The Rupee in Distress June–August 2013 Partha Ray* Abstract This paper looks into the episode of sharp depreciation of the Indian rupee (INR) during June–August 2013 when the rupee-US dollar (INR-USD) exchange rate came down from 56.765 in the beginning of June 2013 to 67.8787 on August 29, 2013, indicating a depreciation of nearly 16 per cent over the three months. This evoked strong reactions from policymakers and analysts alike and cast some doubt on India’s macroeconomic fundamentals. The immediate trigger behind this adverse development in the INR-USD exchange rate came from the news/hints of possible tapering off of the rate of quantitative easing (QE) in the US in end-May 2013 and the associated capital outflows primarily on account of foreign institutional investments (FIIs). Interestingly, the outflows occurred both on account of debt and equity. However, an unsustainable current account deficit (CAD) incurred by the Indian economy over the last few years and its dependence on foreign capital flows for its financing the CAD made the Indian economy vulnerable to such external shocks. Faced with the compulsions of the impossible trinity, the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) did not indulge in massive intervention in the foreign exchange (forex) market to defend the rupee. The cross-country experience during the reference period also suggests that countries with high CAD were more exposed to such speculative attacks on their currencies. Following the explicit announcement of the US Federal Reserve (US Fed) for deferring the decision to taper off the extent of QE in September 2013 and the various measures implemented by the Indian authorities, there have been some improvements both in the current and capital accounts of India’s balance of payments (BoP) over the last six months or so. * The author is Professor, Indian Institute of Management Calcutta (IIMC). The paper is based on the author’s presentations at ICRA’s Monthly Workshops at Kolkata in August and September 2013. The author is indebted to Professors Mihir Rakshit, Dipankar Dasgupta, Amitava Bose, Asis Banerjee, Susmita Rakshit, and Soumyen Sikdar for their comments on these presentations. The author also gratefully acknowledges the discussion on some of the relevant issues with Professor Anup Sinha at an informal presentation at IIMC in September 2013. The author is indebted in particular to an anonymous referee for the detailed comments on an earlier draft of the paper. The usual disclaimer applies. icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 An unsustainable CAD incurred by the Indian economy over the last few years and its dependence on foreign capital flows for its financing the CAD made the Indian economy vulnerable to external shocks. 41 icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 The exchange rate of the rupee witnessed a sharply depreciating trend during the period June–August 2013. The situation assumed almost a panic proportion with various analysts suggesting that the value of the rupee would settle at Rs. 70 per USD. 42 While such volatility in the exchange rate could be the price that an economy has to pay for its increasing openness, for a credible currency regime, India needs to have serious introspection on its CAD and its associated financing options. I. Introduction The forex market in India experienced significant volatility during 2013. In particular the exchange rate of the rupee witnessed a sharply depreciating trend during the period June–August 2013. The INR-USD exchange rate was down from a level of 56.765 in the beginning of June 2013 to 67.8787 on August 29, 2013—a depreciation of over 16 per cent. The situation assumed almost a panic proportion with various analysts suggesting that the value of the rupee would settle at Rs. 70 per USD (Rajwade, 2013; Tarapore, 2013). Financial market players were becoming impatient and pressure was put on the authorities to do something to arrest the relentless slide of the INR. People, from policymakers to the man in the street, were perturbed as well. In some quarters apprehensions were expressed whether India was on the verge of another 1991-like crisis. Predictably, policymakers tried their best to talk up the exchange rate. Thus, the Finance Minister in a statement on August 23, 2013 is reported to have said, “The panic that has gripped the currency market is unwarranted; we believe that the rupee is undervalued and has overshot what is generally believed to be a reasonable and appropriate level.” (The Economic Times, August 23, 2013.)1 But what accounted for this extreme volatility of the rupee during the four months? Was India a victim of speculative attack of currency traders? Or, were India’s fundamentals so bad that such a fate was inevitable? Many such questions have been raised in this context. It is not that economists were unaware of the possibilities of such adverse developments. Rangarajan and Mishra (2013) while analyzing certain long-term trends of the Indian economy stated that the estimated current account deficit for 2011–12 at 4.2 per cent of GDP was significantly above the level that could be sustained over the medium term. The RBI too in its Annual Report for 2012–13 had indicated the sustainable CAD for India to be at 2.5 per cent of GDP. In fact, Sen (2013) found the Indian story of nominal depreciation of the currency to be entirely predictable and squarely blamed the official policy of permitting capital inflows to finance the CAD for the adverse developments on the exchange rate front.2 However, while such adverse exchange rate 1 http://articles.economictimes.indiatimes.com/2013-08-23/news/41440810_1_subbarao-rbi-governor-exchange-rate. 2 Sen’s take on the Indian story is as follows: “Sustained capital inflows caused a real appreciation accompanied by a very high trade deficit and a rising current account deficit. The Indian contribution to this entirely predictable story was that somewhere along the way it picked up high inflation that has now become entrenched in expectations (and the Reserve Bank of India is solely to be blamed for this). This happened as the economy was slowing down. Gold imports, acting as a hedge against inflation, have shot up. The crisis would have occurred at the time of Lehman’s collapse but was averted because of the introduction of quantitative easing (QE) that generated liquidity in the in- developments could no doubt have indicated the fragility of India’s macroeconomic fundamentals, comparing it to the 1991 crisis was entirely misplaced. (Krishnaswamy and Kanagasabapathy, 2013; Appendix.) It is against this background that the present paper takes a look at the episode of rupee depreciation during June–August 2013 and argues that the reason for it lay partly in the talks of tapering off the pace of QE by the US Fed officials (and the consequent capital outflows from India) and partly in some questionable elements of India’s macro fundamentals that cast doubt on India’s BoP sustainability on the external front in the minds of financial market players. The rest of the paper is fairly straightforward. The