Portfolio management: The use of alternative investments for the purpose of diversification Johan Jacob Hattingh Dissertation submitted in fulfillment of the requirements for the degree Magister Commercii in Investment Management in the Faculty of Economic and Management Sciences at the Rand Afrikaans University Johannesburg Study leader: Miss JE Pretorius May 2004 Co-study leader: Prof. CH van Schalkwyk INDEX CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION 1 1.1 INTRODUCTION AND PROBLEM STATEMENT 1 1.2 RESEARCH OBJECTIVES 2 1.3 BENEFITS OF THE RESEARCH 3 1.4 STUDY METHODOLOGY 3 1.5 LIMITATION OF THE STUDY 4 CHAPTER 2: HISTORY AND DEVELOPMENT OF MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY 5 2.1 INTRODUCTION 5 2.2 MARKOWITZ PORTFOLIO THEORY 5 2.2.1 Overview 5 2.2.2 Risk 6 2.2.3 Return 8 2.2.4 The efficient frontier 8 2.3 CAPITAL MARKET THEORY 12 2.3.1 Introduction 12 2.3.2 Overview of the capital market theory (CMT) 13 2.3.2.1 Assumptions of the theory 13 2.3.2.2 Addressing the information need 14 2.3.2.3 Inclusion of a risk-free asset 14 2.4 THE SIGNIFICANCE OF PORTFOLIO THEORY FOR THIS STUDY 2.5 CONCLUSION 16 17 I CHAPTER 3: RISK DIVERSIFICATION: BASIC DEFINITIONS AND APPLICATIONS 19 3.1. INTRODUCTION 19 3.2. RISK 19 3.2.1 Overview 19 3.2.2 Types of risk 20 3.2.3 Risk measurement 21 3.3. RETURN 24 3.3.1 Overview 24 3.3.2 Required rate of return 25 3.3.3 Measurement 27 3.4. THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN RISK AND RETURN 27 3.5. PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION 29 3.5.1 Introduction 29 3.5.2 Constructing the capital market line (CML) 30 3.5.3 Optimal risky portfolio’s 35 3.5.3.1 Diversification 35 3.5.3.1.1 Definition 35 3.5.3.1.2 Systematic vs. unsystematic risk 36 3.5.3.1.3 Methods of establishing diversification 37 I. Different asset classes 37 II. Different market sectors 38 III. Different entities 38 IV. Gaining global exposure 38 V. Exposure to different investment styles 3.5.4 The effect of diversification on the portfolio 38 39 3.5.4.1 Benefits of diversification 40 3.5.5 Constructing the optimal risky portfolio 41 3.5.5.1 Two-asset portfolio 41 3.5.6 Constructing complete portfolios 44 3.6 SUMMARY 47 II CHAPTER 4: IDENTIFICATION OF ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 49 4.1 INTRODUCTION 49 4.2 DEFINING AN INVESTMENT 49 4.3 DEFINING ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT INSTRUMENTS 50 4.4 ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT CATEGORIES 51 4.5 ANTIQUES 52 4.5.1 Definition of an antique 52 4.5.2 Furniture 52 4.5.3 Military memorabilia 55 4.5.4 Clocks and watches 56 4.5.5 Ceramics 58 4.5.6 Glass 59 4.5.7 Books 59 4.5.8 Silver and metalware 60 4.5.9 Firearms 62 4.5.10 Musical instruments 63 4.6 COLLECTABLES 64 4.6.1 Defining collectables 64 4.6.2 Stamps 64 4.6.3 Toys 65 4.6.3.1 Wood and die-cast toys 66 4.6.3.2 Dolls 66 4.6.3.3 Bears 67 4.6.4 Sports memorabilia 68 4.6.5 Precious stones 69 4.6.6 Cars 69 4.6.7 Oriental rugs 71 4.6.8 Autographs 71 4.6.9 Wine 72 4.6.10 Rare, collectable and bullion coins 75 4.6.10.1 Numismatic coins 75 4.6.10.2 Bullion coins 76 III 4.6.10.3 Kruger Rands 77 4.7. ART 77 4.8 GENERAL 80 4.8.1 Containers 80 4.8.2 Racehorses 81 4.8.3 Investing in people (Justin Wilson) 82 4.9. GENERIC FACTORS TO CONSIDER 83 4.9.1 Authenticity 83 4.9.2 Condition 84 4.9.3 Rarity 84 4.9.4 Provenance 85 4.9.5 Familiarity 85 4.9.6 Importance of the asset 86 4.9.7 Technique/workmanship 86 4.9.8 Buying what you like 86 4.10. ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES OF INVESTING IN ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 87 4.10.1 Advantages 87 4.10.2 Disadvantages 88 4.11 SUMMARY 90 CHAPTER 5: EFFICIENT MARKETS AND ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 91 5.1. INTRODUCTION 91 5.2. DEFINING A MARKET 91 5.3. CHARACTERISTICS OF GOOD MARKETS 93 5.4. EFFICIENT MARKETS 94 5.5. THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS (EMH) 94 5.5.1 Weak form EMH 95 5.5.2 Semi-strong form EMH 96 5.5.3 Strong-form EMH 96 5.5.4 Implications of the EMH 97 5.6. EXISTING MARKETS 98 IV 5.6.1 Bond and equity markets 98 5.6.2 Real estate markets 99 5.7. ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT MARKETS 100 5.7.1 Defining alternative investment markets 100 5.7.2 Are alternative markets good markets? 100 5.7.2.1 Availability of information 101 5.7.2.2 Liquidity 101 5.7.2.3 Transaction costs 102 5.7.2.4 Informational efficiency 103 5.7.3 Are alternative markets efficient markets? 103 5.8. CONCLUSION 104 5.9. SUMMARY 104 CHAPTER 6: APPLICATION OF PORTFOLIO THEORY 106 6.1 INTRODUCTION 106 6.2 INCLUSION OF KRUGER RANDS 107 6.2.1 Introduction 107 6.2.2 Assets used in the construction of the portfolios 108 6.2.2.1 Debt instruments 108 6.2.2.1.1 Definition 108 6.2.2.1.2 Assumptions 108 6.2.2.2 Equity investments 109 6.2.2.2.1 Definition 109 6.2.2.2.2 Assumptions 109 6.2.2.3 Cash 110 6.2.2.4 Kruger Rands 110 6.2.2.4.1 Definition 110 6.2.2.4.2 Assumptions 111 6.2.3 Analysis of the assets used to construct the diversified portfolios 111 6.2.3.1 Performance analysis 111 6.2.3.2 Risk analysis 118 V 6.2.4 Portfolio construction 121 6.2.4.1 Co-movements between the assets 121 6.2.4.2 Initial diversified portfolio 124 6.2.4.3 The alternative portfolio 126 6.3 INCLUSION OF WINE ASSETS 128 6.3.1 Introduction 128 6.3.2 Assets used in the construction of the portfolios 130 6.3.3 Analysis of the assets used in the construction of portfolios 131 6.3.3.1 Performance analysis 131 6.3.3.2 Risk analysis 136 6.3.4 Portfolio construction 6.3.4.1 Construction of the diversified portfolio 138 139 6.3.4.2 Construction of the Mouton-Rothschild (MR) portfolio 142 6.3.4.3 Construction of the Montrose portfolio 6.4 INCLUSION OF ART INVESTMENTS 146 150 6.4.1 Introduction and assumptions 150 6.4.2 Assets used in the portfolio construction 151 6.4.3 Analysis of the assets used in the construction of the portfolios 152 6.4.3.1 Performance analysis 152 6.4.3.2 Risk analysis 159 6.4.4 Portfolio construction 160 6.4.4.1 Construction of the diversified portfolio 161 6.4.4.2 Construction of the art portfolio 164 6.5 SUMMARY 166 CHAPTER 7: CONCLUSION 167 7.1 FURTHER RESEARCH POSSIBILITIES 170 BIBLIOGRAPHY 171 VI LIST OF FIGURES Figure 2.1: Probability distribution of assets with different levels of risk 7 Figure 2.2: Risk/Return combinations of two different assets 9 Figure 2.3: Fictitious Efficient Frontier 10 Figure 2.4: Efficient Frontier and Utility Curves 11 Figure 2.5: Combining the Risk-Free Asset and a Risky Portfolio 15 Figure 3.1: Probability Distribution 21 Figure 3.2: The Relationship between Risk and Return 33 Figure 3.3: Systematic risk and Unsystematic risk 40 Figure 3.4: Expected return of the portfolio 43 Figure 3.5: Standard deviation of the portfolio 43 Figure 3.6: Efficient frontiers given different correlations 44 Figure 6.1: Weekly All Bond Index (ALBI) movements 1990 – 2003 Figure 6.2: Weekly All Share Index (ALSI) movements 1990 – 2003 Figure 6.3: 112 112 Weekly 90-Day BA-rate (BA) movements 1990 – 2003 113 Figure 6.4: Weekly price movement of the Kruger Rand 114 Figure 6.5: Weekly HPY for the ALBI (1990 – 2003) 115 Figure 6.6: Weekly HPY for the ALSI (1990 – 2003) 116 Figure 6.7: Weekly HPY for the BA (1990 – 2003) 116 Figure 6.8: Weekly HPY for the Kruger Rand (1990 – 2003) 117 Figure 6.9: Probability distributions of assets 119 Figure 6.10: Scatter plot matrix of asset returns 122 Figure 6.11: Efficient frontier 125 Figure 6.12: Asset mix of a diversified portfolio 125 Figure 6.13: Efficient frontier of the alternative portfolio 126 Figure 6.14: Asset mix of the alternative portfolio 127 Figure 6.15: Monthly price movement of the ALBI 131 Figure 6.16: Monthly price movements of the ALSI 132 Figure 6.17: Monthly rate movements of the 90-day BA-rate 133 VII Figure 6.18: Monthly price movements of the Mouton-Rothschild 1982 133 Figure 6.19: Monthly price movements of the Montrose 134 Figure 6.20: Holding Period Yields on assets 135 Figure 6.21: Probability distributions of assets 137 Figure 6.22: Scatter plot matrix of asset returns 139 Figure 6.23: Efficient frontier for the diversified portfolio 141 Figure 6.24: Asset mix of the diversified portfolio 142 Figure 6.25: Scatter plot matrix of the returns on the assets used in the MR portfolio 143 Figure 6.26: Efficient frontier for the MR portfolio 144 Figure 6.27: Asset mix of the MR portfolio 145 Figure 6.28: Scatter plot matrix of the returns on the assets used in the MR portfolio 147 Figure 6.29: Efficient frontier for the MR portfolio 148 Figure 6.30: Asset mix of the Montrose portfolio 149 Figure 6.31: All Bond Index Movements 152 Figure 6.32: All Share Index Movements 153 Figure 6.33: Annual BA-rates 154 Figure 6.34: Annual movements of the FAI 155 Figure 6.35: HPY movements of the ALBI 156 Figure 6.36: HPY movements of the ALSI 156 Figure 6.37: HPY of the BA 157 Figure 6.38: HPY of the FAI 158 Figure 6.39: Probability distributions of assets 159 Figure 6.40: Scatter plot matrix of asset returns 161 Figure 6.41: Efficient frontier for the diversified portfolio 163 Figure 6.42: Asset mix of the diversified portfolio 163 Figure 6.43: Efficient frontier for the art portfolio 164 Figure 6.44: Asset mix of the art portfolio 165 VIII LIST OF TABLES Table 3.1: Test Data 32 Table 3.2: Test Data 34 Table 3.3: Standard deviation for a given correlation 42 Table 4.1: Performance of the AFPI versus various other assets 54 Table 6.1: Table of comparative performance measures 118 Table 6.2: Variance and standard deviations of assets 120 Table 6.3: Covariance matrix 123 Table 6.4: Correlation coefficient matrix 124 Table 6.5: Portfolio risk and return figures 128 Table 6.6: Table of comparative performance measures 136 Table 6.7: Variance and standard deviation of assets 138 Table 6.8: Correlation coefficient matrix of asset returns 140 Table 6.9: Correlation matrix 144 Table 6.10: Portfolio statistics of the diversified portfolio and the MR portfolio 146 Table 6.11: Correlation matrix 148 Table 6.12: Portfolio statistics of the diversified portfolio, MR portfolio and Montrose portfolio 150 Table 6.13: Table of comparative performance measures 158 Table 6.14: Variance and standard deviation of assets 160 Table 6.15: Correlation coefficient matrix of asset returns 162 Table 6.16: Portfolio statistics of the diversified portfolio and the art portfolio 165 IX CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION 1.1 INTRODUCTION AND PROBLEM STATEMENT Modern financial markets are highly developed and efficient, with market participants having access to seemingly endless amounts of information related to an ever-growing asset selection. Amidst this the basic building blocks for sound investment portfolio construction remain the same. The high levels of efficiency make the process of attaining above-average risk-adjusted returns more difficult than ever before. This should prompt investors to shift their focus to effective portfolio diversification. The following quotes emphasise the importance and some of the characteristics of diversification: • “Modern portfolio theory suggests that diversification is rational…” (Dobbins, Witt and Fielding 1996:12). • “Diversification means that many assets are held in the portfolio so that the exposure to any particular asset is limited.” (Bodie, Kane and Marcus 2003:10). • “This portfolio that includes all risky assets is referred to as the market portfolio…because the market portfolio contains all risky assets, it is a completely diversified portfolio.” (Reilly and Brown 2000:244) • “…given that investors should only take on that part of risk for which they expect to be rewarded.” (Dobbins et al 1996:12) These statements form the basis of any successful investment strategy, be it for the individual investor or the institutional investor. Most advisors, journalists and the like will recommend a healthy balance between cash, equities and debt (bonds), many even recommend holding property in one’s portfolio. 1 The central question being addressed in this study is whether or not cash, equities, bonds and property should be the only assets that investors consider, or are there other alternatives that may hold significant benefits for investors in the form of increased diversification? 1.2 RESEARCH OBJECTIVES The aim of this study is to investigate the potential benefits of including alternative assets (used as a synonym for hard assets throughout the study) in portfolios that are constructed in such a way that they are diversified. The study will start by providing an overview of modern portfolio theory and its most important elements, namely risk, return and diversification. Secondly, the study will identify and discuss various alternative assets that are believed to hold the potential for better diversification and move investors closer to attaining a true market portfolio. Lastly, the study will attempt to prove the hypothesis that these investments do hold the potential of improving the diversification of existing portfolios. Specifically the paper will consider three assets, namely gold coins (in the form of Kruger Rands), wine and art. Focusing on these three aspects will allow the study to verify some of the findings of previous studies, which have shown that the correlations between different alternative investments, such as art and furniture, vary substantially from positive to negative (with more traditional assets), allowing for diversification via the use of these assets. 2 1.3 BENEFITS OF THE RESEARCH The study will aim to emphasise the following: • Any benefits to be gained from using these alternative investments in the construction of a diversified portfolio. • The viability of the use of alternative investments. • Secondary benefits to be obtained from investing in these assets, for example emotional dividends to be gained. The result of this study is believed to be important because: • It will show the diversification effects that these assets might have on existing portfolios. • It will investigate the risk and return pay-off structures of these assets, thus allowing the reader to consider these “alternative” investments as viable additions to his/her portfolio. • If the initial hypotheses are proven to be true, the reader’s investment universe may broaden substantially, allowing for better and more efficient portfolios. 1.4 STUDY METHODOLOGY Initially the study will concentrate on a literature study and overview of basic portfolio theory, after which it will progress into a more detailed study of the key concepts of portfolio theory namely risk, return and diversification. The study will then aim to identify and discuss various alternative investments. This section will give consideration to, among others, the basic constituency of each of the identified asset classes, key characteristics of each of the asset classes and basic determinants of value. This section will also focus on the 3 identification of universal factors which may affect the “investability” of alternative assets in general. The study will conclude with an empirical analysis, aimed at proving the inherent benefits that these assets hold for prospective investors. This section will give consideration to three prominent alternative assets, namely gold coins, wine and art. The study will aim to prove that portfolios, which are believed to be diversified, may be diversified even further via the inclusion of these assets in the portfolio. Consideration, be it direct or indirect, will be given to the effects of changing investment time frames and asset quality. 1.5 LIMITATION OF THE STUDY The limitations of this study, which will become clear as the study progresses include the following: • Due to the fact that none of these alternative assets are traded on formal exchanges (even though progress has been made in at least the wine market), the availability of historical information is limited in various ways. In some instances performance figures had to be generated (based on reasonable assumptions) whilst in other instances (such as was the case for art investments) the extent of the study was limited by the frequency of data, as well as the range of data. • Literature and research aimed specifically at addressing the diversification benefits of alternative assets on existing portfolios, is very limited. 4 CHAPTER 2: HISTORY AND DEVELOPMENT OF MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY 2.1 INTRODUCTION The purpose of this chapter is to serve as an introductory chapter to the history and development of what may be loosely termed “modern portfolio theory.” This chapter will consider the origination and development of some of the concepts which form the basis of this study. The chapter starts with an overview of the Markowitz portfolio theory and progresses into a discussion regarding later developments such as the Capital Market Theory. 2.2 MARKOWITZ PORTFOLIO THEORY 2.2.1 Overview According to Correia, Flynn, Uliana and Wormald (2000:90) modern portfolio theory is based on the culmination of the work of various researchers, but was pioneered by Markowitz (1959) and later Sharpe (1964). Harry Markowitz developed the basic portfolio model at a time when investors were seeking a measure to quantify the risk variable. Bodie, Kane and Marcus (2002:223) state that, according to Markowitz, the variance of the rate of return [on an asset] is a meaningful measure of portfolio risk under a reasonable set of assumptions. 5 These assumptions, as stated by Reilly and Brown (2003:260), are listed below: • Investors will evaluate an investment opportunity as being presented by a probability distribution of expected returns over some period of time; • Investors maximize one-period expected utility, and their utility curves demonstrate diminishing marginal utility of wealth; • Risk of a specific investment will be measured by the deviation from expected return; • Investors’ utility curves are functions of risk and return only; and • For a given level of risk, investors will aim to maximize the level of return. Therefore under the above-mentioned set of assumptions, a single asset or portfolio of assets is considered to be efficient if no other asset or portfolio of assets offers higher expected return with the same (or lower) risk, or lower risk with the same (or higher) expected return. 2.2.2 Risk The risk associated with an asset may be graphically illustrated via a probability distribution that illustrates the dispersion of the realized returns around the mean level of expected return. Greater levels of dispersion imply greater levels of risk associated with the specific asset. (D’Ambrosio 1976:301) Figure 2.1 illustrates the probability distributions of the returns on two different assets. 6 Figure 2.1 Probability distribution of assets with different levels of risk Source: Mason, Lind and Marchal From figure 2.1 it is clear that curve A represents the probability distribution of a low variance (low risk) asset, whilst curve B represents the probability distribution of a high variance (high risk) asset. This conclusion follows on the fact that curve B is flatter (platykurtic) than curve A and therefore the returns on the high risk asset will be more dispersed around a central value, normally the mean rate of return or expected rate of return. A standardized measure of variance around a mean is known as standard deviation. According to Reilly et al (2003:212) standard deviation is an appropriate measure of risk because it: • Is somewhat intuitive; • Is correct and widely recognized; and • Has been used in most theoretical asset pricing models. According to Wilcox (1999:12) Harry Markowitz derived the formula for the calculation of the standard deviation of a portfolio. The formula shown below indicates that the standard deviation of a portfolio is a function of the individual asset variances as well as their weight in the portfolio. 7 n n n ∑ wi2σ i2 + ∑∑ wi w j Covij σ port = i =1 [2.1] i =1 i =1 Where: σ port = the standard deviation of the portfolio w i = the weights of the individual assets as determined by their proportion of value in the portfolio σ = the variance in the rates of return in i 2 i Cov ij = the covariance between the rates of return for assets i and j What is important is the fact that the variance of the portfolio is also a function of the covariance/co-movement of the assets included in the portfolio. Therefore when constructing a portfolio the focus of the investor should not be on the variance of the individual asset but more on the average covariance with the other assets in an existing portfolio. 2.2.3 Return The expected return on a portfolio may be calculated as the sum of the weighted average expected return on the individual assets that make up the total portfolio. (Farrell 1997:21) A detailed discussion on the concepts of risk and return follows in chapter 3. 2.2.4 The efficient frontier D’Ambrosio (1976:326) states that the portfolios on the efficient frontier dominate all portfolios below the frontier, thus the efficient frontier represents 8 that set of portfolios that has the maximum rate of return for every given level of risk, or the minimum risk for every level of return. An efficient frontier may be derived by considering different risk and return scenarios resulting from different combinations of two or more assets. Figure 2.2.4.1 illustrates a fictitious example of a graph that may be derived in this way. Figure 2.2 Risk/Return combinations of two different assets Source: Fischer and Jordan (1975:511) The envelope curve that represents the best of all the possible combinations represents the efficient frontier. Figure 2.2.4.2 represents a fictitious efficient frontier. 9 Figure 2.3 Fictitious Efficient Frontier Source: D’Ambrosio (1976:326) The benefits associated with diversification lead investors/theorists to believe that the efficient frontier will be made up of investment portfolios rather than individual assets, except at the extremes where a portfolio consists of only one asset or security. Investors will invest in combinations of assets (portfolios) that fall along the efficient frontier based on their utility curve. The investor’s utility curves are functions of expected return and expected variance (this follows on the basic assumptions of the Markowitz portfolio theory). These utility curves indicate the trade-off that investors are willing to make between risk and return. According to Stevenson and Jennings (1976:233) the optimal portfolio on the efficient frontier for a given investor, lies at the point of tangency between the efficient frontier and the curve with the highest possible utility, as illustrated in figure 2.4. 10 Figure 2.4 Efficient Frontier and Utility Curves Source: Correia et al (2000:100) According to Correia et al the following can be seen from figure 2.4: • Three discrete indifference curves of investor X (X1, X2, X3). The curves proceed in an upward and leftward direction, depicting the increasing return being sought for increased risk. The slope of the curve reflects the risk preference of the investor. Curve X1 doesn’t encounter any investment opportunity. Curve X2 offers less utility but is the first to contact the set of feasible portfolios on the efficient frontier. Curve X3 encounters the efficient frontier on two occasions, but because curve X2 offers a higher level of utility the investor will prefer to invest in portfolio X. • The three indifference curves of investor Y (Y1,Y2,Y3) represent the utility curves of a more risk-averse investor (as opposed to investor X). This is evident in the increased steepness of the utility curves of investor Y. The steepness implies that a greater level of return is required per unit of risk incurred (Francis 1986:798). In other words this means that a risk-averse investor will require return to increase by a substantial margin for an increase in the level of risk, as opposed to a 11 less risk-averse investor who might only require a small increase in the level of return given an increase in the level of risk. According to Bodie, Kane and Marcus (2002:157) investors assign a welfare or utility score to competing investment portfolios based on the expected return and risk of those portfolios. Portfolios with attractive risk-return characteristics are assigned higher utility values. The utility value of a portfolio will increase if expected return increased and decrease if expected variability (risk) increased. 2.3 CAPITAL MARKET THEORY 2.3.1 Introduction Following the development of the Markowitz portfolio theory, various studies have been performed to address some of the shortfalls identified in the theory. One of the major shortfalls associated with this theory is the need for large amounts of information. Specifically, the investor needs information on the risk and return characteristics of each asset considered as well as information relating to the covariance of each asset pair. The inclusion of a risk-free asset into a portfolio also gave rise to some of the major developments which followed the Markowitz portfolio theory. A breakthrough with regard to the problems posed by the Markowitz portfolio theory came in 1963 when Sharpe developed the Market (or single-index, or diagonal) model. 12 2.3.2 Overview of the capital market theory 2.3.2.1 Assumptions of the theory As was the case for the Markowitz portfolio theory, the Capital Market Theory (CMT) was developed on the basis of a set of assumptions. These assumptions as listed by Dobbins et al (1993:45) are reproduced below: • All investors are Markowitz efficient investors who want to target points on the efficient frontier based on their utility curves. This assumption underlines the fact that the Capital Market Theory (CMT) builds on the Markowitz theory. • Investors are able to borrow or lend any amount of money at the riskfree rate of return (RFR). • All investors have homogeneous expectations. This implies that all investors have similar expectations of the probability distributions of future rates of return. • All investors share the same investment time horizon i.e. 1 month, 6 months, 12 months etc. • All investments in the market are infinitely divisible i.e. investors are able to buy and sell fractions of assets. • There are no taxes or transaction costs involved in the purchase and sale of assets. • There is no inflation or any change in interest rates, or inflation is fully anticipated. • Capital markets are in equilibrium. The aim of the preceding section was not to question the reasonableness of the listed assumptions, but to provide an overview of the theory. 13 2.3.2.2 Addressing the information need As was mentioned in the introduction to this section, one of the shortfalls of the Markowitz portfolio theory identified by theorists is the need for large amounts of information. According to Sharpe, who developed the CMT, “each security’s price movement can be related to the price of the market portfolio – that is, a portfolio comprising a weighted average of all the securities traded on the market.” (Dobbins et al (1993:46). Furthermore returns on different securities within an asset universe are assumed to be related only through common dependence upon the market [portfolio], and as such the necessity to specify the covariance (and correlation coefficients) of returns between security pairs is eliminated. 