Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Does Common Property Forest Management Change On-Farm Behavior? Evidence on Tree Planting in Highland Ethiopia Abstract: Policy reform to increase tree cover is a key priority in a number of low-income developing countries and Ethiopia is no exception. Reforms in Ethiopia include a forest proclamation issued in 2007 and the first-ever federal forest policy approved the same year. Both these documents allow a variety of institutional arrangements for investment in forests, including common property forest management (CPFM), private woodlots and on-farm trees. This paper analyzes behavioral change spurred by better CPFM, with a focus on on-farm tree planting in Ethiopia. Results from our theoretical model suggest that on-farm tree stocks, which provide products that can substitute for those from common forests, should increased by better CPFM systems. We test this finding using data from household and village surveys conducted in the Ethiopian highlands in 2007. Using CPFM indices based on survey respondent perceptions, we find that CPFM in the study area is very loose, informal and could be considered weak. We also find that management varies across sites and households and is driven by population density, management level, forest type and other variables. Different aspects of CPFM show strong correlations, which suggests these components tend to . We find that despite generally loose management, using a variety of estimation techniques, including treatment effects, count data and IV methods, CPFM has a positive association with the number of trees grown and in some cases with decisions to grow trees. These findings suggest that what appears to be informal, loose or ineffective management may have important behavioral effects. One of these behavioral effects appears to be that households grow more trees on their farms when CPFM is more stringent. These and likely other behavioral responses should be considered when planning or evaluating CPFM programs (JEL Q23, Q12). 1|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 I. Introduction In most low-income developing countries households depend on trees to provide a variety of products that are essential to daily life, including fuelwood, fodder for animals and building materials. Furthermore, forests provide important “off-site” benefits, including erosion and flood control. Often forests are “common,” which creates interdependencies between community members that may result in open access, which provides few incentives for stewardship, planting, and management (Gordon 1954). Without clear property rights, as long as resources have value, they will be used in less than ideal ways and almost certainly will be degraded, often to the point where they end up close to worthless. Sometimes this phenomenon is called the “Tragedy of the Commons” (Hardin 1968) and reflects the idea that potentially very valuable resources can be degraded when it is not clear who gets products generated from natural resource investments and/or who has the right to control resources.i Establishing clear property rights through appropriate institutional arrangements is therefore perhaps the critical prerequisite to enhanced tree planting, stewardship, management and tree cover in many low-income countries. Clarifying property rights may not solve all problems, but the economic literature is doubtful that tree cover can be sustainably increased without clear property rights (Gordon 1954; Hartwick and Olewiler 1998; Field 2001). In Ethiopia, which is the focus of this paper, property rights in rural areas are often very weak and this is particularly true for common grazing and forest areas (Mekonnen and Bluffstone 2008). People therefore typically use the land as they want with very limited management; as rural populations and demands on common lands have increased, it is perhaps not surprising that forest cover has declined. What institutional arrangements can be used to establish property rights? Private property, of course, is a possibility and it certainly creates the right incentives for forest management if there are 2|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 few conflicts between uses. For example, if trees only produce fuelwood, private property may be the correct institutional arrangement, because there are few ways owners of fuelwood plantations can infringe on each others’ property rights. Privatization would therefore likely be the correct solution. But, in Ethiopia as in most low-income countries, common forests typically produce multiple products, creating technical barriers to privatization. Furthermore, allocation of forest resources is highly political and villagers may be deprived of historical rights. Poor villagers, who often rely much more heavily on common lands than the rich (Jodha 1986), may as a result find themselves worse off than when land access is open. With an estimated 4.6 percent forest cover, compared with a baseline of perhaps 40 percent forest cover in the 16th century (EFAP 1994; Tumcha 2004), 0.8 percent deforestation per year and 83.3 percent of the population living in rural areas (World Bank 2005) the forestry situation in Ethiopia is highly problematic. Ethiopia also has a rapidly growing human population of about 