extent of rupee depreciation is tracked in Section II. Section III is devoted to the drivers of such sharp depreciation in the external value of the rupee, viz., tapering talks, the consequent capital outflows, and India’s weak fundamentals. Our diagnosis is supported by an analysis in Section IV of the trends in exchange rates of other Emerging Market Economies (EMEs) during the reference period. The next section is devoted to a discussion of the crisis management measures adopted by the Indian authorities. Section VI concludes the paper. II. Extent of Recent Volatility of INR How volatile was the INR? In contrast to many Asian economies, a distinguishing feature of the INR has been that it has shown two-way movements (Chart 1a). Despite some fluctuations, it may not be an exaggeration to say that the rupee has been able to avoid large volatility over a prolonged period of time. This is in consonance with the professed policy objective of the RBI, which has been summarized as follows: “RBI does not have a fixed ‘target’ for the exchange rate which it tries to defend or pursue over time; RBI is prepared to intervene in the market to dampen excessive volatility as and when necessary; RBI’s purchases or sales of foreign currency are undertaken through a number of banks and are generally discrete and smooth; and market operations and exchange rate movement should, in principle, be transaction-oriented rather than purely speculative in nature.” (Jalan, 2003.) The recently submitted report of The Expert Committee to Revise and Strengthen the Monetary Policy Framework (Chairman: Urjit Patel, Deputy Governor, RBI) also endorsed this view when it commented that: “The RBI does not target a specific rate or level for the exchange rate … the RBI intervenes in the market only to smooth exchange rate volatility and prevent disruptions to macroeconomic stability.” (RBI, 2014; p. 11.) So far as the medium-term trend of the INR-USD exchange rate is concerned, note that over 2008–2013 the INR depreciated for a large ternational financial markets. Now the slightest whisper about QE being eased out causes panic in India.” (p. 14.) In a comment on Sen (2013)’s paper, Correa (2013) criticized the policy of the RBI in recent times to increase the repo rate for attracting capital inflows as well as for controlling inflation. icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 In contrast to many Asian economies, a distinguishing feature of the INR has been that it has shown twoway movements. Despite some fluctuations, it may not be an exaggeration to say that the rupee has been able to avoid large volatility over a prolonged period of time. 43 Chart 1 INR-USD Exchange Rate icra bulletin Money & a. During January 2008–December 2013 Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 Given that India had been incurring deficit in the current account, in many b. During April 2013–December 2013 a case any drastic movement in the exchange rate of the INR closely corresponded with the pattern of inflows and outflows on the capital account. Source: Bloomberg. part of 2008, followed by a mildly appreciating tendency till mid-2010 (Chart 1a).3 Since then it has been on a depreciating trajectory coupled in between with some episodes of rupee appreciation vis-à-vis the US dollar. Given that India had been incurring deficit in the current account, in many a case any drastic movement in the exchange rate of the INR closely corresponded with the pattern of inflows and outflows on the capital account (or what the International Monetary Fund, or IMF, calls “financial account” these days). Particularly striking, as already indicated, was the sharply depreciating trend of the rupee during May– 44 3 Note that since the chart plots daily INR-USD exchange rate any upward movement would indicate a depreciating rupee and a downward movement an appreciating rupee. Table 1 Crossing of Psychological Marks in INR-USD Exchange Rate INR-USD Exchange Rate Mark Date 55 60 65 67.88 (Peak) May 21, 2012 July 3, 2013 August 23, 2013 August 29, 2003 1 2 3 4 icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 Source: Bloomberg. August 2013 (Chart 1b),4 a trend which however started reversing from September 2013. In fact, in terms of the psychological marks of multiples of five in the popular perception the scenario appeared starker. The INR-USD exchange rate was 55 on May 21, 2013, but within three months it depreciated by 10 and moved to 65 on August 23, 2013 (Table 1). We turn in the next section to look into the factors behind the relentless fall of the rupee during this period. III. Drivers of Volatility In discussing the drivers of volatility some basic facts are important to take note of. First, barring a few years India has long been incurring deficits on the current account (Chart 2). Second, the CAD Chart 2 Current Account Deficit, Foreign Investment and INR-USD Exchange Rate during 1991–2013 Source: Particularly striking was the sharply depreciating trend of the rupee during May–August 2013, a trend which however started reversing from September 2013. Handbook of Statistics on Indian Economy, 2012–13, RBI. 4 Given that inflation in India has been much higher than in advanced economies, such movement in the nominal exchange rate is also reflected in the real effective exchange rate (REER). Thus, both the 6-country and 36-country REER of India were also on a depreciating trajectory. 45 icra bulletin Table 2 Select Items of BoP: 2012–2013 Money & (USD billion) 20122013 Finance Jan–Apr–July–Oct– Jan–Apr–July– Oct– MarJuneSept Dec MarJuneSeptDec J u l y . 2 0 1 4 1. Current Account 1a) Merchandise 1b) Invisibles 2. Capital Account 2a) Foreign Investment o/w Foreign Direct Investment o/w Foreign Portfolio Investment 2b) Loans 3. Foreign Exchange Reserves (Increase – / Decrease +) Memo: INR-USD Exchange Rate (Min – Max; in Rs.) –21.8–17.1–21.1–31.8 –18.2–21.8 –5.2–4.1 –51.5–43.8–47.8–58.4 –45.6–50.5–33.3 –33.2 29.826.826.726.6 27.528.728.1 29.1 16.616.520.731.5 20.520.6–4.8 23.8 15.3 1.9 15.9 11.9 17.0 6.3 1.5 8.5 1.4 3.8 8.2 2.1 5.7 6.5 8.1 6.1 13.9 –1.9 7.7 9.8 11.3 –0.2 –6.6 2.4 2.76.05.2 10.8 9.23.6 –0.5 3.0 5.7 –0.5 0.2 –0.8 –2.7 49–53 51–57 53–56 52–56 53–55 0.3 10.4 –19.1 54–61 59–68 61–64 Source:RBI. The second and third quarter of the calendar year 2013 witnessed sharp depreciation of the rupee, with the exchange rate of the USD moving from a minimum of Rs. 54 to a maximum of Rs. 68. 