened. 27 28 70 In practice, it may well be that for some modes this may lead to such high transaction costs (e.g. if all passenger car owners are required to trade) that a CO2 tax or charge on fuel is introduced for these modes at the level of the expected price level in the EU ETS. These can take the very simple form of toll boots, or electronic tags. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 To provide incentives for retrofit applications, infrastructure charges will be differentiated to Euro-standard and noise standard. Account will be taken of location (noise & air pollution) and time of day (noise), according to the possibilities that the rail directive provides. Scarcity costs will be addressed in accordance to the possibilities the rail directive provides (i.e. by mark-ups). We assume that revenues generated will be used for rail infrastructure investments. External costs of electricity production will be dealt with upstream. Inland waterways ETS for climate costs. In addition, an annual air pollution charge is levied based on the engine characteristics and size class of the vessel. Revenues will be used to subsidise retrofit technologies. Euro-standards for air pollutants will be tightened. Sea shipping ETS for climate costs. Emission standards for engines will be tightened. Aviation ETS for climate costs. An LTO charge based on NOx and noise emissions is introduced, to finance mitigation and research. NOx and noise standards for aircraft / engines will be tightened. 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 71 Table 18 Overview of internalisation measures in scenario 5 Scenario 5 Climate Air Pollution Noise Other Accidents Road passenger cars Differentiation of vehicle purchase tax & circulation tax Regulation of CO2 emissions of new cars Fuel excise duty partly replaced by ETS Fuel excise duty partly replaced by ETS For diesel: ETS (diesel excise duty lowered, if present) Stricter vehicle emission standards Stricter vehicle noise emission standards - Charge per accident for insurance companies Congestion and scarcity Congestion charge or Cordon charge Stricter vehicle emission standards - Same as cars Same as cars - Charge per accident for insurance companies Inland shipping ETS - ETS - - Aviation ETS Differentiation of LTO charge to noise emission category Stricter aircraft noise emission standards - Charge per accident for insurance companies Charge per accident for insurance companies Charge per accident for insurance companies Mark-ups to existing infrastructure charges to spread traffic over day - Maritime shipping Annual air pollution tax differentiated to vessel size and Euro standard Stricter vehicle emission standards Stricter vehicle emission standards Stricter vehicle noise emission standards Differentiated infrastructure charges to noise standard, time of the day (day/night) and location (urban/non-urban) Stricter vehicle noise emission standards - Road HDV Rail 72 For diesel: differentiated infrastructure charges to Euro standard and location Stricter vehicle emission standards for diesel Rate per LTO, differentiated to emission class and airport location Stricter aircraft emission standards 4.288.1/Methodologies for external cost estimates and internalisation scenarios March 8, 2007 - Governmental levy 3.6.6 Scenario 6 - Current directive for road freight to a maximum Under this scenario, we assume that certain optional measures under the current directive 2006/38 will be made compulsory and therefore be applied to a maximum. That means that we assume that all countries introduce tolls for freight road infrastructure costs, which are differentiated with respect to Euro standard. Toll levels are based on the infrastructure costs as indicated in the Directive, including the infrastructure related expenditures on noise mitigation 29. Mark ups are applied for mountainous areas with acute congestion or significant environmental damage by vehicles. Revenues are used to finance new infrastructure. We do not assume the introduction of regulatory charges to combat air pollution and congestion, as not ruled out by the directive (art. 9). For other modes, we assume no change in the current taxes and charges, as under the reference scenario. This scenario enables one to answer the following question: Is adaptation of the current directive (or is a new directive) required to achieve the aims of internalisation? 29 Note that the Directive allows charges above the marginal producer costs. The additional charge may be taken as partly internalising external environmental costs. 