80 million, largely dependent on low-productivity and rain-fed agriculture. There are also over 70 million livestock that compete for land and forest resources. As noted by the Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations, “The current demographic and socio-economic conditions have led to an unprecedented pressure on [the remaining] mountain forest ecosystems.” It found that over 90 percent of energy for household cooking comes from fuelwood.ii Since 2006 floods potentially linked to lack of tree cover killed hundreds and resulted in significant property damage. Policy reform to increase tree cover is a government priority, with a forest proclamation issued in 2007 and the first-ever federal forest policy approved the same year. Both these documents allow a variety of institutional arrangements for investment in forests, including CPFM, private woodlots, and on-farm trees. Creating government ownership is also a possibility, but as seems to be the case in Ethiopia (where all land is state-owned) and many other low-income countries, state property often 3|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 functions as de facto open access. A more promising institutional arrangement is common property in which users of forests jointly own resources. Devolution of forest management to local-level institutions with the goal of creating incentives for stewardship, planting, and management of common lands has therefore become an increasingly important tool when forests mainly generate direct use values that are not fully compatible (Agrawal 2007). If common property forest management (CPFM) really offers incentives for better management than open access, we should observe behavioral differences when better management exists. In this paper we examine one potential behavioral effect by trying to isolate and understand the effects of generally-considered better CPFM on households’ incentives to invest in trees on their own farmland. As a small but growing literature is establishing, private tree planting is a potentially important behavioral response to better social coordination and higher levels of social capital like CPFM (Nepal et al. 2007; Bluffstone et al. 2008; Mekonnen [forthcoming]). Furthermore, in East Africa as common forests have deteriorated, very small private plantations are increasingly producing critical forest products for rural households. In Kenya a significant proportion of fuelwood and charcoal comes from private lands (Bluffstone et al. 2007) In this paper we seek to contribute to the growing—but still inadequate—literature on the determinants of CPFM and household responses to different aspects of CPFM. To our knowledge, this is also the first study in Africa that looks into the links between CPFM and private tree planting. Using an analytical household model, we find that better CPFM creates incentives for tree planting on household farms. We test this hypothesis using household data from highland Ethiopia and find strong support for this result using a variety of methods. We therefore conclude, as Bluffstone et al (2008) did for the Bolivian Andes, that better CPFM causes households to change their behavior and one effect is more on-farm tree planting. 4|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 The next section discusses the literature related to CPFM. Section 3 presents a household analytical model that extends that used by Bluffstone et al. (2008). Section 4 discusses data and descriptive statistics. Section 5 presents the econometric approach, followed by results in section 6. Section 6 concludes and discusses the implications of the paper. II.Literature on Common Property Forest Management and Household Behavior In recent decades there have been important advances in our understanding of the management of commonly held natural resources. In the process, an enormous literature has emerged that discusses the incentives for community members to cooperate and emphasizes the need for individual interests to be deferred to enhance the long-term community interest. This literature implies that with effective CPFM households would be forced to restrict their collections compared with desired levels (e.g., Olson 1965; Dayton-Johnson 2000; Wade 1988; Ostrom 1990; Bromley 1990; Baland and Platteau 1996; Sethi and Somanathan 1996; Baland and Platteau 1999; Bluffstone et al. 2008). A related literature discusses desirable aspects of CPFM and attempts to disaggregate its components. This work suggests that effective CPFM systems empower communities, have clear access and extraction rules, fair and graduated sanctions, public participation, clear quotas and successful monitoring (Ostrom 1990; Agrawal 2000, 2001). Following Bluffstone et al (2008) we divide CPFM characteristics into institutional characteristics and management tools. Institutional characteristics are the basic values and arrangement of institutions. For example, clarity of access to forest resources, fairness, democracy and public participation are institutional characteristics. Management tools are instruments used to encourage members to mitigate their use of forests or improve forest quality. Fixed allotments of fuelwood and fodder, monitoring by officials and villagers, formal and informal sanctions and work to improve forest quality are all management tools. 