The Effect of the Official Ballot Referendum Form of Meeting on the Towns and School Districts of New Hampshire Authors: Douglas E. Hall Executive Director New Hampshire Center for Public Policy Studies & Stephen F. Knapp Monadnock Strategic Planning In Association with: Institute for Policy and Social Science Research University of New Hampshire February 2000 TABLE OF CONTENTS Acknowledgments Summary of Findings Major Findings Other Findings Summary of Recommendations Introduction 1. Legislative Background 2. Forms of Local Governance 3. Rationale for the Study 4. Project Data Collection Efforts Jurisdictions Reporting Status in 1999 Propensity to Adopt 1. Size of Population 2. Tax Rate Voter Participation 1. Voter Registration 2. Participation in Balloting 3. Absentee Balloting 4. Participation in Annual Meeting Deliberations 5. Budget Voting Warrant Articles 1. Number of Articles 2. Adoption and Repeal of Official Ballot Voting Local Budgets and Appropriations 1. Aggregate Level of 1998 Appropriations 2. Changes from 1997 to 1998 3. Bond Issue Decisions Discussion of Findings 1. Population is the Issue, Not Taxes 2. The Special Case of School Districts 3. How Big is Too Big for Assembly Democracy? 4. The Quality of Public Participation in Local Government Recommendations 1. New Alternatives and Ideas Needed 2. New Thinking About Voter Communications 3. Voting on Bond Issues 4. Collection of Information on Local Governance Appendix 1: Population and City Charters Appendix 2: Official Ballot Jurisdictions 1997-1999 Bibliography Acknowledgments Many people assisted in the implementation of this project. Sara Browning was consultant to the project in 1997, the first year of data collection. Dan Callaghan, Mark Handley, and Shelly Uscinski assisted as volunteers in the tedious task of extracting useful information from the voluminous materials submitted by town and school district officials that year. Staff of the New Hampshire Municipal Association, New Hampshire School Boards Association, and New Hampshire School Administrators Association assisted by urging their members to complete and return questionnaires to the project. Early advice was provided by Bernie Waugh, legal counsel of the Municipal Association, and Ted Comstock, legal counsel of the School Boards Association, as well as members of the Granite State Taxpayers Association. The Survey Center at the University of New Hampshire made hundreds of telephone calls to local officials during both 1997 and 1998 to urge completion and submission of questionnaires. Much assistance was provided by the NH Department of Revenue Administration in 1998 and 1999 by allowing us access to the official budgetary forms filed by municipalities and school districts as part of the Department’s annual tax rate-setting process. Jan Haman was our assistant who spent many hours reviewing and extracting data from these files. The Town Clerks Association also provided invaluable assistance. Most importantly, we must thank the hundreds of town clerks, school district clerks, and school superintendents who went out of their way to compile and report to us information regarding local government actions in 1997 and 1998. We could not have conducted this study without their willingness to go the extra mile for us. Summary of Findings Definitions: The Traditional open meeting is the system whereby all registered voters in attendance at the annual meeting of the town or school district act as the legislative body. They discuss, potentially amend, and dispose of each warrant article at the meeting. Voters in Official ballot meeting jurisdictions discuss and potentially amend warrant articles at an early deliberative session. The final vote is done by ballot on election day. No-meeting jurisdictions are those in which the voters have ceded their right to participate directly by the establishment of a representative body, usually a city or town council. Major Findings The propensity of a town or school district to adopt the official ballot meeting is more strongly associated with large population than it is with high tax rate. Larger units of local government are much more likely to adopt this method than smaller ones. Participation in the deliberative process of the annual meeting is much higher in traditional meeting towns and school districts when compared to official ballot jurisdictions. Participation in each type of jurisdiction is higher in those jurisdictions with smaller populations. Approximately three times as many registered voters vote on the town’s budget and special appropriations in official ballot towns compared to traditional open meeting towns. For school districts, the ratio is even greater: nearly five times as many voters voting on the budget in official ballot districts compared to traditional districts. Official ballot jurisdictions approve higher spending per capita than do traditional jurisdictions. From 1997 to 1998 official ballot towns and districts showed slightly greater rates of increase in their voted appropriations than did open meeting jurisdictions. Official ballot jurisdictions are much less likely to pass bond articles than traditional open meeting towns and districts. Other Findings School districts are more likely to adopt official ballot meeting than municipalities. Much of this difference is related to the large, multi-town cooperative school districts for which there are no municipal counterparts. There is no significant difference in voter registration between official ballot and traditional municipalities and school districts. There is no appreciable difference in the percentage of registered voters who cast ballots in traditional and official ballot municipalities. About 5% more registered voters cast ballots in official ballot school districts than traditional school districts. The difference in absentee balloting is negligible. The percentage of voters voting absentee is very small for both types of governance. Official ballot towns and school districts have more articles on the warrant than traditional open meeting towns and districts. Also, the larger the jurisdiction, the more articles on the warrant. Once adopted, it appears unlikely that a jurisdiction will return to the traditional open meeting form of governance. Official ballot jurisdictions are marginally more likely to decrease their appropriations from those originally presented by the executive body than are traditional jurisdictions. Summary of Recommendations The NH Municipal Association, NH School Boards Association, and the State should cooperate in considering and creating new alternatives for governance among towns and school districts that outgrow the ability to maintain traditional open meetings. Official ballot jurisdictions require new methods to inform and involve voters prior to the time they cast their ballots. The NH Department of Revenue Administration should prepare a report on local bond issue voting on 1999 and 2000 so the legislature can consider whether further changes in law regarding the required super-majority (RSA 33:8) may be necessary. The NH Department of Revenue Administration should annually compile data submitted by local jurisdictions into a single database on local budgets and citizen participation in local governance. The legislature should provide the necessary funds for this purpose, estimated at no more than $10,000. Introduction 1. Legislative Background In 1995 the New Hampshire legislature passed Senate Bill 2 (SB2) and the governor signed it into law. This legislation created RSA 40:13, the official ballot law. Its provisions are still commonly known as SB2, its original bill number, and we will use both names interchangeably in this report. This law provides a mechanism for voters to replace the traditional open town and school district meetings with an official ballot process. If voters in a town or school district adopt SB2, subsequent years’ budgets will be discussed and amended in the open meeting but are only voted upon by ballot on the town election day. In fact, all warrant articles, whether involving money or not, are determined by this method. This proposal was vigorously debated in the legislature before passage in 1995 and both proponents and opponents offered theoretical arguments to bolster their case. Proponents argued that more people would vote on the budget by ballot than in open meeting and hoped that this would rein in growth of local budgets and escalating property tax rates. Opponents argued that attendance at town and school district meetings would decline; that the process itself would be onerous; that so-called "default" budgets which would be implemented if the proposed budget failed would harm local government; that in some communities absentee "snowbird" ballots would decide the local budget. The same arguments have since been heard in communities around the state as citizens have debated whether to adopt the provisions of SB2 in their town or school district. 