46 as a percentage of nominal GDP has gone up steadily over the last 10 years and touched nearly 4.8 per cent by 2012. Third, the deficits were met with inflows in the capital account primarily in the form of foreign investment, in which foreign portfolio investment played a significant role, particularly over the last 10 years. Fourth, foreign portfolio investment is sensitive to news and market gossips and the players who are active in the market for foreign portfolio investment (both debt and equity) tended to exhibit herd behaviour. Trends in more recent quarters are provided in Table 2. The second and third quarter of the calendar year 2013 witnessed sharp depreciation of the rupee, with the exchange rate of the USD moving from a minimum of Rs. 54 to a maximum of Rs. 68. In particular, balances on both the capital and current accounts turned negative during the quarter July–September 2013. An interesting unresolved issue in this context is the relationship between current account balance (CA) and capital account balance (KA). The BoP equilibrium condition can be written as: CA + KA – ∆R = 0, where ∆R is the change in forex reserves (with ∆R < 0 implying reserve accumulation and ∆R > 0 implying drawdown of reserves). Of course, with full flexibility of the exchange rate and in a reserve currency issuing country the importance of ∆R would be minimal. The typical Indian case (for most years since 2000) may be characterised as: CA < 0, KA > 0 and ∆R < 0 with some two-way flexibility of the exchange rate. The relationship between CA and KA is complex, and conceptually, there are elements of simultaneity in their relationship. Hence it would be erroneous to ascribe the causality from CA to KA or the other way round. While the exchange rate, global growth, domestic growth, terms of trade and export and import restrictions can all influence CA, the major determinants of KA would include factors such as country- risk adjusted return, domestic and global growth, and restrictions on inward and outward foreign investment. The Indian case in this framework may be interpreted as follows. With huge amounts of liquidity sloshing around the globe as a result of the policy of quantitative easing in the US, and the growth rate in the Indian economy being reasonably high, considerable capital inflows (both investment and borrowing) got attracted to India in the quest for yield. Around that time (in 2009–10), with good growth and a manageable CAD, the risk profile of India would also have appeared reasonable to a typical foreign institutional investor. This gave a sense of confidence (perhaps false and premature) to the Indian policymakers and prompted them to increasingly liberalize the import regime: the policy towards gold imports over the past three years is an illustration in this regard. This led to widening of the CAD. When hints were dropped about tapering, the Indian economy was not exactly doing too well. With subdued growth, high CAD, and corruption and governance issues, expectedly, the risks associated with the Indian economy could not but appear higher in mid-2012 than in 2009 or 2010. Hence, in such a situation, an FII needs to be compensated with a much higher risk-adjusted return for continuing to invest in India. Thus, faced with the hints of tapering and perceived higher risks in India, there were massive capital outflows. With both CA and KA being negative, the equilibrium was achieved through a combination of some drawdown of reserves and a huge adjustment in the exchange rate. But to begin with, we need to see what caused the outflows in the capital account. In line with the literature already cited above, this paper argues that both the tapering talks as well as India’s high and persistent CAD are responsible for this sharp downward movement of the INR vis-à-vis the USD. Tapering Talks and Capital Outflows It is well known that US monetary policy during a large part of the first decade of the 21st century was somewhat easy.5 In particular, when the sub-prime crisis hit the US economy in August 2007, the US Fed responded quickly. Initially it cut the discount rate and started extended term loans to banks, and then, in September, lowered the target for the Federal funds rate by 50 basis points. Thereafter successive cuts amounting to a total of 325 basis points left the funds rate at 2 per cent by April 2008. (Bernanke, 2012.) When the sub-prime crisis culminated in the global financial turmoil in September 2008, the target for the Federal funds rate was cut further by 100 basis points in October 2008. Finally, by December 2008 the target rate was reduced to a range of 0 to 25 basis points, effectively its lower bound (Chart 3). The effective rate till date continues to be at this level. 5 Taylor (2009) has shown that in terms of a perceived monetary policy rule (typical Taylor’s rule), the actual policy rate fell well below what historical experience would suggest. icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 Faced with the hints of tapering and perceived higher risks in India, there were massive capital outflows. With both current account balance and capital account balance being negative, the equilibrium was achieved through a combination of some drawdown of reserves and a huge adjustment in the exchange rate. 47 Chart 3 Effective Federal Funds Rate and Size of US Fed’s Balance Sheet icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 Faced with the intensification of financial crisis Source: US Fed. and recessionary tendencies, in the latter part of 2008 and early 2009, the Federal Reserve took extraordinary steps to provide liquidity and support credit market functioning, including the establishment of a number of emergency lending facilities. 48 Faced with the intensification of financial crisis and recessionary tendencies, “in the latter part of 2008 and early 2009, the Federal Reserve took extraordinary steps to provide liquidity and support credit market functioning, including the establishment of a number of emergency lending facilities”. (Bernanke, 2012.) The injections of such liquidity, popularly called quantitative easing (QE), led to a bloating of the balance sheet of the US Fed via a number of instruments/facilities such as lending to financial firms and markets; rescue operations; holding of agency (like Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac) securities and mortgage backed securities; and treasury holdings (of varied maturity). Consequently, the size of the US Fed’s balance sheet underwent a huge expansion from around USD 800 billion in mid-2008 to a little over USD 3 trillion in early 2013 (Chart 3). By the time Chairman Bernanke left the US Fed in end-January 2014, the size of the balance sheet of the US Fed surpassed the USD 4 trillion mark—an increase of nearly 390 per cent over its mid-2008 level! With exceptionally low interest rates (both at short and long ends) as well as the huge amount of liquidity overflowing the US economy, short-term capital, which had dried up immediately after the crisis, started flowing to EMEs. In fact, in the initial days of the QE era (QE1 and QE2), there were large net flows of capital to EMEs. (Subramanian, 2014; Chart 4.)6 But after 2010, the flows started declining and continued to do so before the Fed chairman hinted at possibilities of tapering off of QE in May 2013. 