5|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Despite what is an emerging conventional wisdom that CPFM is better than other alternatives, evidence on the effects and efficacy of CPFM components is still limited and the subject of current empirical research; indeed, empirical work focusing on CPFM elements that spur behavioral change has only relatively recently emerged (Hegan et al. 2003; Adhikari 2002; Amacher et al. 1996, 1999; Cooke 2000, 2004; Edmonds 2002; Heltberg 2001; Heltberg et al. 2000; Linde-Rahr 2003). The work of Nepal et al. (2007), Bluffstone et al. (2008) and Mekonnen (forthcoming) are directly related to our paper, because of the focus on incentives for on-farm tree planting. Nepal et al. (2007) looks at a variety of social networks and finds that forest-related institutions particularly spur on-farm tree planting. Other less forest-related groups have limited effects. Bluffstone et al. (2008) uses a methodology similar to that used in this paper to examine whether CPFM spurs on-farm tree planting in Bolivia. They find that better CPFM at its highest level of aggregation—and especially the institutional characteristics component—is positively correlated with more and higher quality on-farm trees. In terms of less aggregated indices, relatively few variables are significant, although two specific property rights aspects of CPFM may reduce on-farm planting. Mekonnen (forthcoming) looks at tree planting in Ethiopia and finds that a variety of labor, asset and credit market imperfections affect onfarm tree planting. III. A Household Analytical Model and Comparative Static Resultsiii Consider a representative farming household living in a large village in a low-income country. The village being “large” means that many households access a nearby forest and strategic interactions regarding the use of the forest are not possible.iv The status quo is open access, though rents may not be completely dissipated (Gordon, 1954). The village is examining the implications of introducing CPFM regulations to curb open access. 6|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 U U (F , X ) (1) The household has a unitary decision process and household utility is an increasing concave function of cooked food (F) and other goods (X) that must be purchased (equation 1). Food is only produced by households and is a function of environmental and non-environmental household labor inputs ( E E and E NE ), common forest quality (Q) and trees planted on-farm (T) that substitute for common forests. Environmental labor includes activities such as fuelwood collection, grazing and cutting of fodder for animals, which provides fuel for cooking and feeds animals that produce meat. Animals also produce dung, which is the main fertilizer in much of the developing world, including Ethiopia. Non-environmental labor consists of household activities like cooking, cleaning, caring for children and agriculture. This function is given in (2).v ( 2) F F ( E E , E NE , Q, T ) (2) First derivatives are positive and second derivatives negative due to the existence of quasi-fixed factors such as tools, animals, etc; common forests do not generate these diminishing returns, because households are “small” collectors of forest products. Labor cross-partial derivatives are assumed to be zero, which means that marginal products of any Ei are not affected by any E h . This approach is taken to reduce dimensionality of the problem in the interest of deriving testable hypotheses. Common forest quality (Q), however, makes environmental labor more productive (i.e. ( F / Q ) 0) . On-farm tree EE inputs into food production (e.g. by stall feeding animals or collecting branches on-farm) do not require environmental labor. Equation 3 is the production function for trees (T), which is only a function of tree planting labor (ET). This simplification focuses attention on labor, which is the main resource allocation issue. 7|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Trees may also, however, be purchased. ET includes planting, watering, chasing away grazing animals and guarding against encroachment. The first derivative of g(ET) is positive and the second derivative negative due to the existence of fixed land. T g ( Et} (3) Production occurs subject to the time constraint in (4). All activities discussed above are included, as well as off-farm wage labor (Ew), which earns incomes used to purchase X and T. Leisure is omitted, because Ethiopian farmers typically work long hours and the labor-leisure tradeoff is not germane to our research questions. E EE ENE ET Ew (4) There is no saving or borrowing. Cash is earned from wages at rate w and spent on X and trees . Households are assumed to be price takers. Due to highly imperfect financial markets there is no borrowing or saving (5). wEw PTT PxX (5) Effective CPFM by its nature utilizes collective action to restrict household deforesting behavior in the name of forest regeneration and boosting rents. Because households’ most important variable factor is labor, similar to the method used by Linde-Rahr (2003) we model these restrictions as inequality constraints on forest-related labor supply.vi Following Heltberg (2001), it is supposed that while forest policies may be endogenous, they are given when villagers make their day-to-day decisions. 