2.3.2.3 Inclusion of a risk-free asset The concept of a risk-free asset has various implications on the basic Markowitz portfolio model and the inclusion of these types of asset have allowed for various developments in asset pricing. In order to fully appreciate the implication of the inclusion of a risk-free asset on the basic portfolio theory it is necessary to define the term. Francis (1986:760) defines a riskless asset (or risk-free asset) as an asset that produces a positive level of return, but it has zero variability and therefore future returns are known. This implies a standard deviation (Markowitz’s measure of risk) that is equal to zero. It may also be proved that the covariance of these assets with any other asset or portfolio of assets will be equal to zero. 14 The effects of the inclusion of a risk-free asset into an existing portfolio are listed below: • The rate of return generated by the portfolio, which now includes a riskfree asset, remains the weighted average of the returns generated by the assets included in the portfolio. • According to Francis (1986:760) the standard deviation of a portfolio that combines a risk-free asset with risky assets is the linear proportion of the standard deviation of the risky asset portfolio. Because of the above-mentioned effects the graph that may be drawn to illustrate possible risk and return characteristics of the portfolio is a straight line between two assets, as illustrated in figure 2.5. Figure 2.5 Combining the Risk-Free Asset and a Risky Portfolio Source: Stevenson and Jennings (1976:257) The investors will be able to attain any point along line RFR-A and RFR-B by investing a portion of their wealth in the risk-free asset and a portion in the risky-portfolio on the efficient frontier (i.e. portfolio A or B). Any combination on these lines dominates all risky portfolios on the efficient frontier that fall below this point, the reason being that these portfolios have equal variance 15 and higher rates of return than any portfolio on the original efficient frontier that falls below the selected portfolio. From this it appears that all portfolios on line RFR-B will dominate all portfolios on line RFR-A. At the point of tangency between the line drawn from RFR to the efficient frontier, that portfolio (portfolio M) dominates all portfolios below that point. Because portfolio M lies at the point of tangency with the efficient frontier, it has the highest portfolio possibility line and therefore all investors will aim to invest in portfolios that lie on line RFR-CM. This portfolio represents a portfolio which includes all risky assets. This portfolio is referred to as the market portfolio and represents a completely diversified portfolio. According to Reilly et al (2003:244) this portfolio includes not only common stocks but also all risky assets such as bonds, options, real estate, coins, stamps, art or antiques. In effect line RFR-CM which may also be termed the Capital Market Line (CML), becomes the new efficient frontier, as all investors will want to target points on the CML. From the above discussions it follows that the relevant risk measure for all risky assets should be their covariance with the market portfolio, this is the risk often referred to as systematic risk. The concepts of risk (systematic and unsystematic) as well as diversification, will be discussed in a later chapter. 2.4 THE SIGNIFICANCE OF PORTFOLIO THEORY FOR THIS STUDY The general principles of portfolio theory as reviewed in this chapter will have a significant bearing on the remainder of the study. As will be seen in later chapters, portfolios constructed during the course of this study will be constructed based on the Markowitz portfolio theory. It should also become evident that the focus of this text will be to study those alternative assets which, at least in theory, form part of the fully diversified market portfolio. Often these assets are forgotten or ignored, but the question 16 arises whether or not these assets may add to the diversification of existing portfolios. The benefits that may be associated with these assets may include, in addition to diversification benefits, improved levels of portfolio return. 2.5 CONCLUSION This chapter provided a literature review of basic modern portfolio theory. From this review it followed that the Markowitz Portfolio Theory, as developed by Harry Markowitz, established the basis for modern portfolio theory, whilst subsequent developments in this field of study included amongst others the Capital Market Theory (CMT). Markowitz showed that the two most important factors to be considered when constructing a portfolio is risk and return. Prior to his findings most investors constructed portfolios based purely on expected return, or at best constructed portfolios based on separate considerations of risk and return. Markowitz provided a measure that enables investors to consider risk and return simultaneously. In addition to this Markowitz identified variance as the appropriate risk measure in a portfolio management and construction setting. Application of the Markowitz Portfolio Theory enable investors to derive Markowitz efficient frontiers which, in addition to their utility curves, would allow them to determine optimal portfolios given their unique risk preferences. Following the discussion on the Markowitz Portfolio Theory this chapter briefly considered the Capital Market Theory (CMT) which introduces the concept of the risk-free asset. In terms of this theory the investor has to decide to invest in a combination of the risky portfolio, i.e. that portfolio that contains all the risky assets traded in the market, and the risk-free asset. According to the CMT the only other decision that the investor has to make, other than deciding to invest, is the whether or not he or she would be willing to borrow 17 or lend at the risk-free rate. This set of decisions, namely the investing decision and the financing decision, gives rise to the separation theorem. For the purpose of this study the Markowitz Portfolio Theory was used in the construction and identification of optimal portfolios. This was done because only the market portfolio (risky portfolio) as identified by the CMT can be diversified. 18 CHAPTER 3: RISK DIVERSIFICATION: BASIC DEFINITIONS AND APPLICATIONS 3.1. INTRODUCTION In the modern investment setting investors are faced with the complicated task of selecting good investments, in addition to this they have to consider trade-offs between risk and return and finally they are required to combine various types of investments in optimal portfolios. This chapter builds on the basic concepts noted in the previous chapter and aims to introduce the reader to a more complicated and detailed discussion of concepts such as risk and return when selecting investments, the consideration of risk and return measurement for individual investments, as well as the impact that the inclusion of assets will have on the risk and return characteristics of existing asset portfolios. Furthermore, the chapter will serve as an overview of the concept of risk diversification and the bearing that diversification has on the investment decision. Diversification as a concept will be discussed as well as the methods used to measure and achieve diversification. 3.2. RISK 3.2.1 Overview Risk manifests itself in various forms, these include amongst others, business risk, country risk, exchange rate risk and financial risk. For the purpose of this chapter, risk (in its broadest sense) may be defined as the uncertainty of future returns, or alternatively as “the uncertainty that an investment will earn its expected return.”(Reilly et al 2000:1210). According to Mason et al (1997:99) the larger the range of expected returns of an asset, the larger the 19 dispersion of the returns and the riskier the asset. Therefore the higher the range of the expected returns (or historical returns) the riskier the asset will be. Bodie, Kane and Marcus 2002:155 reason that the presence of risk means that more than one outcome is possible. The risk associated with an asset consists of two elements, namely: • Systematic risk. According to Francis and Archer (1979:155) systematic risk is the minimum level of risk that may be achieved by means of diversification. All assets carry this risk; as all assets are influenced to some greater or lesser extent by changes in factors such as money supply, interest rates, exchange rates and taxation (Dobbins et al 1996:8). • Unsystematic risk. Cohen, Zinbarg and Zeikel define unsystematic risk as risk that is unique to a specific asset, derived from its particular characteristics. It can be eliminated in a diversified portfolio. The existence of the unique risks and the idea that investors should not expect to be rewarded for taking on risk which can be avoided (Dobbins et al 1996:8) warrants an investigation into the existence of alternative means of reducing unique risks. 3.2.2 Types of risk It is important to note that the term risk is a collective term encompassing various types of risks, including, amongst others, the following: • Business risk; • Financial risk; • Market risk; • Interest rate risk; • Reinvestment rate risk; 20 • Purchasing power risk; • Exchange rate risk; and • Country risk. 3.2.3 Risk measurement The most established measure of risk is standard deviation. Standard deviation may be defined as a measure of variability equal to the square root of variance (Mason, Lind and Marchal 1996:11). It is a measure of dispersion around a mean value. A larger dispersion around a mean value would indicate more variability and presents the investor with greater risk. Figure 3.1 Probability Distribution Source: Dobbins et al (1996:6). As mentioned earlier standard deviation measures dispersion around a mean. According to Dobbins et al. (1996:6) approximately 66.67% of all occurrences should, on average, lie within one standard deviation of the expected outcome, considering the figure 3.1 this implies that 66.67% of the 21 occurrences should fall within the 10% to 22% range and the implied standard deviation should be 6%. The aforementioned statement is made assuming that the return distribution is a normal distribution. Dobbins et al (1994:7) go on to say that 83.33% of occurrences (relating to the above mentioned figure) should fall above 22% (upside potential) and below 10% (downside risk). Variance may be calculated as follows: [r (s ) − R ] =∑ 2 σ 2 s n [3.1] Where : σ 2 = variance R = the mean rate of return on the asset r(s) = the realized return given scenario s From this formula (3.1) it follows that variance of an asset equals the sum of the probability of a given scenario multiplied by the squared difference between realised return and expected return (the mean value). It should be noted that this measurement of risk is based on the past performance of the asset, hence there is no guarantee that the risk characteristics of the asset will remain constant. To eliminate this shortfall as much as possible, investors should use as much historical data as possible. The mathematical equation for the calculation of standard deviation may be represented as follows: σ = σ2 Where: [3.2] σ 2 = Variance as calculated using formulas 3.1. 22 According to Bodie, Kane and Marcus (2002:165) the risk of single assets in a portfolio should be measured in the context of the effect that their returns will have on the variability of the overall portfolio. The fact that the amount of risk associated with a portfolio is dependent on the extent to which the assets in the portfolio move together, results in the assumption that the risk of a portfolio isn’t simply the weighted average risk of the assets that make up the portfolio. Bodie et al (2002:165) further state “covariance measures how much the returns of two risky assets move in tandem.” The following equation is used to calculate the covariance of two assets: Cov AB = ∑ [r A − E (r A )][rB − E (rB )] / n [3.3] Where : P(s) = the probability of scenario s rX = the realized return on asset X E(rX ) = the expected return on asset X From this it seems that the covariance of a portfolio is reliant on two factors, namely: • Variability (standard deviation) of the individual assets, and • The relationship (correlation) amongst different assets included in the portfolio. The correlation coefficient of returns is calculated by using the following formula: ρ AB = Cov AB σ Aσ B [3.4] Where : ρ AB = the correlation coefficien t of assets A and B 23 The portfolio standard deviation, for a three-asset portfolio, may be calculated by using the following formula: 2 σ port = W A2σ A2 + W B2σ B2 + WC2σ C2 + 2W AW BCov AB + 2W AWC Cov AC + 2WBWC Cov BC [3.5] σ = σ 2 port [3.6] Where : W X = the weight that each asset carries in the portfolio σ X2 = the variance of asset X Cov XY = the covariance between the returns on assets X and Y The formulae indicate that factors such as the weight that an asset carries in the portfolio, its standard deviation (risk), as well as the correlation/comovement of the asset with other assets in the portfolio, is essential in the calculation of portfolio variance. This study uses the risk measurement as identified by Harry Markowitz in his portfolio theory. This does not, however, mean that other measures of risk such as beta-coefficients aren’t considered to be applicable or sufficient measures of risk. 3.3. RETURN 3.3.1 Overview Fischer and Jordan (1983:4) define an investment as the current commitment of Dollars for a period of time in order to derive future payments that will compensate the investor for (1) the time the funds are committed, (2) the expected rate of inflation, and (3) the uncertainty of future payments. 24 The return generated by an asset may be defined as the sum of all sources of income or capital gains realized on that asset during the holding period. From the definition mentioned above it follows that these income sources should compensate the investor in terms of time, inflation and risk. The rate of return demanded by an individual investor is known as the investor’s required rate of return. 3.3.2 Required rate of return The investor’s required rate of return is made up of three factors or alternatively it has three dimensions. According to Reilly and Brown (2000:16) these are: • The time value of money during the period of investment, • The expected rate of inflation during the period, and • The risk involved. In order to analyse the investor’s required rate of return, the investor has to take into account the real risk-free rate (RRFR). According to Reilly et al (2000:16) “The real risk-free rate is the basic interest rate, assuming no inflation and no uncertainty about future [cash] flows.” The RRFR is essentially the rate of return that investors would demand if they knew with certainty what cash flows they would receive and when. From this it appears that the RRFR addresses the time value of money dimension of the investor’s required rate of return. Reilly and Brown (2000:17) identify two factors that will influence this rate of return namely, the time frame of the investor and the investment opportunities in the economy. Longer time frames or investment horizons results in the greater probability of opportunity cost and therefore a higher level of return will be commanded by investors. 25 Farrell (1997:126) states that [nominal] rates of interest that prevail in the market are determined by real rates of interest, plus factors that will affect the nominal rate of interest, such as the expected rate of inflation. From this it appears that the nominal risk-free rate of return is equal to the RRFR adjusted for conditions in the capital markets and the inflation rate. A required rate of return that exceeds the NRFR is said to have a risk premium. This risk premium represents the composite of all uncertainty, but certain fundamental elements are identifiable namely business risk, financial risk, liquidity risk etc. (as was discussed earlier). According to Dobbins et al. (1996:7) “investors do not like risk, and the greater the riskiness of returns of an investment, the greater will be the return expected (or required) by investors.” The required or expected rate of return of an investor may be calculated using the following equation: k i = rf + β ( r m − rf ) Where : [3.7] ki = required rate of return on asset i rf = the nominal risk-free rate of return rm = the market return β = the beta of the asset Beta is a standardized measure of the extent to which an asset moves in relation to the market. Beta measures the covariance between the asset returns and the market returns in relation to the variance of the market. Therefore the market portfolio (the portfolio that consists of all risky assets) has a beta coefficient of 1. An asset with a beta of more than one has high levels of systematic risk, whilst assets with low or negative betas have low levels of systematic risk (Francis 1986:260). 26 3.3.3 Measurement According to Bodie, Kane and Marcus (2002:162) the mean or expected return of an asset is a probability-weighted average of its return in all scenarios. The equation may be written as follows: R= ∑ R (s ) [3.8] n Where : R(s) = return in scenario s. Bodie et al (2002:163) state that “[t]he rate of return on a portfolio is a weighted average of the rates of return of each asset comprising the portfolio.” Thus, when calculating the return generated by a portfolio of investments over a period of time, the investor uses the weighted average return of all assets in the portfolio. For example a portfolio made up of asset A and asset B (assume equal weighting), where asset A yielded a return of 40% and asset B a return of 10%, will yield a 25% return over the investment period. The equation for the calculation of the portfolio return will be as follows: R port = W A r A + W B rB + ... + W ∞ r ∞ Where : [3.9] A = portfolio A B = portfolio B 3.4. THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN RISK AND RETURN According to Corgel, Ling and Smith (2001:149) investors are risk averse and because of this the relationship between risk (as measured by standard deviation) and return is positive. Dobbins et al. (1996:9) state that “[t]he capital asset pricing model shows that the expected return of an investment is 27 a positive linear function of market risk (measured by beta)”. Basic investment theory states that as risk increases so too should return, in order to compensate the investor for the increased degree of uncertainty. The risk/return relationship is of critical importance to investors. Investors need to determine their individual risk preferences and should aim to minimize their risk exposure at their required rate of return. According to Bodie, Kane and Marcus (2002:157) investors who are risk averse reject investment portfolios that are fair games or worse. For the purposes of this text fair games may be defined as “prospect[s] that have a zero risk premium”. From this it seems that a risk averse investor will only accept those prospects which offer a positive risk premium. The Markowitz portfolio theory assumes that investors have utility curves, which are functions of risk and return. This needs to be explained. According to Bodie et al (2002:157) “[m]any particular “scoring” systems are legitimate.” One reasonable function that is commonly employed by financial theorists and the Chartered Financial Analyst Institute assigns a portfolio with expected return E(r) and variance σ 2 the following utility score: U = E (r ) − 0.005 Aσ 2 Where: [3.10] U = utility score A = an index of the investor’s risk aversion The factor 0.005 is a scaling convention, allowing the use of absolute values. From the equation it is apparent that the utility score (U) is a function of expected return and variance. Furthermore it may be said that the effect that variance has on the utility score is dependent on the value of A. Larger values of A indicate a greater degree of risk aversion. The utility score derived in this fashion should be compared to the rate of return offered by risk-free investments. 28 The following should apply: • If U minus rate of return offered by the risk-free investment > 0 the investor will opt for the risky portfolio. • If U minus rate of return offered by the risk-free investment = 0 the investor should be indifferent towards the two options but by virtue of the definition of a risk averse investor, the investor should opt for the risk-free alternative. • If U minus rate of return offered by the risk-free investment < 0 the investor will opt for the risk-free alternative. 3.5. PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION 3.5.1 Introduction It is widely accepted that investors should aim to maximize the level of return for a given level of risk. Alternatively they aim at minimizing the risk for a given level of return. This is done by constructing a portfolio of assets which as a whole is subject to the investor’s risk appetite. According to Reilly and Brown (2000:259) an investor’s portfolio includes all of his or her assets and liabilities, not only stocks or marketable securities, but also items such as houses, cars, antiques etc. As was noted earlier Corgel et al (2001:149) believe that all investors are risk averse and therefore the risk-return relationship is positive. It holds true that if investors were faced with a choice between two assets that promise the same level of return they would opt for the asset with the lower level of risk. In order to accept a higher level of risk, investors will demand a higher level of potential return to compensate them for the higher degree of uncertainty. When constructing diversified investment portfolios investors should consider different investments based on their risk and return pay-off structures. 29 Investors should identify their specific investment goals and constraints when determining their risk appetite. 3.5.2 Constructing the capital market line (CML) According to Bodie et al (2002:183) the make-up of any portfolio is subject to decisions being made on one of three levels namely: • The capital allocation decision – which refers to the choice investors need to make between investing in a risk-free asset and a risky asset portfolio. • The asset allocation decision – which describes the distribution of risky investments across different asset classes. (Construction of the optimal risky asset portfolio). • Security selection decision – which describes the choice of particular securities held within each asset class. This section is concerned with the first of these decisions. For illustration purposes certain assumptions need to be made. It should be kept in mind that the aim of this section is to find the balance between investing in a risk-free asset and a risky portfolio. The assumptions are as follows: • The risky portfolio’s composition remains constant throughout the exercise. • The risky portfolio is made up of two assets, namely two mutual funds, one of which is invested in equities and one which is invested in bonds. • The allocation between the two assets in the risky portfolio will be 60% invested in equities and 40% invested in bonds. 30 • As it was assumed that the mix between equities and bonds remains constant, any shift of funds will be from the risky portfolio to the riskfree asset and vice versa. • The risky portfolio essentially becomes a risky asset. • According to Bodie et al. (2002:186) it is common practice to view TBills as the risk-free asset, this study will comply with this assumption. The following values will be used for the illustrations, which follow later in this chapter: rRA = return on the risky asset. E (rRA ) = expected return on the risky asset, assumed to be 15%. σ RA = standard deviation of the risky asset, assumed to be 22%. rf = return on the risk-free asset, assumed to be 7%. y = the portion of the portfolio invested in asset RA. c = the complete portfolio. (1 − y ) = the portion of the portfolio invested in the risk-free asset (F). By applying the reasoning and equations discussed in the section on portfolio return and variance one would be able to calculate the expected return on portfolio C (the complete portfolio) as follows: E (rc ) = [y × E (rRA )][(1 − y ) × E (rf )] [3.11] = y(15) + (1-y)(7) = 7 + 8y From this equation it appears that the base rate of the entire portfolio will be equal to rf and that the portfolio is expected to earn a risk-premium which is 31 dependent on the position in the risky asset and the risk premium of the risky portfolio. From the results of a previous discussion one would be able to calculate the risk (standard deviation) of the entire portfolio (portfolio C) by using the following equation: σ c = yσ RA [3.12] When a risky asset and a risk-free asset are combined in a portfolio, the standard deviation of that portfolio will be a function of the standard deviation of the risky asset (RA) and its weighting in the portfolio. The data in the table 3.1 was used to construct the graph depicted in figure 3.2. Table 3.1 Test Data Y Standard Deviation C E(r) complete 0 0.0 7.0 0.1 2.2 7.8 0.2 4.4 8.6 0.3 6.6 9.4 0.4 8.8 10.2 0.5 11.0 11.0 0.6 13.2 11.8 0.7 15.4 12.6 0.8 17.6 13.4 0.9 19.8 14.2 1 22.0 15.0 Figure 3.2 depicts the relationship between standard deviation (risk) and expected return for the entire portfolio given different weightings in the risky asset RA. 32 Figure 3.2 Expected return The Relationship between Risk and Return 16.0 14.0 12.0 10.0 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 0.0 0.0 5.0 10.0 15.0 20.0 25.0 Standard deviation After determining the Capital Market Line (as depicted in figure 3.2) investors need to determine the optimum mix between investing in the risky asset (RA) and the risk-free asset (F). By assuming three different levels of risk-aversion (A levels), namely five, three and one, and combining them with the information in table 3.1, one would be able to calculate the following utility levels (U) (note that equation 3.14 which is used in the calculation of U is discussed elsewhere). 33 Table 3.2 Test Data Y 0 A=5 7.000 A=3 A=1 7.000 7.000 0.1 7.679 7.727 7.776 0.2 8.116 8.310 8.503 0.3 8.311 8.747 9.182 0.4 8.264 9.038 9.813 0.5 7.975 9.185 10.395 0.6 7.444 9.186 10.929 0.7 6.671 9.043 11.414 0.8 5.656 8.754 11.851 0.9 4.399 8.319 12.240 1 2.900 7.740 12.580 From this it appears that the optimum level of investment in the risky asset (RA) will differ as the aversion to risk changes. A level of A = 5 denotes the risk aversion of an investor with a relatively high level of risk aversion, whilst an A level of 1 denotes the risk-aversion of an investor with a large appetite for risk. Based on the data presented in this section it is evident that where A = 5 investors should carry a weighting of approximately 30% in the risky asset and 70% in the risk-free asset, where A = 3 the optimum weighting should be approximately 60% in asset RA and 40% in asset F, whilst the weighting for A = 1 should be 100% in asset RA. The maximum utility level may be calculated by using the following equation: MaxU y = E (rc ) − 0.005 Aσ c2 = rf + (y × (E (r p ) − rf ) − 0.005 Ay 2σ p2 [3.13] 34 In order to solve the maximization problem the derivative of the abovementioned expression should be used. This may be written as follows: y* = E (r p ) − rf 0.01Aσ p2 [3.14] By substituting the relevant information into the equation the following optimum weightings may be calculated: A=5 : 33.06% in the risky asset. A=3 : 55.10% in the risky asset. A=1 : 100% in the risky asset, this investor might even consider using margin to increase his exposure to the risky asset. 3.5.3 Optimal risky portfolios 3.5.3.1 Diversification 3.5.3.1.1 Definition Diversification may be defined as an active attempt to manage the relationship between risk and return. According to Reilly and Brown (2000:292) diversification aims to reduce the standard deviation of the total portfolio and this assumes imperfect correlations among securities. Dobbins et al (1996:12) states that spreading of risk, or diversification, makes sense, as it removes unique, specific or diversifiable risk. Dobbins et al (1996:12) furthermore state that diversification is rational, given the fact that investors should only take part in risks for which they can expect to be rewarded. 35 3.5.3.1.2 Systematic vs. unsystematic risk Investors face two types of risk, namely: • Systematic risk, and • Unsystematic risk. According to Fischer and Jordan (1983:108) systematic risk or market risk is the form of risk that affects all comparable investments that are available in the marketplace. Accordingly this risk cannot be eliminated via diversification. This risk is also known as non-diversifiable risk. At some point a fully diversified portfolio will reach the world systematic-risk level. It is at this point that no further diversification is possible. Unsystematic risk is caused by factors that are unique to a specific asset or factors that affect only that specific asset. This risk is diversifiable, and may be eliminated by acquiring various different assets. The basic reasoning is that factors that influence one asset, will not necessarily affect other assets in the same manner. The result of the influence on all the assets should counteract one another. Therefore diversification is the process of constructing a portfolio in such a manner that it contains different types of assets, with the specific aim of eliminating the risks associated with any individual assets. This entails that the investor hopes that the variability of the returns on a particular asset will be offset, to some extent, by the variability of another asset in the portfolio. 