Asymmetry of the exchange rate pass-through: An exercise on the Polish data1 Jan Przystupa2 Ewa Wróbel3 Abstract We propose a complex investigation of the exchange rate pass-through in a small open economy in transition. We assess the level, linearity and symmetry of exchange rate pass-through to import and consumer prices in Poland and discuss its implications for the monetary policy. We show that the pass-through is incomplete even in the long run. There is pricing to market behaviour both in the long and short run. We do not find a strong evidence of non-linearity in import prices reaction to the exchange rate and reject the hypothesis of an asymmetric response to appreciations and depreciations. On the other hand, we find an asymmetry of CPI responses to the output gap, direction and size of the exchange rate changes and to the magnitude of the exchange rate volatility. The asymmetry is mostly visible after exogenous shocks. We reject the hypothesis of an asymmetric reaction of prices in a high and low inflation environment. 4 JEL Classification: C22, E52, F31. Key Words: Exchange Rate Pass-through, Non-linear Model. 1 We are thankful to Michael Frömmel, Ryszard Kokoszczyński and Tomasz Łyziak for many helpful comments. 2 National Bank of Poland and Institute for Market, Consumption and Business Cycles Research, Warsaw; corresponding author: Jan.Przystupa@nbp.pl 3 National Bank of Poland. 4 The usual disclaimer applies. 1. Introduction (non-technical summary) Understanding how prices respond to exchange rate is of key importance for any small open economy, in particular, for the economies in transition with a free floating exchange rate. Poland is an example of such country. In this paper we show the main properties of the exchange rate pass-through in Poland and assess their implications for the monetary policy. Our analysis covers a period 1997-2008, which is characterized by a homogenous monetary policy (inflation targeting, flexible exchange rate) and a generally falling inflation rate. We assess the degree of pass-through to import prices, examine if they exhibit pricing to market behaviour and whether they react to the exchange rate symmetrically. We find that pricing to market exists, both in the long run and in the short run, but reject the hypothesis of asymmetric reaction to the exchange rate. Then, we pass to the CPI, show the level of passthrough and examine whether the process is symmetric. In contrast to import prices, in the case of CPI we find some asymmetries with respect to the output gap, direction and size of exchange rate change and its variability. We do not find asymmetry regarding inflation environment. Finally, we discuss implications for the monetary policy. To our knowledge, both pricing to market and asymmetric reactions of import prices and CPI have not been explored on the Polish data. The existing Polish literature on the pass-through is not particularly abundant. It is mostly based on McCarthy (2000) where the impact of a sequence of supply, demand and exchange rate shocks on the import, producer and consumer prices is examined, see Przystupa (2002), Cholewiński (2008). Since it is a popular method, for the sake of comparability with other studies, we also provide results we have obtained this way. They are shown in tables A1-A4 in the appendix. Generally, pass-through of the exchange rate changes to the import prices do not vary over time and slightly exceeds 0.7 after 8 quarters. On the other hand, pass-through to the consumer prices exhibits a notable fall: it dropped by half over the period 2002-2008 from 0.42 to 0.21. Such high pass-through effect at the earlier stages of transformation can be interpreted as a result of fast structural changes in the economy, while the huge drop of the pass-through in the last years as an ‘internationalization’ of the Polish economy due to a massive inflow of the export-oriented foreign direct investment. Figures for the pass-through effect to the import prices are close to results for other developed economies; whereas figures for the consumer prices differ considerably (they are close to the results estimated for 1971-1983 for the countries with the direct inflation targeting, see Ihrig et al. (2006). Pass-through to the import prices, estimated with other methods gives similar results - we can safely say that the long-run pass-through for both nominal effective exchange rate and the bilateral exchange rate lies within the range of 0.7-0.8; moreover, a strong evidence of pricing to market is confirmed. Estimating a dynamic equation for import prices we show that instantaneous pass-through is 0.51 – much lower than in the long run and there is weaker evidence of pricing to market. Also, the error correction works quite efficiently: 46% of disequilibrium is eliminated within one quarter. Checking the nonlinearity of import prices reaction to appreciations and depreciations we find that if there is appreciation of the Polish currency with respect to the euro then the effect of the instantaneous pass-through is 0.55 and there is pricing to market. 65% of disequilibrium is eliminated within one quarter. A different picture emerges for the depreciation periods: neither pricing to market nor error correction mechanism seems to operate. The only factor affecting import prices is the exchange rate. The pass-through effect is 0.59. We cannot reject the hypothesis that pass-through in depreciations 2 and appreciations is equal and tentatively conclude therefore, that there is no asymmetry in import prices’ reaction to the exchange rate. For the CPI we found the strong asymmetry of the pass-through effect along the business cycle: this effect may exceed 0.27 in the early expansion, and then it drops to 0.18-0.19 in the peak and to around zero in the early recession. During the late recession and the trough it is growing up to 0.18-0.19 and to over 0.27 in the early expansion. This is coherent with the behaviour of enterprises in the business cycle, conditioning their investment decisions on expected profits with a maximum in the early expansion and a minimum in the early recession. On the other hand, a strong asymmetric reaction was identified in the periods of appreciations and depreciations. If the zloty appreciates, the pass-through to the consumer prices declines and varies from 0.02 to 0.07. During the depreciations or slight appreciations, the passthrough effect equals 0.24. Also regarding volatility the pass-through effect seems to be strongly asymmetric: for the volatility over 4.3% it is equal to 0.25, and 0.55 otherwise. The lower pass-through in case of higher volatility can reflect the producers’ reluctance to frequent price changes due to the menu costs. Examining the role of the inflation environment in the exchange rate pass-through behaviour we do not obtain a clear picture, hence we decide to reject the hypothesis that the asymmetry exists. 2. Brief review of the literature Theoretical exchange rate pass-through literature is dominated by papers dealing with the degree of price adjustment and factors that affect pass-through. The discussion started after numerous tests on variety of goods and across countries yielded very little evidence supporting an assumption of the absolute or relative Purchasing Power Parity (Rogoff (1996), Ihrig et al. (2006).. One strand of the literature investigates pass-through stressing the role of market organization, product segmentation, pricing to market and competition as factors explaining why it is incomplete. In a seminal paper, Dornbusch (1987) points out that firms operating under imperfect competition may adjust mark-ups in response to the exchange rate shock. Froot and Klemperer (1989) show that if market share matters for future profits, then firms facing an exchange rate appreciation will decide whether to raise current or future profits, depending on their perception of durability of the appreciation. This strand of literature is closely related to the problem of pricing to market behaviour and we shall characterize it in more details in section 2, where we describe the model of import prices. In the second strand of this literature, pass-through is treated as a phenomenon affected by the monetary policy. In a seminal paper Taylor (2000) suggests that price responsiveness to the exchange rate is positively related to the inflation rate. Bailliu and Fujii (2004) find that a transition to a low inflation environment induced by a shift in monetary policy is a cause of a declining pass-through. Devereux and Yetman (2002) build a model in which sticky prices result from menu cost of price adjustment. Monetary policy determines the average rate of inflation and exchange rate volatility. Firms are allowed to choose frequency of price adjustment and optimal frequency varies with the monetary policy regime. For a given menu cost, the higher the rate of inflation and the more volatile the exchange rate, the higher the 3 frequency of price adjustment decisions taken by firms and the higher the pass-through effect. As a result Devereux and Yetman argue, that