4.288.1/Internalisation scenarios February 23, 2007 73 Table 19 Overview of internalisation measures in scenario 6 Scenario 6 Climate Air Pollution Noise Other Accidents Road passenger cars and LDV Road HDV - - - - - Congestion and scarcity - - - - - Differentiation of tolls within limits of 2006/38 and mark-ups for mountainous areas - - Rail Inland shipping Maritime shipping Aviation Differentiation of tolls within limits of 2006/38 and mark-ups for mountainous areas - - - - 74 4.288.1/Internalisation scenarios DRAFT February 23, 2007 3.7 Next steps After the workshop, scenarios will be elaborated further, to a set of four to six scenarios which will be subjected to the impact assessment. This elaboration will include: − Exact changes in price levels and structures per mode. − Technical en organisational requirements per mode (e.g. system to charge per km differentiated to emission class). After the selection and elaboration of the scenarios, an impact assessment will be carried out for the set of four to six scenarios. This will be based on modeling work by TREMOVE and TRANS-TOOLS. Based on the outcome of the impact assessment, the project will come forward with policy and legal strategies. 3.8 Main questions for the workshop a Internalisation strategy per cost category (congestion, accidents, air pollution, climate, noise, other) − Accidents – is internalisation via insurance companies the most appropriate approach? − Climate: Should internalisation by CO2 taxes/charges for some modes and ETS for others be aligned. If so how? − Scarcity – is internalisation by government levies for infrastructure providers the most appropriate approach? − Air pollution: to what extent and for which modes are market based instruments in addition to regulation an appropriate approach? − Noise: what is most effective - regulation or taxes/charges? Should charge levels be based on marginal or average cost levels? − To what extent are market based instruments appropriate for internalising other external cost like nature and landscape costs? − To what extent should intra-sectoral costs (external congestion and external accident costs) be charged for? b Taking account of existing taxes and charges − Is there agreement on the approach proposed - treatment of existing taxes and charges, in particular fuel excise duties? c Use of revenues − Should the revenues from congestion charges be earmarked to intermodal funds or within the mode? − How should revenues from environmental surcharges be earmarked: for mitigation or decreasing labour taxes? d Which of the scenarios should be subjected to the impact assessment? − What are the pros and cons of the various scenarios? 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport February 23, 2007 75 76 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport DRAFT February 23, 2007 References Actions - Benefits and Cost of Climate Change Policies and Measures”, ENV.C.2/2004/0088. http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/climat/pdf/final_report2.pdf Kennisinstituut voor Mobiliteitsbeleid Annema, J.A., E. Bakker, R. Haaijer Stimuleren van verkoop van zuinige auto’s; De effecten van drie prijsmaatregelen op de CO2-uitstoot van personenauto’s (Stimulating the sale of fuel efficiënt cars; Impacts of three pricing measures on the CO2 emissions of passenger cars) Den Haag : KiM, 2001 CAFÉ, 2005 AEA Technology: Damages per tonne of PM21.5, NH3, SO2, NOx and VOC’s of Eu25 Member State (excluding Dyprus) and surrounding seas March 2005 CAPRI, 2001 Nash, C., T. Sansom, B. Matthews Concerted Action on Transport Pricing Research Integration (CAPRI), Final report for publication Brussels : European Commission, 2001 CAPRI, 1999 Rennings, K., A. Ricci, C. Sessa Concerted Action on Transport Pricing Research Integration (CAPRI), Deliverable D3 Valuation of transport externalities Brussels : European Commission, 1999 CE, 2002 Return on roads; Optimising road investments and use with the ‘user pays principle’ CE Delft, 4Cast, Free University of Amsterdam, 2002 ECMT, 1998 European Conference of Ministers of Transport, Efficient transport in Europe, Policies for internalisation of external costs Paris : ECMT, 1998 ECMT, 1998 European Conference of Ministers of Transport, User charges for railway infrastructure, Round table 107 Paris : OECD, 1998 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport February 23, 2007 77 ExternE, 2004 New Elements for the Assessment of External Costs from Energy