2. Forms of Local Governance New Hampshire state law provides for a variety of means of governance for its towns and school districts. For the purposes of this study, the critical question is the means by which the voters get to participate in appropriating funds and setting budgets: through a traditional meeting open to all voters, by official ballot on election day, or not at all. Traditional open meeting is the system whereby all registered voters in attendance at the annual meeting of the town or school district act as the legislative body. The Board of Selectmen in towns and the School Board in school districts prepare the warrant that contains the items (articles) to be acted upon by the legislative body. Generally, the body of voters attending may amend an article before they vote it up or down. Any voter who does not attend the meeting has no role in the process. Official ballot meeting jurisdictions are the ones that have adopted the provisions of RSA 40:13. In these, the articles contained on the warrant are voted up or down in the voting booth on election day. Some time before the voting a deliberative session is held in which the Board of Selectmen or School Board present the articles for discussion and at which those voters in attendance may make amendments by majority vote as they see fit. No-meeting jurisdictions are those in which the voters have ceded their right to participate directly in establishment of budgets to a representative body, usually a city or town council. These have been established as part of the adoption of a city or town charter. In such cases the elected body acts as both the executive and legislative branches. State law allows for a few hybrid forms. These have been assigned to one of the above categories based on the role of the voters in establishing budgets and voting appropriations. Voters in jurisdictions that are dissatisfied with the traditional open meeting form of governance have two options under state law. They may adopt the official ballot referendum form of governance under RSA 40:13, or they may adopt a charter under RSA 49–D3 and RSA 49–B (also known as House Bill 141 or HB141). To substitute the SB2 form of governance requires that a warrant article be placed on the ballot (by petition or by the governing board) and that 60% of the "yea" and "nay" votes on the article be "yea" votes. A similar 60% super-majority is also required to repeal governance under SB2 once it has been established. 3. Rationale for the Study The New Hampshire Center for Public Policy Studies was formed in late 1996. Local governments that had adopted the new form of governance earlier that year were preparing for their first year of official ballot implementation in February and March of 1997. It was apparent that there was no planned central collection of data to determine what the effect of the new procedures would be. Because this change in local governance was one of the most significant in recent history, the Center’s Board of Directors decided to initiate this project. The goal was to test the various hypotheses that had been put forward by both proponents and opponents of the measure. Information about how the process unfolded in each community was not uniformly reported to any state agency. Indeed, as we carried out this project in both 1997 and 1998 we discovered that lists prepared by both state government agencies and associations of local governments that purported to identify those official ballot jurisdictions contained errors. No central authority had a completely accurate list of the governance status of all local jurisdictions, let alone data on any effect that changes in governance might have brought about. Local newspapers did cover the debates about adoption of official ballot voting and the results of implementation in districts and towns in their readership areas. However, this information was not collected uniformly nor was it reported centrally. Had the Center not undertaken this project, important information about the first two years of implementation would have been lost forever. 4. Project Data Collection Efforts There are 410 units of local government encompassed by this study. Among the 234 towns and cities, 14 are of the "no-meeting" type. Among the 176 school districts, 9 are of the "no-meeting" type. Data were solicited from the remaining 387 jurisdictions. In setting up this project the Center asked the NH Municipal Association, NH School Boards Association, Granite State Taxpayers Association and NH Department of Revenue Administration to suggest data elements to be collected and preserved in the Center’s database. Beginning at the conclusion of town and school district meetings in 1997 the Center began a two-year data collection effort. In 1997, survey forms were sent from the New Hampshire Municipal Association to town clerks and from the New Hampshire School Boards Association to school district clerks. The UNH Survey Center made follow-up telephone contacts with those districts and towns that did not respond initially. Ultimately 154 towns and 93 school districts provided copies of their annual reports, minutes of their 1997 annual meetings, and other data. In 1998, thanks to the cooperation of the NH Department of Revenue Administration (DRA), we were able to greatly reduce the amount of data directly requested from the towns and school districts. Survey forms were sent by the NH Municipal Association to town clerks and by the NH School Administrators Association to the superintendents of schools. The UNH Survey Center again made telephone calls to non-respondents. As a result, the 1998 data are more complete than for 1997. In 1998, 189 towns and 130 school districts provided information. We created a database that included the collected information on the voter participation, warrant articles, and appropriation amounts. To these we added line item revenue and appropriation figures for 1996, 1997, and 1998 provided on computer files by DRA. We used 1996 voter registration figures contained in the Secretary of State’s Red Book to fill in those towns that had not provided more recent data. And we used the Office of State Planning’s 1995 estimated population of each jurisdiction. Jurisdictions Reporting Data collection was slightly more successful for the municipalities than the school districts. As shown in Table 1, 85% of traditional towns and 92% of official ballot towns submitted data in 1998. These reporting towns covered 88% of the population operating under a traditional open meeting and 95% of the population operating under the official ballot process that year. Table 1 Municipalities Reporting in 1998 By Count of Municipalities All Reporting Traditional By Covered Population Percent All Reporting Percent 181 153 85% 438,840 386,299 88% Official Ballot 39 36 92% 282,644 269,452 95% No-meeting 14 - - 426,516 - - 234 189 - 1,148,000 655,751 - TOTAL School Districts Reporting in 1998 By Count of Districts All Reporting Traditional Official Ballot No-meeting TOTAL By Covered Population Percent All Reporting Percent 115 85 74% 351,733 257,242 73% 52 45 87% 577,209 527,202 91% 9 - - 334,366 - - 176 130 - 1,263,308 784,444 - Of the school districts operating under the traditional open meeting format, 74% submitted data (representing 73% of the population covered by that form of governance. 92% of the school districts operating under the official ballot process submitted data (representing 91% of that population). Reporting in 1997 averaged about 10-15% lower than in 1998 and the data elements reported were far less complete. While we were unable to obtain 100% reporting, we are satisfied that the achieved reporting rates (very high given the voluntary nature of the project) ensure that our findings and conclusions are warranted. We do not believe they would materially differ if we had been able to obtain universal reporting. Status in 1999 Figure 1M displays the percentage of the state’s population that was covered by each of the different forms of municipal governance. Figure 1S displays the analogous percentages for school districts. While the news media will again devote considerable attention to the "folksy" deliberations of traditional town and school district meetings, it is now true that only about 1/3 of the state’s population live in communities where the municipal government operates under such a system and only about 1/4 live in school districts so governed. Figure 1M Figure 1S In 1997 31 towns used the official ballot meeting for the first time (28 were SB2 and 3 were HB141). 8 more towns began in 1998 and 6 more adopted it for 1999. In 1997 34 school districts operated under SB2. An additional 17 school districts began in 1998 (one under HB141) and 3 more have adopted it for 1999. The geographic distributions of those municipalities and school districts that have adopted the official ballot meeting process are displayed in Map 1M and Map 1S Map 1M Map 1S Propensity to Adopt What factors might lead voters to determine that their local form of governance should be changed? The New Hampshire economy fell into recession in the late 1980s and a real estate "bubble" burst with some property values falling 30% and more. At the same time local budgets continued to grow. The result was a period in which full value tax rates escalated rapidly. Tax revolts broke out, taking different forms in different communities. All this was a backdrop to the passage of SB2 by the legislature and its consideration by voters at the local level. History and political philosophy confirm that maintaining a pure democracy is difficult as the population of the jurisdiction increases. The ancient Greek city-states’ had a practice of "hiving off" self-governing colonies when population grew too large. In nineteenth century New Hampshire, a representative form of elected city councils replaced the pure democracy of open meetings when town populations grew large (see Appendix 1). The 1970-1990 period saw 77 towns in New Hampshire more than double in population. 