pass-through is endogenous to monetary policy. Devereux, Engel and Storgaard (2003) analyze the determinants of an exporting firm’s choice of currency in which it pre-sets prices. With nominal price stickiness, the aggregate degree of exchange rate pass-through is determined by this decision. They develop a model of an endogenous exchange rate pass-through, in a framework in which the exchange rate itself is also endogenously determined. They find a two-sided relationship, namely that exchange rate volatility determines the price setting behaviour of a firm, and therefore the degree of the pass-through, and that the degree of the pass-through determines the volatility of an exchange rate. On the other hand, Campa and Goldberg (2002) show that higher inflation and exchange rate volatility are weakly associated with higher pass-through. To sum up this part of the literature overview, factors that explain an incomplete pass-through in the long run can be considered microeconomic, whereas these affecting its degree in the short run – macroeconomic. Linearity and possible asymmetry are investigated less frequently, even though a question whether they exist is important if not crucial for the monetary authorities. Linear response means that prices react in the same way to “big” and “small” changes in the exchange rate. Many papers rather assumed linearity than tested it. But if there are some menu costs of price adjustment, then relatively small changes in the exchange rate may not be passed onto prices. Only after exceeding a certain threshold these changes might be passed on customers. On the other hand, if domestic prices react more to, say, depreciations than to appreciations, meaning there is an asymmetry in the price reaction to the exchange rate changes, it may reflect distortions in the markets, weak competition in particular. Bussière (2007) provides assumptions and discusses the economic meaning of both quadratic and cubic non-linearities. The quadratic case relies on three assumptions: (i) that export prices are rigid downwards (ii) that quantities of exported goods are rigid upwards (exporting firms work at full capacities) and (iii) that exporting firms care about their market share. Exporters try to offset a fraction of exchange rate movements, and this fraction varies with the magnitude of the exchange rate changes. For a larger appreciation, the reaction of export prices decreases, whereas for a large depreciation – increases. Also, in appreciations exporters reduce their prices by a larger amount, because they fear losing market share. The cubic case relies on the assumption of the existence of menu costs on the side of both exporters and importers. If the former is true, then exporters only slightly adjust prices in their currency in response to the exchange rate changes, while these changes are reflected in the import prices. If the menu costs are at the side of importers, the exporting firms adjust prices to offset small changes in the exchange rate. Recently the gap between empirical literature assuming linearity and symmetry and that testing it has been shrinking. Early works on this topic are Mann (1986) and Goldberg (1995); both find asymmetries in consumer prices’ reaction to appreciations and depreciations. More papers appeared only after the year 2000. Devereux and Yetman in the paper mentioned above use a cross-section time series model to show that there is a non-linear relationship between the degree of pass-through and inflation rate. As inflation rises, pass-through increases too but at a decelerating rate. Pollard and Coughlin (2003) examine the symmetry in response of import prices in manufacturing to appreciations and depreciations as well as to the size of the change of the exchange rate in the US and show that there is some asymmetry in 4 response of import prices in different industries. They find no clear direction of the asymmetry across industries, however, and conclude that pass-through is positively related to the size of the change in the exchange rate. Campa et al. (2006) examine non-linearity in import price adjustment in the EU (15). They explore three types of non-linearities: adjustments which are not proportional to the size of the deviation, adjustments which are non-symmetrical to the sign of the deviation and finally thresholds below which no adjustment takes place. Using data on the industry-level they obtain a strong evidence for the presence of nonlinearities in the adjustment towards long-run equilibrium in certain industries. They also find evidence for the existence of thresholds of no adjustment centred on zero. The thresholds seem to be much lower for the manufacturing than for the commodity industries. Herzberg et al. (2003) use aggregate data for the UK. They do not find evidence of non-linearity in the reaction of import prices. Bussière (2007) investigates whether export and import prices of G7 countries exhibit linear and symmetrical reaction to the exchange rate movements. He finds that a non-linear effect cannot be neglected, although the direction of the asymmetries and the magnitude of non-linearities vary across countries. Wickremasinghe and Silvapulle (2004) find that in Japan import prices of manufacturing display a statistically significant difference in their adjustment to appreciations and depreciations and that the reaction to the former is bigger than to the latter. There is less evidence of import price reactions in the emerging markets. Alvarez et al. (2008) report a weak asymmetry between the reaction of import prices to appreciations and depreciations in Chile. They examine unit import values and wholesale import prices, the former aggregated into three subcomponents by end use: consumer, intermediate and capital goods; the latter distinguished imported goods from three sectors – mining, agriculture and industry. They find that coefficients for depreciations are higher than for appreciations, but null hypothesis that both coefficients are equal is not rejected only marginally for capital goods; for agriculture only depreciations are passed into import prices. Literature dealing with the consumer price index is even scarcer. Goldfajn and Werlang (2000) use a panel of 71 countries and report an asymmetric reaction of pass-through over the business cycle. Correa and Minella (2006) investigate non-linearities in pass-through to consumer prices in Brazil. They estimate a Phillips curve with a threshold for the passthrough and show that the magnitude of a short run pass-through is higher when the economy is growing faster, when the exchange rate depreciates above a certain threshold and – surprisingly – when exchange rate volatility is lower. Posedel and Tica (2007) use a TAR model on Croatian data and find a single threshold of a monthly change in the exchange rate below which it does not affect consumer price inflation. Khundrakpam (2007) finds asymmetry of pass-through related to the direction of the exchange rate changes in India. To sum up, there is growing evidence showing the existence of various types of nonlinearities both on the first stage of the pass-through, i.e. import prices, as well as on the last stage – i.e. consumer prices. Our paper fits in this type of literature. The first part is devoted to the analysis of import prices: we start with a linear equation, and afterwards test whether it is mis-specified, i.e. whether it lacks non-linear terms. We do not find strong evidence for non-linearities, but it seems that in depreciations and appreciations different mechanisms of adjustment operate. In appreciations of the home currency with respect to the euro pricing to market seems to have some impact on import prices. However, this impact disappears in depreciations. The next part of the paper is focused on retail prices. We estimate threshold models and models based 5 on nonreversibility of the linear functions and find an asymmetric reaction of consumer prices to appreciations and depreciations, to the volatility of the exchange rate, and, in the models based on nonreversibility, to the business cycle fluctuations. The impact of the inflation environment does not show any apparent asymmetry. 