36 3.5.3.1.3 Methods of establishing diversification According to Liberty Life Ltd there are various ways in which a portfolio may be diversified. These include: • Gaining exposure to different asset classes; • Gaining exposure to different sectors of a market; • Exposure to different entities within the same market sector; • Gaining Global exposure; and • Exposing the portfolio to different investment styles. I. Different asset classes This method of diversification requires that the investor allocates the funds in his portfolio to different assets, such as stocks, bonds and property. The asset selection i.e. the selection between stock, bonds, property and so on, constitutes the first tier of confinement to the investor’s risk preference. The risk associated with different assets is not the same, for example stocks are generally more risky than bonds. Different assets respond differently to the same variables. Equities wouldn’t necessarily respond in the same manner as bonds to an interest rate change or some other variable. Ideally assets should be totally autonomous in their movement and response to influencing factors. This is, unfortunately, rarely the case, as there tends to be some form of inter-relation between the movements of different asset classes. In many ways the remainder of this study will focus on the diversification value embedded in exposure to different asset classes. 37 II. Different market sectors In this instance the investor or portfolio manager will aim to invest in different industries or sectors within a certain market. In their discussion on the Topdown approach to equity valuation Reilly and Brown (2000:440) note that “alternative industries react to economic changes at different points in the business cycle.” Therefore exposure to different industries within a market will lessen the effect of the change of a specific variable. III. Different entities By investing in different entities within the same industry investors lessen or reduce (to an absolute minimum level) the effect of risk associated with a specific entity, such as financial risk, business risk, etcetera. IV. Gaining global exposure According to Reilly and Brown (2000:78) gaining exposure to assets both locally and internationally “will almost certainly reduce the risk of the portfolio and can possibly increase its average return.” V. Exposure to different investment styles There are various investment styles which will afford the investor the opportunity of making an investment decision. These include, but are not limited to: • Investment based on fundamental analysis; • Growth investing; • Value investing; 38 • Event driven investment; and • Investment based on technical analysis. Gaining exposure to different investment styles eliminates the bias embedded in a single investment style, which should lead to better investment decisions and better diversification. It is nearly impossible for one investor or portfolio manager to master each of the styles mentioned above. The easiest route to diversification in this way would be to gain exposure to managed funds which invest by using different styles. 3.5.4 The effect of diversification on the portfolio According to Correia (2000:89) “[a]t the time of investment, it is not known with certainty which investments will succeed and which will fail. It is therefore sensible to diversify into a number of investments in the expectation that those which are profitable will at least compensate for the losses sustained from those that are not.” This effectively means that diversification is the simplest (though not exact) form of hedging. Including various assets, with “imperfect correlations” into a portfolio, will allow the investor to reduce the general level of risk of that portfolio. According to Francis and Jordan (1983:23) diversification may be defined as the process of combining securities with less than perfectly correlated returns into a portfolio. This process serves to eliminate all unique risk from the portfolio. The standard deviation of a portfolio will eventually reach the level of the market portfolio, where you will have diversified away all unsystematic risk, but market or systematic risk will still exist. 39 Figure 3.3 Systematic risk and Unsystematic risk Source: Farrell (1997:74). Figure 3.3 graphically illustrates what the effect of diversification is on the level of risk of the investor’s portfolio. 3.5.4.1 Benefits of diversification The benefits of diversification include the following: • Diversification lessens the effect of a single adverse price movement, due to the fact that the loss will be offset by the gains made on other assets. • Diversification allows the investor to structure his/her portfolio in such a manner that it reflects his/her risk profile and allows the investor to plan his/her financial position. 40 • It should be mentioned that in order to gain maximum diversification it is advisable for investors to include assets in their portfolio with negative or low positive correlations. 3.5.5 Constructing the optimal risky portfolio The previous section considered the determination of the optimal mix between the risk-free asset and the ‘optimal’ risky portfolio. This section will consider the construction of the optimal risky portfolio. After considering the effects of diversification on a two-asset portfolio, excluding a risk-free asset, a portfolio which includes a risk-free asset will be constructed and discussed. 3.5.5.1 Two-asset portfolio For purposes of illustration the following assumptions will be made with regards to the two-asset portfolio: • The portfolio will consist of an equity portion (E) and a debt portion (D). • The equity asset has an E (re ) (expected return) of 13% and a σ e (standard deviation) of 20%. • The debt asset has an E (rd ) (expected return) of 8% and a σ e (standard deviation) of 12%. • The covariance of the assets is 72. • The correlation coefficient ( ρ ) is 0.30. The following table was generated using the equations for calculating the portfolio’s expected return (equation 3.9) as well as its standard deviation (equations 3.5 and 3.6). 41 Table 3.3 Standard deviation for a given correlation Wd We E(r) portfolio Correlation = -1 Correlation = 0 Correlation = 0.30 Correlation = 1 0% 100% 13.00% 20.00 20.00 20.00 20.00 10% 90% 12.50% 16.80 18.04 18.40 19.20 20% 80% 12.00% 13.60 16.18 16.88 18.40 30% 70% 11.50% 10.40 14.46 15.47 17.60 40% 60% 11.00% 7.20 12.92 14.20 16.80 50% 50% 10.50% 4.00 11.66 13.11 16.00 60% 40% 10.00% 0.80 10.76 12.26 15.20 70% 30% 9.50% 2.40 10.32 11.70 14.40 80% 20% 9.00% 5.60 10.40 11.45 13.60 90% 10% 8.50% 8.80 10.98 11.56 12.80 100% 0% 8.00% 12.00 12.00 12.00 12.00 Of table 3.3 it may be said that the following weightings are the optimum weightings for the given correlation: Correlation = -1 : Approximately 60% debt and 40% equity. Correlation = 0 : Approximately 70% debt and 30% equity. Correlation = 0.30 : Approximately 80% debt and 20% equity. Determining the minimum variance portfolio weighting, may be done by using the following equation: Wmin ( Asset d) = σ e2 − Cov de σ d2 + σ e2 − 2Cov de Wmin ( Asset e) = (1 - Wmin ( Asset d)) [3.15] [3.16] 42 Solving the minimization problem through the use of these equations yields the following optimum weightings given the correlation: Correlation = -1 : Approximately 62.5% debt and 37.5% equity. Correlation = 0 : Approximately 73.53% debt and 26.47% equity. Correlation = 0.30 : Approximately 82% debt and 18% equity. Figure 3.4 Expected return of the portfolio Return 15.00% 10.00% 5.00% 0.00% 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Return 8.00% 8.50% 9.00% 9.50% 10.00% 10.50% 11.00% 11.50% 12.00% 12.50% 13.00% Equity Weighting Figure 3.4 is a graphical representation of the expected return on the total portfolio, given different weightings in the two assets. Figure 3.5 Standard deviation of the portfolio Standard deviation 25.00% 20.00% Correlation = -1 15.00% Correlation = 0 Correlation = 0.3 10.00% Correlation = 1 5.00% 0.00% 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Weight in equity 43 Figure 3.5 illustrates the standard deviation of the complete portfolio for different weightings in the assets. As can be seen from the figure the portfolio’s standard deviation is minimized where the portfolio consists of 40% equity investments and 60% debt investments. Figure 3.6 Efficient frontiers given different correlations 14.00% 12.00% Correlation = -1 10.00% Correlation = 0 8.00% Correlation = 0.3 6.00% Correlation = 1 4.00% 2.00% 0.00% 0.00% 5.00% 10.00% 15.00% 20.00% 25.00% Figure 3.6 combines the information in the previous two graphs. This new graph allows the investor to target those portfolios that will provide the highest level of return for a given level of risk or alternatively those portfolios that provide the lowest level of risk for a given level of return. These conclusions imply that the graph illustrated in figure 3.6 represents the Markowitz efficient frontier. 3.5.6 Constructing complete portfolios In practice investors aren’t faced with the simple problem of deciding to invest in either the risky portfolio or the risk-free asset, under normal circumstances they will have to construct the optimal risky portfolio and combine it with the risk-free asset to construct a complete portfolio. 44 According to Bodie et al. (2002:218) the risky portfolio opportunity set with the highest feasible risk-return payoff will form a tangent with the CML (derived in section 3.5.2). The objective of this exercise will be to find the invested weight in equity and debt (see section 3.5.4) that will result in the maximum slope of the CML. The problem of determining the weighting between bonds and equities may be solved using the following mathematical procedure. (Note that the same assumptions with regard to the expected return, variance and covariance of debt and equity as mentioned in section 3.5.4 will be used in this section of the text). The assumption is made that the risk-free asset will yield a return of 5%. The objective function will be: Max S p = Where: E (r p ) − rf σp [3.17] S p = the slope of the CML The following equation should be used to calculate the risky-portfolio’s expected return: E ( r p ) = W d E ( rd ) + W e E ( re ) [3.18] E (r p ) = W d 8 + W e 13 The variance of the portfolio may be calculated by using the following equation: 2 σ port = [W d2σ d2 + W e2σ e2 ] + 2[W d W eσ d σ e ρ de ] [3.19] 2 σ port = [W d2 144 + W e2 400 ] + 2[W d W e 240 ρ de ] 45 The weight assigned to the debt portion of the portfolio may be calculated as follows: Wd = [E (rd ) − rf ]× σ e2 − [E (re ) − rf ]× Cov de [E (rd ) − rf ]× σ e2 + [E (re ) − rf ]× σ d2 − [(E (rd ) − rf ) + (E (re ) − rf )]× Cov de [3.20] Substituting the relevant data into equation 3.24 yields that the optimal risky portfolio will have a debt weighting of 40% and an equity weighting of 60%. Solving the maximization equation results in a S p of 0.42. The investor’s complete portfolio (i.e. consisting of a mix between the risky and risk-free assets) will be a function of his/her risk aversion. The function (equation 3.24) for solving the complete portfolio’s weighting problem is given below: y* = E (r p ) − rf 0.01Aσ p2 [3.21] Assuming a risk aversion coefficient of A = 3 and A = 5 results in the following answers for the mix of the complete portfolio: A=3 : Percentage invested in risky portfolio = 99.19% (D = 39.67% and E = 59.52%) Percentage invested in the risk-free asset = 100% - 99.19% = 0.18%. A=5 : Percentage invested in risky portfolio = 59.51% (D = 23.8% and E = 35.71%) Percentage invested in the risk-free asset = 100% - 59.51% = 40.49%. 46 From the above-mentioned analysis it follows that investors have different levels of risk aversion, and therefore the asset allocation decision is unique to each individual investor. Specifically factors such as the utility score of the investor and his/her level of risk tolerance are the main determinants of the optimal asset mix. What should be noted further is that return objectives should be considered in conjunction with risk tolerance. 3.6 SUMMARY This chapter builds on chapter 2, in that it considers the key concepts of effective portfolio construction, namely: • Risk; • Return; and • Diversification. This section identified variance and standard deviation as the appropriate measures of risk to be used in an investment environment. The sector also underlines the fact that portfolio risk isn’t simply a function of the weighted standard deviations or variances of the individual assets used in the portfolio, but that the co-movement of the assets’ returns (measured via covariance and correlation) played an integral part of measuring portfolio risk. From this section it followed that the combination of assets with low positive or negative correlations, with the assets in the existing portfolio, provided the highest degree of portfolio diversification. Apart from identifying the appropriate measurement ‘tools’ for risk, the chapter identified various potential sources of risk. In general the chapter identifies two major components of risk, namely systematic and unsystematic risk. The chapter also introduced various methods that may be used to diversify existing portfolios. These methods included amongst others spreading funds 47 between different asset classes and using different management or investment styles when constructing a portfolio. In terms of return the chapter provided ‘tools’ to measure the returns on both individual assets and portfolios. Lastly the chapter provided a practical application of the theories discussed in this and the previous chapter. 48 CHAPTER 4: IDENTIFICATION OF ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 4.1 INTRODUCTION Following the discussion in Chapter 2 surrounding the various benefits and requirements for diversification of investment portfolios the rest of the study will aim to identify and study the diversification benefits of including alternative investments in the investor’s portfolio. The objective of this chapter is to identify various alternative investments. The alternative investment universe is an extensive one and therefore the focus of this chapter will be on the more prominent alternative assets. The assets below are by no means the only alternative assets that investors might consider for investment purposes. The chapter will first consider the definition of an investment. Secondly the different categories of alternative investments will be identified including definitions and explanations of the different assets which fall under each of the different categories. In conclusion the chapter will aim to identify generic factors which might assist the investor when identifying assets for inclusion in his/her portfolio. 4.2 DEFINING AN INVESTMENT In order to identify alternative assets it is important to define investments. Mayo (1997:12) distinguishes between two forms of investments namely: • Economic investments: These investments refer to the purchase of a physical asset that will result in an increase of productive assets. Mayo relates this to a transaction made in the primary market. An example would be where a company sells shares to the public for the first time, known as an initial public offering (IPO). As the sale of shares during 49 the IPO will result in an increase in productive assets in the form of cash, this is an economic investment. • General investments: When individuals or corporate investors invest in stocks or bonds this generally doesn’t influence the level of productive assets. These are investments made with the objective of storing and hopefully increasing value. Acquisitions of these assets are made in secondary markets. The investor utilizes these investments with the intent of transferring purchasing power into the future. Hull (2002:40) distinguishes between two types of assets, namely: • Investment assets, which refer to those assets which are held solely for investment purposes by a significant number of investors. These include assets such as stocks and bonds. • Consumption assets, which are assets held primarily for consumption. These include commodities such as oil and copper. 4.3 DEFINING ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT INSTRUMENTS Alternative investment instruments could be defined as those instruments that offer alternative investment opportunities to those offered by traditional financial instruments such as stocks and bonds, whilst at the same time serving largely the same purpose as traditional investment vehicles, which includes the preserving and transferring of wealth and purchasing power into the future. This causes alternative investment instruments to fall under the category of general investments in terms of Mayo’s classification. Alternative investments may take on many forms ranging from hedge funds to antiques. The focus of this study will be on physical assets (“hard assets”) that are traded in secondary markets. In this text the term alternative asset and hard asset will be used interchangeably unless specified otherwise. 50 4.4 ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT CATEGORIES The study places an alternative investment asset into one of four categories which, together with the basis for the divisions, are listed and explained below. • Antiques This category includes various different assets, as will be discussed in a later part of the chapter, with age being the common denominator between the various assets and the determination of their value. The South African Antiques Dealers’ Association (SAADA) defines an antique as being an item which is more than 100 years old. This definition is accepted in terms of international trade. • Collectables This category includes assets which are desirable due to factors such as rarity, desirability and importance (provenance). These assets aren’t antiques but are expected to appreciate in value. • Art Art in itself is difficult to define. Shah Jahan, who studied the theories of the philosopher Baruch Spinoza, defines art as any human creation which contains an idea other than its utilitarian purpose. Art, as a hard asset class, includes various assets ranging from paintings and sculptures to photographs and drawings. • General This category includes all those assets which do not fall into one of the categories mentioned above but whose values are expected to increase over time. 51 4.5 ANTIQUES 4.5.1 Definition of an antique As mentioned earlier it is accepted by the international community that antiques include all those assets which are at least 100 years old. The following section will look at the various assets which have been identified as falling under this category (South African Antiques Dealers’ Association (SAADA) 2000). 4.5.2 Furniture Antique furniture is amongst the most popular and practical collectable items. The antique furniture galaxy consists mainly of items such as tables, chairs, writing desks, cabinets, bookcases and travelling chests, with samples from England, Europe (in particular French furniture) and China being the most significant. In recent times Cape Dutch furniture has also come to the forefront as being very desirable for investment purposes (SAADA 2000). Antique furniture of English origin is most sought after by investors and collectors. English furniture may be subdivided into different periods each with its own unique characteristics. These include (British Broadcasting Corporation (BBC) 2001): • Tudor 1485 – 1558 • Elizabethan 1558 – 1603 • Jacobean 1603 – 1689 • William and Mary 1689 – 1702 • Queen Anne 1702 – 1727 • Georgian 1727 – 1820 • Regency 1800 –1830 • Victorian 1837 – 1901 52 According to Duthy (1986:113) there have been major buyers of 18th century English furniture for two main reasons: • The insufficient supply of American 18th century furniture to satisfy demand has led to a rise in investor interest in English antique furniture. • English furniture is often more elegant and better made. French furniture may be sub-divided into the following periods (BBC 2001): • Louis XIV 1643 – 1715 • Louis XV 1715 – 1754 • Louis XVI 1754 – 1789 • The Directorate 1789 – 1799 • First Consul 1799 – 1804 • Napoleon I 1804 – 1815 (First empire) • Louis XVIII 1815 – 1824 • Charles X 1824 – 1830 • Louis Philippe 1830 – 1848 • Louis Napoleon 1848 – 1852 (President) • Louis Napoleon III 1852 – 1871 (Second Empire) Chinese furniture may be sub-divided into two main categories: • Ming 1368 - 1644 • Qing 1644 – 1911 Some of the advantages of antique furniture include the fact that there is such a wide array of objects to choose from and that most of the objects may be used for functional as well as display purposes. Objects range in size from small to large and are generally movable. Well constructed and preserved articles command relatively low levels of maintenance. 53 The fact that these objects are movable brings with it the possibility of theft and as a result investors should insure themselves against this possibility. Wear and tear due to repeated or unusual use may detract from the value of these items when using them for purposes other than display. “The Antique Collectors’ Club in England has published an annual review of the prices of antique furniture” (Fiske and Freeman 2003 [on-line]) known as the Antique Furniture Price Index (AFPI). Since its inception in 1968 the AFPI has outperformed most traditional investments including real estate and stock markets. The following table indicates the comparative growth figures for various investments. Table 4.1 Performance of the AFPI versus various other assets* 1968 1988 2000 Stock Market 100 675 1 900 Antique Furniture 100 2 185 3 350 Residential property 100 1 550 2 850 Basket of groceries 100 605 1 000 *Please note that the data pertains to the UK market. Source: Fiske J and Freeman L. From the table it is clear that antique furniture outperformed the stock market and inflation (as represented by the basket of groceries) as well as residential property. Even though these figures seem to be very promising, Fiske et al warns that higher transaction costs associated with investments in furniture as well as liquidity constraints render investment in antique furniture long-term investments. In a subsequent article termed “The 2002 Antique Furniture Price Index” Fiske et al notes that during 2001 the AFPI has shown a remarkable out performance of all the investments listed above. As an example Early Walnut Furniture (Queen Anne to George II) increased by 9% from 2000 to 2001, this 54 followed a rise of 19% from 1999 to 2000. It is interesting to note that during its entire existence the AFPI only had one sustained fall from 2 600 to a level of 2 300 during the 5-year period between 1990 and 1995. In his comment on the performance of the AFPI during 2001, John Andrews, creator of the AFPI, indicates that increases in prices during that year were negatively affected by events such as the 9/11 attacks and the subsequent absence of American buyers (lower demand) from the markets. According to the South African Antiques Dealers’ Association (SAADA) the two most important factors to keep in mind when buying investment antique furniture is quality and authenticity. 4.5.3 Military memorabilia This category of antiques includes a wide range of items including objects such as (BBC 2001): • Antique swords; • Old uniforms; • Medallions; • Archery objects such as bows and arrows; • Axes; and • Shields. Items falling within the scope of this category derive their value from their historical significance. The art of war and warfare forms an integral part of the history of humankind and therefore these items have a certain degree of international appeal. Certain items, however, do have great appeal to investors/collectors from specific regions, such as America, Great Britain and Europe. 55 It may be said that other drivers of value include decoration, provenance and importance of the piece being considered. These objects range from large to small and may be movable and storable depending on the specific assets. Most objects no longer serve their primary purpose and therefore are of little value as far as functionality is concerned, on the other hand they are perfectly suited for display purposes. As is the case with antique furniture, well-preserved and looked after articles command minimal maintenance. An obvious disadvantage of these objects is the fact that they might be dangerous if not stored and displayed properly, this results in an added responsibility for the investor to ensure the safety of third parties. 4.5.4 Clocks and watches The watch as we know it today has undergone an extended evolution, beginning with articles such as sundials and continuing its evolution on an ongoing basis. Antique clocks and watches constitute a large proportion of this evolution and therefore they hold substantial historic significance. Because of their historic importance and man’s fascination with time and general aesthetic attributes, clocks and watches tend to be highly popular and sought after amongst collectors (North 2000). Clocks and watches as antique categories are made up of numerous subdivisions including mantel clocks, pocket watches, water clocks, sandglasses and tall case clocks (grandfather clocks). The British and other European nations, such as the French, were the main pioneers in the development of time measurement and therefore clocks originating from these regions are very popular collectors items. Timepieces may be divided into various categories, some of which were mentioned earlier. The following identifies, lists these categories as well as 56 the names of some of the most significant manufacturers for each of the categories (Clemens von Halem, Halem-times [on-line]): • Wrist watches : Patek Philippe, Rolex, Omega, Vacheron & Constantin, Cartier, IWC (International Watch Company), Movado, Longines, TAG Heuer, Breitling. • Pocket watches : Durrstein & Co., IWC, Longines, Patek Philippe, Thomas Russel and Son, Ulysse Nardin and A. Lange & Sohne. • Clocks : Movado, Lepaute and Prazisionregulator Le Roy. • Chronometers As a general rule clocks are movable and easily stored and this together with the fact that they are highly popular results in clocks and watches being one of the better alternative investment categories. The fact that antique clocks and watches appeal to a broad base of buyers, ranging from investors and specialist collectors to the general public, lends a certain degree of liquidity to them which is found only in a few other categories. There are various designs available which makes them more popular and increases their visual appeal. Working examples add a functional element to these assets which together with their visual qualities enhance the investability of the category. Because of their desirability investors should insure them adequately against eventualities such as theft. Buying a clock that is not in a working condition, with the aim of restoring it, or repairing a clock that has broken down might be relatively expensive as expert knowledge and workmanship will be required in such instances (Phillips 1998). 