42 small towns grew by over 2,000, 25 of which had started under 3,500 population in 1970 and had grown to over 5,500 by 1990. This too was a backdrop to the new possibility of official ballot voting. We investigated to what extent the propensity to adopt official ballot voting is related to a jurisdiction’s population and its tax rate. 1. Size of Population There are 220 towns that are eligible to adopt the official ballot form of local governance (all except the 14 no-meeting communities). We ordered them from lowest and highest on the basis of their 1995 population and then created five equal groups of 44 towns. We similarly divided the 167 eligible school districts into three groups based on their population. Table 2 displays information about each of these groups. Table 2 Municipality Population Groups Group Count of Towns Population Range of Group Total Population Average Population Percent of Total Population Tiny 44 25-800 21,169 481 2.9% Very Small 44 801-1,540 49,523 1,126 6.9% Small 44 1,541-2,935 90,734 2,062 12.6% Medium 44 2,936-4,800 161,919 3,680 22.4% Large 44 TOTAL 4,801-27,000 220 398,139 9,049 721,484 55.2% 100.0% School District Population Groups Group Count of Districts Population Range of Group Total Population Average Population Percent of Total Population Small 56 25-1,900 51,250 915 5.5% Medium 56 1,901-6,100 195,442 3,490 21.0% Large 55 6,101-32,000 682,250 12,405 73.4% TOTAL 167 928,942 100.0% We then investigated the propensity of jurisdictions in each group to adopt official ballot voting. Figures 2M and 2S display the results. Figure 2M Figure 2S In both school districts and towns, the larger population jurisdictions are much more likely to adopt official ballot voting than the smaller ones. 2. Tax Rate We ordered the towns from lowest and highest on the basis of their 1996 full value tax rates and again created five equal groups of 44 towns. Table 3 displays the results. Table3 Municipality Tax Rate Groups Group Count of 1996 Full Value Towns Tax Rate Range of Group Total Population Average Population Percent of Total Population Lowest 44 $5.00-$20.15 77,788 1,768 10.8% Next Lowest 44 $20.16-$24.38 150,863 3,429 20.9% Middle 44 $24.39-$28.24 131,201 2,982 18.2% Next Highest 44 $28.25-$32.53 185,096 4,207 25.7% Highest 44 $32.54-$52.88 176,536 4,012 24.5% TOTAL 220 721,484 100.0% Figure 3 displays the count of official ballot municipalities in each of the tax rate groups for each of the three years 1997, 1998, and 1999. It is similar in design to figure 2M. The chart shows that a slightly higher proportion of towns in the highest tax rate group have adopted official ballot meeting governance than the lower tax rate communities. When Figures 2M and 3 are compared, it is clear that the propensity to adopt official ballot meeting governance is more strongly associated with large population than it is with high tax rate. Figure 3 There is also a moderate relationship between community population and tax rate. On average, more populous municipalities have higher tax rates than less populated ones. Figure 4 is a scatter plot that displays each town at the point where its population and tax rate intersect. (The x-axis is a logarithmic scale in order to compress the great differences in populations. Even then, two towns are off the plot because they have populations below 100.) Those towns that have adopted SB2 (or HB141) are displayed in green. It is easy to see that most of these towns tend to fall on the right side of the graph (higher population) rather than at the top half of the graph (higher tax rate). Figure 4 The "no-meeting" municipalities are also displayed on the graph (with the exception of Manchester which is slightly off the graph to the right). This figure clearly shows that SB2 is, for the most part, an alternative form of governance being adopted by communities that are too large for a pure democracy, yet unwilling or unable to convert to a representative form of government such as a town or city council. Voter Participation Proponents and opponents of SB2 have theorized what happens to voter participation when a community adopts the official ballot meeting form of governance. We investigated a number of questions regarding any differences in voter participation between those municipalities and school districts operating under the traditional open meeting and the official ballot meeting. 1. Voter Registration The first step in voter participation is registration. Only registered voters may vote at open town meetings or by official ballot. Table 4 displays the number of registered voters in municipalities and school districts based on their form of governance in 1998. Table 4 Voter Registration in Municipalities Population Registered Voters % of Population Registered Official Ballot 282,644 192,228 68.0% Traditional 438,840 296,961 67.7% Total 721,484 489,189 67.8% Voter Registration in School Districts Population Registered Voters % of Population Registered Official Ballot 577,209 390,834 67.7% Traditional 351,733 240,254 68.3% Total 928,942 631,088 67.9% The age structure and citizenship status of a community’s population can affect how many of its residents are eligible to be voters. So too can transiency in a community if voter lists are not regularly purged and updated. Even with these possible limitations, it is clear that there is no significant difference in voter registration between official ballot and traditional municipalities and school districts. We did investigate variations in registration by population group against governance type but found no consistent or meaningful differences. Overall both official ballot and traditional meeting towns and school districts have 68% of their population registered. 2. Participation in Balloting Local elections are held by towns and school districts every March. No matter which form of governance in a jurisdiction, balloting occurs for positions such as selectman, school board member, road agent, auditor, town clerk, school district clerk, etc. In official ballot meeting jurisdictions, however, the proposed budget, special appropriation items, and bond issues will also appear on the ballot. We were able to obtain the count of ballots cast in 1998 local elections for 190 towns (out of 220) and 152 school districts (out of 167). We then compared the number of ballots to the number of registered voters in both traditional and official ballot meeting jurisdictions. The results are displayed in Table 5. There is no meaningful difference in voter turnout in the two types of towns. In school district, however, about 5% more voters cast ballots in the official ballot meeting districts than in the traditional open meeting districts. We had been less successful in obtaining the balloting data in 1997, having received the information from only 75 towns and 53 school districts. Nevertheless, the 1997 data confirm the 1998 results. Both 1997 and 1998 results are displayed in Figure 5. Table 5 1998 Balloting in Municipalities Towns Registered Voters Ballots Cast % of Registered Voters Casting Ballots 36 182,979 52,482 28.7% Traditional 154 261,103 76,596 29.3% Total 190 444,082 129,078 29.1% Official Ballot 1998 Balloting in School Districts Districts Registered Voters Ballots Cast % of Registered Voters Casting Ballots 50 380,814 110,690 29.1% Traditional 102 205,729 49,226 23.9% Total 152 586,543 159,916 27.3% Official Ballot Figure 5 There is no appreciable difference in the percentage of registered voters who cast ballots in traditional and official ballot municipalities. About 5% more registered voters cast ballots in official ballot school districts than traditional school districts. 3. Absentee Balloting We also investigated the likelihood that absentee voters would seek to vote in their local elections. Some had postulated that residents who were usually out of state during March meeting season (those with winter homes in sunnier climes) would chose to vote on the local budgets by absentee ballot if they were given that option. Table 6 1998 Absentee Balloting in Municipalities Official Ballot Towns Registered Voters 36 182,979 Ballots Absentee Cast Ballots Cast 52,482 2,400 % of Registered Voters Casting Absentee Ballots 1.3% Traditional 152 257,156 75,320 3,453 1.3% Total 188 440,135 127,802 5,853 1.3% 1998 Absentee Balloting in School Districts Districts Registered Voters 46 347,585 100,227 4,628 1.3% Traditional 100 203,104 48,377 1,850 0.9% Total 146 550,689 148,604 6,478 1.2% Official Ballot Ballots Absentee Cast Ballots Cast % of Registered Voters Casting Absentee Ballots Overall, 1.3% of registered voters cast absentee ballots. There was a slightly lower rate of absentee voting in traditional open meeting school districts. The shortfall, however, amounts to only 854 votes over 100 towns. The difference in absentee balloting is negligible. The percentage of voters voting absentee is very small for both types of governance. These are averages; we did review the figures by district and town. The highest absentee voter participation tends to be in communities that have larger percentages of vacation homes. Freedom School District, for example, had 8.3% of its registered voters cast absentee ballots. Towns such as Rye, Tuftonboro, Stoddard, and Hebron all had more than 5% of their registered voters cast absentee ballots. The higher rates of absentee voting in second-home communities appear to occur about the same under both traditional and official ballot meeting types of governance. 