3. Import price model There is a vast literature pointing that import prices can be affected by domestic prices. The phenomenon is known as pricing to market (henceforth PTM). It was perceived as a result of market imperfections (monopolistic power of price setters) and market segmentation, since in this case producers can charge a mark-up on costs. The mark-up depends on the elasticity of demand for a given product and this in turn is determined by competitors’ prices. Facing a change in the exchange rate, producers can decide whether and to what degree the mark-up should absorb these changes. For example, if the domestic currency of an exporting firm depreciates, it can refrain from increasing its mark-up to build a future market share. Firms having a power to control their prices can charge different prices in different markets. Pricing to market can therefore explain why pass-through tends to be incomplete. Further analyses of PTM show however, that imperfect competition together with market segmentation is not a sufficient condition for a persistently low degree of pass-through5. In this vein, Bergin and Feenstra (2001) use a general equilibrium model to show that segmented markets with identical preferences cannot explain incomplete pass-through in contrast to segmented markets with different preferences. Therefore, they consider translog preferences in which the elasticity of demand varies with the price a firm sets. Corsetti and Dedola (2002) analyze market segmentation resulting from a vertical interaction between monopolistic producers and retailers. They showed that due to the presence of downstream retailers, upstream firms with monopoly power may face different demand elasticities in national markets even under symmetric constant elasticity preferences across countries. Monopolistic firms optimally set different prices to domestic and foreign dealers, and therefore the law of one price fails to hold at producer and consumer levels. In this paper we use a model which is common in the literature on pass-through effect (e.g. Goldberg, Knetter (1997), Bache (2002), Bahroumi (2006). We assume that an exporting firm has some control over its price in the importing country. Namely, it sets the price as a markup over its marginal cost. In the importing country, import price expressed in its own currency is equal to the exporting firm’s price multiplied by the exchange rate. Thus: (1) Pt F = λt CtF , (2) Pt IMP = Et Pt F = Et λt CtF , where Pt F represents export prices of a foreign country, CtF is a marginal cost of production in a foreign country, λt is a firm’s mark-up in the importing country, Et is the exchange rate, and Pt IMP stands for import prices of a home (importing) country. 5 For a more detailed discussion see for example Herzberg et al. (2003), or Bache (2007). 6 Mark-up depends on the competitive pressure from importer’s domestic production and demand pressure, Yt . Competitive pressure can be expressed as a relation between domestic prices and foreign prices in terms of importer’s currency: α Pt H (Yt H ) β (3) λt = K F Et Ct Combining (2) and (3) gives: (4) Pt IMP = K ( Et CtF ) 1−α (P ) H α t 0 < α < 1, 0 < β < 1 and K is constant. (Yt H ) β , taking natural logs (depicted in lower case) we have: (5) ptIMP = κ + (1 − α ) et + (1 − α ) ctF + α ptH + β ytH . In practice it is often difficult to obtain in the empirical study equal parameters at the exchange rate and foreign prices that usually serve as a proxy for costs in the exporting country. Bache (2002) and Barhoumi (2006) stress that exchange rates are more volatile than costs, therefore the extent to which they are passed on prices may differ. One usually starts estimations without this restriction and tests it in the next step. Thus, the estimated equation is: (6) ptIMP = α 0 + α1et + α 2 ctF + α 3 ptH + α 4 ytH + ε t . We shall proceed this way. Some authors also point that domestic demand often turns out to be statistically insignificant (see for example Bussière (2007)). The rationale for that is simple: information that is contained in the measure of demand pressure can be already incorporated in another variable, notably in domestic prices. This is why this term is frequently omitted in estimations. To verify whether it is justified to allow for the output pressure in the dynamic (short-run) equation, we have checked the correlation between the output gap measure (a difference between actual and HP-filtered GDP) and the change in domestic prices – it was quite high, namely 0.538, therefore we decided not to plug the output gap into the equation. 3.1. Estimation method and data Many studies of the pass-through effect are based on short-run dynamic equations. Such estimate has also been made for Poland (Przystupa (2002), Cholewiński (2008)). In this paper we present estimates of a long-run reaction of import prices to the exchange rate. If variables are cointegrated, as they seem to be in this case, then limiting the analysis to the short-run would reduce the information content. On the other hand, cointegration analysis requires data span that is sufficient for inferences on equilibrium levels of the variables. Our analysis covers an eleven-year period only (1997.Q1 2008.Q1). It is relatively short, which makes our conclusions somewhat risky. It needs to be stressed that estimation of asymmetry of exchange rate pass-through relies on an even smaller number of observations, since our sample must be divided into two sub-samples that reflect two different states, e.g. appreciation and depreciation or “big” and “small” changes of the exchange rate. Our results should therefore be treated as guidelines rather than sharp point estimates. 7 Taking into account the shortness of our sample and the small number of usable observations, we decided not to confine the analysis to one method only, but – whenever possible – to use more to reduce uncertainty concerning robustness of our results. Thus, in the case of import prices we use Johansen cointegration method and fully modified least squares. The latter is particularly well suited if there are problems with endogeneity and serial correlation. It is important to note that the period covered in this paper is relatively homogenous in terms of a monetary policy regime, namely inflation targeting and flexible exchange rate. This makes the estimation easier and more reliable and therefore partially offsets the drawbacks of the time span shortness. On the other hand, the EU entry in 2004 constituted a significant disturbance to the real economy. There was an increase in inflation, but also – what is more important for this study – the role of exchange rate as a variable affecting the real sector of the economy has started to change since then. Due to an increasing role of intra-company trade, the impact of the exchange rate on the aggregate demand diminished (see also Łyziak et al. (2008) and Przystupa and Wróbel (2006)6. Moreover, Poland’s foreign exchange market started to be increasingly impacted by the euro, whereas the position of the US dollar was falling. We begin our estimations with the nominal effective exchange rate, but then restrict our discussion to the import prices’ behaviour with respect to the bilateral exchange rate (EUR/PLN7). One reason is the big share of imports from the EU in the total imports (about two thirds in 2007), another is the fact that imports from the euro area consist mostly of manufactured products. Pricing to market and asymmetries in the pass-through, i.e. the issues that are in the centre of our interest, are a feature of manufacturing rather than raw materials. Since our aim is to check whether the exchange rate pass-through in Poland is linear and symmetric, we start with a linear equation and then test whether quadratic and cubic terms are lacking in the dynamic equation. Then we check whether import prices react asymmetrically to appreciations and depreciations. In the estimation we use quarterly data. They are seasonally adjusted with X11. The only exception is the nominal exchange rate, which is not adjusted since, in the case of Poland, it is not significantly affected by seasonal factors. To assess the role of PTM, we use Producer Price Index (source: Main Statistical Office (GUS)); due to the data problems till the end of 1999 it is an overall index, whereas since 2000 it comprises goods produced for the domestic market only. As shown by graph A5 in the Appendix, the overall index and the index of prices for domestic market started to diverge mostly in 2004, thus we assume that this should not significantly influence our results. As a proxy for foreign prices we use euro area export prices (source: Eurostat). We do not employ unit export values of Poland’s main trading partners. Silver (2007) points that unit export values can be substantially biased in representing export and import prices. Import price data come from GUS, whereas nominal exchange rate (quarterly average) - from the National Bank of Poland. All data are in logs, the base year for price indices is 2000. As it is clear from table A9 foreign and domestic prices as well as the exchange rate are non stationary. One may have some doubts whether import prices are stationary. ADF test shows that seasonally adjusted data with an intercept can be considered as I(0), whereas raw data are 6 The authors show changes in the exchange rate regime and the role of the exchange rate in the monetary transmission. 7 Upside movement of the exchange rate means appreciation. 8 rather non-stationary. Johansen test (Table A5 – A7) indicates that there is one cointegrating relation, therefore we treat import prices as an I(1) variable8. 