C O V E R S T O R I E S Antitrust, Vol. 25, No. 2, Spring 2011. © 2011 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association. FTC Challenges to “Invitations to Collude” BY LARRY FULLERTON F OR ALMOST TWENTY YEARS, THE Federal Trade Commission has taken the position that “invitations to collude” may violate Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act.1 Invitations to collude are generally understood to be unilateral solicitations to enter into unlawful horizontal price-fixing or market allocation agreements. The Commission has maintained that such a solicitation may be anticompetitive and condemned as unlawful under Section 5 without a finding that the soliciting and solicited firms formed any “contract, combination . . . or conspiracy” as required by Section 1 of the Sherman Act.2 The Commission’s challenges to invitations to collude are thus a particular application of the Commission’s asserted authority to challenge anticompetitive conduct that does not also violate any other antitrust statute, i.e., the Commission’s “pure” Section 5 authority.3 Historically, the Commission has taken an unusual per se approach to these cases. Under this approach, the Commission first evaluates the suspected invitation to collude internally in light of factors that bear on the likelihood and magnitude of its possible anticompetitive effects, including any purported justifications. If the Commission then decides, on the basis of this internal analysis, that intervention is warranted, it proceeds to challenge the respondent’s conduct as illegal per se—that is, illegal without a finding (or even an allegation) that the challenged conduct had any actual past or likely future anticompetitive effects. This highly discretionary approach was not terribly controversial so long as it was applied only to private communications that could be interpreted unambiguously as solicitations to enter into horizontal price-fixing or market allocation agreements. In the Valassis case in 2006, however, the Commission extended this approach to reach suspected invitations to collude that were communicated publicly.4 More recently, in the U-Haul case, the Commission asserted even broader discretionary authority over both private and public invitations to collude.5 These cases have made the Commission’s stance on invitations to collude significantly more controversial, particularly with respect to public communications, Larry Fullerton is a partner at Sidley Austin LLP and an Associate Editor of A N T I T R U S T . He ser ved as Deputy Assistant Attorney General in the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice from 1995–1998. He would like to thank Adam Doverspike for his work on this article. The views expressed are exclusively those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of Sidley Austin LLP or its partners or clients. 3 0 · A N T I T R U S T and have increased uncertainty about when the Commission will intervene. The Commission could address these uncertainties by issuing guidelines explaining how it will exercise the substantial enforcement discretion that it has asserted. In the meantime, the Commission’s consent orders in the Valassis and U-Haul cases do provide clients with basic guidance on what types of conduct to avoid. Such guidance is important not only for companies making statements that might be construed as invitations to collude, but also for companies that might be seen as the targets of such communications. If a perceived target is not careful, its actions could be construed as an “acceptance” of an improper invitation, resulting in dramatically greater antitrust exposure for both companies. Early Policy Development Enforcement interest in suspected invitations to collude began in 1982 with the highly publicized, blunt proposal of American Airlines President Robert Crandall to his counterpart at Braniff to “[r]aise your goddamn fares twenty percent [and] I’ll raise mine the next morning.” The Department of Justice challenged this invitation successfully as an attempt to monopolize under Section 2 of the Sherman Act.6 Beginning in 1990, the Department also obtained a series of criminal convictions for wire fraud for alleged attempts to fix prices using the telephone.7 The Commission’s first challenge to an alleged invitation to collude under Section 5 came in the Quality Trailer Products case in 1992.8 This case, and a series of cases that followed,9 involved private communications with competitors that the Commission interpreted as solicitations to enter into price-fixing or market allocation agreements. While some of these complaints recited that the soliciting and solicited parties together had high market shares,10 they did not allege that the respondents’ solicitations had any actual past or likely future anticompetitive effects. Rather, at most, they alleged that the “invitation, if accepted, was likely to result in higher prices, reduced output, and injury to consumers.” 