4. Participation in Annual Meeting Deliberations Both SB2 and traditional jurisdictions hold annual meetings of voters in the late winter. The difference is that in the traditional open meetings each warrant article is debated, potentially amended, and ultimately voted upon by those in attendance. In jurisdictions where the official ballot meeting form of governance has been adopted, the meeting (now commonly called the deliberative session), can discuss and amend warrant articles, but no final vote takes place. Instead, the articles (as amended if any amendments are passed) are then placed on the ballot for voting Table 7 1998 Annual Meeting Attendance in Municipalities Towns Registered Voters Attending Meeting % of Registered Voters Attending Official Ballot Traditional 33 175,569 4,116 2.3% 144 243,261 22,494 9.2% 1998 Annual Meeting Attendance in School Districts Districts Registered Voters Attending Meeting % of Registered Voters Attending Official Ballot 44 355,246 6,939 2.0% Traditional 79 166,180 10,077 6.1% We obtained attendance information from most town and school district clerks. There is no requirement that the count of voters be part of the minutes they take and many votes are taken by voice so there may be no actual count of votes. In many cases the attendance figures were taken from the voter checklists used at the meetings. In a few less formal communities, the clerks provided us their best estimate of the attendance. Table 7 displays the results. Attendance at the annual meetings in those jurisdictions that have adopted SB2 is about 1/4 to 1/3 that which occurs in traditional jurisdictions. Overall, 9.2% of the voters participated in traditional open town meetings, but only 2.3% participated in the deliberative meetings in official ballot towns. There is generally lower turnout for school district meetings, with 6.1% participating in traditional jurisdictions compared to 2.0% in official ballot districts. We had far less complete reporting for 1997 but the results from those towns and districts that did report confirmed the 1998 data to a large degree. Both years’ data are plotted in Figure 6. Figure 6 We recognize that historically meeting attendance is proportionally lower in larger communities. Thus, it is reasonable to question whether the lower participation in official ballot jurisdictions might simply be the result of their tending to be larger in population. One way to test this theory would be to compare the attendance of SB2 jurisdictions with their own history of attendance prior to voting to adopt SB2. The data for 1996 would be useful. However, there is no requirement that meeting attendance information be submitted to any state agency nor is there any requirement that such information be recorded and maintained locally as a part of the public record. For the most part, 1996 information is lost to history. We did review the similar information we had collected from jurisdictions that had operated under traditional open meeting governance in 1997 but changed to SB2 or HB 141 in 1998. Of those 17 school districts and 8 towns, we had complete data on only 9. This is too small a subset from which to draw any conclusions. Fortunately, there is another way to investigate this question. We can look at meeting attendance in each of our population size groups. Figures 7M and 7S display the results. Because of the small number of smaller jurisdictions that have adopted official ballot meetings and reported to us, some of the data should be used with caution. After accounting for size, however, it is clear that voter participation in annual meetings is approximately twice as great in towns and districts with traditional meetings as in those that have adopted SB2 and HB141. Participation in the deliberative process of the annual meeting is much higher in traditional meeting towns and school districts when compared to official ballot jurisdictions. Participation in each type of jurisdiction is higher in those jurisdictions with smaller populations. Figure 7M Figure 7S 5. Budget Voting We have compared participation in the processes of registration, balloting, absentee balloting, and annual meeting. Voting on a jurisdiction’s budget, however, takes place at a different time in traditional and official ballot communities. In official ballot communities, a voter votes on the budget as part of the balloting process while in traditional open meeting communities, the budget vote is part of the annual meeting. We compare the percentage of voters who voted on the budget in 1998 by combining some of the data provided above. Table 8 1998 Budget Voting in Municipalities Official Ballot Traditional Towns Registered Voters Voting on Budget % Voting on Budget 36 182,979 52,482 28.7% 144 244,152 22,494 9.2% Ratio 3.1 1998 Budget Voting in School Districts Districts Registered Voters Voting on Budget % Voting on Budget Official Ballot 50 380,814 110,690 29.1% Traditional 79 166,180 10,077 6.1% Ratio 4.8 Approximately three times as many registered voters vote on the town’s budget and special appropriations in official ballot towns compared to traditional meeting towns. For school districts, the ratio is even greater: nearly five times as many voters voting on the budget in official ballot districts compared to traditional districts. The reason the ratio is higher for districts than towns is the relatively lower turnout for traditional school district meetings in comparison to town meetings. The balloting turnout, as expected, is almost equal, 29%, for both towns and districts that have adopted official ballot meeting governance. Warrant Articles 1. Number of Articles In 1998 there were 4,720 articles on the warrants of the 207 towns from which we were able to obtain this information. The average warrant, therefore, had 23 articles. Among official ballot meeting communities the average was 27, while among traditional meeting towns it was 22. Eleven towns had fewer than 10 articles while seventeen towns had 40 or more articles. There were 1,356 articles on the warrants of the 150 school districts from which we were able to obtain this information. The average warrant, therefore, had 9 articles. Among official ballot meeting districts the average was 11, while among traditional meeting districts it was 8. Twelve districts had fewer than 5 articles while five districts had 20 or more articles. Higher population towns and districts had more warrant articles than those with lower population. Among the high population school districts, those utilizing the official ballot meeting had an average of 32 articles while those using the traditional meeting had an average of 22 articles. Official ballot towns and school districts have more articles on the warrant than traditional open meeting towns and districts. Also, the larger the jurisdiction, the more articles on the warrant. Based on our review of the minutes of the towns and districts, we speculate that some official ballot jurisdictions include contingency articles in case a particular article should fail. For example, if the article to totally renovate the town hall fails, then a second article might be included to do emergency repairs. While these types of situations can be worked out in traditional town meetings under a single article by the amendment process, there is no provision for amendment at the time of the final ballot vote in official ballot situations. 2. Adoption and Repeal of Official Ballot Voting We received reports of votes on the adoption of SB2 from thirteen towns and eleven school district on their 1998 ballots. The ballot question achieved the necessary 60% of votes cast in six towns and in three school districts. These are shaded in Table 9. Table 9 1998 Votes to Adopt SB2 in Municipalities In Favor Opposed Percent in Favor 2,240 740 75% Carroll Not available Not available Passed Epping 605 487 55% Henniker 392 409 49% 28 92 23% Not available Not available Passed 48 164 23% Not available Not available Passed 1,635 933 64% 365 295 55% Not available Not available Passed Tamworth 185 153 55% Warren 124 105 54% Amherst Hill Litchfield Milan New Ipswich Pelham Plymouth Rye 1998 Votes to Adopt SB2 in School Districts In Favor Opposed Percent in Favor Auburn 225 280 45% Chesterfield 231 243 49% Gilford 460 458 50% Harrisville 87 144 38% Hinsdale 92 150 38% Litchfield Not available Not available Passed Madison 211 189 53% Marlborough 227 262 46% Rollinsford 244 180 58% Rye 888 435 67% Not available Not available Passed White Mtn. We also received reports on votes to rescind SB2 from four towns and five school district on their 1998 ballots. None of these ballot questions achieved the necessary 60% of votes. Table 10 1998 Votes to Rescind SB2 in Municipalities In Favor Opposed Percent in Favor Barrington 457 598 43% Bennington 100 291 26% Weare 335 1,289 21% Winchester 249 410 38% 1998 Votes to Rescind SB2 in School Districts In Favor Opposed Percent in Favor Allenstown Not available Not available