3.2. Estimation results As we have mentioned above, there is one cointegrating equation of import prices, domestic prices, foreign prices and the exchange rate. Both nominal effective exchange rate (NEER) and the bilateral exchange rate give the cointegration. The cointegrating vector is presented in tables A8 and A9. We start estimates with the unrestricted vector – all variables have a proper sign. Contrary to domestic prices, foreign prices are not significant. Significance of domestic prices means that there is pricing to market behaviour in the long run. The long-run exchange rate pass-through is 0.91 for the nominal effective exchange rate and 0.71 for the bilateral exchange rate. Now we pass to the restricted version of the cointegrating relation. First we check whether the coefficients at NEER (or the bilateral exchange rate) and coefficients at foreign prices are equal. In both cases a Chi-square test shows that we cannot reject this hypothesis. In the restricted version the pass-through is approximately 0.8 for both NEER and the bilateral exchange rate. All variables are statistically significant, and the significance of domestic prices implies the existence of a pricing to market effect. Next, we check whether the passthrough effect is full. This hypothesis is not rejected at the 1% level for the bilateral exchange rate but rejected for the nominal effective exchange rate. Neither the restriction α1 = α 2 = 1, α 3 =0 (the law of one price) nor the restrictions α1 = α 2 , α 2 + α 3 =1 (unit homogeneity) and α1 = α 2 =1 (unit coefficients on the exchange rate and foreign prices) for the bilateral exchange rate can be rejected at the 1% level. For the nominal effective exchange rate only the law of one price cannot be rejected at the 1% level. All these restrictions, with exception of the law of one price for the bilateral exchange rate are rejected at 5% significance level; this however can be rejected at the 10% level. All in all, we conclude that while for the nominal effective exchange rate the results seem quite clear, for the EUR/PLN exchange rate we need a cross-check. To have a clearer picture we estimate the model with FMLS and then impose the same set of restrictions. Table A9 (right hand panel) shows that, with the exception of foreign prices, in the unrestricted cointegrating vector all parameters are statistically significant, and all coefficients obtained with these two methods are similar. The point estimate of long-run passthrough is 0.68. Data show that there is long-run pricing to market. As previously, restriction α1 = α 2 cannot be rejected. Once again, all parameters are statistically significant. Contrary to the results obtained with the Johansen method, all remaining restrictions are rejected at the 1% level of significance. To sum up this part of our estimates, we can safely say that the long-run pass-through for both the nominal effective exchange rate and the bilateral exchange rate lies within the range of 0.7-0.8, and that there is equality of the coefficients of the exchange rate and foreign prices. There is no strong support in the data for the existence of the law of one price, unit long-run coefficients on the exchange rate and foreign prices, and long-run unit homogeneity in 8 Hjalmarsson and Österholm (2007) show that Johansen’s trace test and maximum eigenvalue test may bring erroneous results under the situation of nearly integrated variables. They suggest performing additional test which relies on a system of restrictions imposed on the cointegrating vector. We have performed this test and do not reject the hypothesis that the variables are cointegrated in the long run. 9 domestic and foreign prices. A final step in the cointegration analysis is the test of exogeneity. All tested variables - exchange rate, foreign prices and domestic prices - seem to be weakly exogenous. (Table A10). Exchange rate is strongly exogenous, but domestic producer prices are not9. Then we estimate a dynamic equation for import prices using cointegrating vector obtained from the FMLS, namely: 4 4 4 4 i =0 i =0 i =0 i =1 (7) ∆ptIMP = β 0 + β1 ECt −1 + ∑ β 2,i ∆et −i + ∑ β 3,i ∆ptF−i + ∑ β 4,i ∆ptH−i + ∑ β 5,i ∆ptIMP − i + vt , where EC is the error correction term and ∆ stands for the first difference of a variable. After elimination of statistically insignificant parameters we get the following results (Table A11): instantaneous pass-through is 0.51 – much lower than in the long run, there is weaker evidence of pricing to market in the short run than in the long-run. On the other hand, the error correction works quite efficiently: 46% of disequilibrium is eliminated within one quarter. To check whether import prices react in a non-linear way to the exchange rate we perform a test similar to the Ramsey’s RESET test, but with the Taylor expansion for the non-linear function10. It should reveal whether our equation lacks square or cubic terms. There is no strong evidence of the lacking square terms (Statistic F(1.39) =0.267 sign. level 0.61, LM(1)=0.299 sign. level 0.58). However, it is possible that there is a very weak cubic nonlinearity (F(2,38) =2.001 sign. level 0.15, LM(2)=4.19 sign. level 0.12). Our next step is to examine how changes in the exchange rate are transmitted to the import prices in the periods of appreciation and depreciation of the Polish currency. Thus we set: At = { 1 if ∆ e t ≺ 0 0 otherwise and Dt = { 1 if ∆ e t 0 0 otherwise and in equation (7) we replace ∆et with β1A ( At ∆et ) + β1D ( Dt ∆et ) and estimate separately the equation for the appreciation and depreciation of the exchange rate. The results are reproduced in tables A12 and A13. If there is appreciation of the Polish currency with respect to the euro the correcting mechanism is very efficient: 65% of disequilibrium is eliminated within one quarter. There is pricing to market, which means that exporters in the euro zone do not increase mark-ups, but rather care about future market share. The effect of the instantaneous pass-through is 0.55, but it is estimated with a low T-statistic. A different picture emerges for the depreciation periods: Neither pricing to market nor error correction mechanism seems to operate. The only factor affecting import prices is the exchange rate. The pass-through effect is 0.599. We could not reject the hypothesis that passthrough in depreciations and appreciations is equal. We tentatively conclude therefore, that there is no asymmetry in import prices’ reaction to the exchange rate. Pricing to market manifests itself in periods of appreciations of the domestic currency only. When exporters’ currency appreciates the exporters do not tend to lower their mark-ups. What can be the reason for such asymmetry? There are at least three, seemingly consistent, arguments. First, exporters expect appreciation rather than depreciation of the Polish zloty with respect to the 9 We do reproduce the results of Granger causality here. The same test is used in Herzberg et al. (2003) 10 10 euro and treat depreciations as short-lived and therefore are not afraid of losing market share. Second, prices are rigid downwards, exporters therefore are not eager to adjust them if their currency appreciates. Third, if exporters do not increase their mark-ups in favourable conditions, then they would incur losses if they decided to lower them in a case of the appreciation of their currency. We have also checked how pass-through works in two additional cases: a positive and a negative sign of the error correction term. The former means that import prices are higher than the equilibrium level determined by exporters’ prices and domestic prices due to, for example, too high transportation costs, inclusion of other costs in the price (like insurance or hedging costs), or misperceived intensity of competition. If this is the case, a process of return to the equilibrium relies mostly on exchange rate adjustment. There is also statistically significant pricing to market behaviour, but its impact is very limited. Depreciation of the domestic currency exchange rate is a factor that increases other prices (domestic prices). Pricing to market is small probably because in this case importers can involve only a small part of transportation and distribution costs in their prices. If import prices are lower than the equilibrium level, then the error correcting mechanism works quickly and efficiently eliminating 65% of the disequilibrium in one quarter; there is also a statistically significant and relatively big impact of pricing to market, which means that distribution and transportation costs may be overpriced. 