11 These cases were all settled with consent orders that prohibited similar conduct in the future. What is most interesting about these early cases is the contemporaneous explanations for them provided by Kevin Arquit, who was then Director of the FTC Bureau of Competition, and his successor as Acting Director, Mary Lou Steptoe.12 These commentaries not only provided consistent, straightforward, and reasonably clear legal and policy explanations for the Commission’s newly asserted cause of action, but they also acknowledged its limitations. As described by Arquit, the “invitation prohibited in Trailer Products was a nonpublic, straightforward solicitation which, if accepted by the solicited party, would give rise to a per se price-fixing violation.” 13 Characterizing this conduct as a “naked” invitation to fix prices “utterly without efficiency justification,” Arquit defended the Commission’s summary approach to condemning such solicitations on the basis that it would deter price fixing without at the same time chilling competitively benign or procompetitive behavior.14 According to Arquit, this created a “per se prohibition against solicitations to fix prices.” 15 To Arquit, the legal and policy rationale for this per se approach suggested two limitations on its application. First, the approach should not be applied to solicitations to enter into agreements that were not per se illegal, such as a solicitation to enter into an agreement to form a legitimate joint venture.16 Second, the per se approach should not be applied to public invitations to collude. Arquit acknowledged that the “fact that an invitation to collude is made in a public forum should not, of course, immunize communications that harm competition any more than a publicly arrived at agreement automatically avoids liability under Section 1 of the Sherman Act.” He noted, however, that a per se approach to ambiguous public statements could “inhibit procompetitive communications that only incidentally conveyed information to competitors.” 17 He also noted that public speech is “more susceptible than private speech to detection by law enforcement authorities, and is less likely to result in a secret agreement.” 18 For these reasons, Arquit believed that if public speech were involved, “[m]arket structure analysis and legitimate efficiency justifications should be given full consideration.” 19 Steptoe likewise saw the Quality Trailer Products case as establishing a per se approach to invitations to collude in the context of private communications. She likewise cautioned against extending this approach to “instances of public communications,” where there are “more likely to be efficiency justifications” and “the public nature of the communication itself may cast doubt on a real collusive purpose or expectation.” 20 Arquit and Steptoe thus explained the Commission’s early cases as establishing a per se rule of limited scope. For this rule to apply, the communication must be private, and it must be fairly interpreted as a solicitation to enter into a price-fixing or market allocation agreement. When these conditions were met, the conduct would be illegal per se, and the Commission would not need to demonstrate actual past or likely future anticompetitive effects or (apparently) consider purported business justifications. In effect, the anticompetitive effects associated with the solicitation would be presumed, just as the law presumes anticompetitive harm from an actual agreement to fix prices. In all other cases, Arquit and Steptoe agreed, market structure and efficiency justifications should be given “full consideration,” presumably under a rule of reason analysis.21 This approach is consistent with subsequent commentators who have argued that if the Commission wishes to challenge public communications as invitations to collude, it should do so only after taking into account market structure and possible efficiency justifications.22 The Commission’s early per se formulation was at the time, and remains today, somewhat controversial, and it might be difficult in a close case to characterize any given course of conduct as a “straightforward” solicitation to enter into a price-fixing or market allocation agreement. Nonetheless, this approach had the virtue of being a comparatively clear-cut rule for counseling purposes.23 Application to Public Communications in Valassis The Commission’s policy approach lost this comparative clarity when the Commission began to challenge public communications as invitations to collude under Section 5, starting with the Valassis case in 2006. According to the Commission’s complaint in this case, the CEO of Valassis Communications, a producer and distributor of discount coupon booklets, extended an unlawful invitation to collude to News America, its only competitor, in a conference call with financial analysts. Allegedly, the CEO of Valassis opened the call by stating that