Failed Barrington 451 604 43% Claremont 456 1,352 25% Weare 323 1,332 20% Wilton-L’boro 317 367 46% It is clearly easier to achieve the necessary 60% vote to adopt the official ballot voting than it is to achieve the same 60% to repeal the measure. While we have a history of adoption votes of only three years, rescission has an even briefer history. Nevertheless, based on this experience it appears that future years will see adoption of SB2 or HB141 by more towns and school districts, especially among those with larger populations. Once adopted, it appears unlikely that a jurisdiction will return to the traditional open meeting form of governance. Local Budgets and Appropriations 1. Aggregate Level of 1998 Appropriations We obtained data from 220 towns and 167 school districts on their 1998 proposed and voted appropriations. From the total amounts we subtracted those appropriations for which funds were to be raised by bond issues in order to separate the operating appropriations from the large capital appropriations. In each municipality and school district the governing body prepares a warrant with proposals for appropriations that are to be considered by the townspeople. In an official ballot jurisdiction, this proposed budget may be amended during the deliberative session and is voted on by ballot; operating budgets that do not win approval are automatically replaced by a "default budget". In traditional jurisdictions, there is no "default budget" and the amending and voting processes both take place at the open meeting and continue until some budget is passed. The initially proposed operating appropriations for the 220 municipalities totaled $563,993,845. The proposed operating appropriations for the 167 school districts totaled $1,156,759,312. At the end of their respective deliberative and voting processes, the total approved by the voters was $556,332,833 for the municipalities and $1,147,752,029 for the school districts. Of the total local public expenditure approved by the voters, 2/3 was for schools and 1/3 for municipal governments. Higher appropriations per capita were proposed and approved in official ballot municipalities than in traditional ones, while the difference among school districts was statistically negligible. This is shown in Table 11. The municipal difference is almost certainly associated with the greater population base of the official ballot communities: larger communities tend to have water, sewer, library, police, economic development, and recreation budgets that may not even exist in the smaller towns. Public school programs tend, however, to be very similar from district to district because of law and tradition. Table 11 1998 Operating Appropriations in Municipalities Official Ballot Traditional Total Count of Towns 39 181 220 1995 Population 282,644 438,840 721,484 Proposed Amount $246,400,113 $317,593,732 $563,993,845 Voted Amount $238,886,764 $317,446,069 $556,332,833 Proposed/Capita $871.77 $723.71 $781.71 Voted/Capita $845.19 $723.38 $771.10 Change/Capita $(26.58) $(0.34) $(10.62) -3.0% +0.0% -1.4% % Changed from Proposed 1998 Operating Appropriations in School Districts Count of Districts 1995 Population 52 115 167 577,209 351,733 928,942 Proposed Amount $720,071,844 $436,687,468 $1,156,759,312 Voted Amount $713,553,819 $434,198,210 $1,147,752,029 Proposed/Capita $1,247.51 $1,241.53 $1,245,24 Voted/Capita $1,236.21 $1,234.45 $1,235.55 $(11.29) $(7.08) $(9.70) -0.9% -0.6% -0.8% Change/Capita % Changed from Proposed In aggregate, voters in traditional towns approved budgets almost identical to those proposed by their governing bodies. Voters in official ballot towns had a slightly greater propensity to reduce their proposed budgets, reducing them by 3% on average. The difference among school districts, however, was negligible, with reductions in both official ballot and traditional districts under 1%. Figure 8 2. Changes from 1997 to 1998 Table 12 contains the 1997 and 1998 voted appropriations for these 220 municipalities. Voter approved operating appropriations in the towns in 1998 were 7.2% higher than the year before while the increase in the school districts was somewhat less, 6.1%. Overall, voters in official ballot jurisdictions approved 1998 budgets that showed slightly greater rates of increase over 1997 than did voters in traditional jurisdictions. The 39 municipalities that operated under SB2 or HB141 in 1998 had a 10.1% increase in their aggregate voted operating appropriations over 1997. This was an increase of $77.44 per capita, double that of the 181 traditional towns. While the one year increase among school districts was more uniform, the official ballot districts did increase their spending on a percentage and per capita basis slightly more than the traditional districts. Table 12 1997-1998 Operating Appropriations in Municipalities Official Ballot Traditional Total Count of Towns 39 181 220 1995 Population 282,644 438,840 721,484 1997 Voted $216,999,723 $301,962,244 $518,961,967 1998 Voted $238,886,764 $317,446,069 $556,332,833 $21,887,041 $15,483,825 $37,370,866 Increase/Capita $77.44 $35.28 $51.80 % Increase 10.1% 5.1% 7.2% Increase 1997-1998 Operating Appropriations in School Districts Count of Districts 1995 Population 52 115 167 577,209 351,733 928,942 1997 Voted $671,357,953 $410,740,259 $1,082,098,212 1998 Voted $713,553,819 $434,198,210 $1,147,752,029 Increase Increase/Capita % Increase $42,195,866 $23,457,951 $65,653,817 $73.10 $66.69 $70.68 6.3% 5.7% 6.1% Figure 9 This is clearly the most surprising finding of this study. Many observers assumed that the official ballot communities would have shown a propensity to increase their appropriations at a much lower rate than the traditional communities. Contrary to those assumptions, at least between 1997 and 1998, traditional towns both spent less and increased their spending less rapidly than official ballot towns. Among school districts, the differences in spending levels per capita and the increase in those spending levels were insignificant. 3. Bond Issue Decisions We also investigated what happened to bond issues proposed in 1998 in the municipalities and school districts. Almost exclusively, bond issues are proposed for major capital improvements: land acquisition, facility construction and renovation, major equipment purchases. To pass, bond issues were required to obtain a 2/3 super-majority of the voters in both traditional and official ballot jurisdictions. This requirement makes passage of bond issues more difficult than passage of operating budgets. It is not, surprising, therefore, that voters in both types of jurisdictions voted bonded appropriations considerably below those proposed on the original warrants. Table 13 1998 Bonded Appropriations in Municipalities Official Ballot Traditional Total Count of Towns 39 181 220 1995 Population 282,644 438,840 721,484 Proposed Amount $24,730,164 $34,320,816 $59,050,980 Voted Amount $12,591,164 $28,406,773 $40,997,937 Proposed/Capita $87.50 $78.21 $81.85 Voted/Capita $44.50 $64.73 $56.82 $(42.95) $(13.48) $(25.02) 50.9% 82.8% 69.4% Change/Capita % Approved 1998 Bonded Appropriations in School Districts Count of Districts 1995 Population Proposed Amount Voted Amount Proposed/Capita Voted/Capita Change/Capita % Approved 52 115 167 577,209 351,733 928,942 $135,821,381 $48,736,801 $184,558,182 $11,115,681 $10,193,743 $21,309,424 $235.31 $138.56 $198.68 $19.26 $28.98 $22.94 $(216.05) $(109.58) $(175.74) 8.2% 20.9% 11.5% As shown in Table 13, proposals in the towns for new bonding were not dissimilar, averaging $87.50 per capita in official ballot communities and $78.21 per capita in traditional communities. Voters in official ballot jurisdictions were very much less likely to approve bonds to fund capital projects than were voters in traditional jurisdictions. About half of the dollar amount was approved by voters in the official ballot towns, while more than 80% of the proposed amount was approved in traditional towns. School districts were much less likely to see their proposed bond issues approved than municipalities. Proposals in official ballot districts totaled almost $100/capita more than in the traditional districts. While 20% of the proposed amount was approved in traditional school districts, less 10% was approved in official ballot districts. Figure 10 The above analysis is weighted based on the dollar value of proposed and voted bond issues. The disposition of a large bond issue contributes more to the result than does the disposition of a smaller one. We also counted the number of jurisdictions in which at least one bond issue was placed on the warrant and the number that approved one (or more) issues. Table 14 and Figure 11 present the results of this analysis of the propensity of a town or school district to approve at least one bond issue. Table 14 1998 Bond Approval by Municipalities Official Traditional Ballot Total 1 or more bond issues on warrant 15 49 64 1 or more bond issues approved 6 33 39 No bond issues approved 9 16 25 40% 67% 61% % approving at least 1 bond issue 1998 Bond Approval by School Districts 1 or more bond issues on warrant 19 16 35 1 or more bond issues approved 4 7 11 15 11 26 21% 44% 31% No bond issues approved % approving at least 1 bond issue Figure 11 The probability that at least one proposed bond issue will be approved is about 25% higher