4. Exchange rate pass-through models based on the Phillips curve. In this chapter we examine a hybrid New-Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) model. In the hybrid NKPC for an open economy inflation is a function of three factors: (i) next period’s expected inflation rate ( Etπ t +1 ) extended by the empirically observed persistence of inflation (backward looking inflation π t −1 ) – e.g. Fuhrer and Moore (1995); (ii) real marginal costs approximated by the output gap ( yt ) – e.g. Woodford (2003); (iii) real exchange rate – contemporaneous ( etr ) and expected ( Et etr+1 ) – e.g. Woodford (2003). Accepting the NKPC, we agree that behaviour of inflation depends on the slope of the Phillips curve. If the Phillips curve is linear, the slope is constant. . If it is non-linear, the slope is not constant and behaviour of inflation is a function of the output gap and the exchange rate. On the other hand, steepness of the slope of the Phillips curve depends on the determination whether the function is convex or concave. Filardo (1998) finds that the Phillips curve is not purely convex or concave and that convexity or concavity is determined by the output gap. If the output gap is positive, the Phillips curve is convex (firms are more inclined to raise prices than to lower them, but the cost of fighting inflation is falling – the slope of the Philips curve steeping) and if the output gap is negative, the Phillips curve is concave (firms are more reluctant to raise prices than to lower them, but the cost of fighting inflation is rising – the slope is flatting). In this chapter we investigate the possibility of non-linear reaction of inflation to the exchange rate changes along the business cycle. 11 4.1. Estimation methods As we have mentioned in the Introduction, the exchange rate pass-through to consumer prices in Poland seems to be relatively high (about 0.2), akin to that of the developed countries in the eighties of the last century. In such circumstances it is of key importance for the monetary policy to know whether the process is linear and symmetric. We check pass-through linearity with respect to (i) business cycle approximated by the output gap, (ii) appreciations and depreciations of the nominal effective exchange rate of the zloty, (iii) volatility of the nominal effective exchange rate and (iv) inflation environment. We distinguish two states (regimes) for any economic process. The output gap, NEER and inflation are set up as the variables which cause a transition from one regime to another. We use two methods to divide the sample into properly defined sub-samples. The first one splits the sample into classes, depending on the observation whether a given variable exceeds some threshold. If all explanatory variables are exogenous then Threshold AutoRegresive (TAR) models can approximate a nonlinear autoregressive structure, where the number of regimes is small – see Tong (1990) or Hansen (2000). Caner and Hansen (2004) develop an estimator which can be used for models with the endogenous variables and an exogenous threshold variable. This allows estimation of thresholds for dynamic models. Basing on the procedure and a program described in Caner and Hansen (2004) we estimate a SETAR (SelfExciting Threshold AutoRegresive) model of a general form: Yt + θ 0 + θ1Yt −1 + … + θ pYt − p + I (Yt − d ≤ τ )(φ0 + φ1Yt −1 + … + φqYt − q ) = ε t where: Y – vector of explanatory variables; d=1 and 0 ≤ q ≤ p ; εt – white noise; τ ∈Τ - threshold parameter: I(y ≤τ ) = { 1 if y ≤τ 0 otherwise Usually the threshold value is unknown and has to be estimated. Estimation of the threshold with the ML method needs to determine the maximum of the likelihood function, whereas the estimation of the threshold with the TSLS or GMM method – to minimize the sum of the squared residuals. Our sample consists of 46 observations and due to their small number we assume that the threshold should split the data into sub-samples with minimum 15 observations. Franses and van Dijk (1999) show that a safe choice is min. 15% of observations in the sub-sample. In order to estimate threshold values we use four specifications of the threshold model (based on the Phillips curve), differing basically by the variables used as the threshold for the passthrough: output gap, NEER, NEER volatility and inflation environment. The second method refers to Wolffram’s (1971) idea, developed further by Houck (1977), for investigating nonreversibility of the linear functions through segmenting the variables involved. 12 Let us assume the variable Y depends on the values of X being suspected for asymmetry, and on the set of other variables Z. We want to examine whether one-unit increases of X from period to period have a different impact on Y than one-unit decreases of X: ∆ Yi = a 0 + T1 ∑a 1, j ∆X j=0 ' i− j + T2 ∑a 2, j j=0 ∆ X i' '− j + a 3 Z i where for i = 1,2,…,t : ∆Yi = Yi − Yi −1 ∆ X i' = X i − X i −1 if Xi > Xi-1 and = 0 otherwise; ∆ X i'' = X i − X i −1 j = 1,2,…,T1,T2; if Xi < Xi-1 and = 0 otherwise; T1,T2 < t (j – number of lags assigned to ∆X i' , ∆X i'' ). A nonreversibility of the function ∆Yi occurs, i.e. the reaction is asymmetric, if T1 ∑ a1, j ≠ j =0 T2 ∑a j =0 2, j Both methods divide the sample into different sub-samples with different economic interpretation. Output gap, suspected of the asymmetric impact, can serve as an example (Figure 1). Figure 1. The economic interpretation of the threshold model and model based on nonreversibility of the linear functions 3 Nonreversible linear models Nonreversible linear models t1≤t0 t1>t0 2 EU accession 1 Threshold models Threshold models % 0 Threshold models Russian crisis -1 -2 19 97 Q 1 19 97 Q 3 19 98 Q 1 19 98 Q 3 19 99 Q 1 19 99 Q 3 20 00 Q 1 20 00 Q 3 20 01 Q 1 20 01 Q 3 20 02 Q 1 20 02 Q 3 20 03 Q 1 20 03 Q 3 20 04 Q 1 20 04 Q 3 20 05 Q 1 20 05 Q 3 20 06 Q 1 20 06 Q 3 20 07 Q 1 20 07 Q 3 20 08 Q 1 20 08 Q 3 -3 output gap threshold Source: Authors` calculations. 13 proxy of the business cycle The output gap was calculated as a percentage deviation of the actual GDP from a potential11. Assuming that the output gap is a proxy for the economic activity along the business cycle, its values exceeding the estimated threshold can be interpreted as periods of prosperity (late expansion, peak and early recession), whereas the values below the threshold – as a slump (late recession, trough and early expansion). The threshold estimated for the output gap identifies 25 periods of prosperity and 21 periods of slump (Figure 1). The sub-sample derived from the nonreversibility of the linear function, for ti+1>ti, points out periods of expansion or recovery (early expansion, late expansion and peak), while the subsample for ti+1≤ti describes periods of contraction or recession (early recession, late recession and trough). This method identifies 24 periods of expansion and 22 periods of contraction. The total sample contains 46 observations between 1q 1997 and 2q 2008 and seems to cover one and a half business cycles and two exogenous shocks: “the Russian crisis” in 1998 and Poland’s accession to the EU (2004)12. The exchange rate pass-through to the CPI was estimated on the basis of the Philips curve similar to the one in a highly aggregated New-Keynesian model developed at the National Bank of Poland for inflation forecasting (see Kłos et al., 2005). The model was built on the standard assumptions of sticky prices and wages. Basic macroeconomic relationships include: the IS curve, uncovered interest parity (UIP) and the Phillips curve13. The shape of the Phillips curve used to estimate the pass-through effect is as follows: π tq,k = α1,qk Etπ t +1 + (1 − α1,qk − α 2,q k )π t −1 + α 2,q k (∆etr−1 ) + α3,q k yt −2 + ε t i i i i i i where π stands for inflation (CPI), qi is a threshold variable (i=1…4); i=1 → output gap (y); i=2 → ∆ nominal effective exchange rate (∆e); i=3 → volatility of the nominal effective exchange rate (s); i=4 → inflation (π): actual inflation – inflation target (τ); k=1,2; k=1 for qi > τ (τ = threshold); k=2 for qi ≤ τ and er is a nominal effective exchange rate plus foreign inflation. We estimate the Phillips curve using the GMM method. The instrumental variables were derived from a set of variables explaining behaviour of the exchange rate of the zloty (see the recalled NBP model). Nominal effective exchange rate and the output gap were also included. Such procedure allows for relationships among the variables as in the model of inflation. The instrumental variables were chosen in the manner assuring proper sign at all explanatory 11 As before, potential GDP was derived from the Hodrick-Prescott filter with λ=1600. To diminish the role of the last observations, the sample was lengthen by an AR(1) process. 12 The approximate date of Poland’s accession to the EU was known since 2002 but the reaction of the economy was hardly predictable – therefore it can be treated as a shock. 13 The output gap in the model depends on its lagged value, the ex-ante real interest rate, the real effective exchange rate and the external demand. NEER is determined — in line with the arbitrage condition — as a function of the USD/PLN exchange rate and the EUR/USD cross rate (exogenous variable), while the USD/PLN exchange rate is modelled within the concept of the UIP. The explanatory variables of the USD/PLN exchange rate are the lagged value of this variable, the interest rate disparity, the term structure of interest rates, the EUR/USD cross rate and risk factors. The list of risk factors includes the output gap, budget deficit, net exports, current account deficit and foreign direct investment. 14 variables, correct value of the t-statistic and p-value of the J-statistic. Finally, we estimate 16 equations with the threshold and the nonreversibility method. All details are presented in table A15 in the Appendix. When interpreting the results, one must bear in mind a small number of observations used in the estimation. 