Valassis planned to raise its floor price for full pages to $6 per thousand to customers that might be considering switching their business to or expanding their business with Valassis. For a few days, Valassis would honor outstanding bids to prospective customers at lower prices, but after a specified date, all prospective customers would be quoted the new, higher price. The CEO also stated that Valassis would be monitoring News America’s response to this announcement and that, if News America did not raise its prices, the parties’ recent price war would resume: “We expect that concrete evidence of News America’s intentions will be available in the marketplace in short order. If News continues to pursue our customers and market share then we will go back to our previous strategy.” 24 Although the communication in Valassis was public, the Commission’s complaint tracked those in earlier cases involving private invitations to collude. For example, the Commission did not allege that the conduct that Valassis actually engaged in, by itself, had any actual past or likely future anticompetitive effects. It did allege, however, that Valassis and News America were the only two competitors in a market in which entry was difficult and that the “invitation to collude, if accepted by News America, would likely have resulted in higher . . . prices and reduced output.” 25 The Commission also alleged that Valassis acted with the intent to facilitate collusion and without a legitimate business justification.26 The Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order released by the Commission in this case explained that while previous Commission actions challenging invitations to collude have generally involved private communications, “the fact of public communication should not, without more, constitute a defense . . . .”27 At the same time, the ComS P R I N G 2 0 1 1 · 3 1 C O V E R mission acknowledged that a variety of considerations should enter into liability determinations in the context of public communications, stating that liability should depend upon “the substance and context of the communication, including issues of intent, likely effect, and business justification, and should not turn solely on the arena in which the communication occurs.” 28 With respect to Valassis, the Commission noted that the market was characterized by “durable” or “longstanding duopoly,” that Valassis communicated with its rival with “extraordinary specificity,” and that “[m]uch of this information would not have been publicly communicated, even to investors and analysts . . . but for Valassis’s effort to induce collusion.” 29 The Commission also acknowledged that corporations have “many obvious and important reasons for discussing business strategies and financial results with shareholders, securities analysts, and others” and that, for this reason, “the Commission is extremely sensitive to the fact that antitrust intervention involving a corporation’s public communications must take great care not to unduly chill legitimate speech.” 30 In Valassis, however, the Commission determined that the public statements went “far beyond” disclosure for legitimate business reasons and presented a “substantial danger of competitive harm.” 31 Under such “limited circumstances,” the Commission said, it may challenge an invitation to collude under Section 5, “even where the conduct did not result in competitive harm.” 32 The Commission’s consent order prohibited Valassis from inviting collusion or entering into any collusive scheme going forward.33 However, in a proviso also included in the later U-Haul order, the Commission permitted Valassis “publicly to disclose any information . . . required by the Federal Securities Laws.” 34 Expanded Per Se Rule At first blush, the Valassis case may appear to have established a traditional rule of reason approach to public invitations to collude—but it did not. While the Commission acknowledged that liability in the context of public communications should depend on a number of factors, including “likely effect and business justification,” it adhered to its historical approach and refrained from alleging any actual or likely anticompetitive effects in its complaint. Indeed, in its Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order, the Commission expressly affirmed that it felt free to challenge invitations to collude “even where the conduct did not result in competitive harm.” Instead, Valassis established an unusual form of per se rule under which the Commission may itself evaluate the factors that bear on the likelihood and magnitude of anticompetitive effects and any purported justifications for the challenged conduct. If the Commission decides, based on its internal analysis, that antitrust intervention is warranted, it may challenge the conduct without regard to its actual or likely effects. This is best thought of as an extension of the Commission’s 3 2 · A N T I T R U