in traditional towns and school districts than in official ballot jurisdictions. In addition, towns are about 20% more likely to approve at least one proposed bond issue than are school districts and this difference is consistent for both types of governance. Discussion of Findings 1. Population is the Issue, Not Taxes Since 1995, discussion of the adoption of the official ballot in towns and school districts has been viewed as a discussion about controlling local spending and, thus, the level of local taxes. The involvement of local taxpayers associations among the primary proponents of changing to an official ballot has caused much of this perception. Our findings, however, challenge the notion that official ballot voting is really about spending and taxation. The propensity to adopt official ballot voting is strong in larger towns and school districts, not necessarily in those with higher taxes. And, once adopted, there are minimal differences in operating budget decisions. The real issue appears to be the inability of traditional open town and school district meetings to function to the satisfaction of local residents in larger jurisdictions. Budgets and taxes are simply the content of local debate that must be resolved, whatever form of local government exists. Since the mid-1960s, New Hampshire has experienced rapid population growth. This growth has been both the result and the cause of economic growth. It has, therefore, been touted as a benefit. Local communities and the State itself have developed mechanisms to encourage further population growth. Almost entirely overlooked has been the fact that the traditional form of pure democracy represented by our town and school district meetings can only work with relatively small populations. The ancient Greeks believed in an upper limit of about 5,000 and hived off colonies when their populations grew too large. New Hampshire's own thirteen cities replaced the open meeting with representative city councils when their populations averaged 8,200. Yet today we have towns with a population of 20,000 or more trying to maintain a form of government that is ideal for no more than a few hundred. Until the movement to introduce official ballot voting began, there was little systematic thinking or planning for the changes in local governance that increased populations would bring to New Hampshire communities. Few alternatives were being designed or advocated. No warnings about the downside of larger populations on local direct democracy were being issued. Unfortunately, by being seen as simply as a taxing and spending issue, the introduction of official ballot voting has not yet sparked the discussion we need about the future of local government as town and school district jurisdictions continue to grow. 2. The Special Case of School Districts Since the late 1940's, the State has encouraged the creation of larger regional school districts, especially in regard to high schools. Partly, this was based on research showing that students in larger schools tended to perform better and partly it was done on the basis of cost efficiencies that might result from larger school units. Even today, the state still rewards larger cooperative districts with greater state building aid than it does comparable small, single town districts. Consolidation among municipal governments has not been similarly encouraged. This policy has resulted in multi-town cooperative districts and "Authorized Regional Enrollment Agreements" among other structures. By creating jurisdictions with larger populations, it has had the unanticipated side effect of lifting some cooperative school districts above the 6,000 population threshold where it becomes more difficult to operate traditional open meetings with reasonably high voter participation. This, we believe, is the most important reason why official ballot voting has been acceptable to a larger percentage of school district voters than municipal voters. 3. How Big is Too Big for Assembly Democracy? This is the question that the citizens and news media of New Hampshire have not addressed in recent years. Perhaps nostalgia and self-promotion have conspired to pretend that all of New Hampshire can continue its rural 19th century traditions. Whatever the cause, we now need a realistic appraisal. History can provide some guidance. The ancient Greeks suggested a very practical limit. The assembly had to be small enough for each speaker to be heard by all participants and, especially, for the herald (our moderator) to be able to run the meeting without "the lungs of a Stentor". Only in the twentieth century did microphones and amplifiers allow us to overcome this limit. A second limit is the capacity of available meeting facilities. Small town halls can only accommodate a few hundred. While school gyms or lunch rooms can often accommodate more, most jurisdictions would be very hard pressed to find a single meeting place where 25% of the local voters could gather comfortably and without violating fire regulations. Recently, technology has allowed multiple sites to be joined together by closedcircuit television, although not always successfully. These two problems have been described as contributing to the first demise of a New England town meeting: "In 1822, Boston, with a population in excess of 43,000, abandoned the town form of government in favor of a city charter because of attendance problems. Faneuil Hall was overcrowded when a controversial article was on the warrant, and only voters near the moderator could hear the deliberations." New Hampshire's thirteen cities adopted their city charters and gave up direct meetings when their populations averaged only 8,200 (see Appendix 1). There is, however, a third, more important limit which technology cannot resolve. Assume that 20% of a jurisdiction's voters attend a deliberative meeting, that 1/3 of those in attendance are inclined to speak about at least one issue, and that the average speaker takes 3 minutes. A meeting in a town with 600 voters will have an attendance of 120, of whom 44 will speak for a total of slightly over 2 hours. Adding the overhead time for opening, closing, voting, moderator's rulings, and presentations by the school board or board of selectmen, the meeting will take 3-4 hours. This is very close to the average open deliberative meeting in a small community. If the same proportions held true in a town of 6,000 voters, the meeting would last 30-40 hours! Obviously this does not happen. To accommodate the larger population, each citizen has less potential "air time". Of those who attend the meeting, a smaller percentage will actually speak. Participants who might have addressed their peers (had they been living in small towns) will be precluded from doing so by the shared sense that it is more important "to move the issue along". Understanding that they might not have an opportunity to share their views on issues, many will chose not to attend at all. This explains our findings of much lower attendance rates in larger jurisdictions. Both the citizens who react to practical time limits by choosing not to attend (and thus not even vote) and those who attend but "bite their tongue" and do not speak, are potentially frustrated and alienated from the process of local governance. Yet certainly some people do attend and speak at these meetings. Those who do, therefore, may be viewed by others as part of a special elite or special interest group. Non-speakers may feel that they have been effectively locked out from participation in their local government. Rather than surrender their role completely, these individuals are likely to see official ballot voting as the only way they can still participate meaningfully in their local government. It is our contention that this, and not a tax revolt, explains the recent popularity and adoption of official ballot voting. 4. The Quality of Public Participation in Local Government There are fundamental qualitative differences among the alternative forms of local government that a community may adopt. The most important difference is the effect of the single individual on the outcome of a legislative action. At one extreme, city and town council and representative town meeting forms, the individual voter has a small indirect effect on the action by virtue of voting for a representative to the Council. The Councilor is accountable to all the voters from his/her district. At the other extreme in the open town meeting the individual has the opportunity directly effect the outcome through his/her speaking on the particular proposal. Further, he or she can propose amendments to the action. In between these two extremes, the official ballot form provides the individual who attends the deliberative session with the opportunity to amend the legislative proposal; however, there is no opportunity for him or her to communicate with all of the actual voters as there is on the floor of the open town meeting. David Mathews, President of the Kettering Foundation has pointed out the importance of public action in a democracy. He points out that public action is more than voting and supporting elected officials. Before people can act as a public, they must first decide how. Public deliberation is the way that the public decides how to act. In Mathew’s view public deliberation involves people weighing the