57 4.5.5 Ceramics According to the British Broadcasting Corporation (BBC) ceramics may be sub-divided into two main categories, namely, pottery and porcelain. The BBC furthermore states that porcelain tends to be highly prized and therefore it is more valuable than pottery. One of the major risks associated with investment in ceramics is forgery or the inability to guarantee authenticity. This is especially true if the investor uses only the maker’s mark to determine authenticity, as many “factories copied each other’s marks to make their products more desirable” (BBC 2003). On their website the BBC identifies size, age, rarity, decorative appeal and condition as the main determinants of value. Some of the most desirable ceramic pieces are those manufactured by the Chinese, Japanese, English and Dutch producers. With regard to Chinese porcelain the most significant pieces are those produced during the Ming and Qing dynasties. China started producing porcelain as early as the Tang dynasty (618AD – 906AD) and up until the late Ming period (1368AD – 1644AD) European producers weren’t able to match the quality of Chinese porcelain. This gave rise to a large import demand from European customers. “According to legend, the first Japanese porcelain was made in 1616” (BBC:2003). These pieces have a strong Chinese influence but are characterized by distinctive use of colours and patterns. English porcelain can be sub-divided into early and later pieces, the earlier pieces being characterized by their simplistic designs and inferior quality to Chinese and Japanese specimens. Later pieces are identifiable based on their colourful and decorative designs, often providing a “fascinating visual record of the major events and personalities of the Victorian age” (BBC 2003). Some of the most prominent manufacturers of English ceramics include Staffordshire, Chelsea, Bow, Bristol, Worchester and Derby. 58 From a South African point of view the blue and white Dutch porcelain, known as Delft, holds a significant historical value, especially for investors who are of Dutch decent. 4.5.6 Glass Glass objects may adopt various forms including decanters, drinking glasses, bowls and even paperweights. According to the BBC the major determinants of value include rarity, shape of the piece, colour and decoration. There are various types of collectable glass including soda glass, potash and lead glass. Decorations may also adopt various forms including cutting, enamelling, fire enamelling, cold enamelling, gilding, engraving and acid etching. One of the major risks involved in investing in glass is the possibility of counterfeiting, and prospective investors should specialize and educate themselves prior to investing in glass objects. 4.5.7 Books Investing and collecting antique and rare books appeals to a wide audience. Books are universal “mascots” of development and therefore they hold a very prominent historical significance. First edition books are the most collectable and sought after but other factors also have a bearing on the desirability and ultimately the value of a book. These factors include condition, provenance of the book, the importance of the book as well as whether the book has been autographed by the author (BBC 2001). 59 One of the major benefits associated with books is certainly the fact that they have both local, and in many instances international appeal. Books are given their size, transferable and relatively easy to store. An obvious disadvantage of investing in books is the possibility of damage caused by extensive usage and improper storage. 4.5.8 Silver and metalware The range of items produced by using silver is seemingly endless, such items include among others: • Teapots, chocolate pots and coffee pots; • Mugs and jugs; • Caddies and coasters; • Salvers and Trays; • Flatware (knives, forks and spoons); and • Candlesticks. One of the main concerns for the serious silver collector is whether or not an item was manufactured from silver or if it is in fact a plated item. Even though silver-plated antiques are highly desirable and collectables in their own right they tend to command lower prices than similar items manufactured from sterling silver. England introduced a silver standard in 1300 after it became apparent that pure silver was unworkably soft. According to this standard silver objects had to be tested and marked to ensure that they contained at least 92.25% silver. The marks have become invaluable tools for investors/collectors to determine the origin and age of silver items. 60 Collectors/investors distinguish between four marks namely, the: • Sterling guarantee mark (all items which consists of 92.25% silver are termed sterling). • Town mark. • Date letters. • Maker’s mark. The patina of silver objects, caused by various scratches and knocks, will most definitely affect the value of the piece. Repolishing silver objects may render them undesirable and worthless. Investors/collectors should also be aware of silver “substitutes” such as Sheffield Plate (made from a fusion between copper and silver), Electroplate (a technique used to cover a base metal with a thin layer of silver via electrodisposition). These alternatives, as was mentioned earlier, may also provide the investor/collector with good value, but are usually ‘cheaper’ than sterling items. Items made from other metals may also be collectable. These metals include pewter, brass, copper, Sheffield plate and electroplate. One of the potential pitfalls of investing/collecting unmarked objects (which is often the case for other metals) is dating and the investor should have a good understanding and knowledge of the particular item he/she is considering. According to TIAS.com certain factors need to be considered by collectors of metalware be it silver or another alternative. These factors include the following: • Due to the number of niche segments in silver collecting, investors/collectors are urged to choose a maker, style or era in which to specialize. 61 • Collectors are advised to mix-and-match items with different designs and innovations as this will lend more aesthetic appeal to the collecting often increasing the level of enjoyment (emotional dividend) drawn from the collection. • Collectors should not refrain from investing/collecting items that show signs of natural use, as it often enriches the patina of the piece. • Investors should be on the lookout for modified items as they often have little investment value. 4.5.9 Firearms The invention of the modern firearm has great historical significance as this invention and the subsequent developments made to the original creation are responsible for bringing about an entire revolution in the art of warfare. Throughout its history development of the firearm had very definite objectives including the ability to fire with great rapidity without constant reloading, safety, durability and ease of use. These distinct objectives gave rise to the continuous and on-going development of firearms throughout history (The History Channel 2004). Initial designs, especially related to the ignition mechanism, were expensive to implement. Examples of this include the use of wheel-lock rifles and flintlock rifles. The cost of production, in addition to strict laws governing the use of guns ensured that guns, were rare and ownership concentrated to a select few, the likes of which included Heads of State, royalty and the rich minority. From the previous paragraph it follows that firearms derive their value from factors such as rarity, historical significance, condition and to a certain extent decoration (guns were often tailor-made and customized to suit the needs of the owner). 62 As a general rule firearms are moveable objects which may be easily transferred between parties. There are, however, various drawbacks related to collecting and investing in firearms, these include the existence of various laws and regulations governing the ownership and use of firearms as well as the inherent danger associated with objects of this nature. 4.5.10 Musical instruments Musical instruments, especially antique instruments, offer the investor/collector the opportunity to own a piece of history that not only offers the possibility of capital appreciation but also immeasurable pleasure from playing it. Some of the most sought after musical instruments are most certainly pianos, guitars and violins. According to Peter Davis (2002) of Lona’s Pianos in Midrand the five most prominent names in piano manufacturing are Bosendorfer, Julius Bluthner, C Bechestein, DH Baldwin and Steinway & Sons. According to Lona Davis (2002) “there is an excellent market in SA for antique pianos, and that every Rand spent on restoring an antique piano adds at least R2 to R3 to its value.” “[V]intage guitars are reaping big dollars as collectors' items, creating a whole new trade in classic instruments.” (Slack:2003). According to Charles Slack (2003) larger more ornate guitars and pre-world war II guitars are some of the most valuable and most suited for investment. The most prominent guitar brands include Martin, Gibson and Fender. The main drivers of value in the case of musical instruments are most certainly the maker/manufacturer, quality of the materials used (for example 63 the type of wood), quality of the craftsmanship, condition of the piece and originality (with no modifications). 4.6 COLLECTABLES 4.6.1 Defining collectables Collectables may be defined as assets that derive value from their inherent rarity. Terms such as “limited edition”, “one of a kind” are familiar expressions used to describe those assets which form part of this group of alternative assets. In economic terms collectables have value because there is a limited supply and a great demand for the asset, but one has to keep in mind the fact that unquantifiable factors such as emotional or historical significance will ultimately determine whether or not an asset is collectable. Good examples of collectables are certain toys (the He-Man and Thundercat ranges are currently very collectable), autographs, records and comic books. 4.6.2 Stamps Stamps have always been popular among collectors, with many collecting from an early age. There are thousands of different stamps to be collected from various countries and regions. The fact that many people collect stamps may afford the investor some degree of liquidity, whilst the sizes of these items allow them to be easily stored and transferred between parties. Due to the large variety of stamps that are available the investor needs to specialise within a certain area of collecting. Stamps are normally unique to a specific country or region. Investors might find that a stamp isn’t in demand in regions or countries other than that of its origin. 64 One of the potential problems with stamp collecting is the fact that its appeal as a hobby in on the decline. The love for stamps is generally “learned” from an early age and therfore modern developments such as computer games, the Internet and television have resulted in a lack of interest in stamps. 4.6.3 Toys According to The Guardian (2001) “[r]are and collectable toys have been going for record prices over the last decade or so, as the toy market has really taken off.” According to the BBC, collectors of toys tend to specialize in a particular area such as clockwork toys, robots or cars, or in toys produced by a specific maker. Collectable toys were mainly manufactured from one of the following materials: • Lead. Used in the production of various soldiers and other toys dating from the 18th and 19th century. (BBC:2003) • Die-cast. First produced in 1910 in France. Currently Dinky Toys, manufactured in England by the Meccano Co., are some of the most collectable toys. • Wood. Used as the primary material for some of the earliest toys. • Celluloid. Used to produce toys prior to the discovery of plastic. • Tinplate. Used to produce toys during the late 19th and early 20th centuries. Most tinplate toys represent icons of the industrial revolution, especially developments in transport such as trains, planes and automobiles. 65 4.6.3.1 Wood and die-cast toys These toys tend to be less sophisticated than toys made from other materials. Wooden toys in particular have a certain naivety to them. German manufacturers produced wooden toys in quantity during the 19th and 20th centuries, and some of the most collectable wooden toys were produced in America by manufacturers such as the Schoenhut Company. Toy soldiers from the 18th and 19th century were made from lead using either solid or hollow-cast manufacturing techniques. The most valuable of these were manufactured by firms such as Lucotte, Heyde and William Britain. The market for die-cast toys was dominated by Dinky toys, with rare Dinky toy advertising vans or unusual series being very valuable. 4.6.3.2 Dolls Collectors of dolls categorize them “according to the medium of the head”. (BBC 2003) These mediums include wood, bisque, composition and fabrics. The value of a doll may be increased by its wardrobe or costume (original costumes command the highest prices). During the 19th and 20th centuries the art of doll making was changed by the discovery of various manufacturing techniques such as rag, parian, celluloid, wax, papier-mâché, plastic and vinyl. Collectors often opt to concentrate on one particular sort of doll i.e. wooden dolls, plastic dolls or rag dolls. Dolls needn’t be old in order to be collectable. Limited edition dolls of ranges such as Barbie or Sindy are not only collectable but very desirable. 66 4.6.3.3 Bears The earliest Teddy bears were manufactured in the beginning of the 20th century by the German company Steiff. Early examples by well-known makers are the most valuable, with Steiff bears remaining “the most valuable of all teddies because of their unique historical appeal and exceptionally high quality”. (BBC 2003) The Guardian (2001) points out that the main determinants of value for collectable toys are the maker, the rarity of the particular model and condition. Toys which are still in their original packaging also tend to command higher prices than similar toys without the packaging. According to ToyNutz (2003) collectors are willing to pay premiums of between 5% and 40% for toys in their original packaging. Toys are collectable because they have a certain nostalgic value. Collectors collect toys ranging from dolls to model cars. These items tend to be small in size rendering them easy to store and transfer between collectors or investors. A major advantage of toys as an alternative investment class is the fact that many people are oblivious to the fact that they own a collectable or valuable toy, thus the investor is afforded the opportunity to acquire toys at discount prices. Many collectable toys aren’t very old and as such investors may be able to find bargains at informal markets such as a garage sale. The fact that these items draw some of their value from an emotional element may affect the desirability of the asset in as much as toys from certain time periods will be more significant to one age group than another. In addition to the fact that toys may only appeal to certain age groups the collector/investor needs a keen understanding of the toy market and specialized knowledge of particular toys. Investors/collectors should also be wary of counterfeit toys. Toys in general tend to acquire value over the longer-term, as toys are usually readily available initially, they only start to appreciate in value once the number of specimens in good condition has been significantly reduced. 67 4.6.4 Sports memorabilia Sport plays a very important role in the modern society. It serves as a central point of interest bringing together a diverse group of people. In the past few decades most forms of sport lost their amateur status and became professional and even corporate activities, bringing with it a high degree of interest and commercialism. Many people idolise sportsmen and women, and therefore they are willing to pay large amounts of money to own significant pieces of sport history. This demand led to the creation of the sport memorabilia market. The number of assets falling under this category is seemingly endless ranging across various sport disciplines. They may hold international appeal, such as a autographed shirt worn by Michael Jordan or a autographed helmet of Ayrton Senna or Michael Schumacher, or they may have only local appeal such as a rugby or soccer jersey signed by some local team. Assets from those sports which are played on an international level will provide the investor with universally accepted investments. Sports that would form part of this section of the market includes the following: • Tennis; • Soccer; • Athletics (particularly the Olympic games); and • International motor sports (Formula 1 and Le Mans). Assets falling under this category tend to be movable and transferable over international borders. If chosen correctly certain assets might afford a high degree of liquidity to the investor. It would seem that authentic assets autographed by the relevant sport personality command higher prices than those authentic assets which do not bear an autograph. Investing in local assets will definitely limit the liquidity that the investor may expect from the investment. Investors should be on the lookout for 68 reproductions or fake assets. Some assets may only have short-lived investment potential as they form part of a craze or fad, but soon lose their appeal. 4.6.5 Precious stones Investing in, or collecting precious stones could be very rewarding in both emotional and economic terms. The stones form part of the world’s natural resources and it is safe to assume that these stones are available in limited quantities. As more and more resources are depleted the more valuable the stones become, as demand increases and supply remains constant. The cost of mining precious stones also increases as mines have to go deeper to find more stones, this increased cost will be factored into the prices of gemstones, thus increasing their value. Gems are normally easily transferable and sought after across the globe. The fact that they hold international value means that the investor has a much larger market than would be the case for some or other alternative asset with limited international appeal. Investors should, however, have a specialised knowledge regarding precious stones but likely there are numerous information resources available to them. “[P]rices are dependent on the type, colour, quality and size of the stone” (Gemworld 2003) Some of the most important gemstones include diamonds, rubies, emeralds, sapphires and opals. Gemstones should appeal to investors especially because they are portable, transferable and take up very little space. 4.6.6 Cars In many societies the car that you drive affords you some form of social status, and because of this rare cars are very sought-after. Well known 69 brands such as Porsche, Ferrari, Lamborghini and Lotus are always in high demand. An interesting phenomenon has started to emerge in the South African new car market, where the supply of certain models is controlled by manufacturers, which in turn leads to transactions in the used car market being completed at higher prices than those quoted in the primary market. For example in March 2003 the listed price of a BMW M3 Coupe was R536 000 whilst 2002 models were selling for between R500 000 and R600 000 (wheels24.com, BMW and Autotrader.co.za:2003). Similarly a Mercedes-Benz SL 500 Convertible had a March 2003 list price of R1 325 000 whilst a similar car was selling for R1 600 000 in the used car market. Most manufacturers of luxury vehicles tend to employ a waiting list system whereby a customer will order a vehicle and be placed on a waiting list, a sort of first-come-first served system. Waiting periods range from a few months to a number of years, which allows pro-active investors to generate attractive returns. Rare vehicles such as certain Porsches, Ferrari’s and Aston Martins will always offer some form of return on investment, but these makes tend to demand high capital investments and as such only a select few investors are able to use them for investment purposes. The emergence of the waiting list system discussed in the previous paragraph opens this investment category to a larger investor base. One of the biggest advantages of investing in cars is the availability of information. At any one time there will be a number of comparable cars for sale, allowing the investor to assess whether or not the car is a worthwhile asset or not. 70 4.6.7 Oriental rugs Oriental rugs have always been regarded as investments, with many high net worth individuals purchasing rugs. In recent times, however, investors shied away from rugs as the market became oversupplied. Oriental rugs are categorized by their place of origin or the tribe that manufactured them. The difference between rugs from different tribes or parts of the world often lies in the distinctive use of colours, patterns, motifs and weaves (De Araujo 2003). From a valuation point of view factors such as size, richness of colours, fineness of knots, intricacy of design and condition play vital roles. According to De Araujo (2003:7) collectable rugs should be handmade and proof thereof will ultimately enhance intrinsic value. 4.6.8 Autographs This category of alternative investments is very similar to that of sport memorabilia. The demand for certain autographs will decline if they form part of a fad, whilst some autographs will always be highly sought after such as a James Dean or Elvis Presley autograph. Autographs, like sport memorabilia, may have international appeal or only local appeal depending on the person whose autograph is involved. Autographs that hold international appeal tend to be those of major international musicians, film stars, sports men and women and heads of state. Again autographs are storable, transferable and if chosen correctly may be relatively liquid. 71 4.6.9 Wine In his article “Collecting vs. Investing” James Laube (1997) warns of a difference between wine collection and investing in wine. According to Laube a wine collector buys wine with the primary purpose of drinking it at some point in time. Investing on the other hand, according to Laube, is to buy wine with the primary purpose of generating a profit. Laube points out that in order to be a successful wine investor one needs to be able to estimate the future of the economy, because “when times are good, people spend on fancy wines”. This emphasizes the fact that the investor should be able to estimate the future economic performance, but in addition to this the investor should also be able to foresee which wines will be in demand during the next market boom. Laube recommends that any wine investor should hold a balanced portfolio of wines comprising of those wines which he/she expects to perform well during the next market run, balanced/hedged by holding “blue chip” wines such as Bordeaux, vintage Port and California Cabernets. Lastly Laube is of the opinion that one of the major obstacles for any wine investor is that of emotional attachment to an investment. According to The Guardian (2001) “wine investment is [within] the reach of many ordinary investors” this is because ordinary investors are able to acquire quality wines at reasonable prices. The wine market is followed by various investors and collectors and is therefore a global market. Liquidity in the market is created by the existence of global wine exchanges such as Uvine, allowing a broad base of buyers and sellers to transact with one another. Uvine operates like most financial markets where investors are able to obtain bid-and-ask prices. On their website the Chateaux Management Group (2003) states “the fine wine market presents a vast untapped source of investment potential.” They further state that fine wines often outperform traditional investments such as bonds and equities, and that the negative correlation that fine wines seem to 72 have with more traditional investments, should improve portfolio diversification. Dunbar Fine Wines echo CMG’s general observation that fine wines provide exciting investment and diversification possibilities. Dunbar (2003) states that “[w]ine appreciates in value because it is constantly being consumed.” From this it follows that the value of a fine wine should increase because of a limited supply, resulting in a higher level of equilibrium between demand and supply. Lawrence Hayward and Partners (2003) are of the opinion that investments in Fine Clarets hold the following advantages: • Growth should continue to develop as a result of increased international demand and limited supply. • “Investment in fine Claret tends to be unaffected by unpredictable events or fluctuating world economies.” It may be said that these advantages would also apply to all other fine wine investments. According to Stephen Reiss (2003) various factors will have an influence on the quality of the wine. Amongst others the following should be considered as being very important: • Climate. Changes in temperature and rainfall will result in differences in the final products of various estates. • Soil. Tends to remain constant over time. • Age of the vines. As time passes vines produce less, but more intense, fruit. • Genetics of the vines. Tends to remain constant over time. • Skill of the wine maker. The level of skill of different winemakers will vary. 73 As was mentioned earlier the demand for wine is a very important determinant of value. It has to be said that value is also a function of quality, which is ultimately determined by the above-mentioned factors. Reiss (2003) also points out that New World Wine prices are primarily determined by demand, which is often influenced by trends and fads amongst consumers. From this discussion the following may be identified as some of the advantages of wine investments: • Investors are able to construct personalized portfolios, which take into account risk-aversion and the expectations of the individual; • Investors are able to acquire a tangible asset; • Wines are generally transferable between investors and have international appeal; • Wine markets are established with auctions being the primary medium for trade; • There are various tax benefits associated with wine investments especially as far as capital gains tax is concerned; and • The asset may be consumed if expected returns are not realised. The following are some of the disadvantages or risks of investing in wine: • The value of the wine will be adversely affected if it isn’t properly cellared; • Wines may be overpriced upon purchase. This is usually the case where the price was driven up based on current trends and speculation; • Certain costs need to be considered that may detract from the returns realized on the investment, these costs include commissions, insurance and storage costs; and • The market is to a large extent unregulated and therefore vulnerable to abuse. 74 Recent developments in the wine market include the development of wine futures, where investors are able to purchase wine prior to it being bottled (Uvine 2004). In terms of these contracts the investor will purchase the finished product before the grapes are actually harvested. This strategy may prove to be very profitable, but it is also very risky. 4.6.10 Rare, collectable and bullion coins “For many years, financial consultants have been advising their clients to hold coins. Their reasoning is simple: rare coins have been known to be an eventempered and reliable investing tool because coin values seem to keep pace with other investing classes such as stocks, bonds, funds, and real estate.” (Wyman:2003) Investing in coins may be subdivided into three subsections namely, investing in numismatic coins, investing in semi-numismatic coins and investing in bullion coins. The focus of this discussion will be on numismatic coins and bullion coins, as semi-numismatic coins hold little value other than their collectable value. 4.6.10.1 Numismatic coins Numismatic coins are legal tender coins that were minted decades ago and now exist in very limited supply (Searll:2003). From this it seems that these coins may be antique coins or collectable coins that derive value from amongst others rarity, age, condition and beauty (Goldfinger.com 2003). The actual value of the metallic content of the coins is not the primary determinant of value. 