S T S T O R I E S earlier per se approach into the new context of public communications.35 Case Against U-Haul The U-Haul case supports this characterization of the Commission’s emerging analytic framework and can be read to assert an even broader discretionary authority to decide what is or is not anticompetitive and illegal. In that complaint, the Commission alleged that U-Haul, the largest consumer truck rental company in the United States, invited its closest competitor, Avis Budget Group, Inc. (Budget) to join with U-Haul in a collusive scheme to raise rates for one-way truck rentals. U-Haul involved both private and public communications. According to the complaint, U-Haul’s CEO instructed U-Haul’s regional managers and dealers to reach out privately to their counterparts at Budget to exhort them to match U-Haul’s higher rates. A year later, U-Haul’s CEO allegedly instructed managers to raise their rates, anticipating that “Budget will come up.” 36 But Budget did not immediately follow. Then, during a conference call with stock analysts, in response to a question about U-Haul’s pricing strategies, U-Haul’s CEO explained that U-Haul was trying to “show price leadership” for the good of the entire industry.37 He said that U-Haul was attempting to indicate to competitors, such as Budget, that they should not “throw the money away,” and that they should “[p]rice at cost at least.” 38 The CEO then indicated that he had instructed U-Haul managers to wait a while longer for Budget to respond and that he was optimistic that Budget would respond by raising prices: [F]or the last 90 days, I’ve encouraged everybody who has rate setting authority in the Company to give [it] more time and see if you can’t get it to stabilize. In other words, hold the line at a little higher. And if they [Budget] perceive that we’ll let them come up a little bit, I remain optimistic they’ll come up, and it has a profound effect on us.39 In its complaint, the Commission did not distinguish between U-Haul’s private and public communications. Instead, the Commission alleged that “[e]ach and all” of U-Haul’s communications established an invitation to collude, which, “if accepted by Budget, would likely result in higher one-way truck rental rates and reduced output.” 40 As in earlier cases, while the complaint stated that U-Haul and Budget together accounted for a large percentage of the market, the Commission did not allege that U-Haul’s conduct alone had any actual or likely anticompetitive effects. According to the Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order filed in the case, U-Haul’s conduct threatened competitive harm because even an “unaccepted invitation to collude may facilitate coordinated interaction by disclosing the solicitor’s intentions and preferences.” 41 In particular, the Commission felt that the improper communications from U-Haul, including the public statements made by U-Haul’s CEO, “could have encouraged Budget [or other competitors] to raise rates.” 42 However, as indicated, the complaint did not allege that any competitor had, in fact, raised its rates, and nowhere did the Commission analyze the likelihood that any competitor would attempt to raise rates, succeed at the attempt, and thereby cause competitive harm. Significantly, and again without distinguishing between private and public communications, the Commission also made clear that it was prepared to infer an actionable invitation to collude from “less egregious” conduct than was present in U-Haul, stating: “It is not essential that the Commission find repeated misconduct attributable to senior executives, or define a market, or show market power, or establish substantial competitive harm, or even find that the terms of the desired agreement have been communicated with precision.” 43 Ultimately, the consent order in U-Haul mirrored the Commission’s order in Valassis. Valassis and U-Haul together appear to assert a broad discretionary authority on the part of the Commission. Whether a suspected invitation to collude is extended in private or in public, the Commission may itself evaluate and take into account any factors it deems relevant to the liability determination before challenging the invitation under what is essentially a per se rule. Need for Commission Guidelines One could reasonably object to the Commission’s broad assertion of discretionary authority on policy grounds. Even when the Commission sought to use Section 5 in the 1980s to challenge the unilateral adoption of “facilitating practices” (e.g., advance public announcements of future price changes) the Commission acknowledged that it had to demonstrate anticompetitive effects.44 At a minimum, the Commission’s recent actions cry out for a more complete explanation than is afforded by its publicly filed documents.45 As part of a broader debate about the scope of the Commission’s pure Section 5 authority, Commissioner William E. Kovacic has called upon