costs and consequences of various approaches to solving public problems so that they become aware of how other members of the public see these costs and consequences. This awareness, in turn, enables them to find courses of action that are consistent with what the community values. In this way the public interest is defined, and it is through these deliberative activities that the public agenda is set. This activist role for the public has its foundations in the earliest town meetings and has been the backbone of local government throughout the history of New Hampshire. In the early history of the State, the public’s very survival depended upon working together to solve problems. The open meeting and the deliberative sessions associated with the official ballot meeting assure a vestige of the deliberative concept. Gradually, local government is being turned over to professional planners and managers. Today, as the towns become larger and the pace of life quickens, there are signs that the public’s role is shrinking to one of simply voting. The poor attendance at deliberative sessions in SB2 towns and school districts is testament to that fact. Recommendations 1. New Alternatives and Ideas Needed New and creative thinking should be applied to the question of how to best provide a meaningful role for voters in local governance once population is too large to maintain traditional open meetings. Until the passage of SB2 in 1995, the only alternative that had been adopted by any community was the approval of a city or town charter. Official ballot voting is with us now, just as city charters have been for more than 100 years. One alternative that has been available under New Hampshire law but has remained unused to date is that of the representative town meeting. RSA 49:D-3 outlines how such a method of governance would work in New Hampshire towns, establishing the election of representatives from town districts who would then be the designated voters at town meeting although other voters would be able to speak and debate. This alternative is not available, however, to school districts. It has been adopted by 42 towns in Massachusetts, 7 in Connecticut, 1 in Maine, and 1 in Vermont. The town of Fairhaven, Massachusetts, for example, elects 429 meeting members. New ideas could also be considered and potentially enacted into law to provide other choices to jurisdictions that have effectively outgrown the ability to maintain open meetings. For example, a "sortition-based" representative town meeting might maintain a truly diverse assembly yet avoid special interest group electoral politics. Sortition is the random selection of registered voters such as is used in the selection of our juries. It was the primary method of selection in classical Athens, played a role in the Republic of Venice, and has recently been proposed to replace the lifetime and hereditary seats in the British House of Lords. If 100-400 voters were randomly selected for a single year, they might bring a dedication to the job of governance not unlike that they bring to juries. A recent description of sortition describes its advantage this way, "A system of universal lot-drawing for public office would create proportionality in the sense of giving public officials roughly the same composition as the general citizenry without giving disproportionate weight to people with any narrow set of characteristics." We are not advocating these alternatives as superior to official ballot voting, city charters, or any other alternative. We simply suggest that rather than expending immense energy re-debating the advantages and disadvantages of the specifics of SB2, some of our leaders should be proposing and creating new and better ways for larger jurisdictions to maintain a healthy local government and strong citizen involvement. Primary leadership in this direction should come from the New Hampshire Municipal Association, the New Hampshire School Boards Association, and the State, probably through its legislative committees with responsibility for municipal and school government. Two groups of leaders should be brought together to begin discussion: those in jurisdictions that have adopted official ballot voting and those with a population base or growth that may lead them to do so in the future. A realistic assessment of the situations faced by these communities and creative leadership, both locally and at the state level, could result in new laws establishing new options. 2. New Thinking About Voter Communications Good public decisions are based on the informed judgments of the voters. But how are voters informed? In small communities with traditional open meetings, voters are informed of budget issues and options primarily in three ways. First, before the meeting is held, the local gossip and word-ofmouth network is typically hard at work. Second, the open meeting allows for discussion of the proposed budget and any controversial items prior to one or more votes. For the most part, voters have an opportunity to hear different explanations and views on each issue before they make up their own minds. Third, the voters have an opportunity to change the proposal in a manner that may lead a solution more acceptable to the voters than the alternatives presented by the selectmen or school board. It is not uncommon for some "horse-trading" to go on around a particularly controversial warrant article. By the time a vote is taken, there is reasonable assurance that all those who will vote have been able to take into account new information and the divergent views of their fellow residents. Towns with larger populations, and especially those with many new residents, do not have the strong word-of-mouth network that smaller towns possess. Voters may arrive at the meeting having spoken only with a few others about the priorities and issues in the proposed budget. For towns that have adopted SB2, our findings show a much smaller percentage of voters attending their deliberative sessions. Thus, when it is time to cast a budget vote by ballot in the larger SB2 jurisdictions, neither of the main communications mechanisms that are part of life in a small jurisdiction will have ensured that voters are informed. We also found examples of use of the amendment process available in the deliberative sessions to undermine the intent of a warrant article. For example, deliberative meeting attendees have amended a special appropriation article so that the amount requested was "zero" dollars, effectively taking the decision as to whether to purchase the item out of the hands of the voter, who could then only approve or disapprove a zero amount. Some official ballot jurisdictions have tried, admittedly on an ad hoc basis, to create new communications channels to inform potential voters of budgets and the budget choices they will face on the ballot. For example, some boards of selectmen and school boards have used direct mail to inform voters of specific proposals and the reasons therefor. But a truly informed electorate must have the opportunity to hear other views as well, much as they do at an open meeting. There has been little or no systematic planning for how to ensure that official ballot voters are provided the information that will allow them to make informed choices after hearing differing views. The voters are generally dependent upon the media for information about the legislative options before them. Most of the states major media outlets serve a large region with multiple towns and school districts making it virtually impossible for them to do justice to each of the 23 (on average) warrant articles for each town and school district within their service area. The NH Municipal Association and NH School Boards Association should jointly address this gap by first surveying the actions of official ballot jurisdictions, monitoring and supporting local experimentation, and then recommending new communications channels. The potential of new technology to be of great assistance should not be overlooked. Public address systems and closed-circuit TV have already allowed for larger meetings. Town web sites, voter e-mail, specialized password-protected local "chat" rooms for discussing town business, streaming video, and cable TV shows prior to balloting day, all hold promise as new avenues for informing the local electorate. It is recognized that these new forms of effective communication will have a budgetary cost not associated with word of mouth and meeting attendance. It will be important, however, for new communications channels to allow for differing views, not just the official views of the selectmen or school board. For this reason, these mechanisms should, perhaps, be under the authority of the moderator. It is the moderator, after all, who is responsible for ensuring that all views are treated fairly and with respect during traditional open meetings and that ballots are cast and counted honestly. 