75 From a South African investor’s perspective some of the most sought after and valuable coins, according to the South African Antiques Dealers’ Association (SAADA), include: • 1926 Farthing or “oortjie”; • 1931 Tickey or threepenny; • 1899 Gold pound of the old Zuid-Afrikaansche Republiek; and • “Veldponde” minted in mining workshops. 4.6.10.2 Bullion coins According to Goldfingercoins.com (2003) a bullion coin is a legal tender coin whose current market price depends on its [metallic] content, rather than its rarity or face value. Gold and silver tend to be the most common metals used to produce these bullion coins. Some of the most well-known and collected bullion coins include the following: • U.S. Gold Eagles; • Canadian Maple Leaves; • Australian Kangaroos; • S.A. Kruger Rands; and • Austrian Philharmonics. Some of the major advantages associated with bullion coins include the following: (Goldfinger.com:2003) • Coins are produced in standard sizes based on their gold/silver content. Some of the more common sizes include 1oz., 0.5oz., and 0.25oz. and 0.1oz; • Coins are accepted and traded on a global basis; • Bullion coins are easy to liquidate, especially in comparison with numismatic coins; and 76 • Afford the investor the opportunity to gain exposure to gold investments via alternative routes than acquiring gold bars or ingots. 4.6.10.3 Kruger Rands As part of the investigation into the possible benefits of investing in alternative assets, a portfolio which includes a Kruger Rand investment will be constructed in a later chapter and therefore a further investigation into the history and characteristics of Kruger Rands is warranted. “The South African Kruger Rand was first released in 1967. For the first 20 years of its existence, it dominated the gold bullion market, and is still the most widely held gold coin in the world today.” (Goldfinger.com:2003) According to the South African coin dealer, InvestGold, the value of a Kruger Rand is determined by three factors namely: • The gold content of the coin and more specifically the current gold price; • The current exchange rate (important for South African investors); and • The discount/premium used to determine the bid-ask spread. According to InvestGold dealers quote bid-prices at a discount of between 3% and 6% of the current gold price multiplied by the prevailing exchange rate whilst quoting ask-prices at premiums of between 3% and 6%. 4.7. ART It is almost an impossible task to accurately define the term “art” - one man’s “heap of rubble” is another man’s “masterpiece”. According to kamprint.com (2003) art captures the deepest aesthetic and cultural qualities, and acquires 77 tangible investment value as a source of these qualities. The allure of investing in art, as is the case with most other alternative investments, was most certainly increased via the use of mass media and films. Investing in art is portrayed as being exclusive and sophisticated. The truth of the matter is that “speculating in the art market has ruined many more investors than it has enriched” (kamprint.com:2003). One example of speculation in the art market and the detrimental effects thereof is that of Mr. Ryoei Saito, who bought a Van Gogh and a Renoir for $161 million, during the asset inflation of the 1980’s. The pieces were later disposed of by his creditors at a third of their purchase price. (New York Times:1999) Examples such as this should not distract from investors considering art as a viable investment alternative but should serve as a warning. Investing in art demands that the investor should spend time studying the field before making any decisions. Some of the main “drivers” of value in the art markets are authenticity, condition, provenance, familiarity, technique and importance. In his article titled “Art and Money: Perfect Together” Uhlfelder (2003) states that “[m]any retail investors might have a hard time getting used to the idea that anything as hoity-toity as art can be a good investment. But museumquality fine art is a legitimate asset class. So much so, that some brokerages have added fine art services to their private banking operations.” Uhlfelder (2003) cites the example of the Monet painting titled Nympheas as a success story in terms of art investments. This 1906 painting was purchased at a Sotheby’s auction in 1960 at a price of $50 000, in 1999 it was sold in New York for a sum of $22.6 million. This resulted in an average return per annum of 17%, outperforming the S&P 500 by an average of 4.5% per annum during that period. Uhlfelder warns that art is by no means immune to the “vagaries” of the economic cycle, citing that the same Monet painting sold three years later at the price of $18.7 million – a decline of 6% per year (still outperforming the S&P 500 during the same period). 78 According to Michael Moses, associate professor at the Stern School of Business at NYU, art auctioned since 1960 has outperformed the broad equity market and with little correlation with stocks. Moses warns that investors/collectors of art can expect greater degrees of volatility than is the case for other asset classes, but adds that the low correlation with equities make art investments suited for diversification purposes. Art may take on many forms including paintings, sculpture, drawings and photographs The development of technology has given rise to artists expressing themselves in various electronic formats such as DVD and video. Art investors should apply basic investment principles to their art portfolio namely balancing the portfolio and ensuring that the risk profile is of such a nature that the investor’s entire portfolio (art and other investments) suits his/her risk appetite. As is the case for most asset classes art investments cater for a wide range of risk appetites. According to Bisaria “[i]f you invest a part of your total art investments in some young contemporary artists’ works, the risk is heavier, though the reward too may be higher later. You must balance these investments with buying some old masters’ works which will always appreciate in value.” The price of art, as is the case for any other investment, is determined by the basic forces of demand and supply. What is unique, however, to the art market is that the supply side is limited, especially in the case of a deceased artist. If the investor gives careful consideration to the value drivers in the art market and adheres to them he/she is almost certain to reap the benefits. It is suggested that investors take a medium-to-long-term view with regard to art investments. 79 4.8 GENERAL 4.8.1 Containers According to the South African Tank Container Association (www.satca.co.za:2003) the stainless steel tank container industry, which operates internationally, is a growing and stable industry. By mid 2001 the industry had 150 000 units in use and it was expected to show growth of approximately 7.5% per annum. According to International Tank Containers Pty (Ltd) (2003:4) investors purchase tanks through leasing companies such as Intertank. The company takes delivery and ownership of the tank on behalf of the investor. The container then forms part of a larger tank container pool. Any income generated by the pool of containers is distributed amongst the investors in proportion to the number of tanks owned. This ensures that even though a specific tank may be out of operation for a period of time, investors still realize returns. Returns are denominated in US Dollars (paid to South African investors in Rands at the prevailing exchange rate) and as such these investments offer a Rand-hedge to South African clients. One of the major benefits of this investment is the fact that various companies specialize in financing and managing tank containers on behalf of the investor. In addition to this it is not uncommon to realize a return of 10% in Dollar terms before tax incentives (www.satca.co.za 2003) making this a viable investment alternative for those investors seeking to hedge against the Rand by means other than investing in the stock market. Intertank (2003:5) lists the following as potential benefits of tank container investments: • Locally funded investment; • Dollar based asset; 80 • No limitation on the number of tanks that may be purchased; • No Reserve Bank or Revenue authorization required; • Income earned in a basket of currencies, converted to Dollars; • All earnings can be retained offshore and freely dealt with; • Tax efficiency; and • A hedge against adverse Rand movements. De Araujo (2003:23) identifies the following as possible constraints of tank container investments: • Sudden strengthening of the Rand may affect investors who opt to convert proceeds to Rand; • Various inherent costs such as repair and maintenance costs, as well as finance charges; and • Possibility of cheaper tanks being produced in the future. 4.8.2 Racehorses “For many adventurous investors, a racehorse investment combines the excitement of a thrilling hobby with the very real possibility of making a profit.” (CNNMoney.com:2001) Racehorses as investments differ from other alternative investments in that they pose the possibility of producing a periodic income stream for the owner as well as capital appreciation. Periodic income takes the form of winnings received from entering track events, whilst the bloodlines of thoroughbreds result in the horse appreciating in value as it poses the possibility of breeding future champions. 81 Investing in racehorses may take on various forms including the following: • Owning a racehorse. This may take the form of an individual owning a horse but according to CNNMoney (2001) partnerships are becoming increasingly popular. • Owning breeding stock. May also take the form of individual ownership or syndicated ownership. • Pin hooking, which involves buying and selling thoroughbreds in a similar manner to trading stocks. Tony Cobitz (2001), racehorse expert, concedes that it is true that investing in racehorses is speculative when compared to more traditional investment vehicles, according to Cobitz one major piece of common-sense advice can make it all worthwhile: Only invest disposable income. Racehorse investments pose some unique risks including the possibility of the horse becoming sick or being injured bringing its career and therefore earnings potential to a premature end. 4.8.3 Investing in people (Justin Wilson) Recently an up-and-coming racecar driver, Justin Wilson, created an interesting investment scheme which would allow investors to invest in his career and performances as a Formula One driver. The following extract indicates the basis on which investors were able to invest in Justin Wilson. “The potential return for investors is in two stages, and of course will be dependent on Justin’s success. The first stage is for investors to double their money, and this may be paid out after three years and once sufficient capital has accrued in Justin Wilson plc, which will receive all income related to his activities as a motor racing driver. Justin will be limited to a personal income 82 of £50,000 in 2003, £75,000 in 2004, £100,000 in 2005 and thereafter index linked until investors have received double their investment. Once this has been achieved, the second stage is for investors to be collectively entitled to 10% of all Justin Wilson plc’s income until 2012.” (Investinwilson.com:2002) This is an example in which the investing public was given the opportunity to gain exposure to an “investment” that derives its value from factors other than economic conditions and company performance. It is also a very good example of how an alternative investment was made more accessible by combining it with a traditional investment (that being the company). If this scheme is successful one might expect to see more athletes creating such companies. 4.9. GENERIC FACTORS TO CONSIDER The ultimate objective for any investor is to derive a return on investment that will compensate him/her for sacrificing current money for future consumption. When analysing more traditional assets such as stock and bonds there are certain criteria to which these assets must conform before they are considered to be investments. The same “rule” applies to hard assets, even though the factors which are to be considered differ greatly from those of more traditional assets. The following discussion will study each of the factors which were identified. 4.9.1 Authenticity Authenticity refers to the originality of the piece, and as mentioned earlier, one of the greatest risks involved in investing in hard assets is most definitely forgery. 83 Authenticity also extends further than the mere determination of originality, according to Kamprint.com (2003) “[w]orkshop practices in times and places which valued originality less than we do today also play a part in evaluating authenticity, as it was often customary for masters to sign works actually made by their students or employees.” Discovering that a painting thought to be the work of an old master is actually that of one of his students will most certainly result in a significant drop in value of the asset. 4.9.2 Condition From the discussion on different alternative investments it should be evident that the condition of the asset tends to be one of the major determinants of value for numerous alternative investments. Under normal circumstances an asset in perfect original condition will command the highest possible price, however, investors should keep in mind that in certain instances, such as antique furniture, the result of normal wear and tear may increase the value of the asset as it increases the premium placed on the patina of the asset. According to Kamprint.com (2003) “[d]efects provide opportunity for investment profit if the cost of the item plus the cost of competent restoration is much less than the current market value of the item in fine condition.” 4.9.3 Rarity Many alternative investments, especially those resorting under the category of collectables, derive their value from the fact that supply of the specific asset is limited and the demand for the specific asset is substantial. Supply may be limited in an “artificial” manner via the introduction of limited edition or limited production of a specified asset, or supply may become 84 limited as a result of the natural consumption of an asset. The latter form of supply “manipulation” necessitates a medium to long-term investment horizon for alternative assets. Kamprint.com (2003) points out that “the investment opportunity consists of buying when [assets] are plentiful and holding them until they become rare.” As was seen in the discussion on investing in cars it became apparent that the fact that producers/manufacturers limited availability/supply resulted in the possibility of realizing short-term profits. 4.9.4 Provenance Provenance basically refers to the ownership history of a particular asset. Collectors/investors are normally willing to pay a premium for an asset that has been owned by a prominent figure such as a celebrity. 4.9.5 Familiarity As a general rule people are attracted to those assets with which they are familiar, mass media and rise to prominence of the Internet has led to an increase in investor education as far as their knowledge of investments are concerned. Names such as Van Goch, Bordeaux and Ferrari are household names and as such the investor base as well as research base on these and other familiar assets are automatically increased. 85 4.9.6 Importance of the asset Importance of an asset refers to its historical significance, specifically the influence that the asset, or development thereof, might have had on subsequent asset and technical innovations brought about by the asset. 4.9.7 Technique/workmanship It is evident that quality of an asset, together with supply/demand, is one of the key value determinants of alternative investments. The quality of a manufactured product/asset can be directly related to the skill of the creator or the techniques used in the manufacturing process. Investors/collectors are, under normal circumstances, willing to pay a premium for assets of superior quality. According to kamprint.com (2003) “technical wizardry in the absence of aesthetic appeal does not bring a high price.” 4.9.7 Buying what you like Investors/collectors are generally advised to purchase only those hard assets in which they have an interest or those they particularly fancy. The reasons for this are multiple. • Firstly, hard assets do not provide the investor with a periodic income stream such as dividends or coupon payments, instead they provide “periodic income” in the form of emotional dividends and as such the investor should buy those assets which will afford him/her with the best emotional dividends. 86 • Secondly, should the value of the asset decrease dramatically the investor will still have an asset which he/she fancies. 4.10. ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES OF INVESTING IN ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS On his website www.goodbyedebthellowealth.com (2003) Karl Green identifies the following advantages and disadvantages of investing in hard assets. 4.10.1 Advantages • Hard assets are often considered inflation hedges as well as hedges against bear markets. From a South African point of view various hard assets act as Rand hedges as the majority of demand for hard assets comes from the UK and US markets. • Various hard assets have “inherent appeal beyond their monetary value, which can result in a sales premium.” (Green:2003) As a general rule creating or preserving wealth via the use of hard assets/alternative investments is done via capital appreciation, only in exceptional cases do these investments provide periodic incomes such as dividends or rent, however, in most cases they provide “emotional dividends” to the owner for which investors would be willing to pay a premium. These emotional dividends take various forms such as the enjoyment of a fine wine and the status of owning a prized piece of art. • They have potential for appreciation. It is, however, important that the investor should consider those factors that will have a bearing on the value of the asset. 87 • Some are liquid. Many hard assets are traded via dealers, auctions or even exchanges (precious metals) and as such they offer investors some form of liquidity. The lack of liquidity in some of the assets may be attributed to the low level of supply, current owners may be reluctant to sell their prized possessions. The increased use of the Internet to transact has created a market and also market liquidity for various collectables, antiques and hard assets. Many professional collectors believe that prices quoted on sites such as eBay.com give a true reflection of the value of an asset. According to Harry Rinker “If you want to see what something is really worth, go on eBay, check some sales. That’s what your stuff is really worth.” The Internet has increased the supply side of the value determination equation resulting in prices dropping by some margin to reflect their “true” value. The researcher is of the opinion that in the long run this added liquidity will be beneficial as investors will be able to purchase and sell assets at fair values. 4.10.2 Disadvantages • Hard assets do not generate current income. As mentioned earlier return on these assets takes the form of capital appreciation and emotional dividends in most instances. • Value is based on subjective criteria and qualified experts are required for valuation. • Vital information used in the determination of the value of most alternative investments is limited. This may be attributed to the fact that these investments are traded in various markets ranging from exchange traded market and OTC-markets (precious metals) to fairs (antiques fairs). 88 • They may be subject to significant decreases in value. Current market moods and fads may leave the investor with an undesirable specimen, this characteristic does, however, extend to more traditional markets as well, one only needs to consider the bursting of the Information Technology bubble in the late 90’s. Again the importance of taking into consideration future expectations as well as value determinants are of the utmost importance for successful investments. • It may be difficult to ascertain the authenticity of hard assets. Authenticity is most definitely one of the major determinants of value for most hard/alternative assets. • The nature of the market is such that investors often purchase the assets in the retail market, and sell them in the wholesale market. This might lead to investors not realizing the true potential of their investments. Another factor to be considered is the fact that dealers charge high commissions. This is not always the case but depends on the asset chosen. • Investors have to contend with the fact that a large volume of these assets is sold via auction and therefore they will be bidding for specimens against industry professionals. This is, however, not always the case. Purchasing assets via an auction might result in acquiring valuable assets at discounted prices especially if the private investor visits smaller auctions. • Another constraint of investing in art is that of theft, which brings in its wake the additional cost of insuring the assets. 89 4.11 SUMMARY This chapter served as a review of the numerous assets that may be considered alternative investments. The term alternative investment may be used to describe various types of unusual investments ranging from hedge funds to antiques. This chapter identifies an alternative asset as being a hard asset, i.e. an asset with physical features. This chapter aimed to provide a definition for the term alternative asset (as used in the context of this study). The definition provided in this chapter is a modified rendition of the basic definition used to define investments in their broadest sense. Apart from reviewing various asset types, the chapter subdivides the assets into one of four groups, each with its own unique characteristics. These groups include: • Antiques; • Collectibles; • Art; and • General. Following the discussion on each of the asset types the chapter aimed to identify a set of factors which influence the value, and hence the performance of these assets in general. This set of factors included factors such as authenticity, provenance and quality of materials used. Lastly the chapter identified various advantages and disadvantages of investing in alternative assets, coming to the conclusion that the major drawbacks of these assets are their illiquid nature, and the fact that investors need in-depth knowledge with regards to a specific asset or asset type. 90 CHAPTER 5: EFFICIENT MARKETS AND ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 5.1. INTRODUCTION The study necessitates a discussion pertaining to the markets in which alternative assets are traded. It is assumed that ‘traditional investments’ such as stocks and bonds are traded on organized, ‘efficient’ and developed markets, but this doesn’t necessarily apply to alternative investments. The first section of this chapter will define the term market, identify those characteristics that may be associated with a good market, and review and discuss the efficient market hypothesis (EMH). The second section of this chapter will identify the common characteristics of the alternative investment markets, compare the identified characteristics to those of a good market and lastly discuss the efficiency of alternative markets with reference to the EMH. 5.2. DEFINING A MARKET Reilly and Brown (2000:107) define a market as the means through which buyers and sellers are brought together to aid in the transfer of goods and/or services. They go on to identify certain key elements of this definition, namely: • The existence of a market isn’t dependent on the existence of a physical location; • The market doesn’t necessarily own the goods and services being transferred; and • A market’s operations aren’t limited to one specific product or service. 91 In the South African setting one is able to identify various ‘official’ markets, these include: The money market – “[t]he money market is defined as that part of the financial market which deals in instruments with maturities ranging from one day to one year…” (Goodspeed 2003:41) The equity market – “[t]he equity market is part of the capital market. Capital markets are markets in which institutions, corporations, companies and governments raise long-term funds to finance capital investments and expansion projects.” (Goodspeed 2003:47) The FX market – “[t]he foreign exchange market [FX] is the financial market where currencies are bought and sold.” (Goodspeed 2003:36) Bond market – the bond market falls under the capital market. Derivative market – the derivative market refers to a market where instruments, which derive their value from the “prices” (Goodspeed 2003:53) of underlying assets, are traded. 92 5.3. CHARACTERISTICS OF GOOD MARKETS In their discussion of the organization and functioning of security markets, Reilly and Brown (2000:107) identify the following factors that characterise a good market: • Availability of information. Investors entering the market aim to do so at a price justified by prevailing supply and demand. This requires information which is timely and accurate, information on past transactions and current factors such as outstanding bids and offers. • Liquidity. This refers to the ability to buy and sell assets quickly and at a known price. • Low transaction costs. Lower transaction costs make markets more efficient. • External or informational efficiency. Refers to the market’s ability to accurately reflect all the information with regards to supply and demand factors in the asset price. The availability of information, as a characteristic of a good market, implies that there are various sources of information available, that there is an interest in the ‘business’ of the asset and that a sufficient number of investors follow the performance of the asset thereby creating a need for information. As was stated earlier the requirement of liquidity refers to the ability of investors to realize their assets quickly and at a known price. According to Radcliffe (1982:6) the ability to sell an asset quickly is also referred to as marketability, and even though it is a necessary condition for liquidity, it is, in itself, not a sufficient condition. The second premise for liquidity of assets is that of price continuity, i.e. the assurance that prices wouldn’t change much from one transaction to another, unless substantial information has been 93 made available. Price continuity is affected by market depth which refers to the number of market participants who are willing to buy and sell the asset at prices above or below the current market price. 5.4. EFFICIENT MARKETS The following section will consider the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH). In order to assist the reader in the understanding of the EMH, this section will consider the assumptions which are made with regard to efficient markets. These are (Stevenson and Jennings 1976:303): • A large number of competing, profit-maximizing participants analyze and value securities independently; • New information regarding securities comes to the market in a random fashion; • Competing investors attempt to adjust security prices rapidly to reflect the effect of new information; and • The expected returns implicit in the current price of the security should reflect its risk. 5.5. THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS (EMH) According to Dobbins, Witt and Fielding (1994:16) “[t]he EMH suggests that share prices fully reflect all available information, any new or shock information being immediately incorporated into the share price.” This definition of the EMH may be adapted to encompass all assets (not just shares) which are traded in efficient markets. The EMH evolved from Eugene Fama’s PhD dissertation (1960) in which he argued that in an active market with informed participants, assets will be priced in a manner which reflects available information on the asset. 