the Commission to issue a policy statement or guidelines that would articulate a framework for analyzing such cases and describe how the Commission will exercise its asserted enforcement discretion.46 In part, this was intended to help the Commission to win their pure Section 5 cases in court. But the need for guidelines exists even in the comparatively established area of invitations to collude— and for the same reasons. Taking up Commissioner Kovacic’s call for guidelines would provide needed clarity for businesses and those who counsel them. Such guidelines should address private and public invitations to collude separately. In each case, the Commission should explain whether it is taking a per se or rule of reason approach, and discuss its analytical framework. The Commission should explain under what circumstances it will presume harm and which business justifications will be recognized and when. In the area of private solicitations to enter into price-fixing and market allocation agreements, the Commission’s tra- ditional approach seems reasonably well-accepted,47 and little more may be required than to endorse the explanation and the limitations already acknowledged by Arquit and Steptoe. Where public invitations to collude are concerned, however, at least three topics should be addressed, as follows. First, the Commission should clarify the line between an advance public announcement of a future price increase and an invitation to collude that would be actionable under Section 5. Presumably, an advance announcement of a price increase alone cannot be an invitation to collude. If competitors “accept” the implied suggestion of a price increase by raising their own prices, that conduct does not form an agreement that could be challenged as illegal per se (indeed, it is generally accepted that such conduct would not be unlawful at all under Sherman Section 1).48 Even an advance announcement of a price increase coupled with evidence of a subjective intent to exercise price leadership should be insufficient to constitute an invitation to collude. Yet, in the U-Haul complaint, the Commission emphasized that U-Haul had expressed the subjective desire to exercise price leadership, as if that had special importance. Would that have been sufficient, in the Commission’s view, to establish an invitation to collude? If not, what else would be needed? The U-Haul and Valassis cases suggest that the following factors will strengthen the inference that a public communication constitutes an invitation to collude: (1) the competitor being solicited is clearly identified; (2) the competitor being solicited is the soliciting firm’s “closest” competitor; (3) the references to future prices and price policies are “specific;” (4) the announced future price comes into or remains in effect only if competitors respond by raising their prices; and/or (5) competitors are threatened with lower prices if they do not respond. But it is not clear how these factors are to be evaluated or what happens if only some of the factors are present in a given case or they point in different directions. Second, the Commission should clarify the market characteristics that support an inference of likely anticompetitive harm. As has been discussed, it is widely understood that liability for public communications should depend in part on a showing that the market is already susceptible to express or tacit collusion. In Valassis, the Commission acknowledged as much, saying that liability should depend in part on the “context of the communication” and emphasizing that the market in that case was characterized by “durable duopoly.” 49 But it did not make clear the market characteristics that generally should be taken into account, nor did it establish thresholds for those characteristics. Finally, the Commission should clarify what justifications it will recognize and in what circumstances. In Valassis, the Commission acknowledged that corporations have “many obvious and important reasons” for discussing business strategies and financial results with shareholders, securities analysts, and others.50 But what are the reasons that the Commission is prepared to recognize? In the consent orders in both Valassis and U-Haul, the Commission appeared to recognize only S P R I N G 2 0 1 1 · 3 3 C O V E R one—the need to make disclosures “required” by the securities laws. Are there others? And what about disclosures that are not required by the securities laws but nevertheless advance their purposes? Indeed, some have argued that at least some corporate disclosures are immune entirely from antitrust challenge under the Supreme Court’s decision in Credit Suisse v. Billing, where those disclosures advance the purposes of the securities laws and fall within the scope of federal securities regulatory authority.51 Rules of Thumb for Counselors Even in the absence of definitive guidance from the Commission, there are a few rules of thumb that