Technologies (NewExt).” Final Report to the European Commission, DG Research, Technological Development and Demonstration (RTD), http://www.ier.unistuttgart.de/public/de/organisation/abt/tfu/projekte/newext/ newext_final.pdf. ExternE, 2005 Bickel, P., R. Friedrich Externalities of Energy, Methodology 2005 update Luxembourg : European Commission, 2005 GRACE, 2007 (Generalisation of research on accounts and cost estimation). On-going. Project coordina-tor: ITS, Leeds : Grace, 2007 HEATCO, 2005 Bickel, P. Developing Harmonised European Approaches for Transport Costing and Project Assessment, Deliverable 2: State-of-the-art in project assessment, EU-funded project (contract no. FP6-2002-SSP-1/502481) Germany : HEATCO, 2005 HEATCO, 2006 Bickel, P. Developing Harmonised European Approaches for Transport Costing and Project Assessment, Deliverable 5: Proposal for Harmonised Guidelines, EU-funded project (contract no. FP6-2002-SSP-1/502481 Germany : HEATCO, 2006 High Level Group, 1999 Calculating transport environmental costs, final report of the expert advisors to the High Level Group on infrastructure charging (working group 2), 1999 INFRAS/IWW, 2004 External costs of transport - update study, INFRAS/IWW on behalf of the International Union of Railways (UIC) Zurich/Karlsruhe : INFRAS/IWW, 2004 ITS, 2001 Sansom, T. Surface Transport Cost and Charges, Great Britain 1998, Final Report for the Department for the Environment, Transport and the Regions Leeds : ITS University of Leeds, 2001 78 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport DRAFT February 23, 2007 Lakshmanan, 2001 Lakshmanan, T.R. and P. Nijkamp, P. Rietveld, E.T. Verhoef Benefits and costs of transport; Classification, methodologies and policies, Papers Reg. Sci. 80, 139-164, 2001 Lindberg, 2006 Case study 1.4: State-of-the-art of external marginal accident costs, Lindberg, G., Annex to Deliverable D3 Marginal coast case studies for road and rail transport, GRACE (Generalisastion of Research on Accounts and Cost Estimation), funded by sixth Framework Programme Leeds : ITS, University of Leeds, 2006 Lindberg, 2006 Marginal cost case studies for road and rail transport - Deliverable D3, Lindberg, G. (VTI) with contribution from partners, GRACE (Generalisastion of Research on Accounts and Cost Estimation), funded by sixth Framework Programme Leeds : ITS, University of Leeds, 2006 Lindsey and Verhoef, 2001 Lindsey, C.R. and E.T. Verhoef, Traffic congestion and congestion pricing’ in D.A. Hensher and K.J. Button (eds.) (2001) Handbook of Transport Systems and Traffic Control, Handbooks in Transport 3 Mayeres and Proost, 2001 Marginal tax reform, externalities and income distribution, Journal of public economics, 79, 343-363 MC-ICAM, 2004 Marginal Cost pricing in transport; Integrated Conceptual and Applied Model Analysis; 8 deliverables http://www.its.leeds.ac.uk/projects/mcicam/index.html (consulted January 4th, 2007) Methodex: Harmonising and sharing of methods and data in environmental and health externalities evaluation; extraction of operational estimates from existing studies (excluding energy and transport). http://www.methodex.org/index.htm Milne et al.,2000 Milne, D., E. Niskanen and E.T. Verhoef, Operationalisation of marginal cost pricing within urban transport, Project AFFORD, VATT research report no. 63, Helsinki, 2000 http://vplno1.vkw.tu-dresden.de/psycho/projekte/afford/download/AFFORDdel1.pdf (consulted January 4th, 2007) 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport February 23, 2007 79 NEEDS, 2005a Ott, W., M. Baur, Y. Kaufmann New energy externalities development for sustainability, Deliverable D4.1 - RS 1b: Assessment of Biodiversity Losses Zurich : NEEDS, 2005 NEEDS, 2005b New energy externalities development for sustainability, Deliverable D4.1 - RS Integration Zurich : NEEDS, 2005 NewExt, 2004 Friedrich, R. New Elements for the Assessment of External Costs from Energy Technologies NewExt, Final Report to the European Commission DG Research Stuttgart : NewExt, 2004 NRC, 2002 National Resource Council, Committee on the Effectiveness and Impact of Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) Standards, 2002 OSD, 2002 Unfallkosten im Strassen- und Schienenverkehr der Schweiz 1998, Ecoplan im Auftrag des Bundesamtes für Raumentwicklung (Office for Spatial Development, OSD) Bern : OSd, 2002 OSD, 2003 Externe Kosten des Verkehrs im Bereich Natur und Landschaft, Econcept und Nateco im Auftrag des Bundesamtes für Raumentwicklung (Office for Spatial Development, OSD) Bern : OSD, 2003 OSD, 2004a Externe Gesundheitskosten durch verkehrsbedingte Luftverschmutzung Aktualisierung für das Jahr 2000, Ecoplan, INFRAS, ISPM im Auftrag des Bundesamtes für Raumentwicklung (Office for Spatial Development, OSD), des Bundesamtes für Umwelt, Wald und Landschaft, des Bundesamtes für Energie sowie des Bundesamtes für Gesundheit Bern : OSD, 2004 OSD, 2006 Externe Kosten des Strassen- und Schienenverkehrs 2000 – Klima und bisher nicht erfasste Umweltbereiche, städtische Räume sowie vor- und nachgelagerte Prozesse, INFRAS im Auftrag des Bundesamts für Raumentwicklung (Office for Spatial Development, OSD) Bern : OSD, 2006 80 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport DRAFT February 23, 2007 Peter, 2003 Peter, B. Rail infrastructure charging in the European Union Berlin : TU, 2003 Proost, 1999 Proost, S., K. van Dender TRENEN II STRAN - Final Report for Publication, Project funded by the EC, Contract no: ST.96.SC.116, Brussels, 1999 RECORDIT, 2001 Schmid, S.A. Real Cost Reduction of Door-to-Door Intermodal Transport, Deliverable 4: External cost calculation for selected corridors IER/ University of Stuttgart, November, 2001 REMEDE Resource Equivalency Methods for Assessing Environmental Damage in the EU ongoing 6th Framework project, http://www.envliability.eu/ Revenue Deliverable 6, 2006, Deliverable 6; Synthesis and policy conclusions, Version 1.2, 30 May 2006 Rothengatter, 2003 How good is first best? Marginal cost and other pricing principles for user charging in transport, Transport policy 10, p121-130 Schade, 2006 schade, W., Doll, C., Maibach, M., Sieber, N., Crespo, F., Lilco, A., Conti, N. (2006): Analysis of the contribution of transport policies to the competitiveness of the EU economy and comparison with the United States (COMPETE). Study carried out for the European Commission. Project co-ordinator: Fraunhofer-ISI Karlsruhe, 2006 Stern, 2006 The Economics of Climate Change, The Stern Review, Nicholas Stern, Cabinet Office - HM Treasury, 2006available at http://www.hmtreaury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_cha nge/sternreview_index.cfm TREMOVE 2 KU Leuven: Final Report Part 2: Description of the baseline, 5.12.06 UBA, 2006a Ökonomische Bewertung von Umweltschäden – Methodenkonvention zur Schätzung externer Umweltkosten, Umweltbundesamt, Dessau 2006 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport February 23, 2007 81 UBA, 2006b Praktische Anwendung der Methodenkonvention: Möglichkeiten der Berücksichtigung externer Umweltkosten bei Wirtschaftlichkeitsrechnungen von öffentlichen Investitionen, Markus Maibach, Niklas Sieber, Roman Bertenrath, Dieter Ewringmann, Lars Koch, Michael Thöne, Endbericht Zürich/Köln : UBA, 2006 UNITE, 2001 Nellthorp, J. Unification of accounts and marginal costs for transport efficiency, Valuation Conventions; J. Nellthorp et.al Leeds 2001. UNITE, 2003 Unification of accounts and marginal costs for transport efficiency, Final report for publication, C. Nash with contribution from partners Leeds : UNITE, 2003 US FHA, 2006 Congestion pricing; a primer, US Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration, December 2006, FHWA-HOP-07-074 Verhoef, 2002 Marginal cost based pricing in transport: Key implementation issues from the economic perspective, paper prepared for imprint http://www.imprint-eu.org/public/Ev_v2.pdf Verhoef, 2003 Rijen? De economie van verkeerscongestie en andere stedelijke externaliteiten, December 2003 Verhoef, 2004 Vormgeving en effecten van prijsbeleid op de weg; Effectiviteit, Efficiëntie en Acceptatie vanuit een Multidisciplinair Perspectief, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam, SEO, RUG, TU Delft, September 2004 Verhoef, 2007 Personal communication Watkiss, 2005a The Impacts and Costs of Climate Change. Final Report September 2005. P. Watkiss et al., Commissioned by European Commission DG Environment, prepared as task 1 of the project ‘Modelling support for Future Actions - Benefits and Cost of Climate Change Policies and Measures’ ENV.C.2/2004/0088. http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/climat/pdf/final_report2.pdf 82 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport DRAFT February 23, 2007 Watkiss, 2005b The Social Cost of Carbon (SCC) Review – Methodological Approaches for Using SCC Estimates in Policy Assessment. P. Watkiss et al., Final Report November 2005, Research on behalf of UK Defra 4.288.1/Input paper for a workshop on internalisation of external cost of transport February 23, 2007 83