3. Voting on Bond Issues Official ballot jurisdictions have a much lower probability of approving bond issues to fund capital projects such as school building, sewer system renovation, etc. During the years of this study a 2/3 vote was required by law for approval of such bond issues. The 1999 legislature, however, amended the law, RSA 33:8, so that official ballot jurisdictions will require only a 60% vote beginning in 2000. Without taking sides on whether any specific proposed capital project is truly needed or not, a very large and clear statistical difference in favor of rejecting capital projects could, if continued over more than a few years, become a serious problem. This is especially so because the very communities that have adopted official ballot voting are, almost by definition, experiencing population growth that will eventually necessitate expanded or improved infrastructure. Close monitoring of bond votes over the next few years should be undertaken. The results of all such votes are already submitted to the NH Department of Revenue Administration by both towns and school districts annually. DRA should prepare relevant summaries of all such votes taken in 1999 and 2000 and determine whether the great difference between traditional and official ballot jurisdictions continues. This information should be submitted to the legislature to determine whether further changes in the requirement for approving bonded indebtedness should be made. 4. Collection of Information on Local Governance In both 1997 and 1998 as we planned this study's data collection activities, we sought a definitive list of communities that had adopted SB2 and HB141 forms of official ballot voting. We were provided lists by the NH Department of Revenue Administration, the NH Municipal Association, and the NH School Boards Association. We would later discover that each of these lists contained errors and omissions. In effect, no one in New Hampshire knew what forms of local governance were current in each of our towns and school districts. Nor was there one location where that information could be obtained. For state elections each town must submit copies of voter checklists and vote tallies to the Secretary of State, but there is no similar requirement for local elections. Local jurisdictions are required to send copies of proposed budgets, minutes of meetings, and final approved budgets to DRA annually. These materials are then filed, reviewed, and used by DRA to set tax rates. However, each jurisdiction's information is maintained in a separate manual file for each year. While standard forms are used, evidently no attempt is made to enter the collected data into a single computer file that would allow trends in a single community to be monitored over time, or differences among communities to be ascertained easily. The submitted minutes include votes on warrant articles, thus allowing a very good estimate to be made of the number of voters participating. We believe that the well-being of local governance in New Hampshire is very important. Whether direct voter participation in local government is falling off or is increasing ought to be of as much interest, if not more, as voter turnout in national elections. NH DRA should annually compile much of the quantitative local data submitted to it into a single computer database and then make that data available to all interested parties. Towns and school districts would be able to see how they differ from each other in voter participation and budget decisions. We are aware that cost is often cited as a reason for the State not to undertake any new activity. At times, however, our study was a pilot test of such an undertaking. From our close observation, we believe this recommendation would probably take one DRA staff member about one month to complete each year. This time could be reduced still further to the extent that local jurisdictions submit their material already in an agreed upon standard computer form. We believe the investment of $5,000 $10,000 to accomplish this would result in a much better understanding of the diversity and trends in local government budgets and citizen participation in New Hampshire. Appendix 1: Population and City Charters Thirteen municipalities in New Hampshire are now legally incorporated as cities, having adopted city charters. Manchester voters were the first to approve a change from town government to a city charter government in 1846. The most recent was Lebanon, where the change occurred in 1958. One of the most important changes that occurs when a town becomes a city is that the voters as a whole give up their role as the legislative body and entrust nearly all the work of the town meeting to an elected legislative body, variously termed a city council or board of aldermen. The direct democracy of town meeting is replaced by a representative form of local government. Table A1 lists each New Hampshire city, the year is first city charter was adopted, and an estimate of the total population at the time. The average population of these New Hampshire municipalities was just over 8,200 when their voters gave up direct democracy and replaced it with a representative form of government. In all but one, the change occurred before the population reached 10,000. Table A1 Municipality Manchester Became City Estimated Population 1846 9,653 Portsmouth 1849 9,553 Nashua 1853 9,279 Concord 1853 9,272 Dover 1855 8,349 Keene 1874 6,296 Rochester 1891 7,663 Somersworth 1893 6,452 Laconia 1893 6,713 Franklin 1895 4,966 Berlin 1897 7,339 Claremont 1947 12,611 Lebanon 1958 9,138 Average 8,253 In 1995 there were eighteen New Hampshire towns with populations that exceeded 8,200 and which had not opted to become cities: Derry, Conway, Raymond, Hooksett, Hanover, Amherst, Windham, Pelham, Durham, Milford, Hampton, Exeter, Bedford, Goffstown, Hudson, Londonderry, Merrimack, and Salem. Most of these towns had experienced population growth of more than 100% since 1960. Of these, Derry, Londonderry, and Durham, had adopted a town council form of representative government in which budget is considered and passed by a representative council. The remainder have struggled to maintain their direct democracy and town meetings, at least for budget approval purposes. Appendix 2: Official Ballot Jurisdictions 1997-1999 Municipalities 1997 1998 1999 1998 1999 SB2 SB2 Allenstown SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Alton SB2 SB2 SB2 Amherst SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Barrington SB2 SB2 Allenstown Alstead Amherst Atkinson Barrington School Districts 1997 SB2 SB2 Bedford SB2 SB2 SB2 Bennington SB2 SB2 SB2 Claremont SB2 SB2 SB2 Canaan SB2 SB2 SB2 Contoocook Valley SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Conway SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Derry Cooperative SB2 SB2 SB2 Carroll Charlestown Conway SB2 SB2 SB2 Epsom Danville SB2 SB2 SB2 Exeter Dorchester SB2 SB2 SB2 Exeter Regional Coop Enfield SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Epsom SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Fall Mountain Regional SB2 SB2 SB2 Goffstown SB2 SB2 SB2 Exeter SB2 SB2 SB2 Governor Wentworth Regional SB2 SB2 SB2 Goffstown SB2 SB2 SB2 Hampstead SB2 SB2 SB2 Grafton SB2 SB2 SB2 Hampton SB2 SB2 SB2 Hampstead SB2 SB2 SB2 Hampton Falls SB2 SB2 SB2 Hampton SB2 SB2 SB2 Hillsboro-Deering Coop SB2 SB2 SB2 Hooksett SB2 SB2 SB2 Hudson SB2 SB2 SB2 Hudson SB2 SB2 SB2 John Stark Regional SB2 SB2 SB2 Kearsarge Regional SB2 SB2 Keene SB2 Lebanon Litchfield Kensington Kingston SB2 Litchfield Littleton Londonderry SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 HB141 HB141 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 HB141 HB141 HB141 Littleton SB2 SB2 SB2 Merrimack SB2 SB2 SB2 Londonderry SB2 SB2 SB2 Milford SB2 SB2 SB2 Lyndeborough SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Mascenic Regional SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Mascoma Valley Regional SB2 SB2 SB2 Milton New Ipswich Newmarket Newton HB141 HB141 HB141 Merrimack SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Milford SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Milton SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Monadnock Regional SB2 SB2 SB2 New Boston SB2 SB2 SB2 Newfound Area SB2 SB2 SB2 Newmarket SB2 SB2 North Hampton Orange SB2 Pelham Plaistow SB2 SB2 Rye Salem SB2 HB141 HB141 HB141 SB2 SB2 Sandown SB2 SB2 SB2 Newport North Hampton SB2 SB2 SB2 Seabrook SB2 SB2 SB2 Oyster River Coop SB2 SB2 SB2 Sunapee SB2 SB2 Pelham SB2 SB2 Wakefield SB2 SB2 Raymond SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Weare SB2 SB2 SB2 Rumney Winchester SB2 SB2 SB2 Rye Wolfeboro SB2 SB2 SB2 Salem SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Sanborn Regional SB2 SB2 SB2 Seabrook SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Wakefield SB2 SB2 Weare SB2 SB2 Sunapee Timberlane Regional SB2 White Mountains Regional Winchester SB2 SB2 SB2 SB2 Windham SB2 SB2 SB2 Winnacunnett Coop SB2 SB2 SB2 Bibliography 1. Dahl, Robert A., On Democracy, Yale University Press, New Haven, Connecticut, 1998 2. Dahl, Robert A. & Tufte, E. R., Size and Democracy, Stanford University Press, Stanford, California, 1973 3. Knag, Sigmund, "Let's Toss For It: A Surprising Curb on Political Greed", The Independent Review, v.III n. 2, Fall 1998, pp 199-209. 4. Soule, Lewis, "The New Hampshire Town Meeting", photocopied paper, publisher and date unknown. 5. Zimmerman, Joseph F., The New England Town Meeting: Democracy in Action, Praeger Publishers, westport, Connecticut, 1999 6. Zimmerman, Joseph F., "The New England Town Meeting: A De Facto Representative Assembly", presentation at annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston Massachusetts, September 5, 1998.