6 This is at some variance with the findings of Fratzscher, Duca and Straub (2013) that “QE1 policies during the first phase in 2008–2009 have triggered a substantial rebalancing in global portfolios, with investors shifting out of EMEs and other AEs and into US equity and bond funds”. In contrast, “Fed policies during the second phase in 2010 (QE2) induced a portfolio rebalancing in the opposite direction, pushing capital into EMEs”. Chart 4 Net Capital Flows to Emerging Markets, 1990–2013 (% of EMs’ GDP) icra bulletin Money & 5.0% QE Era In percent of GDP 4.5% 4.0% Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 3.5% 3.0% 2.5% 2.0% By end-May 1.5% 1.0% 2013 the US Fed 0.5% Source: 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0.0% Subramanian (2014). By end-May 2013 the US Fed dropped its first hint that in view of the improving situation in the US, the pace of its asset purchase programme could be slowed down. On May 22, 2013, US Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke made the following statement in his testimony before the US Congress: “Over the nearly four years since the recovery began, the economy has been held back by a number of headwinds. Some of these headwinds have begun to dissipate recently, in part because of the Federal Reserve’s highly accommodative monetary policy. Notably, the housing market has strengthened over the past year, supported by low mortgage rates and improved sentiment on the part of potential buyers. Increased housing activity is fostering job creation in construction and related industries, such as real estate brokerage and home furnishings, while higher home prices are bolstering household finances, which helps support the growth of private consumption.” (Bernanke, 2013.) This statement was largely interpreted by the financial market players as a hint that the US Fed may soon start tapering off the size of the bond-buying programme. Subsequently, Chairman Bernanke indicated in as many words that the inevitable withdrawal of stimulus would happen sooner than expected and said in a press conference on June 20, 2013: “If the incoming data support the view that the economy is able to sustain a reasonable cruising speed, we will ease the pressure on the accelerator by gradually reducing the pace of purchases.” Thus, what was a hint on May 22 got confirmed with the June 20 statement. These statements generated a spate of withdrawals from the emerging economies; the more vulnerable (in terms of market-watched indicators like CAD or fiscal deficit) a country was, more was the with- dropped its first hint that in view of the improving situation in the US, the pace of its asset purchase programme could be slowed down. 49 icra bulletin Table 3 FII Investment Flows Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 In contrast to the earlier trends in FII inflows, the three months, June, July and August 2013, were characterized by substantial outflows in both debt as well (USD million) Financial Year Equity Net Investment 2006–07 2007–08 2008–09 2009–10 2010–11 2011–12 2012–13 2013–14 so far Jan-13 Feb-13 Mar-13 Apr-13 May-13 Jun-13 Jul-13 Aug-13 Sep-13 Oct-13 Nov-13 Dec-13 Jan-14 Feb-14 Debt Net Investment 5,942 13,433 –10,712 23,353 24,295 9,012 25,832 10,243 4,096 4,142 1,913 1,184 3,772 –1,764 –986 –947 1,994 2,927 1,130 2,527 –13 420 Total Flows 1,3217,263 3,19316,626 492–10,220 6,56829,921 8,37132,666 10,06319,075 5,21531,047 –5,747 4,496 614 4,710 755 4,898 924 2,836 1,288 2,471 520 4,292 –5,366 –7,130 –2,111 –3,097 –1,379 –2,325 –1,260 734 –2,095 832 –784 346 863 3,390 2,021 2,009 2,555 2,975 Source:RBI. as equity. drawal and larger the consequent impact on its exchange rate. India was no exception to this trend. In contrast to the earlier trends in FII inflows, the three months, June, July and August 2013, were characterized by substantial outflows in both debt as well as equity on account of FIIs; so much so that during the three months, aggregate outflows amounted to nearly USD 12.5 billion, larger than the aggregate outflows of USD 10.2 billion during the crisis year of 2008–09 (Table 3). An interesting feature of FII outflows during June–August 2013 was the predominance of debt outflows. In fact, even after flows on account of equity turned into inflows after September 2013, debt outflows continued for three more months. Incidentally, this trend is in tune with international evidence presented by Forbes and Warnock (2012) who found: “Most episodes around the world—80% of episodes of sharp changes in capital inflows (driven by foreigners) and 70% of episodes of sharp movements in capital outflows (driven by domestics)—result primarily from changes in debt flows.”(p. 17.)7 50 7 Market watchers widely believe that foreign capital flows to the Indian debt market are dominated by five to six foreign banks. Thus, the possibility of herding behav- As already noted, following the announcement by the US Fed on postponing tapering off of asset purchase programmes, by September 2013, FII flows started coming back, primarily on account of the equity market as the withdrawal on account of debt instruments continued for three more months. The reasons are not far to seek. The Record of the Federal Open Market Committee’s meeting of July 30–31 hinted that withdrawal would be delayed and went on to say: “Almost all committee members agreed that a change in the purchase program was not yet appropriate, and a few said that it might soon be time to slow somewhat the pace of purchases as outlined in that plan.” Finally, the FOMC Statement released on September 18, 2013 put an end to all speculation and stated the following categorically: “The Committee will closely monitor incoming information on economic and financial developments in coming months and will continue its purchases of Treasury and agency mortgage-backed securities, and employ its other policy tools as appropriate, until the outlook for the labor market has improved substantially in a context of price stability. … Asset purchases are not on a preset course, and the Committee’s decisions about their pace will remain contingent on the Committee’s economic outlook as well as its assessment of the likely efficacy and costs of such purchases.” With such statements about postponement of the tapering off of the QE in the US, the FIIs started coming back to India, the investments initially in the form of equity; debt flows took some time and started coming back only from December 2013. These eased the pressure on the INR. Were Weak Fundamentals Responsible for Capital Outflows? But why was India affected by those apparently innocuous statements of the US Fed? One of the asymmetries of the herd behaviour of the FIIs is that when the going is good, often FII flows tend to enter the emerging countries in a somewhat undifferentiated manner. 8 The so-called “herd behaviour” is often based solely on “market sentiment” rather than an objective assessment of market fundamentals. After all, acquiring information can be costly in terms of time and money. Moreover, for institutional investors, herding can emerge from either a rational or irrational form of investors’ behaviour. In fact, when investors irrationally withdraw credits from otherwise stable and “healthy” economies, initial capital flight could cause a reduction in the value of assets, which in turn could cause a rational capital flight.9 iour tends to be more in the debt market that has fewer market players than in the equity market, which has a far larger number of players. 