may be teased out of the Valassis and U-Haul cases to provide clients with basic guidance on avoiding unwelcome interest from the Commission. First, clients should be counseled not to contact competitors privately and say or write anything that could be construed as a solicitation to enter into a price-fixing or market allocation agreement. A straightforward, private invitation to collude is not a gray area; the Commission should be expected to take an active enforcement interest in such conduct. Second, when planning public communications, such as a press release or an analyst call, clients should be counseled to consider carefully the legitimate informational needs of their intended audiences and avoid disclosing more information about future pricing and marketing plans than is strictly necessary. In such public communications, clients should avoid appearing to identify specific competitors in any way that might make them seem like the target of the communication, particularly if they are close competitors. Clients should also focus their public announcements on what they plan to do, rather than on what their competitors or the industry are likely to do, and avoid making announcements of future actions that are contingent upon competitors responding in a certain way. Specifically, clients should avoid appearing to threaten to reduce prices or resume a price war if competitors fail to respond to an invitation to raise prices. Where the market at issue is concentrated and stable, has barriers to new entry, and is otherwise susceptible to tacit or express collusion, clients should be most vigilant in adhering to these principles. Third, clients should not assume that disclosures that further the purposes of the securities laws are necessarily immune from antitrust challenge (although of course they may be). Finally, clients must seek counsel and respond carefully if they feel that they may be seen as the target of a competitor’s public invitation to collude. Even if a client does nothing more than raise its own prices after a perceived invitation has been issued, it may still be seen as having accepted the invitation, and it may thereby have exposed itself to significant liabilities under Section 1 of the Sherman Act. If a price increase was already contemplated before the invitation was extended, clients should work with counsel before proceeding with the increase to determine whether there is adequate 3 4 · A N T I T R U S T S T O R I E S existing evidence that the increase was unrelated to the competitor’s communication. Lawyers also should counsel their clients generally about public and internal communications to ensure that the company does not appear inadvertently to have accepted a perceived invitation to collude.52 Counsel should consider contacting the Commission to make clear that any perceived invitation was unwelcome and that, in any event, the company did not accept it. 䡵 1 Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act prohibits “unfair methods of competition.” 15 U.S.C. § 45. 2 Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits any “contract, combination . . . or conspiracy in restraint of trade.” 15 U.S.C. § 1. 3 This article will assume, without concluding, that the Commission’s authority under Section 5 is broad enough to reach at least some invitations to collude. That is certainly the view of leading commentators. See, e.g., P HILLIP E. A REEDA & H ERBERT H OVENKAMP, A NTITRUST L AW , A N A NALYSIS OF A NTITRUST P RINCIPLES AND T HEIR A PPLICATION ¶ 1419.1 (3d ed. 2009). 4 Complaint, Valassis Commc’ns, FTC File No. 051- 0008 (Apr. 19, 2006), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0510008/0510008c4160 ValassisComplaint.pdf; Decision & Order, Valassis Commc’ns, FTC File No. 051- 0008 (Apr. 19, 2006), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/ 0510008/0510008c4160ValassisDecisionandOrder.pdf; Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order To Aid Public Comment, Valassis Commc’ns, 71 Fed. Reg. 13,976 (Mar. 20, 2006), available at http:// www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0510008/060314ana0510008.pdf. 5 Complaint, U-Haul Int’l, FTC File No. 081-0157 (July 14, 2010), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0810157/100720uhaulcmpt.pdf; Decision & Order, U-Haul Int’l, FTC File No. 081-0157 (July 14, 2010), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0810157/100720uhauldo.pdf; Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Order to Aid Public Comment, U-Haul Int’l, 75 Fed. Reg. 35,033 (June 21, 2010), available at http://www.ftc.gov/ os/caselist/0810157/100609uhaulanal.pdf. 6 United States v. Am. Airlines, 743 F.2d 1114, 1116 (5th Cir. 1984). 7 United States v. Ames Sintering Co., 927 F.2d 232 (6th Cir. 1990); James F. Rill, Report from Official Washington, 60 A NTITRUST L.J. 217, 221–23 (1991); Daniel Booker & Thomas Allen, Attempted Price-Fixing Targeted for Criminal Action, A NTITRUST , Fall/Winter 1991, at 30. 