4.2. Estimation results. The results seem to be consistent with these obtained by Mann (1986), Goldberg (1995), Goldfajn and Verlang (2000), and Correa and Minella (2006). They are presented in Table 1 and Figure 2. Table 1. The asymmetry of the exchange rate pass-through to the consumer prices Asymmetry of the exchange rate passthrough to CPI related to: Threshold models (τ = threshold) variable > τ τ = 0.24% Output gap (y) 0.192 ∆ nominal effective exchange rate (∆e) Volatility of the nominal effective exchange rate (s) Inflation (π) variable ≤ τ 0.179 τ = 2.08% 0.065 0.239 τ = 4.32% 0.247 0.549 τ = level of official inflation target 0.195 0.201 Pass-through (general) Nonreversible linear models t1 > t0 t1 ≤ t0 0.274 0.091 0.018 0.238 0.139 0.141 0.160 0.183 0.229 Source: Authors’ estimation. The threshold for the output gap shows a slight deviation from zero (0.24) suggesting a small inefficiency of the monetary policy, particularly during prosperity. In that period, a smaller role of output gap in the explanation of inflation is combined with the bigger role of inflation expectations. The respective coefficients are 0.14 and 0.71, compared to 0.22 and 0.49 during the slump (table A16). It may reflect an increasing power of employees in wage negotiations during prosperity, resulting in a higher propensity of producers to price increases. It is directly transferred to consumers` expectations, which become more and more forward-looking. The Wald test shows no statistically significant differences in the exchange rate pass-through between the periods of prosperity and the periods of slump. However, there is a huge difference in the pass-through effects between the periods of expansion (0.27) and contraction (recession): 0.09. Combination of these two findings would suggest that the pass-through effect may even exceed 0.30 in the inflexion point between early and late expansion Then it drops to 0.19-0.21 in the peak and to around zero in the inflexion point between early and late recession. During the late recession and the trough it is growing up to 0.19-0.21 and exceeds 0.30 in the early expansion. This is coherent with the behaviour of enterprises in the business cycle, 15 conditioning their investment decisions on expected profits with a maximum in the early expansion and a minimum in the early recession (see, e.g. Kalecki (1943) or Mankiw (2006). The enterprises’ propensity to change prices follows profit expectations. On the other hand, there is a strong asymmetric reaction in the periods of appreciations and depreciations. If the zloty appreciates (or, according to the threshold model, the appreciation rate is over 2%), the pass-through to the consumer prices declines and varies from 0.02 to 0.07. During the depreciations or slight appreciations (below 2%) and depreciations, the passthrough effect equals 0.24. Figure 2. The cross-reaction of the asymmetric shocks of the output gap and the nominal effective exchange rate. 3 After huge rise of the NBP's reference rate it was consecutively cut by 9 pct. points during one year. That rised market expectations for another changes of the interest rates and resulted in considerable appreciation of zloty, amplified by the drop of the share of net exports in GDP to -2.5% in 2002. Att.: floating exchange rate was introduced in April 2000. 2 1 Effects of over-heating. Plus drop of the risk premium after The EU accession. 19 97 Q 19 1 97 Q 19 3 98 Q 19 1 98 Q 19 3 99 Q 19 1 99 Q 20 3 00 Q 20 1 00 Q 20 3 01 Q 20 1 01 Q 20 3 02 Q 20 1 02 Q 20 3 03 Q 20 1 03 Q 20 3 04 Q 20 1 04 Q 20 3 05 Q 20 1 05 Q 20 3 06 Q 20 1 06 Q 20 3 07 Q 20 1 07 Q 20 3 08 Q 20 1 08 Q 3 0 -1 -2 -3 Recovery after the "Russian" crisis: low dynamics of exports combined with high growth of imports (share of the net export in the GDP rises to -6,5% in 2000) resulted in increase of the risk premium for the Polish zloty. Plus rise of the NBP's reference rate by 6 pct. points to combat inflation. The EU pre-accession shock:expected rise of prices caused high increase of demand resulted in over-reaction of supply. Increasing uncertainty involved a slight depreciation of zloty. High pass-through (over 0.25) Average pass-through Low pass-through (below 0.05) Source: Authors’ estimations. Combining the pass-through effect over the business cycle and during appreciations and depreciations we can define periods of low and high pass-through,. There is low pass-through if appreciation and contraction occur simultaneously. The high pass-through is characteristic for periods of a simultaneous occurrence of expansion and depreciation. However, the probability that such phenomenon takes place over the business cycle is relatively low. , Examining the data for Poland, we find two periods of high and low pass-through (Figure 2). The first one occurred in 1998, when the Russian economy contracted due to a severe financial crisis which burst out in this country in the last quarter of 1997. Poland, being in the ascending phase of the business cycle, was therefore affected by a negative external shock. During the fall of the GDP growth rate, the pass-through remained at an average level. The coincidence of a faster growth and the depreciation, i.e. the high pass-through, occurred just after the shock and lasted about four quarters. The rapid recovery was followed by a 16 slowdown and the appreciation of the zloty induced by the market expectations for successive cuts in the interest rates. The period of the low pass-through effect lasted about 7 quarters and ended up together with the slowdown of the exchange rate appreciation. The second episode of such a coincidence occurred before Poland’s accession to the EU. The “ordinary” recovery was accelerated by the external positive shock. An excessive rise in demand resulted in an over-reaction of supply. Increasing uncertainty together with a diminishing interest rates disparity involved a slight depreciation of the zloty. The period of high pass-through effect lasted from the 2q 2003 until the 1q 2004 (Poland joined the EU in May 2004). It was followed, similarly to the first episode, by a period of a low pass-through, lasting till the 1q of 2005. This can suggest that episodes of high and low pass-through occur together and immediately after an exogenous shock. Seemingly, it does not matter whether the shock is positive or negative. The average volatility of the Polish zloty calculated for each quarter between 1997 and 2008 as a standard deviation of the daily data is equal to 7.1%, and varies from 2.8% in 2007 to over 10% in 2003 and 2004 (Figure 3). The threshold value for the volatility of the nominal effective exchange rate of the zloty was estimated at the level of 4.3%, with 29 observations over the threshold and 17 below. The pass-through effect seems to be strongly asymmetric: for the volatility over 4.3% it is equal to 0.25 and 0.55 otherwise. The lower pass-through in the case of higher volatility can reflect the producers’ reluctance to frequent price changes due to the menu costs. These results are consistent with Pollard and Coughlin (2003) or Correa and Minella (2006).14 Generally, the periods of high volatility of the zloty are simultaneously these of high pass-through; hence they do not raise the total effect. Figure 3. History of the Polish zloty exchange rate 14 crowling peg to the currency basket 12 5,00 crowling peg to the currency basket + crowling band (from +/7% in 1995 to +/-15% in 1999) floating exchange rate 4,50 4,00 10 3,00 EU accession 2,50 2,00 PLN/USD 6 fixed exchange rate in % 8 3,50 1,50 4 1,00 2 0,50 0,00 9 20 07 -1 231 20 08 -1 031 1 1 1 0 20 06 -1 22 20 05 -1 23 20 04 -1 23 20 03 -1 23 1 9 1 PLN/EUR volatility 20 02 -1 23 20 01 -1 23 20 00 -1 22 1 USD/EUR volatility 19 99 -1 23 1 1 19 98 -1 23 19 97 -1 23 9 PLN/USD volatility 19 96 -1 23 1 0 19 95 -1 22 19 94 -1 23 19 93 -1 23 19 9 19 09 01 19 0-1 -04 91 2-3 19 12- 1 92 31 -1 231 0 PLN/USD exchange rate (right scale) Source: NBP data. Authors’ calculation. Examining the role of the inflation environment in the exchange rate pass-through we do not estimate the threshold – it was set up at the level of the NBP inflation target. For the 14 However Correa and Minella got different results for appreciations and depreciations. 17 nonreversible linear function models the sample was divided according to the ascending or descending periods of inflation. The results are not clear – the Wald test on the lack of asymmetry produces p-value at the level around 10%. Hence we decided to reject the hypothesis of asymmetric reaction. 