8 There is large literature on herd behaviour; see Hirshleifer and Teoh (2001) for a survey. 9 Lakshman, Basu and Vaidyanathan (2013) found some limited evidence of herding in the Indian capital market. icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 With statements about postponement of the tapering off of the QE in the US, the FIIs started coming back to India, the investments initially in the form of equity; debt flows took some time and started coming back only from December 2013. These eased the pressure on the INR. 51 icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 Apart from the interest rate differential and liquidity conditions, in a long menu of market fundamentals, the two most watched indicators are current account balance and fiscal balance. By the metric of CAD, India’s progress report was rather alarming as it touched nearly 4.8% by 2012–13. 52 But in case any crisis is brewing, while withdrawing financial flows FIIs tend to differentiate between the countries in terms of their market fundamentals. This trend was distinctly noticeable in Greece when the market players suddenly started differentiating Greece from other euro countries and the sovereign bond spread of Greece went up to stratospheric levels. The present crisis is no exception to this observed behaviour. Moreover, it has been empirically found that less easy global financing conditions, with possibilities of rising interest rates in advanced economies and low investor risk appetite, generally see temporary tides of capital outflows. (Bluedorn & others, 2013.) Apart from the interest rate differential and liquidity conditions, in a long menu of market fundamentals, the two most watched indicators are current account balance and fiscal balance.10 By the metric of CAD, India’s progress report was rather alarming as it touched nearly 4.8 per cent by 2012–13 or around USD 90 billion. The reasons are not far to seek. India has a number of items, imports of which have increased substantially in recent years. Illustratively, both gold and oil imports have gone up substantially and Indian exports in recent years have suffered, reflecting the continuing recessionary situation in the global economy. In fact, the trade deficit widened from USD 42.2 billion in the first quarter (Q1) of 2012–13 to USD 50.2 billion in Q1 of 2013–14, mainly on account of a sharp increase in gold imports. In particular, imports grew by 6.0 per cent in Q1 of 2013–14 as against a decline of 5.7 per cent in Q1 of 2012–13 with gold imports having almost doubled from USD 9.2 billion in Q1 of 2012–13 to USD 17.9 billion in Q1 of 2013– 14. Besides, notwithstanding a fall of 5.7 per cent in international crude oil prices (Indian basket) in Q1 of 2013–14 (year-on-year), oil imports grew by 6.4 per cent. Persistence of high inflation in India could also have played some role here. The burgeoning CAD was financed by three major types of capital inflows, viz., foreign direct investment (FDI), foreign portfolio investment (FPI, in which FII is the dominant item), and short-term debt. In 2012–13, while dependence on FDI came down, that on both FPI and loans increased substantially (Table 4). The current situation is clearer from the quarterly numbers of these three components of foreign investment that the RBI releases as part of the quarterly BoP statistics. The fall in FPI flows during the quarter ending September 2013 was very substantial. With such large outflows on account FPI, it is no wonder that the rupee came under huge pressure (Chart 5). For example, in the context of the exchange rate turmoil during June–August 2013 a recent market-watch report observed: “It is noteworthy that for a number of emerging economies, including South Africa, Turkey, and India, much of the current turmoil is also due to deterioration in economic fundamentals, primarily high current account deficits, entrenched inflationary pressures, and deteriorating public finances.” (Deloitte Global Economic Outlook, Fourth Quarter 2013, available at http://dupress.com/ articles/global-economic-outlook-q4-2013.) 10 icra bulletin Table 4 Financing of Indian CAD (USD billion) Memo: CAD Select Items of DForex INR-USD Capital Account Reserves Exchange Rate FDI FPI Loans (Increase –/ Decrease +) Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 2004–05 44.9315 –2.5 3.7 9.3 10.9 –26.2 2005–06 44.2735 –9.9 3.0 12.5 7.9 –15.1 2006–07 45.2849 –9.6 7.7 7.1 24.5 –36.6 2007–08 40.2410 –15.7 15.9 27.4 40.7 –92.2 2008–09 45.9170 –27.9 22.4 –14.0 8.3 20.1 2009–10 47.4166 –38.2 18.0 32.4 12.4 –13.4 2010–11 45.5768 –48.1 11.8 30.3 29.1 –13.1 2011–12 47.9229 –78.2 22.1 17.2 19.3 12.8 2012–13 54.4091 –88.2 19.8 26.9 31.1 –3.8 2013–14 (Apr– Dec 2013) 60.0819 –31.1 20.7 –4.4 6.2 –8.4 Apr–June 2013 55.9491 –21.8 6.5 –0.2 3.6 0.3 July–Sept 201362.1278 –5.2 8.1–6.6–0.5 10.4 Oct–Dec 2013 62.0339 –4.1 6.1 2.4 3.0 –19.1 Source:RBI. Chart 5 Foreign Investment Inflows Source:RBI. IV. Some Cross-Country Evidence India was not alone in this bandwagon of currency pressure during June–August 2013. Chart 6 (Panels a and b) depicts the exchange rates (with respect to USD) of the currencies of the four of the five countries in the BRICS bloc along with Mexico, Malaysia and Indonesia wherein the exchange rates have been normalized to May 22, 2013 (i.e., the date of the US Fed announcement on tapering) as equal 53 icra bulletin Money & Finance Chart 6 Exchange Rates (in USD) in Select Countries (May 22 = 1) Panel a: China, India, Indonesia, and South Africa J u l y . 2 0 1 4 With the exception of China, the currencies of all the other Panel b: Mexico, Malaysia, and Brazil countries were on a depreciating trend over May–August 2013. Illustratively, by September 1, 2013, both the Indian rupee and the Brazilian real had depreciated by more than 15% each since the US Fed’s announcement in May 2013. 54 Source: Bloomberg. to unity. As earlier, an upward (downward) movement will indicate a depreciating (appreciating) exchange rate. With the exception of China, the currencies of all the other countries were on a depreciating trend over May–August 2013. Illustratively, by September 1, 2013, both the Indian rupee and the Brazilian real had depreciated by more than 15 per cent each since the US Fed’s announcement in May 2013. Dividing the period of 2013 (till Nov 21, 2013) into three distinct periods, viz., (a) January 1–May 22; (b) May 22–September 19; and (c) September 19–December 23, Chart 7 shows that during the second sub-period almost all currencies had undergone large depreciation with the exception of the reserve currencies (pound sterling, euro and yen) and the Chinese yuan. However, during the third period, there was some improvement. Are there any similarities between the countries experiencing significant currency depreciation? To address this question, Table 5 re- Chart 7 Cross-Country Exchange Rate Movements in 2013 icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 Brazil, China, Mexico and South Africa are all characterized by significant CAD as well as fiscal Source: Compiled from Bloomberg Data. deficit—the two indicators that are ports the CAD and fiscal deficits (both as