8 115 F.T.C. 944 (1992). 9 Complaint, MacDermid, Inc., FTC File No. 991-0167, 1999 FTC LEXIS 191 (Dec. 21, 1999); Complaint, Stone Container Corp., 125 F.T.C. 853 (1998); Complaint, Precision Moulding Co., 122 F.T.C. 104 (1996); Complaint, YKK (U.S.A.) Inc., 116 F.T.C. 628 (1993); Complaint, A.E. Clevite, Inc., 116 F.T.C. 389 (1993). 10 See, e.g., Clevite Complaint, supra note 9, ¶ 7 (“JPI and Miba together manufactured more than 95 percent of all locomotive engine bearings sold in the United States.”); YKK Complaint, supra note 9, ¶ 4 (“YKK and Talon, Inc. together account for approximately 82 percent of all zippers manufactured and/or sold in the United States.”). 11 Stone Container Complaint, supra note 9, ¶ 7 (emphasis added). 12 Kevin J. Arquit, The Boundaries of Horizontal Restraints: Facilitating Practices and Invitations to Collude, 61 A NTITRUST L.J. 531 (1993); Mary Lou Steptoe, The Impact of Section 5 of the FTC Act on Communications Among Competitors, Remarks Before ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Advanced Antitrust CLE Inst. (Oct. 15, 1993), reprinted in 7 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 50,120. 13 Arquit, supra note 12, at 547. 14 Id. at 545, 546. 15 Id. at 547. 16 Id. Accord Susan S. DeSanti & Ernest A. Nagata, Competitor Communications: Facilitating Practices or Invitations to Collude? An Application of Theories to Proposed Horizontal Agreements Submitted for Antitrust Review, 63 A NTITRUST L.J. 93, 113 (1994) (“[T]he main limiting principle to the invitation-to-collude theory appears to be that the solicitation constitute a naked invitation to join in conduct that would be per se illegal.”). 17 Arquit, supra note 12, at 548. 18 Id. 19 Id. 20 21 22 Steptoe, supra note 12, at 48,960–61; see also DeSanti & Nagata, supra note 16, at 113 (“the theory may be restricted to private invitations to collude.”). Indeed, Steptoe specifically suggested that “instances of apparent public invitations should be analyzed on the more general model of facilitating practices.” Steptoe, supra note 12, at 48,961. Both Arquit and Steptoe saw invitations to collude as a subcategory of facilitating practices. Arquit, supra note 12, at 542; Steptoe, supra, at 48,954. However, this characterization may be unnecessarily confusing. As DeSanti and Nagata explain, the theories upon which the Commission have challenged invitations to collude, on the one hand, and facilitating practices, on the other, have differed. The first is a per se offense that “appears not to be limited by market structure or entry screens” while the latter “is limited to oligopolistic markets.” See DeSanti & Nagata, supra note 16, at 113–15. A REEDA & H OVENKAMP , supra note 3, ¶ 1419.1d2 (“[S]hould the Commission undertake the delicate task of judging public ‘invitations’ that have not been ‘accepted’? . . . Our answer is affirmative—at least where a market is susceptible to tacit price coordination.”). 23 Cf. Amanda P. Reeves, Conduct-Specific Tests? How the Federal Trade Commission Can Reframe the Section 5 Debate, CPI A NTITRUST J., Feb. 2010 (2), at 1, 5 (It is possible that “the comfort that practitioners have acquired with invitation-to-collude cases results from the fact that describing an invitation-to-collude violation is straightforward.”). 24 Valassis Complaint, supra note 4, ¶ 13.f. 25 Id. ¶ 15 (emphasis added). 26 Id. ¶ 14. 27 Valassis Analysis, supra note 4, at 4. 28 Id. 29 Id. at 4–5. 30 Id. at 5. 31 Id. 32 Id. (emphasis added). 33 Valassis Decision & Order, supra note 4, at 3. 34 Id. at 4 (emphasis added); U-Haul Decision & Order, supra note 5, at 5. 35 To see this more clearly, compare the Commission’s approach to challenging public invitations to collude with its approach to challenging consummated mergers on a coordinated interaction theory. In both cases, the Commission is challenging past conduct on the grounds that it may increase the likelihood or effectiveness of tacit or express collusion. As discussed above, in the case of public invitations to collude, the Commission challenges the conduct without alleging that the respondent’s conduct has had any actual past or likely future anticompetitive effects. In the case of the consummated merger, however, the Commission alleges likely effects. Consider, for example, the Commission’s challenge to Polypore’s consummated acquisition of Microporous, where the Commission alleged in part that the transaction made “coordination more likely” in a market for battery separators for the automotive industry. In its complaint, the Commission alleged that the acquisition “has led and will lead to increased prices.” See Complaint ¶ 38, Polypore Int’l, FTC File No. 081-0131 (Sept. 9, 2008), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9327/091008cmp9327.pdf. Following an administrative adjudication of this complaint, the Commission found that the transaction did in fact have anticompetitive effects in this market. See Opinion of the Commission at 26–32, Polypore Int’l, FTC File No. 081-0131 (Dec. 13, 2010), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/ d9327/101213polyporeopinion.pdf. A challenge to a consummated merger is a rule of reason case, of course. The Commission’s approach to public invitations to collude is clearly something different. 