5. Conclusions for the monetary policy. In the paper we do an ‘exchange rate pass-through exercise’ on the Polish data, so the results can be country-specific. We find no evidence of a non-linear reaction of import prices with respect to the exchange rate changes. Due to the market imperfections asymmetry arises in the domestic links of the distribution chain. Our estimations of the consumer prices’ reaction show that the exchange rate pass-through tends to vary alongside business cycle. It is relatively small during contractions and high during expansions. It also differs for changes in the nominal effective exchange rate below and above a threshold level, which is about 2 percent. In periods of increased exchange rate volatility, the pass-through effect becomes lower and tends to rise in the time of lower volatility. Defining periods of the high and low pass-through effect (as a combination of the passthrough over the business cycle and during appreciations and depreciations) we find that the high pass-through occurs together with exogenous shocks and the low pass-through immediately after such shocks, no matter if they are positive or negative. Hence, during the “ordinary” economic fluctuations, monetary policy faces average level of the pass-through rather than an asymmetric one. The Polish example shows that even if there is some evidence of asymmetries with respect to, say, the output gap and appreciations and depreciations, to have a proper overview of its potential impact on the monetary policy, all sources of possible asymmetries should be considered. 18 Statistical Appendix Table A1: Exchange rate pass-through. Estimation based on the McCarthy’s SVAR. Pass-through effect 2 quarters after → for ↓ 4 quarters 8 quarters Est.02 Est.08 Est.02 Est.08 Est.02 Est.08 Import transaction prices (PM) 0.51 0.50 0.69 0.65 0.79 0.73 Price index of the sold production of industry (PPI) 0.27 0.24 0.50 0.44 0.59 0.51 Consumption price index (CPI) 0.17 0.11 0.36 0.19 0.42 0.21 Source: Authors’ calculations Table A2: Time decomposition of the pass-through effect. Time decomposition of the passthrough effect for ↓ (total P-T=100) Import transaction prices (PM) Q0 Quarter after shock Q1 Q2 Q3 17 49 25 4 5 Price index of the sold production of industry (PPI) 12 35 29 10 14 Consumption price index (CPI) 10 42 31 7 10 Q4 to Q8 Source: Authors’ calculations Table A3. Exchange rate pass-through for Poland. Period of estimation Method applied 1998-2008 VAR/VECM Przystupa,Wróbel 1991-2004 Ca’Zorzi et al. 1999-2004 Korhonen, and Wachtel 1998-2008 Model based on the Phillips curve Przystupa and Wróbel Model NSA used at NBP 1990-1999 One-equation models Campa and Goldberg 1998-2008 Exchange rate pass-through to: Import prices Consumer prices Short-term Long- term Short- term Long- term 0.81 ~ 0.70 1.30 ~ 0.25 0.56 0.09 0.09 0.22 0.27 0.50 0.99 19 Table A4: Exchange rate pass-through. Period of estimation Method used Euro zone 1990-2002 VAR/VECM Faruqee 1983-2004 Ca’Zorzi et al. Pass-through effect for: Import prices Consumer prices After 2 q After 8 q After 2 q After 8 q 0.42 1.17 0.01 0.02 0.55 0.72 0.06 0.13 0.66 0.81 Single eq. model 1990-2004 Campa et al. Structural model DIT countries 1971-1983 1984-2004 USA 1990-2002 Gagnon and Ihrig VAR/VECM Faruqee 1983-2004 Ca’Zorzi et al. 0.18 0.03 0.15 0.30 0.21 0.38 0.26 0.41 0.01 0.02 Single eq. model 1990-2004 Campa et al. Table A5. Unit root test (ADF) Variable, in logs, nsa Trend and intercept, statistic, p-values in ( ) -2.450 (0.350) ptIMP -2.941 (0.160) ptH t- Intercept, t-statistic, p-values in ( ) -2.36 (0.158) -1.386 (0.580) ptF -2.237 (0.458) 0.754 (0.992) et -1.525 (0.806) -1.750 (0.400) ptIMP -0.983 (0.936) Trend and intercept, statistic, p-values in ( ) -2.640 (0.266) ptH -3.085 (0.122) -1.607 (0.720) ptF -2.756 (0.221) 0.275 (0.974) e NEER t Variable, in logs, sa 20 -0.524 (0.877) t- Intercept, t-statistic, p-values in ( ) -2.699 (0.082) Table A6. Johansen cointegration test - trace statistics (NEER) Hypothesized no of ce(s) None At most 1 At most 2 At most 3 Eigenvalue Trace statistics 0.493755 0.317904 0.207372 0.103637 60.42062 31.14904 14.69788 4.704618 0.05 critical value 54.07904 35.19275 20.26184 9.164546 Probability 0.0219 0.1009 0.5615 0.5125 Table A7. Johansen cointegration test - trace statistics (bilateral exchange rate) Hypothesized no Eigenvalue Trace statistics 0.05 critical Probability of ce(s) value None 0.457465 57.91189 54.07904 0.0219 At most 1 0.399639 32.22877 35.19275 0.1009 At most 2 0.161961 10.79939 20.26184 0.5615 At most 3 0.077288 3.378395 9.164546 0.5125 Table A8. Cointergating vector - NEER VECM (cointegration Johansen), t-stat in [ ] unrestricted α1 α2 α3 1.44 [2.21] 0.95 [5.19] restricted: α1 = α 2 Chi-square=0.56, p. 0.45 α1 α2 α3 -0.81 0.81 [7.50] 1.13 [17.65] restricted: α1 = α 2 = 1 Chi-square=9.64, p. 0.008 restricted: α1 = α 2 = 1, α 3 =0 Chi-square=11.1, p. 0.011 restricted: α1 = α 2 , α 2 + α 3 =1 Chi-square=10.21, p. 0.006 -0.91 21 [5.92] [7.50] Table A9. Cointegrating vector, bilateral exchange rate EUR/PLN VECM (cointegration Fully modified least squares Johansen), t-stat in [ ] t-stat in [ ] unrestricted -0.71 [2.47] 0.68 [4.73] α1 α2 α3 0.41 [0.35] 0.74 [1.09] 0.83 [2.27] 0.82 [4.14] restricted: α1 = α 2 Chi-square=0.03, p. 0.86 Chi-square=0.018, p. 0.91 α1 α2 α3 -0.78 0.67 [7.15] restricted: α1 = α 2 =1 Chi-square=7.24, p. 0.026 Chi-square=12.46, p. 0.002 restricted: α1 = α 2 = 1, α 3 =0 Chi-square=7.49, p. 0.058 Chi-square=260, p. 0.000 restricted: α1 = α 2 , α 2 + α 3 =1 Chi-square=6.87, p. 0.032 Chi-square=40.0, p. 0.000 [5.28] 0.78 [5.28] 0.67 [7.15] 0.71 [7.22] 0.84 [15.29] Table A10. Test of weak exogeneity Variable Chi-square (1) H 2.49 p e 0.011 H 2.67 p Table A11. Dynamic import price equation Variable Coefficient 0.0011 β0 Probability 0.11 0.92 0.102 t-stat 0.16 β1 β 2,0 -0.464 -3.02 0.51 3.94 β 4,0 0.898 1.82 Table A12. Dynamic import price equation: appreciation of the EUR/PLN, usable obs.: 24. Variable Coefficient t-stat, p-value in ( ) A -0.0023 -0.16 (0.874) β0 β1A -0.654 -2.96 (0.008) A β 2,0 0.55 1.58 (0.131) A β 4,0 1.29 1.8 (0.091) 22 Table A13. Dynamic import price equation: depreciation of the EUR/PLN, usable obs.: 20 Variable Coefficient t-stat D -0.0055 -0.39 β0 β1D -0.225 -1.03 D β 2,0 0.599 2.07 D β 4,0 0.77 1.12 Table A14. Dynamic import price equation: positive EC , usable obs.: 21. Variable Coefficient t-stat EC + 0.00183 0.08 β0 β1EC + -0.31 -0.63 EC + β 2,0 0.66 4.27 EC + β 4,0 0.003 0.0031 Table A15. Dynamic import price equation: negative EC , usable obs.: 23. Variable Coefficient t-stat EC − -0.019 -1.62 β0 β1EC − -0.65 -2.01 EC − β 2,0 0.16 0.82 EC − β 4,0 2.0 3.39 23 Table A16. Phillips curve π tq,k = α1,qk Etπ t +1 + (1 − α1,qk − α2,q k )π t −1 + α2,q k (∆etr−1 ) + α3,q k yt −2 + ε t i i i i i Coefficients α1 qi > τ 1-α1- α2 α2 α3 Threshold models (τ = threshold) i No. of obs. after adj. p-value of J-statistic 0.708 (7.16) 0.484 -0.192 (2.50) 0.138 (1.81) 22 0.59 0.497 (4.80) 0.476 (3.98) 0.682 -0.179 (2.43) -0.065 (5.19) 0.219 (1.79) 0.318 (2.79) 19 0.64 21 0.19 0.450 (3.26) 0.931 (2.32) 0.789 -0.239 (3.24) -0.247 (2.63) 0.236 (2.67) 0.271 (1.75) 19 0.99 25 0.23 0.611 (3.76) 0.700 (2.88) 0.938 -0.549 (2.56) -0.195 (3.17) 0.548 (1.81) 0.425 (2.08) 15 0.68 15 0.37 0.738 (8.01) 0.463 -0.201 (1.98) 0.064 (1.74) 26 0.46 Output gap qi ≤ τ qi > τ 0.589 ∆NEER qi ≤ τ qi > τ Volatility NEER qi ≤ τ qi > τ 0.316 0.495 Inflation qi ≤ τ Nonreversible linear models ti+1 > ti 0.568 (2.30) 0.706 -0.274 (1.96) 0.563 (2.11) 21 0.44 0.499 (3.78) 0.577 (3.73) 0.562 -0.091 (1.88) -0.018 (1.63) 0.306 (1.82) 0.543 (1.68) 20 0.52 21 0.29 0.389 (1.73) 0.576 (5.21) 0.849 -0.238 (1.69) -0.140 (2.36) 0.151 (1.61) 0.132 (1.68) 19 0.98 20 0.21 0.619 (3.34) 0.922 (2.78) 0.522 -0.141 (2.17) -0.160 (1.72) 0.359 (1.90) 0.287 (1.98) 21 0.99 21 0.61 0.949 (5.17) 0.417 -0.183 (1.87) 0.262 (1.63) 20 0.27 Output gap ti+1 ≤ ti ti+1 > ti 0.441 ∆NEER ti+1 ≤ ti ti+1 > ti Volatility NEER ti+1 ≤ ti ti+1 > ti 0.564 0.238 Inflation ti+1 ≤ ti 24 Figure A1. Import prices (year 2000=100), overall PPI and PPI for the domestic market (year 2000=100), bilateral exchange rate, foreign prices (deflator of euro area export prices of manufacturing, year 2000=100). 