94 "An 'efficient' market is defined as a market where there are large numbers of rational profit-maximizers actively competing, with each trying to predict future market values of individual securities, and where important current information is almost freely available to all participants. In an efficient market, competition among the many intelligent participants leads to a situation where, at any point in time, actual prices of individual securities already reflect the effects of information based both on events that have already occurred and on events which, as of now, the market expects to take place in the future. In other words, in an efficient market at any point in time the actual price of a security will be a good estimate of its intrinsic value." (Fama 1965) The EMH may take on one of three forms namely: • Weak; • Semi-strong; and • Strong. 5.5.1 Weak form EMH “Weak form tests of the EMH are concerned with the extent to which share prices can be used to predict future prices, and a great deal of evidence suggests that the historic series of prices cannot predict future prices.” (Dobbins et al 1994:17) “Successive price changes are independent. Any implications from historic events for future share prices are reflected in today’s price.” (Dobbins et al 1994:69) From this it follows that this form of the EMH implies that the study of past information in the evaluation of investment opportunities will not have any relationship with future price movements, and as such investors who rely on historic information to perform asset analyses won’t experience superior returns. 95 The fact, however, remains that past information may be used to a certain extent in order to determine the perceived risk/return characteristics of an asset. 5.5.2 Semi-strong form EMH Semi-strong form tests attempt to measure the extent to which share prices fully react to publicly available information relating to stock splits, earnings announcements, forecasts and large block trades. (Dobbins et al 1994:17) Prices adjust instantaneously to such new information as is contained in earnings announcements, stock splits, dividend announcements and large block trades. It is therefore not possible to use such public information to make excess returns. (Dobbins et al 1994:70) This form of the EMH encompasses the weak form of the EMH. According to Fischer and Jordan (1983:454) the hypothesis implies that investors who base their decisions on important new information after it is public should not derive above-average profits from their transactions because the security price will already reflect all such public information. 5.5.3 Strong-form EMH Dobbins et al (1994:17) states that “strong form EMH tests are designed to discover whether share prices reflect all information, even information which is not available to the public.” This form of the EMH encompasses both the weak and the semi-strong form of the hypothesis. It argues that no investor should be able to outperform the market even if he/she has access to ‘privileged’ information. 96 Implied in this form of the EMH is the fact that investors will not be compensated for risk in excess of the market risk, underlining the importance of effective portfolio management and diversification. 5.5.4 Implications of the EMH The EMH has various implications for individual and professional investors, on various fronts of their investment activity, ranging from implications on technical analysis to fundamental analysis. The main focus of this study is the area of portfolio management and therefore the focus of this section will be on the implication of the EMH on portfolio management. One of the most significant implications of the EMH on portfolio management is the premise that the market rewards only unavoidable risks. This implies that investors and portfolio managers should not expect to earn returns for taking risks which may be diversified away. According to Stevenson and Jennings (1976:312) the EMH implies that investors should follow a passive portfolio management strategy. Money managers struggle to out-perform the general market on a consistent basis, they reason that these money managers employ superior and inferior analysts, whose “recommendation-performance” often neutralizes each other. Reilly et al. (2000:250) suggest that money managers who have access to analysts with superior analytical abilities and unique insights should follow these analysts’ recommendations. More importantly they recommend that money managers who do not have access to superior analysts should construct their portfolios to comply with their clients’ risk preferences, diversify their portfolio completely and minimize transaction costs. This implies that the average individual investor should also construct his/ her portfolio based on these guidelines. 97 5.6. EXISTING MARKETS This section will discuss existing markets such as the equity and bond market with reference to the characteristics of a good and efficient market as discussed above. The section will sub-divide existing markets into ‘traditional markets’ and ‘semi-traditional markets’ the difference will become apparent upon further discussion. In the last part of this section the efficiency of alternative markets will be considered. 5.6.1 Bond and equity markets Both equity markets and bond markets may be classified under the term traditional markets. The following are some of the identifiable characteristics of these markets: • These markets are highly competitive, that is, there are numerous institutional and individual investors who participate in the market, each investor believing that he/she will be able to outperform the overall market. • “They have access to a great deal of information, such as economic forecasts, stockbrokers’ reports, newspaper articles, investment advisory services and company reports, and they have the current market price of all quoted securities and have access to past price movements.” (Dobbins et al 1994:17) • According to Dobbins et al. (1994:16) investors can expect that “[i]n such highly competitive and well-informed markets” prices will fully reflect all available information and that prices will adjust quickly to new or shock information. If these characteristics of ‘traditional’ markets were compared to the requirements of an efficient market, one would be able to conclude that these traditional markets are highly efficient. Therefore at the very least the semi- 98 strong form of the EMH applies to equity and bond markets. According to Dobbins et al (1994:17) there is a host of evidence that supports the belief that equity and bond markets subscribe to the strong form of the EMH. 5.6.2 Real estate markets The real estate market may be classified as a ‘semi-traditional’ market, because even though it is a very active market, it isn’t quite as developed as the ‘traditional markets’. Some of the prominent characteristics of this market and the assets traded in the market, are listed below (Viruly 2000:1-3): • Large individual values. Direct property investments require large capital investments, which tends to concentrate the ownership of property investments in the hands of high net-worth individuals and institutions. • Not a standardized investment. No two properties are exactly the same and as such their value will not be determined on exactly the same set of factors. • Can be improved by active management. The investor has the ability to improve the performance of the property by taking certain actions, this isn’t the case for assets traded in the ‘traditional’ markets. • Information tends to be poor. Property market information tends to be imperfect, and “[t]he price at which transactions take place is not always made public.” • No organized market. There is no centralized market which handles transactions in this market. Developments in the property market such as the introduction of property unit trusts (PUT’s) and property loan stock companies (PLS’) have introduced some liquidity and formality into the market. The direct property market, however, remains to a large extent ‘unorganised’. 99 Upon comparing the characteristics of the property market to the requirements of efficient markets it becomes evident that this market subscribes, at most, to the semi-strong form of the EMH. Even though there might be numerous competing investors who participate in the market, Viruly (2000:1) states that information and the flow of information within the market tends to be poor. From this one is able to deduce that investors with superior sources of information should be able to make superior investments based on that information, one might go as far as saying that, if the flow of public information regarding a specific property investment is sufficiently inefficient, investors who have timely access to information in the public realm might be able to use public information to make superior investment decisions. One would still expect prices to change and react to information, but the reaction might be delayed. 5.7. ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT MARKETS 5.7.1 Defining alternative investment markets Alternative investment markets refer to those markets where alternative investments (as identified in the second chapter of the paper) are traded between buyers and sellers. 5.7.2 Are alternative markets good markets? In order to successfully answer the question as to whether or not alternative markets are good markets one needs to discuss the characteristics of these alternative markets with reference to the characteristics of good markets as identified earlier. 100 5.7.2.1 Availability of information One of the characteristics of a good market is the availability of information regarding the assets traded in that market. As was seen previously this necessitates that various sources of information be available and that there is sufficient interest in the asset. The investigations of this study into the alternative investment arena make it apparent that information isn’t readily available in the public sphere; even historical performance figures are very difficult to obtain. Alternative markets tend to comply with this requirement of a good market in varying degrees. For example the development of wine exchanges such as Uvine is an indication of the rapid development of that market. Wine and wine investments are widely followed by various investors/collectors. On the other hand various alternative investments are less popular for investors/collectors. It would be safe to assume that the importance of familiarity of the asset should not be underestimated, the conclusion may be made that the more specialized the asset becomes, the less the following of that asset will become. The second premise of availability of information is that of the existence of a number of sources of information. Again alternative markets comply with this requirement in varying degrees, as indicated by the investigations of this study. It should be said that the existence and development of the Internet has placed a wide selection of information at the fingertips of investors, resulting in the increased flow of information in these markets. The assumption that the more specialized the asset becomes the less information and sources of information are available seems to hold true. 5.7.2.2 Liquidity The requirement of liquidity has two facets, namely marketability and price continuity. 101 Marketability is the ability to sell/buy an asset quickly and at a known price. In popular markets the ability to sell/buy an asset should not pose a problem to the investor/collector and the further development of exchanges for alternative investments should only improve the situation. One of the most prominent problems for most alternative investments is the lack of price continuity. This lack of price continuity may be attributed to various factors including the fact that some of the value of alternative investments is determined by unquantifiable elements such as emotions and the allure of status. Another contributor to this characteristic of alternative investments is the fact that a large number of assets are sold via auction and therefore various factors, other than the perceived value of the asset, may influence the price, such factors include, for example, the number of people in attendance during the auction and the publication of advertisements prior to the commencement of the auction. The researcher is of the opinion that the lack of liquidity in the alternative markets isn’t necessarily determined by the demand side of the market, but may also be influenced by the supply side, i.e. holders of alternative assets are reluctant to sell them even if a large demand exists. This statement should help in explaining the price premium commanded due to the rarity of a specific asset. 5.7.2.3 Transaction costs A good market is characterized by, amongst others, the ability of its participants to transact at low costs. Unfortunately assets transacted in the alternative markets are subject to high transaction costs, in many instances as much as “30%” (Fiske and Freeman 2001). The fact that transaction costs are high should not discourage the investor to consider these assets as alternative investment opportunities, but it should 102 lead the investors to consider alternative investments as being medium to long-term investments. As the markets for these alternative investments start to develop and the popularity for investors increase, transaction costs will start to decline, increasing the allure of these investments. 5.7.2.4 Informational efficiency Informational efficiency refers to the market’s ability to accurately reflect all information with regard to the current demand and supply of an asset. Essentially alternative markets are ‘unexplored’ territory for investors (especially institutional investors). The flow of information is insufficient (at the best of times) and in many instances non-existent. From this one should be able to deduce that investors with timely access to information regarding alternative assets should be in a position to make investments that will yield superior returns. 5.7.3 Are alternative markets efficient markets? To what form of the EMH does alternative investments subscribe and what is the implication thereof? From the discussion on the characteristics of alternative markets various aspects such as the flow and availability of information in alternative markets suggests that most alternative markets subscribe to the weak form of the EMH even though there are certain exclusions to this, such as the wine market which, in the opinion of the researcher, subscribes to the semi-strong form of the EMH. The implication of this statement is far reaching and may in itself explain the allure that alternative investments hold for investors. The major implication for 103 investors is that they would be able to derive superior returns on the back of timely public information in those markets which subscribe to the weak form of the EMH and superior returns on the back of privileged or insider information in those markets which subscribe to the semi-strong form of the EMH. 5.8. CONCLUSION The discussion in this section reinforces the importance of proper portfolio diversification. The researcher is of the opinion that the inclusion of alternative investments into a portfolio may result in a greater degree of diversification. From this section and previous sections it follows that the drivers of value differ between ‘traditional’ and alternative assets. This may result in low positive or even negative correlations between the returns on alternative assets and the returns on traditional assets. If this proves to be true then the inclusion of alternative assets into existing diversified portfolios may prove to be beneficial. 5.9 SUMMARY This chapter briefly considers the concept of a market, identifying some of the characteristics of good or efficient markets. Following this the chapter considers the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) in each of its three forms, that being the weak, semi-strong and strong form. The chapter also considers some of the characteristics of markets that are generally perceived to be ‘traditional’ and efficient markets, including the stock market and the bond market. Lastly the chapter considers the markets for alternative assets in the context of the characteristics of good markets, and the EMH. From this consideration it followed that in general these alternative assets were being traded in 104 inefficient markets, but that the degree of inefficiency may vary between different assets. In particular more recognizable assets such as wine and gold coins tend to trade in semi-efficient markets not unlike the direct property market. 105 CHAPTER 6: APPLICATION OF PORTFOLIO THEORY 6.1 INTRODUCTION This chapter will aim to apply basic portfolio theory to different data sets. The objective of the exercise is to generate empirical evidence of the diversification benefits (or lack thereof) associated with the incorporation of alternative assets into an existing portfolio. The construction of the portfolios is subject to some assumptions each of which will be discussed at the relevant time. In the following sections each of the alternative assets, as well as the more traditional assets will be discussed and evaluated at the hand of the theory as discussed in Chapter 2. The assets to be analyzed in this section include: • Gold coins (Kruger Rands); • Wine investments; and • Art. These assets represent some of the more popular alternative investment choices and therefore provided the data necessary to complete the study. Please note that a conscious decision was made not to include property investments in this analysis. The author is of the opinion that various studies have investigated and proven the benefits associated with property investments. The results of the statistical analysis performed in the chapter is based on historical data gathered from various data sources which include iNet Bridge, Oanda.com, Decanter.com and the JSE Securities Exchange. 106 6.2 INCLUSION OF KRUGER RANDS 6.2.1 Introduction In this section the study will analyze historical data in order to determine the possible diversification benefits that may be associated with the inclusion of Kruger Rand investments into a fully diversified risky portfolio. The section will firstly consider the construction of a fully diversified portfolio, consisting of debt and equity investments. Secondly Kruger Rands will be included in the diversified portfolio in order to determine their diversification benefits as an alternative investment choice. The study was conducted on the following basis: • Weekly data ranging between 1 Jan 1990 and 31 Dec 2003 was used to calculate the relevant figures. This resulted in a sample of 730 observations. • The period reflects a balance between a significant amount of historical data and applicability of the study given the prevailing economic climate. • The period also includes the reaction of the market to a shock event, in this instance the effect of the 9/11 attacks on the US. Weekly data was used as opposed to monthly or annual data as it allowed for more observation and therefore it should result in more accurate inferences. • Any assumptions made with regard to a specific asset will be discussed at the relevant time. 107 6.2.2 Assets used in the construction of the portfolios The purpose of this study is to identify the effect that the inclusion of an alternative investment will have on a diversified portfolio. In order to fulfill this purpose the study will construct a diversified portfolio (given the frequency of the data used) for each of the alternative investments, prior to the inclusion of the alternative investment. Each initial diversified portfolio will be constructed via the use of debt instruments, equity investments and cash. After constructing the initial diversified portfolio, an alternative investment will be included in the asset mix in order to determine the effects that it might have on the existing portfolio. 6.2.2.1 Debt instruments 6.2.2.1.1 Definition According to Bodie et al. (2003:296) a debt security may be defined as a security, such as a bond that pays a specified cash flow over a specific period. 6.2.2.1.2 Assumptions The following assumptions were made with regard to the debt investment: • A typical investor would include a debt instrument as part of a diversified portfolio. This assumption is reasonable in as far as debt instruments are generally considered to be one of the primary investment vehicles. • The South African All Bond Index (ALBI) represents a fully diversified bond portfolio. 108 • It was assumed that an investment product, which replicates, exactly, the performance of the ALBI index is available to investors. It was furthermore assumed that there were no transaction costs involved in the purchase or sale of any of the assets. • Assets are infinitely divisible and as such investors are able to buy and sell fractions of an asset. 6.2.2.2 Equity investments 6.2.2.2.1 Definition Bodie et al. (2003:6) defines equity as an ownership share in a corporation. Therefore equity investments include ordinary shares as well as preference shares. 6.2.2.2.2 Assumptions The following assumptions were made with regard to debt investments: • It may reasonably be assumed that a typical investor would include equity investments into an efficient and diversified portfolio. • Similar to the assumption made for debt investments, it is assumed that the JSE All Share Index (ALSI) represents a fully diversified equity portfolio. • The assumption is made that an investment product, which replicates, exactly, the performance of the ALSI may be acquired or disposed of by an investor, free of any transaction costs. • Assets are infinitely divisible and as such investors are able to buy and sell fractions of an asset. 109 6.2.2.3 Cash Most investors, institutional or individual, include cash or cash equivalents in their diversified portfolios. Cash serves various purposes including: • Provision for emergencies; • Provision for liquidity; and • Ensuring that investors are able to exploit future investment opportunities. The inclusion of cash in a diversified portfolio is therefore important for the purposes of this study. Accordingly the following assumptions relate to the cash portion of the portfolio: • The yield on the 90-Day South African Banker’s Acceptance (BA) rate was used as a proxy for the return that investors were able to realize on the cash investment. • The BA-rate is believed to be more representative of actual interest rate movements than the repo-rate, as it has shorter reset periods. • The BA and thus the cash investment is not a substitute for the riskfree asset as its returns (as will be seen later) are volatile. 6.2.2.4 Kruger Rands 6.2.2.4.1 Definition Chapter three contains a detailed discussion of Kruger Rands and therefore it would be sufficient to define these assets for the purpose of this section as a South African bullion coin traded worldwide. 110 6.2.2.4.2 Assumptions Price data and return data for Kruger Rands aren’t readily available, as there existed no formal exchange for the product at the time of this investigation. In order to generate price data, historical information pertaining to the Rand gold price was used as a proxy for the performance of the Kruger Rand. This is a reasonable assumption as, according to Investgold Ltd, Kruger Rand market makers determine the price of the asset based on the Dollar gold price multiplied with the prevailing Rand-Dollar exchange rate and a bid spread of approximately –3% and an ask spread of approximately +6%. For the purpose of this study the spreads weren’t taken into account in order to simplify the statistical calculations. 6.2.3 Analysis of the assets used to construct the diversified portfolios In this section a comparative analysis is performed on the assets identified in the previous section. The purpose is to indicate the performances of the individual assets and their risk characteristics, but also to evaluate the comovements of the assets. 6.2.3.1 Performance analysis Figure 6.1 represents the weekly movements of the ALBI index over the 730week observation period. 111 Figure 6.1 Weekly All Bond Index (ALBI) movements 1990 - 2003 Index Level 200 150 100 50 2002/12/31 2001/12/31 2000/12/31 1999/12/31 1998/12/31 1997/12/31 1996/12/31 1995/12/31 1994/12/31 1993/12/31 1992/12/31 1991/12/31 1990/12/31 1989/12/31 0 Date Source: Inet Figure 6.1 indicates that the index has increased over the observation period. Figure 6.2 represents the weekly movements of the All Share Index (ALSI) over the same holding period. Figure 6.2 Weekly All Share Index (ALSI) movements 1990 - 2003 14000 Index Level 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000 2002/12/31 2001/12/31 2000/12/31 1999/12/31 1998/12/31 1997/12/31 1996/12/31 1995/12/31 1994/12/31 1993/12/31 1992/12/31 1991/12/31 1990/12/31 1989/12/31 0 Date Source: Inet 112 Again the index increased over the holding period. Figure 6.3 represents the weekly movements of the 90-day BA-rate over the holding period (1990 – 2003). Figure 6.3 Weekly 90-Day BA yield-rate (BA) movements 1990 - 2003 Source: Inet In contrast to the other assets the yield on the 90-BA has declined over the holding period. Lastly figure 6.4 indicates the price movement of the Kruger Rand asset over the same holding period. 113 Figure 6.4 2002/12/31 2001/12/31 2000/12/31 1999/12/31 1998/12/31 1997/12/31 1996/12/31 1995/12/31 1994/12/31 1993/12/31 1992/12/31 1991/12/31 1990/12/31 4000 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 1989/12/31 Price Movement Weekly price movements of the Kruger Rand Date Source: Inet Figure 6.4 indicates that the Kruger Rand’s price increased over the observation period. The steepness of the trend line in figure 6.4 would lead one to suspect that the price increase experienced by the asset was greater than that of all the other assets considered. Direct comparisons between the returns on these assets are not possible from the charts cited above. Only general inferences, such as the ones made with regards to a general increase or decrease in the price of the asset or index level are possible. In order to directly compare the performances of the assets over the holding period, asset returns had to be standardized. This was done by calculating the holding period yield (HPY) for each asset. Note that in this case a week represented an individual holding period. 114 The following equation represents the calculation of HPY: HPY = HPR − 1 Where: [6.1] HPR represents the holding period return (calculated by dividing the end value of the asset by its initial value, for a specific holding period). Figure 6.5 Weekly HPY for the ALBI (1990 – 2003) Source: Inet Figure 6.5 represents the holding period yields for the ALBI (debt investment) during the period Jan 1990 to Dec 2003. Of this figure it may be said that most of the observations lie in the band between –2.00% and +2.00%, however, there are some outliers as indicated by points A and B on the figure. Only when it is compared to similar figures for the equity asset and the cash component of the diversified portfolio can the debt instrument be properly analyzed. Figures 6.6 and 6.7 represent the holding period yield for the equity asset and the cash component of the diversified portfolio respectively. 115 Figure 6.6 Weekly HPY for the ALSI (1990 – 2003) Source: Inet Figure 6.7 Weekly HPY for the BA (1990 – 2003) Source: Inet Figure 6.6 indicates that even though there were some outliers (as indicated by A and B), most of the observations (HPY) for the ALSI were concentrated in a band between –5.00% and +5.00%. In the case of the BA (as indicated in 116 figure 6.7) the returns are represented on an annualised basis and as such the cash investment never produced a negative return. Figure 6.8 Weekly HPY for the Kruger Rand (1990 – 2003) Source: Inet Figure 6.8 indicates the weekly HPY for the Kruger Rand asset during the period ranging from 1990 to 2003. The chart indicates that on average the Kruger Rands provided investors with a weekly return ranging between –5% and +5%. In order to directly compare the returns on the various investments, it is essential to annualise the return figures. These figures should be annualised using equation 6.2: Annual HPY = [πHPR] 1 n −1 [6.2] Applying this equation to the returns of the different assets produced the following set of results. 