percentages of nominal GDP) of six EMEs. Interestingly, Brazil, China, Mexico and South Africa are all characterized by significant CAD as well as fiscal deficit (FD)—the two indicators that are watched regularly by the financial market participants as well as rating agencies to assess the attractiveness of an investment destination in a rough and ready manner. It is thus no wonder that, when financial market players are faced with a tapering-like situation and the possible consequent threat of drying up of liquidity, countries with large CADs and FDs tend to experience capital outflows and depreciation of the exchange rate. A related issue is the nature of relationship between the CAD and FD. International financial institutions like the IMF often propagate the twin deficits hypothesis which states that budget deficits would lead to the CAD (Kumhof and Laxton, 2009). On the other hand, in some quarters, the “Lawson doctrine” (named after Nigel Lawson, the British Chancellor of the Exchequer in Margaret Thatcher’s Cabinet during the 1980s) is quite popular. According to this doctrine, as long as the CAD reflects the saving–investment imbalances of the private agents, it is not alarming (perhaps in line with the Ricardian equivalence); however, when it is accompanied by fiscal deficit, CAD is bad.11 Admittedly, this 11 When individuals, as in the Ricardian equivalence, maximise their utility, subject to their inter-temporal budget constraints, and the economy’s investment-saving watched regularly by the financial market participants as well as rating agencies to assess the attractiveness of an investment destination. 55 icra bulletin Table 5 Current Account Balance and Fiscal Balance of Some EM Economies (% of GDP) Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 There is a mild positive association between CAD and exchange rate Country Brazil –1.7–1.5–2.2–2.1 –2.4–3.4 China 9.34.94.01.9 2.32.5 India –2.3–2.8–2.7–4.2 –4.8–4.4 Mexico –1.8–0.9–0.3–1.0 –1.2–1.3 Russia 6.34.14.45.1 3.72.9 South Africa–7.2–4.0–2.8–3.4 –6.3–6.1 Brazil –1.4–3.1–2.7–2.5 –2.7–3.0 China –0.7–3.1–1.5–1.3 –2.2–2.5 India –10.0–9.8–8.4–8.5 –8.0–8.5 Mexico –1.0–5.1–4.3–3.4 –3.7–3.8 Russia 4.9–6.3–3.4 1.5 0.4–0.7 South Africa–0.4–5.5–5.1–4.0 –4.8–4.9 General Government Net Lending/ Borrowing & Current Account Balance Money 2008200920102011 20122013 Source: World Economic Outlook Database, IMF, October 2013. depreciation. In fact, acute exchange rate pressures were felt especially by the macroeconomically vulnerable economies, Brazil, Indonesia, India, and Turkey. 56 notion springs primarily from a philosophy of fiscal fundamentalism and hence may not have much relevance. Of course, if the FD is largely financed by sovereign borrowing in the global market (denominated in a foreign currency) and is subscribed to by foreign entities, such FD can be linked to capital inflows. To the extent surplus in capital flows (via sovereign debt) can induce an economy to incur a CAD, the two deficits can be interlinked.12 Fortunately, the sovereign debt in most of the six countries in Table 5 is not alarming. The empirical literature has, however, mostly concluded that the link between the FD and CAD is weak or non-existent. (Bussière and others, 2010.) While the Chinese currency hardly faced any depreciation in its exchange rate, in terms of recent movements (as captured by the trend line) there is a mild positive association between CAD and exchange rate depreciation. (RBI, 2013.) In fact, acute exchange rate pressures were felt especially by the “macroeconomically vulnerable economies”, Brazil, Indonesia, India, and Turkey (Chart 8).13 Thus, significant CADs accompanied by dependence on fickle portfolio flows could have made India vulnerable to external shocks.14 imbalance is an outcome of inter-temporal optimisation of such individuals, one need not worry about current account deficits. 12 Parenthetically, one may note that in some sense, this is the situation in a number of Euro area crisis countries. 13 These countries have been included as part of a group of countries named “Fragile Five” by the investment bank Morgan Stanley in a recent internal note; see https://www.morganstanley.com/public/Tales_from_the_Emerging_World_Fragile_Five.pdf. 14 Reportedly, Moody’s Analytics in a recent report (entitled “How US Monetary Tightening Affects Asian Markets”) had remarked that: “India and Indonesia are the most vulnerable to capital outflows because of high reliance on external funding.” (The Hindu, September 23, 2013, available at http://www.thehindu.com/business/Economy/ india-most-vulnerable-to-capital-outflows-moodys/article5160832.ece.) Chart 8 Current Account Balance/GDP and Extent of Currency Depreciation/Appreciation icra bulletin Money & Appreciation (–) / Depreciation (+) Finance Current account balance Source: Subramanian (2014). V. The Indian Policy Initiatives Faced with capital outflows, the pressure on CAD and the associated exchange rate depreciation, the Indian authorities initiated a number of measures, to which we now turn.15 RBI Intervention Strategy The first question that comes up in this respect is: How much did the RBI intervene in the forex market to arrest the fall of the rupee? While providing a policy buffer, forex reserves could allow a country to intervene in such conditions.16 However, the RBI’s direct intervention in the forex market was somewhat limited; during the months of June– September 2013, the total extent of intervention of the RBI was a little above USD 14 billion (Chart 9). After all, as on May 31, 2013, India’s total forex reserves amounted to USD 288 billion, of which foreign currency assets of USD 259 billion could have been used for market intervention. (Seshan, 2014.) The reason appears to be that, given the compulsions of the impossible trinity (whereby a country cannot have an independent monetary policy, a fixed exchange rate and prefect capital mobility at the same time) and India’s macroeconomic configuration, chasing any illusive exchange rate could have been futile. After all, such a strategy would have meant either presence of an elaborate set-up of capital controls or huge forex reserves, both of which India did not have. See Sinha (2014) for a discussion on these measures. Reportedly, Brazil announced a USD 60 billion currency intervention programme in August 2013, involving swaps and repurchase agreements with businesses requiring dollars. Turkey’s central bank is reported to have sold USD 6–8 billion in foreign currency auctions since June 2013. (RBI, 2014.) 15 16 J u l y . 2 0 1 4 Given the compulsions of the impossible trinity and India’s macroeconomic configuration, chasing any illusive exchange rate could have been futile. After all, such a strategy would have meant either presence of an elaborate set-up of capital controls or huge forex reserves, both of which India did not have. 57 Chart 9 Net Purchase/Sale of Foreign Currencies by RBI (USD million) icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 The RBI implemented two key policies to lessen the pressure on the exchange rate. First, the RBI opened a forex swap window to meet the entire daily dollar requirements of three public sector oil marketing companies. Second, the Indian and the Japanese governments have expanded their bilateral currency swap arrangement. 