140 130 130 120 120 110 110 100 100 90 90 80 80 70 70 97 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 98 99 00 01 02 PPI Import prices .29 110 .28 108 .27 106 .26 104 .25 03 04 05 06 07 PPI_domestic 102 .24 100 .23 98 .22 96 .21 94 .20 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 97 07 98 99 00 01 Exchange rate(EUR/PLN) 02 03 04 05 06 07 Foreign prices .03 -1.0 .02 -1.1 .01 -1.2 .00 -1.3 -.01 -1.4 -.02 -1.5 -.03 -1.6 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 97 Output gap 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 Nominal effective exchange rate 25 07 08 References Alvarez R., Jaramillo P., and Selaive J. (2008). ‘Exchange rate pass-through into import prices: The case of Chile’, Working Paper No. 465, Central Bank of Chile, www.bcentral.cl/eng/studies/working-papers/465.htm. Anderton B. (2003). ‘Extra-euro area manufacturing import prices and exchange rate passthrough’ ECB Working Paper No. 219, Frankfurt, European Central Bank, www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp.219.pdf. Bache I., W. (2002). ‘Empirical Modelling of Norwegian Import Prices’, Working Paper No. 1, Norges Bank, http://www.norgesbank.no/upload/import/publikasjoner/arbeidsnotater/pdf/arb-2002-01.pdf. Bache I., W. (2007). ‘Econometrics of Exchange rate Pass-Through’, Doctoral Dissertations in Economics No. 6, Norges Bank. www.norgesbank.no/upload/63207/bache_doctoral_dissertation.pdf. Bailliu J., and Fujii E. (2004). ‘Exchange Rate Pass-through and the Inflation Environment in Industrialized Countries: An Empirical Investigation’, Working Paper No. 2004-21, Bank of Canada, www.bank-banque-canada.ca/en/res/wp/2004/wp04-21.pdf. Barhoumi K. (2006). ‘Differences in long run exchange rate pass-through into import prices in developing countries: An empirical investigation’, Economic Modelling, 23, pp. 926-951. Bergin P. R., and Feenstra R. C. (2001). ‘Pricing-to-market, staggered contracts, and real exchange rate persistence’, Journal of International Economics, 54, pp.333-359. Bussière M. (2007). ‘Exchange rate pass-through to trade prices. The role of non-linearities and asymmetries’, ECB Working Paper No. 822, Frankfurt, European Central Bank, http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp.822.pdf. Campa J. M. and Goldberg L. S. (2002). ‘Exchange Rate Pass-Through into Import Prices: A Macro or Micro Phenomenon?’, NBER Working Paper No. 8934, Cambridge, MA: NBER, http://www.nber.org/papers/w8934. Campa J. M., Goldberg L. S., and Gonzalez-Minguez J.M. (2005). ‘Exchange rate PassThrough to Import Prices in the Euro Area’, NBER Working Paper No. 11632, Cambridge, MA: NBER, http://www.nber.org/papers/w11632. Campa J. M., Gonzalez-Minguez J.M., and Sebastiá-Barriel M. (2006). ‘Non-linear adjustment of import prices in the European Union’ Documentos de Trabajo No. 0635, Banco de España, www.bde.es/informes/be/docs/dt0635e.pdf. Caner M., and Hansen B. E. (2004). ‘Instrumental variable estimation of a threshold model’, Econometric Theory, 20, pp. 813-843. 26 Ca`Zorzi M., Hahn E., and Sanchez M. (2007). ‘Exchange rate pass-through in Emerging Markets’, ECB Working Paper Series No. 739, Frankfurt, European Central Bank, http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp.739.pdf. Cholewiński R. (2008). ‘Wpływ zmian kursu walutowego na dynamikę procesów inflacyjnych’, NBP Working Paper No. 226, National Bank of Poland, http://www.nbp.pl/publikacje/materialy_i_studia/ms226.pdf. Correa A. S., and Minella A. (2006). ‘Nonlinear Mechanisms of the Exchange Rate PassThrough: A Phillips curve model with threshold for Brazil’, Working Paper Series No. 122, Banco Central do Brasil, www.bcb.gov.br/pec/wps/ingl/wps122.pdf. Corsetti G., and Dedola L. (2002). ‘Macroeconomics of international price discrimination’, ECB Working Paper No. 176, Frankfurt, European Central Bank,, www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp.176.pdf. Devereux M. B., Engel Ch., and Storgaard P. E. (2003). ‘Endogenous Exchange Rate PassThrough when Nominal Prices are Set in Advance’, NBER Working Paper No. 9543, Cambridge, MA: NBER, http://www.nber.org/papers/w9543. Devereux M. B., and Yetman J. (2002). ‘Price Setting and Exchange rate Pass-Through: Theory and Evidence’, Working Paper No. 22/2002, Hong-Kong Institute for Monetary Research, www.hkimr.org/cms/upload/publication_app/pub_full_0_2_26_wp200222_text.pdf. Dornbusch R. (1987). ‘Exchange Rates and Prices’, American Economic Review, 77, pp. 93106. Faruqee H. (2006). ‘Exchange rate pass-through in the euro area’, IMF Staff Papers, 53, Washington, D.C.: IMF, pp.63-88, www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/staffp/2006/01/pdf/faruqee.pdf . Filardo A. J. (1998). ‘New Evidence of the Output Cost of Fighting Inflation’, Economic Review.83, pp.33-61, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/econrev/PDF/3q98fila.pdf. Franses P. H., and Van Dijk D. (2000). Nonlinear time series models in empirical finance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Froot K., and Klemperer P. (1989). ‘Exchange rate pass-through when market share matters’, American Economic Review, 79, pp. 637-654. Fuhrer J., and Moore G. (1995). ‘Inflation Persistence’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, pp. 127-159. Gagnon J. E., and Ihrig J. E. (2004). ‘Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Pass-Through’, International Journal of Finance and Economics, 9, pp.315-338. Goldberg P. K. (1995). ‘Product differentiation and oligopoly in international markets: The case of the US automobile industry’, Econometrica, 63, pp. 891-951. 27 Goldberg P. K., and Knetter M. M. (1997). ‘Goods price and exchange rate: what have we learned’, Journal of Economic Literature, 35, pp. 1243-1272. Goldfajn, I., and Werlang S. (2000). ‘The pass-through form depreciation to inflation: A panel study’, Working Paper Series No. 5, Banco Central do Brasil www.bcb.gov.br/pec/wps/ingl/wps05.pdf. Hansen B. E. (2000). ‘Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation’ Econometrica, 68(3), pp. 575-604. Herzberg, V., Kapetanios G., and Price G. (2003).’Import prices and exchange rate passthrough: theory and evidence from the United Kingdom’, Working Paper No. 182, Bank of England, www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/workingpapers/wp182.pdf. Hjalmarsson E., and Österholm P. (2007). ‘Testing for Cointegration Using the Johansen Methodology when Variables are Near-Integrated’, IMF Working Paper No. 07/141, Washington D.C.: IMF. Houck J.P. (1977). ‘An Approach to Specifying and Estimating Nonreversible Functions’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 59, pp. 570-572. Ihrig J. E., Marazzi M., and Rothenberg A. D. (2006). ‘Exchange Rate Pass-Through in the G-7 Countries’, International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 851, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Kalecki M. (1943). Studies in Economic Dynamics, London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd. Kłos B., Kokoszczyński R., Łyziak T., Przystupa J., and Wróbel E. (2005). ‘Structural Econometric Models in Forecasting Inflation at the National Bank of Poland’, NBP Working Paper No. 31, National Bank of Poland, www.nbp.pl/publikacje/materialy_i_studia/31_en.pdf. Khundrakpam J. K. (2007). ‘Economic reforms and exchange rate pass-through to domestic prices in India’, BIS Working Paper No.225, Basel, Bank for International Settlements, http://www.bis.org/publ/work225.pdf. Korhonen I., and Wachtel P. (2005). ‘A Note on Exchange rate Pass-Through in CIS Countries’, BOFIT Discussion Paper No. 2/2005, Bank of Finland, http://www.bof.fi Łyziak T., Przystupa J., and Wróbel E. (2008). ‘Monetary Policy Transmission in Poland: A Study of the Importance of Interest Rate and credit Channels’, SUERF Studies No.1, Vienna, SUERF. Mankiw N. G. (2006). Macroeconomics, New York. N.Y.: Worth Publishers, 6th edition. Mann C.L. (1986). ‘Prices, Profit Margins, and Exchange Rates’, Federal Reserve Bulletin, 72, pp. 366-379. 28 McCarthy J. (2000). ‘Pass-through of exchange rates and import prices to domestic inflation in some industrialized countries’, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports No. 111, New York, N.Y., http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr111.html. Pollard P. S., and Coughlin C. C. (2003). ‘Size Matters: Asymmetric Exchange Rate PassThrough at the Industrial Level’, Working Paper No. 2003-029C, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2003/2003-029.pdf. Posedel P., and Tica J. (2007). ‘Threshold Autoregressive Model of Exchange Rate PassThrough Effect: The Case of Croatia’, Working Paper No. 07-15, University of Zagreb, Faculty of Economics and Business, http://web.efzg.hr/repec/pdf/Clanak%2007-15.pdf. Przystupa J. (2002). ‘The exchange rate in the monetary transmission mechanism’, NBP Working Paper No. 25, National Bank of Poland, www.nbp.pl/publikacje/materialy_i_studia/25_en.pdf. Przystupa J., and Wróbel E. (2006). ‘Looking for an Optimal Monetary Policy Rule: The Case of Poland under IT Framework’, NBP Working Paper No. 38, National Bank of Poland, www.nbp.pl/publikacje/materialy_i_studia/38_en.pdf. Rogoff K. (1996). ‘The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle’, Journal of Economic Literature, 34, pp.647-668. Silver M. (2007). ‘Do Unit Value Export, Import and Terms of Trade Represent or Misrepresent Price Indices?’, Working Paper, No. 07/121, Washington, D.C.: IMF, www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2007/wp07121.pdf. Taylor J. B. (1993). ‘Discretion versus policy rules in practice’, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Elsevier, 39, pp. 195-214. Taylor J. B. (2000). ‘Low inflation, pass-through, and the pricing power of firms’, European Economic Review, 44, pp. 1389-1408. Tong H. (1990). Non-linear time series: a dynamical system approach, Oxford: Oxford University Press,. Wickremasinghe G., and Silvapulle P. (2004). ‘Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Manufactured Import Prices: The Case of Japan’, International Trade, No. 0406006. Woodford M. (2003). Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, Princeton N.J.: Princeton University Press. Wolffram R. (1971). ‘Positive Measures of Aggregate Supply Elasticities: Some New Approach–Some Critical Notes’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 53, pp. 356359. 29