117 Table 6.1 Table of comparative performance measures Asset Simple Average HPY Annualized HPY Debt 0.06% 2.98% Equity 0.22% 10.09% Cash 13.93% 13.93% Kruger Rands 0.16% 7.40% Source: Inet Table 6.1 indicates that the debt investment proved to be the worst performer of all the assets considered, in terms of return. On the other hand cash investment seems to have outperformed all the other assets based solely on return. From the discussion on portfolio theory it was apparent that securities and portfolios should not be assessed based solely on returns, but that the risk of each asset should also be considered. The following section will briefly consider the relevant risk measures for each of the assets. 6.2.3.2 Risk analysis The initial chapters of this study identified the measures of variance and standard deviation as the most widely used and recognized measures of investment risks. From that discussion it transpired that the higher the level of standard deviation, the higher the risk associated with the asset. Also the discussion on the capital market theory indicated that investors would expect a direct relationship between risk and return. Thus if risk increases so too should return. 118 This section of the study uses probability distributions of asset returns to illustrate the degree of standard deviation for each of the assets. Figure 6.9 illustrates the probability distributions for each of the assets mentioned in the previous section, starting with debt instruments, moving to equity investments cash and ending with the Kruger Rand. Figure 6.9 Probability distributions of assets Source: Inet Figure 6.9 (note that each of the figures is based on the same scale) indicates that the cash investment proved to be the most risky asset of the assets being analysed. This conclusion may be made by considering the extent to which the returns of the asset tends to deviate from the mean. The wider the dispersion around the mean the higher the risk associated with the asset. The kurtosis (level of peakedness) of the distribution of the debt instrument indicates that this asset is represented by a leptokurtic distribution, which indicates that this asset tends to have a high concentration of returns situated around the mean. When compared to the more platykurtic distributions of the equity, cash and Kruger Rand investments, it may be said that the debt instrument has lower levels of risk than the equity, cash and Kruger Rand 119 investments. When considering these risk measures in conjunction with the return analysis it may be said that the results are in line with the belief that return should increase as risk increases. Table 6.2 lists the percentage annual volatility for each of the assets. This measure is an annualised standard deviation figure for each of the investments and as such these figures were calculated by applying the following formulae: σ 2 i [R =∑ n t =1 Where : i − Ri n ] 2 σ i2 represents the variance of the asset [6.3] R i represents the realized return on asset i R i represents the mean return on asset i and σ i = σ i2 [6.4] Where : σ i represents the standard deviation of asset i In order to derive the percentage annual volatility the calculated standard deviation is annualised. Table 6.2 Percentage Annual Volatility of assets Percentage Annual Volatility Debt 8.86% Equity 19.48% Cash 22.77% Kruger Rands 15.50% Source: Inet 120 Table 6.2 confirms the results indicated by the probability distribution curves cited in figure 6.9. In addition to this it allows investors to rank the assets in order of riskiness. For this section cash investments represent the most risky of the assets, whilst debt instruments represent the lowest risk. 6.2.4 Portfolio construction Following the analysis of the individual assets, investors have to consider whether or not they would benefit from combining these assets in portfolios. Ultimately the investors would like to add investments to a portfolio that would lead to the highest level of diversification, therefore if an investment increases the degree of diversification of a diversified portfolio, investors should consider these assets for investment purposes. The aim of this section is to prove that a well-diversified portfolio, consisting of equities, bonds and cash, may be diversified even more through the inclusion of the Kruger Rand asset. In order to prove the above-mentioned hypothesis, the study will aim to construct a well-diversified portfolio consisting of a mixture between cash, equities and fixed-income investments. After considering the unique characteristics of this particular portfolio, the study will investigate the effects that the inclusion of the Kruger Rand in the portfolio will have on it in terms of risk and return. 6.2.4.1 Co-movements between the assets As was indicated in the discussion on portfolio theory, Markowitz and other theorists underlined the fact that diversification of a portfolio can be attained by adding investments to the portfolio that have low positive or negative correlations with those assets in the existing portfolio. 121 Figure 6.10 Scatter plot matrix of asset returns Source: Inet Figure 6.10 represents a scatter plot matrix in terms of which the returns of two assets were plotted against one another. This process was completed for all possible asset combinations. An upward sloping trendline indicates a positive relationship between the returns of the individual assets, whilst a downward sloping trendline indicates a negative relationship between the asset returns. This exercise assists investors in detecting the existence of positive or negative relationships between assets, prior to conducting various measurement calculations. Various measures of co-movement may be used to determine the relationships between the assets used to construct a portfolio, one of these 122 measures is covariance, which Reilly and Brown (2000:262) defines as a measure of the degree to which two variables move together relative to their individual mean values. The formula used for the calculation of covariance is cited below: Cov AB = ∑ [R A ][ − R A RB − RB ] n [6.5] Where : R x represents the realized return on asset x R x represents the mean rate of return on asset x n represents the number of observatio ns Applying the above-mentioned formula to the data gathered for each of the different assets results in the following covariance matrix: Table 6.3 Covariance matrix Debt Equity Cash Kruger Rands Debt 1 Equity 0.0000762 Cash 0.00000042 0.000064 1 Kruger Rands -0.0000658 -0.0000541 1 0.000107 1 Source: Inet Even though these figures indicate whether or not the relationships between assets are positive or negative, they are difficult to interpret. In order to address this problem, the resultant figures need to be standardized. The correlation coefficient of assets provides investors with such a standardized measure. Correlation coefficients range between –1 and +1. Where –1 indicates a perfect negative relationship between two variables and +1 indicates a perfect positive relationship between two variables. The correlation coefficient indicates both the direction and magnitude of the relationship between assets. 123 The following formula may be used to calculate the correlation coefficient for each of the assets. ρ xy = Cov xy [6.6] σ xσ y Table 6.4 Correlation coefficient matrix Debt Equity Cash Kruger Rands Debt 1 Equity 0.230 1 Cash 0.001 -0.075 1 Kruger Rands -0.249 0.1843 -0.008 1 Source: Inet Table 6.4 indicates that all of the assets have either a low positive correlation with one or more of the other assets, or a negative correlation with the other assets, a fact that indicates the possibility of diversification between the different asset classes. 6.2.4.2 Initial diversified portfolio This section aims to identify the portfolio that offers the investor the highest level of return for a given level of risk, assuming that the investor invests in a mix between cash, equities and fixed-income investments. 124 Figure 6.11 Efficient frontier Source: Inet For the purpose of this study it is assumed that investors aim to identify the minimum variance portfolio, or the portfolio with the lowest level of risk. The portfolio that satisfies this requirement may be found when the following asset mix is attained: Figure 6.12 Asset mix of a diversified portfolio Cash 11.56% ALSI 14.35% ALBI 74.09% Source: Inet 125 Given the above mentioned asset mix it is clear that the minimum variance portfolio would have provided the holder of the portfolio with a annualised return of 5.26%, and a standard deviation of 7.41%. 6.2.4.3 The alternative portfolio In order to avoid confusion the diversified portfolio which includes the Kruger Rand asset will be labeled the alternative portfolio. Following the construction of the diversified portfolio the question remains as to whether or not the inclusion of an alternative asset into that portfolio will hold any additional benefits for the investor. In order to answer this question one would need to construct an efficient frontier of the alternative portfolio and identify the minimum variance portfolio. After this has been done a direct comparison between the two portfolios is possible. Figure 6.13 Efficient frontier of the alternative portfolio Source: Inet 126 Figure 6.13 illustrates the efficient frontier of the alternative portfolio. On the basis of visual inspection it would seem as though this portfolio holds a lower level of risk than the diversified portfolio, this is evident in the lower levels of standard deviation indicated by the figure. As was the case for the diversified portfolio, the assumption is made that the investor will target the minimum variance portfolio. In doing so the following figure (figure 6.14) illustrates the asset mix of the alternative portfolio. Figure 6.14 Asset mix of the alternative portfolio Kruger Rand 18.84% Cash 10.50% ALSI 8.88% ALBI 61.78% Source: Inet Figure 6.14 indicates that the alternative portfolio should be constructed in such a manner that 18.84% of its total value is made up of the Kruger Rand asset. Given the above mentioned asset mix it is clear that the minimum variance alternative portfolio would have provided the holder of the portfolio with an annualised return of 5.59%, and a standard deviation of 6.86%. 127 This indicates that the alternative portfolio will enhance both return and risk. Table 6.5 tabulates the risk and return figures for both the portfolios. Table 6.5 Portfolio risk and return figures Portfolio Return Risk Diversified Portfolio 5.26% 7.61% Alternative Portfolio 5.59% 6.86% Source: Inet From this we are able to conclude that investors who held diversified portfolios, could have enhanced both risk and return on their portfolios if they included Kruger Rands to their portfolios. Furthermore it may be said that portfolios that weren’t effectively diversified would also have benefited from the inclusion of the Kruger Rand. Lastly as all asset allocation decisions are based on historical data it follows that rational investors should expect that the inclusion of Kruger Rands in their portfolios should lead to increased diversification. 6.3 INCLUSION OF WINE ASSETS 6.3.1 Introduction This section of the study will aim to identify possible benefits associated with the inclusion of wine as an alternative investment in diversified portfolios. This section of the study will follow the same methodology used in the section on Kruger Rands. 128 As there are numerous wines available for investors to choose from, an analysis of all possible wine assets would be near impossible. This study will focus on two specific wine assets namely: • A 1982 Mouton-Rothschild (First growth wine); and • A 1982 Montrose (Second growth wine). Apart from the decision to include a first growth and a second growth wine in the analysis, the wines were chosen at random. The 1982 vintage was chosen at random, but to ensure the highest possible degree of comparability it was decided that both wines should be from the same vintage. It should be noted that the difference between a first growth wine and a second growth wine relates to the quality of the wine, and more specifically it may be said that the first growth wine is of a higher quality than the second growth wine. It should be noted that the following general assumptions were made during this analysis: • Monthly price data related to each asset was used for the period August 1995 to December 2002. This was done in order to accommodate the fact that price data related to the wine assets was published on a monthly basis and was only available for the stated period. • Wine prices were denominated in British Pounds and therefore they were converted to Rand prices via the prevailing Pound/Rand exchange rate. The effect of this was also considered during the study. As was the case in the previous section of the study, any other assumptions related to a specific asset will be discussed at the relevant time. 129 6.3.2 Assets used in the construction of the portfolios This section will aim at identifying each of the assets that was used in the construction of the relevant portfolios. As most of the assets were defined in previous sections of this study, this section will only list the relevant assets and highlight the assumptions pertaining to each of the assets. The assets that were used included: • Debt instruments o The study used the monthly price data for All Bond Index (ALBI) as a proxy for a fully diversified fixed-income portfolio. • Equity investments o This section of the study used the monthly price data for the All Share Index (ALSI) as a proxy for a fully diversified equity portfolio. • Cash o Monthly data pertaining to the 90-day Banker’s Acceptance (BA) rate (yield rate) was used as a proxy for the returns generated by cash investments. • Mouton-Rothschild o Assumptions for this asset are mentioned in a previous section. • Montrose o Assumptions for this asset are mentioned in a previous section. As was the case in the previous section, it is assumed that normally, rational investors will hold diversified portfolios that are constructed in order to include a mixture of debt instruments, equity investments and cash. Thus it is the aim of this section to identify the possible benefits of including a wine asset into such a diversified portfolio. Lastly the assumption is made that investors are able to buy and sell fractions of any given asset. 130 6.3.3 Analysis of the assets used in the construction of portfolios This section aims at analysing each of the above-mentioned assets on an individual basis. The analysis of the performance of each asset will be followed by a risk analysis of each asset. Following the individual analysis of each asset various comparisons will be made. This section will also give consideration to the co-movements that the assets experienced during the observation period. Lastly it should be noted that even though both wine assets are analysed in this section they will be used individually in the construction of new alternative portfolios. This is done in order to reduce repetition and therefore isolate the effect of differing qualities between the assets. 6.3.3.1 Performance analysis Figure 6.15 graphically illustrates the monthly price movements of the ALBI during the observation period ranging between Aug 1995 and Dec 2002. Figure 6.15 Monthly price movements of the ALBI Source: Inet 131 From figure 6.15 it is apparent that the index has shown an increase during the period under observation. This is in line with the increase the index showed based on weekly prices as indicated in a previous section. Figure 6.16 shows the corresponding price movements of the ALSI during the period Aug 1995 to Dec 2002. Figure 6.16 Monthly price movements of the ALSI Source: Inet As was the case for the ALBI the ALSI showed an increase during the period. Figure 6.17 illustrates the monthly movements of the 90-day BA-rate for the period Aug 1995 to Dec 2002. 132 Figure 6.17 Monthly yield movements of the 90-day BA-rate Source: Inet Figure 6.17 indicates that the yield on the 90-day BA has declined during the period under review. This is evident from the fact that the trendline depicted in figure 6.17 is downward sloping. Figure 6.18 represents the price movements of the Mouton-Rothschild during the review period. Figure 6.18 Monthly price movements of the Mouton-Rothschild 1982 Source: Inet 133 It should be noted that figure 6.18 represents the price movements of the Mouton-Rothschild in Rand terms. Thus even though the price of the asset has increased during the review period, some of that increase may be attributed to favourable exchange rate movements. Lastly figure 6.19 represents the price movements of the Montrose wine asset during the period being reviewed. Figure 6.19 Monthly price movements of the Montrose Source: Inet Again this graph illustrates the monthly price movements in Rand terms and therefore some of the performances indicated by the graph may be attributed to favourable exchange rate movements. Direct and meaningful inferences can’t be made from these figures, but they allow the investor to make general inferences such as indicating positive or negative price performance. In order to compare the performances of the assets directly, these figures need to be standardized. This is done by calculating the holding period yield 134 (HPY) on each of these assets. Figure 6.20 depicts each asset’s HPY for the period under review. Figure 6.20 Holding Period Yields on assets Source: Inet Figure 6.20 illustrates the returns on the assets on comparable terms. From the figure it may be concluded that the Mouton-Rothschild should prove to be the riskiest of the assets, this is because its HPY-movements have the largest range (i.e. the largest difference between the lowest and the highest HPY). The Montrose investment should (based on the same reasoning) prove to be the second riskiest of the assets. 135 From the data used to construct the figures used above, one would be able to derive the following table (table 6.6) Table 6.6 Table of comparative performance measures Asset Simple Average Annualized HPY HPY Debt 0.41% 4.37% Equity 0.94% 8.92% Cash 13.62% 13.62% Mouton-Rothschild 2.84% 23.23% Montrose 2.04% 19.34% Source: Inet From table 6.6 it is clear that on a pure return basis the Mouton-Rothschild wine asset outperformed all the other assets during the review period. Debt was the worst performing asset during the same period. The fact that the Montrose provided similar performance to the MoutonRothschild may prove to be important, as it indicates that lower quality wines may provide investors with high return levels at affordable prices, which is similar to the performance of small-cap stocks in relation to large-cap stocks. The full extent of this will only be evident upon completion of the risk analysis. 6.3.3.2 Risk analysis From the earlier discussion of the study it was apparent that risk is the uncertainty of realized returns being equal to expected returns. Given this definition it may be said that dispersion around the mean provides the investor with a measure of risk, specifically the wider the dispersion the higher the level of risk. 136 Probability distributions of return provide the investor with a visual record of the dispersion of returns around a central value. Figure 6.21 Probability distributions of assets Source: Inet Figure 6.21 illustrates the probability distributions of the assets being considered. From this graphical depiction it may be concluded that the Montrose wine asset has the widest dispersion of returns around its mean whilst the cash investment seems to have the lowest level of dispersion around its mean. This leads to the conclusion that the Montrose wine asset is the riskiest of the assets being considered, whilst cash bears the lowest level of risk. 137 In order to facilitate further analysis of the risk characteristics the study calculated the percentage annual volatility for each of these assets. The resultant figures are tabulated in table 6.7. Table 6.7 Percentage Annual Volatility Percentage Annual Volatility ALBI 11.27% ALSI 22.99% BA 10.85% Mouton-Rothschild 53.98% Montrose 37.86% Source: Inet From table 6.7 it is apparent that the Mouton-Rothschild asset proved to be the riskiest asset based on percentage annual volatility, whilst the cash investment was the least risky based on the same measure. This accentuates the importance of proving risk attributes by means other than visual inspection. 6.3.4 Portfolio construction Following the analysis of the individual assets the study focuses on constructing portfolios which consist of combinations between the assets mentioned above. This section of the study may be broken down into three sections. Firstly a portfolio consisting of a mixture between the more “traditional” assets will be constructed, i.e. a portfolio consisting of a mixture between equities, debtinstruments and cash. In order to avoid confusion this “traditional asset” portfolio will be labelled the “diversified portfolio”. Secondly the first growth 138 wine, namely the Mouton-Rothschild, will be added to this portfolio in order to observe the benefits, if any, it holds as far as diversification is concerned. This new portfolio will be labelled the “MR portfolio”. Lastly the second growth wine will be added to the diversified portfolio in order to judge its effects on diversification. This last portfolio will be labelled the “Montrose portfolio”. 6.3.4.1 Construction of the diversified portfolio In order to construct a diversified portfolio, Markowitz indicated that the relationship or co-movement of the asset returns were of vital importance. Figure 6.22 depicts the scatter plot matrix of the returns on the debt instruments, equity investments and cash investments used in the construction of the diversified portfolio. Figure 6.22 Scatter plot matrix of asset returns Source: Inet 139 From figure 6.22 it appears that there is a positive relationship between the ALBI and the ALSI whilst the relationship between the BA and the other two assets (ALBI and ALSI) is negative. From the data used to construct the scatter matrix the following correlation coefficient matrix may be derived. Table 6.8 Correlation coefficient matrix of asset returns Debt Equity Debt 1 Equity 0.4679 1 Cash -0.0891 -0.17284 Cash 1 Source: Inet Table 6.8 indicates a negative correlation between cash investments and equity investments, this should bode well for diversification. The smaller negative correlation between debt instruments and cash should also provide an added degree of diversification. Using the various findings of prior sections an efficient frontier may now be derived for the diversified portfolio. Figure 6.23 illustrates this efficient frontier. 140 Figure 6.23 Efficient frontier for the diversified portfolio Source:Inet As mentioned in the section on the Kruger Rand the assumption is made that the investors will target the minimum variance portfolio presented by the efficient frontier. This results in the following asset mix: 141 Figure 6.24 Asset mix of the diversified portfolio Source: Inet If an investor held a portfolio constructed in the fashion denoted by the optimal asset mix he/she would have realized an annualised return of 9.26% whilst facing a standard deviation of 7.41%. 6.3.4.2 Construction of the Mouton-Rothschild (MR) portfolio Following the construction of the diversified portfolio, the effects of the inclusion of the Mouton-Rothschild wine asset on that portfolio will be examined in this section. As was the case in the previous section it is important to establish the relationship between the Mouton-Rothschild and the other individual assets. Figure 6.25 represents the scatter plot matrix of the returns of the different assets against one another. 142 Figure 6.25 Scatter plot matrix of the returns on the assets used in the MR portfolio Source: Inet From figure 6.25 it may be concluded that the relationship between the returns on the assets used in the construction of the diversified portfolio remain the same. Furthermore from the figure it seems that there is a negative relationship between the return on the Mouton-Rothschild asset and the ALBI, a positive relationship between the returns on the BA and the Mouton-Rothschild. The returns of the ALSI and that of the Mouton-Rothschild are slightly positively related. These conclusions may be made by considering the slope of the trend line, where a positive slope would indicate a positive relationship and vice versa. The steeper the slope the stronger the relationship, thus it may be said that the positive relationship between the ALBI and the ALSI is much stronger than the relationship between the BA and the Mouton-Rothschild. 143 The relationship of the Mouton-Rothschild to the other assets should be conducive to diversification, as they are all small positive or negative relationships. The data used in the construction of the scatter plot matrix may be used to calculate and derive the correlation matrix as shown in table 6.9 below. Table 6.9 Correlation matrix Debt Equity Cash MoutonRothschild Debt 1 Equity 0.4679 1 Cash -0.0891 -0.17284 1 Mouton-Rothschild -0.0899 0.00276 -0.0518 1 Source: Inet The figures stated in table 6.9 confirm the conclusion made from the visual inspection of the scatter plot matrix. The assets may be used to construct the following efficient frontier. Figure 6.26 Efficient frontier for the MR portfolio Source: Inet 144 The efficient frontier in figure 6.26 was constructed by varying the weights of the different assets used in the construction of the portfolio and then calculating the standard deviation and return on the portfolio. This figure plots the returns against the corresponding standard deviations. As was the case for the previous portfolios the assumption is made that investors will target the minimum variance portfolio. When compared to the efficient frontier for the diversified portfolio it would seem as if the MR portfolio provided the holder of the portfolio with higher returns and lower risk. This deduction is based on visual inspection and should be confirmed or rejected upon calculation of the relevant portfolio statistics. From the dataset used it appears that the minimum variance portfolio would have the following asset mix as indicated in figure 6.27. Figure 6.27 Asset mix of the MR portfolio Source: Inet Based on the above-mentioned asset mix the relevant portfolio statistics may be calculated. These statistics are presented in Table 6.10 below. 145 Table 6.10 Portfolio statistics of the diversified portfolio and the MR portfolio Diversified portfolio MR portfolio Return 9.26% 9.71% Standard Deviation 7.41%%. 7.27% Source: Inet From table 6.10 it appears that the return on the MR portfolio was higher than that of the diversified portfolio during the period under review, and furthermore the MR portfolio presented the investor with a lower level of risk, as measured by standard deviation. The conclusion to be drawn from this analysis is that the inclusion of the Mouton-Rothschild in the portfolio enhanced its overall performance. Given that the Mouton-Rothschild was chosen on a random basis it may be said that there is a possibility that other randomly selected first-growth wines may provide similar results. 6.3.4.3 Construction of the Montrose Portfolio The final analysis to be performed in the section on wine investment is the construction of the Montrose wine asset. This wine is, as was mentioned earlier, a second growth wine. The difference between first and second growth wines relates to their respective quality, where the first growth wine is of a higher quality that the second growth wine. This section of the study aims to investigate the question as to whether lower quality wines may also hold diversification benefits for investors. As was seen in a previous section the second growth wine proved to be more risky than the first growth wine, but also had a higher mean historical return. Figure 6.28 represents the scatter plot matrix of the returns of the different assets against one another. 