58 Source: RBI Bulletin, various issues. Other Measures Instead of intervening heavily to defend the rupee, the RBI implemented two key policies to lessen the pressure on the exchange rate. First, the RBI opened a forex swap window to meet the entire daily dollar requirements of three public sector oil marketing companies (viz., Indian Oil, Hindustan Petroleum, and Bharat Petroleum) with effect from August 28, 2013. Under the swap facility, the RBI undertook sell/ buy USD-INR forex swaps for fixed tenure with the oil marketing companies through a designated bank. This swap facility continued for the next three months and was withdrawn on December 2, 2013 after the rupee stabilized to a large extent. Second, the Indian and the Japanese governments have expanded their bilateral currency swap arrangement from USD 15 billion to USD 50 billion to impart stability to the forex situation. A number of other policy measures were also initiated to augment capital inflows. These included: exemption of incremental FCNR(B)/NRE deposits with a maturity of three years and above from cash reserve ratio/statutory liquidity ratio (CRR/SLR) requirements; exclusion of the incremental FCNR(B)/NRE deposits from adjusted net bank credit for computation of priority sector lending targets; liberalization of FDI norms through review of limits; raising of the overseas borrowing limit of banks from 50 to 100 per cent of the unimpaired Tier I capital (with the option of swap with the RBI); and permitting of borrowers to avail themselves of external commercial borrowings (ECBs) under the approval route from their foreign equity holder company for general corporate purposes. Finally, two major steps were taken to curb gold imports—one of the major factors responsible for increasing India’s import bill. First, the RBI rationalized gold import rules whereby under the new norms, all banks and authorized agencies would have to ensure that at least 20 per cent of the imported gold was made available for exports and a similar amount retained with the customs. Second, import duty on gold was increased twice; initially, on June 5 the duty was raised to 8 per cent from 6 per cent, and then to 10 per cent on August 13.17 All these measures went a long way in containing the CAD and easing pressure on the rupee. With slowdown in imports (particularly gold import) and improvements in global trade, India’s trade deficit went down for the sixth consecutive month in December 2013. Following the shrinking of the trade deficit, the CAD declined from 4.9 per cent of GDP in Q1 to 1.2 per cent of GDP in Q2 of 2013–14. The RBI expressed the optimism that the full year CAD “is likely to be contained within the sustainable level of about 2.5 per cent of GDP”. (RBI, 2014a.) VI. Concluding Observations The paper has examined the recent depreciation of the INR against the USD during June–August 2013. The proximate factors triggering the episode were the US Fed’s announcements of tapering off QE in end-May 2013 and the consequent withdrawal of capital flows (primarily on account of portfolio outflows, both debt and equity). India with its somewhat fragile macroeconomic fundamentals, as reflected in its high and increasing CAD (financed mostly by foreign portfolio inflows), was affected by these adverse global developments. In fact, India’s was not an isolated instance in this respect: the exchange rates of various other countries with similar macro fragility also depreciated sharply following the QE tapering off related announcements. The rupee started recovering following the introduction of a number of measures for reducing CAD coinciding with the announcement of the US Fed in September 2013 to the effect that the proposed tapering off would be deferred for the time being. Thus, as in Agatha Christie’s Murder on the Orient Express, the responsibility for the instability in the forex market in India during the three months could not be pinned down to a single villain. While the US Fed’s tapering talks were no doubt the initial trigger, the dependence on volatile foreign investment and short-term debt to finance an increasing CAD (along with the deterioration in various other macroeconomic indicators watched by market players) constituted compelling reasons for the withdrawal of foreign institutional investors from India. Apart from this lesson, the episode underscores the flip side of opening up the financial sector. At the risk of being accused of pontificating, one may state that financial globalization is a double-edged sword: it brings capital in good times and takes it out in bad. It is a matter of concern that the Indian economy was not prepared for such 17 Earlier on January 21, 2013 the government raised gold import duty by 2 percentage points to 6 per cent. icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 India’s was not an isolated instance: the exchange rates of various other countries with similar macro fragility also depreciated sharply following the QE tapering off related announcements. 59 icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 60 bad times. And it is little wonder that the heavy dependence on foreign capital proved costly. Incidentally, such dependence on fickle sources for financing CAD is not new. For instance, during the 1980s, India developed a great dependence on non-resident Indian (NRI) deposits, thereby increasing its vulnerability to external shocks (Rakshit, 2009), and the crisis of 1991 only got worse with the withdrawal of such deposits. Does this mean that the policymakers forgot the earlier crises? Also, in a larger context, have we been oblivious of Keynes on internationalization? In his words: “Ideas, knowledge, science, hospitality, travel—these are the things which should of their nature be international. But let goods be homespun whenever it is reasonably and conveniently possible, and, above all, let finance be primarily national.”18 These are however broader issues and beyond the scope of the present paper. 18 Keynes, J.M. (1933): “National Self-Sufficiency”, The Yale Review, Vol. 22, no. 4, June 1933, available at https://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/interwar/keynes.htm. Appendix icra bulletin Money Comparison between 1991 Crisis and the June–August 2013 Exchange Rate Debacle Variable 1 Global prices Gulf Crisis (1983–84 to 1992–93) & Finance Current Situation (2003–04 to 2012–13) Oil and commodity prices went up and Global commodity and crude prices have been J u l y . 2 0 1 4 became more volatile after the first Gulf War. more or less stable during the last few years. 2 Domestic Inflation rate was more volatile and inflation it was 7.1% in 1992–93. Inflation, though high during the last three years, is declining and stands at 5.7% as of 2012–13. 3 Growth is subdued at 6.9% and will decline, going by the current trends. Domestic GDP growth Growth picked up from 1992–93 because of the many economic measures initiated. 