36 U-Haul Complaint, supra note 5, ¶ 21. 37 Id. ¶ 24. 38 Id. ¶ 24.a. 39 Id. ¶ 24.c. The CEO also indicated that Budget did not have to match U-Haul’s rates precisely to prevent U-Haul from dropping its rates; rather, U-Haul would tolerate a small price differential of up to 3 to 5 percent. Id. ¶ 24.d. 40 Id. ¶ 26 (emphasis added). 41 U-Haul Analysis, supra note 5, at 4. 42 Id. 43 Id. In a clarifying Statement issued when the settlement was announced, Chairman Jon Leibowitz and Commissioners William E. Kovacic and J. Thomas Rosch emphasized that the “parties have settled an invitation-tocollude case and not a Sherman Antitrust Act Section 1 conspiracy case.” According to these Commissioners, “invitations to collude do not require proof of an agreement; nor do they require proof an anticompetitive effect.” Statement of Chairman Leibowitz, Commissioner Kovacic, and Commissioner Rosch, U-Haul Int’l, FTC File No. 081-0157 (June 9, 2010), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0810157/100609uhaulstatement.pdf. 44 E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. v. FTC, 729 F.2d 128, 141 (2d Cir. 1984) (“[T]he Commission majority concedes that ‘facilitating practices will be found to violate § 5 . . . only if the weight of the evidence shows that competition has been substantially lessened’ and that it was required to ‘establish a clear nexus between the challenged conduct and adverse competitive effects before invoking our authority in this regard.’”). 45 Cf. J. Thomas Rosch, Commissioner, FTC, The Great Doctrinal Debate: Under What Circumstances Is Section 5 Superior to Section 2?, Remarks Before N.Y. State Bar Ass’n Annual Antitrust Conference 3 (Jan. 27, 2011), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/rosch/110127barspeech.pdf ("In my view, the Commission does a greater service in these hard cases [including invitations to collude] by declaring the practice to be a Section 5 violation provided that we clearly explain why the conduct constitutes an unfair method of competition so that future parties are on notice."); Reeves, supra note 23, at 7 (“if the Commission is to use Section 5 and prevail in the federal courts, it needs to give doctrinal shape to Section 5”); Stephen Calkins, Counterpoint: The Legal Foundations of the Commission’s Use of Section 5 to Challenge Invitations to Collude Is Secure, A NTITRUST , Spring 2000, at 80 (“It should not be a challenge to glean the views of the Commission on an important initiative” such as invitations to collude). 46 William E. Kovacic & Marc Winerman, Competition Policy and the Application of Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 76 A NTITRUST L.J. 929, 944 (2010). 47 U.S. Chamber of Commerce, Unfair Methods of Competition Under Section 5 of the FTC Act: Does the U.S. Need Rules “Above and Beyond Antitrust”?, A NTITRUST C HRONICLE , Sept. 2009 (2), at 2–3 (invitations to collude may be an example of “certain, limited forms of anticompetitive conduct that may not be covered by the antitrust laws, and thus may warrant scrutiny under Section 5.”); A. Douglas Melamed, Comments Submitted to the Federal Trade Commission Workshop Concerning Section 5 of the FTC Act (Oct. 14, 2008) (“[A]n invitation by one competitor for another to enter into a naked conspiracy” is one of the “least problematic” applications of Section 5), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/comments/section5workshop/53763300004.pdf. 48 Accord A REEDA & H OVENKAMP , supra note 3, ¶ 1419.1d2 (“[A]n oligopolist who raises prices to a supracompetitive level ‘invites’ rivals to follow . . . [but] ‘acceptance’ of this ‘invitation’ by following . . . does not violate either [FTC Act] § 5 or Sherman Act § 1. Tolerating successful price leadership necessarily entails toleration of unsuccessful price leadership.”). 49 Valassis Analysis, supra note 4, at 4. 50 Id. at 5. 51 Credit Suisse Sec. (USA) LLC v. Billing, 551 U.S. 264 (2007). See John Roberti, Remarks Before ABA Section of Antitrust Law Teleconference Program on “Avoiding Accusations of Public Conspiracies and Invitations to Collude” (Sept. 27, 2010), http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/at-bb/audio/ 10/09-10.shtml (audio). 52 See, e.g., In re Delta/AirTran Baggage Fee Antitrust Litig., No. 1:09MD 2089(TCB), 2010 WL 3290433, at * 10 (N.D. Ga. Aug. 2, 2010) (denying motion to dismiss a claim that Section 1 was violated when AirTran invited Delta to collude during an earnings call and Delta subsequently accepted that invitation in its own earnings call). S P R I N G 2 0 1 1 · 3 5