146 Figure 6.28 Scatter plot matrix of the returns on the assets used in the MR portfolio Source: Inet The relationships between the returns on the assets used to construct the diversified portfolio remain the same. Figure 6.28 indicates a low level of positive correlation between the returns on the Montrose asset and those of both the ALBI and the ALSI. Furthermore it may be said that the returns on the Montrose asset and the BA seem to be positively correlated as well. These characteristics may prove beneficial for the portfolio construction process. The data used in the construction of the scatter plot matrix may be used to calculate and derive the correlation matrix as shown in table 6.9 below. 147 Table 6.11 Correlation matrix Debt Equity Cash Debt 1 Equity 0.4679 1 Cash -0.0891 -0.17284 1 Montrose 0.1737 0.3375 0.0459 Montrose 1 Source: Inet The figures stated in table 6.11 confirm the results of the visual inspection of the scatter plot matrix. The assets mentioned above may be used to construct the following efficient frontier. Figure 6.29 Efficient frontier for the Montrose portfolio Source: Inet 148 Again the assumption is made that investors will target the minimum variance portfolio. Based on visual inspection it would seem as if the Montrose portfolio provided higher levels of return than the diversified portfolio. Furthermore it may be said that the Montrose portfolio may have presented lower levels of risk than the diversified portfolio. In a subsequent section the relevant statistics that will either confirm or reject the conclusions of the visual inspection process will be calculated. From the dataset used it follows that the minimum variance portfolio would have the following asset mix as indicated in figure 6.30. Figure 6.30 Asset mix of the Montrose portfolio Source: Inet Based on the above-mentioned asset mix the relevant portfolio statistics may be calculated. These statistics are presented in Table 6.12 below. 149 Table 6.12 Portfolio statistics of the diversified portfolio, MR portfolio and Montrose portfolio Diversified MR portfolio portfolio Montrose Portfolio Return 9.26% 9.71% 9.23% Standard Deviation 7.41%. 7.27% 7.38% Source: Inet From table 6.12 it appears that the return on the Montrose portfolio was lower than that of both the diversified portfolio and the MR portfolio during the period under review. The figures cited in table 6.12 also indicate that this level of return was achieved at a lower risk level than was the case for the diversified portfolio. Upon calculating the level of return produced per unit of risk taken it becomes clear that the inclusion of the Montrose asset into the diversified portfolio resulted in a slight diversification advantage for the investor. The conclusion that may be drawn from this analysis is that second growth wines may be included in portfolios in order to enhance their overall performance. Furthermore these results indicate that the quality of the wine isn’t necessarily a determining factor with regard to its diversification capabilities. Even though the first growth wine did result in a higher level of diversification the question has to be asked whether or not this warrants the substantial cost differences between the two wine classes. 150 6.4 INCLUSION OF ART INVESTMENTS 6.4.1 Introduction and assumptions This section of the study aims to analyse the effects that the inclusion of an art investment into an existing diversified portfolio will have on the level of diversification of such a portfolio. As was the case in previous sections certain assumptions had to be made in order to facilitate the analysis. The following summarizes the assumptions and details surrounding the use of the art investment: • The performance of the Fine Art Index will be used as a proxy for a general art investment product. • The study was performed by making use of annual price data relating to the FAI, dating back to 1989. This was due to informational constraints. • The assumption is made that an investment product exists that will afford investors the opportunity to invest in the Fine Art Index (FAI). • Fractions of an investment may be bought or sold. • All other assumptions will be made at the relevant time. 6.4.2 Assets used in the portfolio construction As was the case in previous sections the assumption is made that the initial diversified portfolio will be constructed via an asset mix between debt, equity and cash. The following details pertain to each of these assets: • Debt instruments 151 o The annual index movements of the All Bond Index (ALBI) were used as a proxy for the price movements of the debt portion of the portfolio. • Equity investments o The annual index movements of the All Share Index (ALSI) were used as a proxy for the movements of the equity portion of the portfolio. • Cash o The annual rate changes of the 90-Day Banker’s Acceptance rate (BA) were used as a proxy for the movement of the cash portion of the portfolio. In addition to these assets the art portfolio (which denotes that portfolio which includes the art investment) will include a theoretical asset which replicates (exactly) the changes in the FAI. The assumptions pertaining to this asset are listed above. 6.4.3 Analysis of the assets used in the construction of the portfolios This section will concentrate on performance analysis and risk analysis of the individual assets, a later section will also consider the degree of co-movement that exists between the various assets. 6.4.3.1 Performance analysis Figure 6.31 illustrates the annual index movements of the ALBI during the period ranging between 1989 and 2002. 152 Figure 6.31 All Bond Index Movements Source: Inet From figure 6.31 it appears that the index level increased over the holding period, but it tended to fluctuate between a level of 115 and 165. Figure 6.32 illustrates the index movements of the All Share Index over a corresponding holding period. Figure 6.32 All Share Index Movements Source: Inet 153 Figure 6.32 indicates the ALSI index increase during the holding period from a level of about 2800 to a level of about 9500. Figure 6.33 plots the annual BA-rate over a holding period which is concurrent with that of the previous two assets. Figure 6.33 Annual BA-rates Source: Inet Figure 6.33 indicates that the 90day BA yield-rate has declined during the holding period. This downward movement should not be seen in isolation and should be considered on a portfolio wide basis. Lastly figure 6.34 illustrates the annual movements of the Fine Art Index (FAI) during the holding period. 154 Figure 6.34 Annual movements of the FAI Source: Inet From figure 6.34 it appears that the FAI has increased during the holding period that ranges from 1989 to 2002. Even though the figures listed above allow investors to make certain initial conclusions, these conclusions are normally relatively limited. In order to be able to directly compare the results indicated by these graphs the figures need to be standardized. The following section will standardize these figures via the use of the holding period yield calculation. The holding period yield movements for the debt investments are illustrated in figure 6.35. 155 Figure 6.35 HPY movements of the ALBI Source: Inet From figure 6.35 it appears that the HPY on the ALBI ranged between –0.2% return per annum to +0.15% per annum. Also the figure indicates that at times the HPY experienced swings between positive and negative returns. Figure 6.36 illustrates the HPY movements for the equity investment (ALSI) over the holding period. Figure 6.36 HPY movements of the ALSI Source: Inet 156 From figure 6.36 it appears that the HPY on the equity investment ranged between -0.1% per annum and +0.65% per annum. This wider range of movements should lead the investor to believe that the equity asset was more risky than the debt investment. This is in line with the conclusions made in previous sections of this study. The HPY movements for the cash investment (BA) are plotted in figure 6.37. Figure 6.37 HPY of the BA Source: Inet Lastly figure 6.38 graphically illustrates the HPY movements of the art investment (FAI). 157 Figure 6.38 HPY of the FAI Source: Inet From the figure it appears that the HPY on the FAI ranged between the levels of –0.35% and +0.32% per annum. This should lead one to believe that the art investment was less risky than the equity investments. From the data used to construct the figures used above, one would be able to derive the following table (table 6.13) Table 6.13 Table of comparative performance measures Asset Simple Average Annualized HPY HPY Debt 3.27% 2.53% Equity 12.29% 9.28% Cash 14.08% 14.08% Art Investment 3.19% 1.50% Source: Inet 158 From table 6.13 it appears that the cash investment generated the highest level of return during the holding period, whilst the art investment generated the lowest overall return during the holding period. 6.4.3.2 Risk analysis As was the case in the previous analyses, the assets should be analysed in terms of both risk and return. This section will consider the risk characteristics of the assets being analysed. Again the probability distributions of the returns on the assets will be used to provide a visual reflection of the dispersion of returns around a mean value. It should be noted that higher levels of dispersion indicate higher levels of risk. Figure 6.39 Probability distributions of assets Source: Inet Figure 6.39 illustrates the probability distributions of each of the assets (the graphs were drawn on the same scale). From this it seems that the ALSI proved to be the riskiest of all the assets, whilst cash was the least risky of the 159 assets. The FAI was more risky than the ALBI and cash, but less risky than the ALSI. The following table (table 6.14) tabulates the numerical values of the assets percentage annual volatility. Table 6.14 Percentage Annual Volatility Percentage Annual Volatility ALBI 10.65% ALSI 24.73% Cash 3.13% Art 17.88% Source: Inet Table 6.14 confirms the results of the visual inspection performed above. From the table one would be able to deduce that the ALSI was in fact the riskiest of the assets over the holding period and cash the least risky of the assets. 6.4.4 Portfolio construction Following the analysis of the individual assets the study focuses on constructing portfolios which consist of combinations of the assets analysed above. This section will consider the relationships between the assets that are to be included in the subsequent portfolios. Secondly the section will aim to construct a diversified portfolio consisting out of a mixture of debt, equity and cash. Lastly the section will aim to consider the effects of the inclusion of the 160 art investment in the diversified portfolio. It should be noted that this new portfolio will be labelled the “art portfolio”. 6.4.4.1 Construction of the diversified portfolio Prior to the actual construction of the portfolio consideration should be given to the relationships that exist between the price movements of the different assets. Figure 6.40 illustrates a scatter plot matrix of the relationships between the different asset returns. Figure 6.40 Scatter plot matrix of asset returns Source: Inet From figure 6.40 it would seem as if there is a positive relationship between the returns on the ALBI and the ALSI, as well as between the returns on the ALBI and the FAI. The relationships between the ALSI and cash and the ALBI 161 and cash are decidedly negative. There seems to be a negative relationship between the returns on the ALSI and the FAI, whilst there is a small negative relationship between the returns on cash and the FAI. From the data used to construct the scatter matrix the following correlation coefficient matrix may be derived. Table 6.15 Correlation coefficient matrix of asset returns Debt Equity Cash Debt 1 Equity 0.2292 1 Cash -0.4115 -0.5063 1 Art 0.1836 -0.2233 -0.0268 Art 1 Source: Inet From table 6.15 it seems that the negative relationships that exist between the returns of the cash asset and the debt instrument, the equity investment and the cash asset as well as the equity investment and the art investment hold the promise of enhanced diversification of portfolios. Using the various findings of prior sections an efficient frontier may now be derived for the diversified portfolio. Figure 6.41 illustrates this efficient frontier. 162 Figure 6.41 Efficient frontier for the diversified portfolio Source:Inet As was the case in the previous sections the assumption is made that an investor will target the minimum variance portfolio, i.e. that portfolio with the lowest level of risk. Following the selection process the asset mix for the minimum variance portfolio is illustrated in figure 6.42. Figure 6.42 Asset mix of the diversified portfolio Source: Inet 163 This asset mix would have presented the investor with a return of 7.28% and a level of risk equal to 7.87% as measured by standard deviation. 6.4.4.2 Construction of the art portfolio This section will aim to analyse the benefits, or lack thereof, of including the art investment in the diversified portfolio. From the previous calculations the following efficient frontier (as illustrated in figure 6.43) may be constructed for the art portfolio. Figure 6.43 Efficient frontier for the art portfolio Source:Inet From figure 6.43 it would seem as if the inclusion of the art investment in the diversified portfolio would have had an effect on the risk and return of the diversified portfolio. Again the assumption is made that investors will target the minimum variance portfolio. This strategy would have resulted in an asset mix as indicated in figure 6.44. 164 Figure 6.44 Asset mix of the art portfolio Source: Inet Based on the above-mentioned asset mix the relevant portfolio statistics may be calculated. These statistics are presented in Table 6.16 below. Table 6.16 Portfolio statistics of the diversified portfolio and the art portfolio Diversified Art portfolio portfolio Return Standard Deviation 7.28%% 11.70% 7.87%. 2.37% Source: Inet From table 6.16 it appears that the inclusion of the art investment in the diversified portfolio resulted in an increase in the level of return, as well as a decrease in the level of risk of the portfolio, as measured by standard deviation. 165 The conclusion that may be drawn from this analysis is that the inclusion of the art investment in the diversified portfolio would have benefited the holder of the portfolio during the holding period, reviewed in this study. 6.5 SUMMARY This chapter applied the theoretical principals of portfolio construction to three alternative assets, that being wine, art and gold coins. The experiments started off by establishing a ‘traditional’ diversified portfolio consisting of a mixture of cash, bond and stocks. This portfolio then served as a proxy for a completely diversified portfolio (the market portfolio as identified in the discussion on modern portfolio theories). Following the construction of this proxy portfolio, the effects of including a single alternative asset to the existing asset-mix was considered. The alternative assets used for the purposes of this chapter included Kruger Rands (gold coins), 1982 Mouton Rothschild and 1982 Montrose (wine), and a art investment based on an art index. These assets were chosen on the basis of the availability of historic price information. Each of the experiments performed during this chapter indicated that these assets had a positive impact on both the risk and return characteristics of the proxy portfolio. In most instances return increased, whilst overall risk decreased. These results stem mainly from the low positive and negative correlations that these assets had with the assets used in the proxy portfolio. Upon considering the results obtained from these experiments it followed that investors may benefit from considering some of these alternative investments when constructing diversified portfolios. It should however be noted that investors are urged to take a medium to long-term view on these assets. 166 CHAPTER 7: CONCLUSION This section will discuss the various conclusions that may be made following the completion of the study. • At the outset of the study the aim was to determine whether or not alternative/hard assets might be used to diversify existing portfolios even further. The study commenced with a brief overview of various modern portfolio theories and their respective origins, then the study moved on to discuss in detail the subjects of risk and return, including their respective methods of measurements. From there the focus of the study moved to the identification of various alternative assets. The next section of the study gave consideration to the theories surrounding efficient markets and the efficient market hypothesis. This formed the theoretical basis for the study. • The last section of the study concentrated on producing and investigating empirical evidence which would confirm or reject any initial assumptions made during the early stages of the study. The following section will briefly consider some of the most prominent findings of each of the chapters and the study as a whole. After considering the various portfolio theories, including the Markowitz portfolio theory and the Capital Market Theory, the conclusion was reached that the methods used, within these theories to construct diversified portfolios, would be directly applicable to this study. More specifically this decision was made to use the Markowitz Portfolio Theory as the basis for this study in light of the fact that the Capital Market Theory is an extension of the Markowitz Portfolio Theory and as such the findings of the study should not be significantly different if the portfolios were constructed by using the CMT. From this initial study followed the close examination of various concepts related to portfolio management in general. 167 The study investigated more closely, the most important features of the different portfolio theories. This included an in depth look at the definitions and measurement of both risk and return. The section identified standard deviation, as used in the Markowitz portfolio theory, as the relevant measure for risk. In keeping with this it was decided to construct consequent portfolios along the guidelines set out by the Markowitz portfolio theory. The study concentrated on the identification and discussion of various alternative investments/assets. These assets included assets such as furniture, art, investment cars, containers and ceramics. Each asset or asset class was briefly reviewed. The main contribution of this study, apart from identifying various assets, was the identification of those factors which may be regarded as universal value drivers of these assets. Among these factors were authenticity, quality and provenance. Upon completion of the investigation into the various assets it became apparent that even though there were various alternative assets available for inclusion into portfolios, some assets were more prominent than others. The most significant assets as identified by the study included Gold, Wine and Art. The study also provides a framework for the classification of assets into one of four groups, those groups being antiques, collectibles, art and general alternative investments. The identification of the more prominent alternative assets, as mentioned above, led to the investigation of the effects that these assets would have on existing portfolios. It should be noted that these assets were identified based on the availability of price data and information relating to the assets. Even though the main aim of the study was not to investigate the efficiency of the alternative asset markets, as the study progressed it became apparent that a brief discussion of this subject was warranted. The study gave consideration to the various characteristics of good markets as well as to the different forms of the efficient market hypothesis (EMH). Upon conclusion of the initial examination various markets were tested in broad terms, against the characteristics identified. These markets included equity markets, bond markets, property markets and the alternative investments markets. The 168 findings of this section of the study are considered to be significant as it would appear that most alternative markets subscribed to the weak-form of the EMH. This would lead investors to believe that they should be able to derive above average risk-adjusted returns, based on superior information, or access to information regarding the asset. The study indicated that one of the major disadvantages of alternative asset markets were their informational inefficiency. This section was also identified as one that holds promise for further investigation on the subject matter of alternative investments. The findings of this empirical seemed to be important given the goal of the study. During the course of this section of the study, the researcher performed an analysis of those alternative assets which were perceived to be the prominent groups/assets. What is important, and this warrants the study as a whole, is the fact that the inclusion of an alternative asset into an existing portfolio (assumed to be a fully diversified portfolio, given various assumptions) gave rise to a greater or lesser extent, to improved diversification and return. The results of the study reject the hypothesis that these investments do not hold any benefits in terms of further diversification of diversified portfolios. Throughout the study it becomes apparent that alternative investments/hard assets hold untapped potential for improving the risk/return characteristics of existing investment portfolios. The study identified various benefits and constraints associated with investing in these assets. It should be noted that no asset class is without constraint or disadvantage and therefore investors should not exclude the possibility of including an alternative asset into their existing portfolios (taking note of constraints and giving it the necessary consideration). 169 7.1 FURTHER RESEARCH POSSIBILITIES As the study progressed it became apparent that very little research has been done in this particular field, especially from an investment management perspective. However two areas for further research appeared to be most prominent. The first of these areas pertain to the effectiveness of the markets in which these alternative investments are traded. It would seem as if most assets are bought and sold on an auction basis or privately which would lead one to believe that price formulation is highly subjective. The second area that offers the possibility of further research would be to research the possibility of introducing ‘artificial’ liquidity and tradability into these markets. This may be done in much the same way as has been done in the property market, i.e. by unitising larger asset holdings. This type of development should increase the efficiency of the alternative investment markets, but may also alter some of its unique characteristics. 170 BIBLIOGRAPHY • Anonymous. Hard Assets May be a Better Investment. April 2002. Television Broadcast. Available: http://www.goldline.com/KCAL2.htm • Anonymous. 2002. Alternative Investments: Fundamentals. [on-line]. Available: http://www.financial -guide.ch • Anonymous. 2002. Investing in Art: A Guide to What Moves the Art Markets. Available: http://kamprint.com • Anonymous. 2001. Investing in Wine. The Guardian. December 7. • Birdsong C and Drennen NH. 2002. Art and Antiques as Investments. Available: http:// www.ext.colostate.edu. • British Broadcasting Corporation. 2001. Collector’s Guide. Available: http://bbc.co.uk/antiques/collecting_guide/ot.html. • Bodie Z, Kane A and Marcus AJ. 2003. Essentials of Investments. New York: McGraw-Hill. • Bodie Z, Kane A and Marcus AJ. 2002. Investments 5th Edition. Boston: McGraw-Hill Irwin. • Brentwood Wine Company. 2003. Investing in Wine. Available: http://brentwoodwine.com • Cohen JB, Zinbarg ED and Zeikel A. 1987. Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management 5th Edition. Boston: Irwin. • Cole M. 2002. Investment Potential is Music to the Ears. Business Day July 12. • Corgel JB, Ling DC and Smith HC. 2001. Real Estate Perspectives: An Introduction to Real Estate 4th Edition. Bogotá: McGraw-Hill Irwin. • Correia C, Flynn D, Uliana E and Wormald M. 2000. Financial Management 4th Edition. Cape Town: Juta. • D’Ambrosio CA. 1976. Principles of Modern Investments. Toronto: Science Research Associates Inc. • Dobbins R, Witt S and Fielding J. 1996. Portfolio Theory and Investment Management: An Introduction to Modern Portfolio Theory. Great Britain: Blackwell Business. 171 • Duthy R. 1986. The Successful Investor. A guide to Art, Wine, Antiques and other Growth Markets. London: Collins. • Eckstein S. 2003. Bear Market Collectibles: A ready supply online means even limited-edition items are losing value. Article. Atlanta Journal. • Edwards N and Pereira M. 2002. Investing in Art is a Risky Proposition. Available: http://cityguide.news-press.com. • Fazzi R. Jun 2002. Investors Get Down to Earth. Financial Advisor Magazine Online. Available: http://www.financialadvisormagazine.com/articles/jun_2002_investors.h tml • Fischer DE and Jordan RJ. 1983. Security Analysis and Portfolio Management 3rd Edition. London: Prentice-Hall. • Fisher C. 2001. Buying Antiques for Investment. Available: http://artantiques.allinfo-about.com • Fiske J and Freeman L. 2003. Antiques as Investments. Available: http://www.Fiskeandfreeman.com. • Fiske J and Freeman L. 2003. The 2002 Antique Furniture Price Index. Available: http://www.fiskeandfreeman.com • Francis JC. 1986. Investments: Analysis and Management 4th Edition. Hamburg: McGraw-Hill. • Francis JC and Archer SH. 1979. Portfolio Analysis 2nd Edition. New Jersey. Prentice-Hall. • Hogan T and Baierl. 1999. Investing in Global Hard Assets: A Diversification tool for Portfolios. Ibbotson Associates. • Hull JC. 2002. Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets 4th Edition. London: Prentice-Hall. • Laube J. 2003. Collecting vs. Investing. Available: http://www.winespectator.com. • Mason RD, Lind DA and Marchal WG. 1997. Statistical Techniques in Business and Economics 10th Edition. Bangkok: McGraw-Hill. • Mayo H.B. 2000. Investments: An Introduction. Orlando:Harcourt College Publishers. 172 • Mei J and Moses M. 2001. Art as an instrument and the underperformance of masterpieces: Evidence from 1875-2000. Working Paper. Stern School of Business. New York University. • Monks H. 2002. Investors’ best friend. The Observer. October 2002. • North C. 2003. Antique Clocks Survive the Test of Time Available: http://www.collectingchannel.com. • Phillips P. 1998. Collecting Clocks. Available:http://antiques.about.com • Poposki K and Katlarova S. 2002. Introduction to Risk, measuring and calculating portfolio risk, diversification and value addivity and hedging financial risk. Working Paper. University of Sv. Kliment Ohridski. • Radcliffe RC. 1982. Investment Concepts, Analysis and Strategy. Dallas: Scott, Foresman and Company. • Reilly FK and Brown KC. 2003. Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management 7th Edition. Australia: Thomson South-Western. • Rubino. 2003. Art as an Asset Class. Available: http://faculty.fuqua.duke.edu. • SAADA website. 2003. South African Antique Dealers Association. Available: http://saada.co.za • Stevenson R and Jennings E. 1976. Fundamentals of Investments. Boston: West Publishing Company. • Uhlfelder E. 2003. Art and Money: Perfect Together. Available: http://registeredrep.com. • Wilcox JW. 1999. Investing By The Numbers. New Hope: Frank J. Fabozzi Associates. • Woliver R. 2002. Invest in Cars. Available: http://www.bankrate.com. • Woliver R. 2002. 8 Tips for Investing in Cars. Available: http://www.bankrate.com. • Woliver R. 2002. Investing in Art Takes Taste and Business Savvy. Available: http://www.bankrate.com. • Worthington A.C. and Higgs H. 2002. Art as an Investment: Risk,Return and Comovements in Major Painting Markets. Working Paper. School of Economics and Finance. Queensland University of Technology. 173