4 Foreign ex- In 1990–91, at one point in time, it was only change reserves USD 1 billion, just enough to finance barely two weeks’ imports. Foreign exchange reserve is at USD 279 billion as of July 29, 2013, sufficient for 6.8 months’ imports. 5 CAD CAD became unsustainable because global CAD has become unsustainable because of commodity prices increased, pushing up increasing import of petroleum products, interest costs and amortization, with a drying gold and many other luxury items. up of remittances, especially from Kuwait. 6 Trade deficit Export income was able to meet 78% of import bill, which rose mainly because of an increase in global oil and commodity prices. Exports can pay for only 61% of imports mainly because of higher oil and gold imports. 7 Net invisibles Net invisibles declined from USD 3.5 billion in 1983–84 to USD 1.9 billion in 1992–93. Able to cover only 35% of trade deficit. Net invisibles position is not bad at USD 107.8 billion and is able to cover about 55% of trade deficit. 8 Debt payment Debt payment increased and was equivalent (net income) to 88.8% of remittances in 1992–93. Debt payment has increased but is only 33.3% of remittances as of 2012–13. 9 Remittances Average growth was 4.7% during the period and the figure was USD 3.9 billion. Average growth has been 12.9% during the period and the figure is USD 64.3 billion as of 2012–13. 10 Net capital receipts Net capital receipts have been more than sufficient to defray the CAD and thus there have been additions to the foreign exchange reserve in most years except 2008–09 and 2011–12. Net capital receipts were not sufficient to defray the CAD; hence the increasing recourse to drawdown from foreign exchange reserve and withdrawals from IMF to pay for the deficits. 11 Foreign Foreign investment was insignificant during investment the period. Foreign investment flows have been sufficient to cover the deficit and have added to foreign exchange reserves. However, overdependence, especially on volatile portfolio investments, is dangerous. 12 NRI deposits NRI deposits are 0.8% of GDP as of 2012–13. Deposits were 0.1% of GDP in 1991–92 and rose to 0.8% by 1992–93. 13 What ahead? Improved after 1992–93 as the government adopted different economic and reform measures to improve the overall health of the economy. Present position is much better than that in 1991. Hence for the present recourse to IMF is not warranted. Measures that would constrict imports, like imposing higher customs duty on gold, while taking adequate measures to attract the more stable foreign direct investment can help in overcoming the present difficulties. Source: Krishnaswamy and Kanagasabapathy (2013). 61 icra bulletin Money & Finance J u l y . 2 0 1 4 62 References Bernanke, Ben (2012), “Monetary Policy since the Onset of the Crisis”, speech delivered at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming on August 31, 2012, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/ newsevents/speech/bernanke20120831a.htm. Bernanke, Ben (2013), “Testimony on the Economic Outlook”, before the Joint Economic Committee, U.S. Congress, Washington, D.C. on May 22, 2013, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20130522a.htm. Bluedorn, John, Rupa Duttagupta, Jaime Guajardo and Petia Topalova (2013), “Capital Flows are Fickle: Anytime, Anywhere”, IMF Working Paper, WP/13/183. Bussière, M., M. Fratzscher and G. Müller (2010), “Productivity Shocks, Budget Deficits and the Current Account”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 29: 1562–79. Correa, Romar (2013), “Open-Economy Macro and Inflation Targeting: A Tutorial”, Economic & Political Weekly, December 21, 2013. Forbes, Kristin J. and Francis E. Warnock (2012), “Debt- and Equity-Led Capital Flow Episodes”, NBER Working Paper No. 18329, available at http://www.nber.org/ papers/w18329. Fratzscher, Marcel, Marco Lo Duca and Roland Straub (2013), “On the International Spillovers of US Quantitative Easing”, ECB Working Paper No. 1557/June 2013, available at http://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp1557.pdf. Hirshleifer, David and Siew Hong Teoh (2001), “Herd Behavior and Cascading in Capital Markets: A Review and Synthesis”, Munich Personal RePEc Archive, available at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5186/1/MPRA_paper_5186.pdf. Jalan, Bimal (2003), “Exchange Rate Management: An Emerging Consensus?”, speech of the RBI Governor at the 14th National Assembly of Forex Association of India on August 14, 2003, available at http://rbi.org.in/Scripts/BS_SpeechesView.aspx?Id=133. Krishnaswamy, R. and K. Kanagasabapathy (2013), “The Balance of Payments Situation: 1991 and Now”, Economic & Political Weekly, August 17, 2013. Kumhof, Michael and Douglas Laxton (2009), “Fiscal Deficits and Current Account Deficits”, IMF Working Paper, No. WP/09/237, available at http://www.imf. org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2009/wp09237.pdf. Lakshman, M.V., Sankarshan Basu and R. Vaidyanathan (2013), “Market-wide Herding and the Impact of Institutional Investors in the Indian Capital Market”, Journal of Emerging Market Finance, 12: 197. Rajwade, A.V. (2013), “External Sector, Growth and the Exchange Rate”, Economic & Political Weekly, July 20, 2013. Rakshit, Mihir (2009), Macroeconomics of Post-Reforms India, Delhi: Oxford University Press. Rangarajan, C. and Prachi Mishra (2013), “India’s External Sector: Do We Need to Worry?”, Economic & Political Weekly, February 16, 2013. Reserve Bank of India (2014), “Report of the Expert Committee to Revise and Strengthen the Monetary Policy Framework” (Chairman: Urjit Patel), Mumbai, RBI, available at http://rbi.org.in/scripts/PublicationReportDetails. aspx?UrlPage=&ID=743. Reserve Bank of India (2014a), “Macroeconomic and Monetary Developments—Third Quarter Review 2013–14”, January 28, 2014, available at http://rbi.org.in/ scripts/AnnualPublications.aspx?head=Macroeconomic%20and%20Monetary%20Developments. Sen, Partha (2013), “India’s Current Account Woes: An Attempt to Clarify”, Economic & Political Weekly, October 12, 2013. Seshan, A. (2014), “Should the RBI defend the rupee? No”, Business Line, June 14, 2013, available at http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/opinion/should-the-rbidefend-the-rupee-no/article4814891.ece. Sinha, Anup (2014), “Macro Overview”, ICRA Bulletin: Money and Finance, February. Subramanian, Arvind (2014), “International Impacts of the Federal Reserve’s Quantitative Easing Program”, prepared testimony submitted to the House Committee on Financial Services Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade on January 9, 2014, available at http://www.iie.com/publications/testimony/subramanian20140109.pdf. Tarapore, S.S. (2013), “Let the rupee slide, and fast”, Business Line, June 13, 2013, available at http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/opinion/columns/s-s-tarapore/letthe-rupee-slide-and-fast/article4811064.ece. Taylor, John B. (2009), Getting Off Track, Stanford, California, Hoover Institution Press. [All URLs accessed during February–March 2014]