8|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 L U [{F ( EG, ENE , Q, T ) g ( ET )} , ( wE w PT g ( ET ) )] 1( E EE ENE ET Ew) PX (6) 2( E w Ew) 3( E EE ) * * E We substitute (3) into (2) and (5). After solving (5) for X we substitute the result into (1) and do the same for (2). The resulting Lagrangian that the household maximizes is given in (6). In addition to the time constraint represented by constraint λ1, λ2 and λ3 represent restrictions on labor supply. The Kuhn-Tucker conditions are that if the constraints bind, the Lagrange multipliers are positive rather than zero. λ2 > 0 therefore says that households are unable to work in the wage labor market as much as they would like. λ3 > 0 represents restrictions on environmental labor supply imposed by CPFM. Though it is easiest to think of these constraints as extraction time limits, as will be shown in the following section Ethiopian CPFM constraints may be quantitative and specific (e.g. allowable cutting of fuelwood, maximum days grazing, fees for extraction) or qualitative (e.g. households may take what they need but not more, face social sanctions for over-use or that allocations are fair). a. b L U F (Q ) 1 3 0 EE F E E L U F 1 0 ENE F E NE (7) U F g PT g , 1 0 ET F g ET PX ET L w d. 2 0 Ew PX c. To derive comparative static results, an explicit form of 7c must be assumed. In rural Ethiopia, because markets are very thin food is virtually always produced on-farm and not purchased or sold. It is therefore likely there is close to complete separability between X, the purchased good, and food, 9|Page Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 which is produced as part of substistence agriculture. An additive function captures this separability and so in 7c we assume such a function. Setting 7a=7b=7c gives (8) U F g U F PT U F (Q) 3 ( ) F E E ET F g PX F ENE Assuming ( (8) U F PT ) 0 , which says that on the margin households find it in their interest F g PX to plant trees rather than buy them, we examine the effects of λ3 being positive rather than equal to zero, which indicates that CPFM constraints bind. In the comparative statics we allow λ3 to increase starting from zero (i.e. open access). Figure 1 To maintain equality as λ3 increases ∂g/∂ET and ∂g/∂ENE must decline. Given diminishing returns to labor, this outcome would only occur if ET and ENE increase; labor therefore shifts from environmental labor based on the use of common forests into non-environmental and tree labor. The latter result is of interest here, because it indicates that CPFM labor constraints increase tree planting. These labor shifts are larger the tighter the constraint. ET and ENE are therefore increasing in λ3. 10 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Figure 1 presents the situation focusing on EE and Figure 2 does something similar with regard to ET. Figure 1 presents the situation. The horizontal axis is environmental labor and the vertical axis is marginal utility. Because ( U F PT ) > 0, households trade off environmental labor against onF g PX farm tree labor and choose environmental labor to maximize utility as in (8). We see that without CPFM restrictions households would choose EE_OA1, which is the open access equilibrium. With binding CPFM restrictions households are constrained to environmental labor of E E , which is consistent with a higher MU of environmental labor and lower MU of tree planting labor (consistent with higher labor supply). Households forgo forest rents and would like to move labor into forestry activities, but is not permitted to do so. With diminishing marginal returns to ET, Figure 1 indicates that tree planting increases due to CPFM restrictions. Over time it can be expected that effective CPFM will cause common forest quality (Q) to increase. Such an outcome increases the marginal productivity of EE and MU EE therefore shifts to the right as represented in MU EE (Q2 ) . We see that the desired level of environmental labor increases to EE_OA2. Allowing households to respond to increased Q degrades the resource, however, reducing Q and shifting MU EE back to MU EE (Q1 ) . EE_OA2 is therefore not a long-run equilibrium and labor supply would revert back to EE_OA1. Allowing households to take advantage of increased forest rents through increased labor supply is therefore counterproductive. Rents must therefore be taken in terms of households gathering more forest products per hour collected. As shown in Figure 1, even at EE_OA1 rents increase. Households are better off from improvements in forest quality not because they can reallocate labor to forest dependent activities, but because each unit of (constrained) forest labor is more productive. Because of the restrictions on EE the increase in Q has no effect on ET or on-farm tree planting. 11 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Figure 2 Figure 2 presents a diagram similar to Figure 1, except in terms of ET. We see that under open access to common forests tree planting labor would be ETE-OA. Under CPFM EE is restricted and from the open access equilibrium labor shifts into on-farm trees and ET = ET_ E E . As common forest quality increases the marginal cost of ET, which is MU_EE, increases and households would like to reduce their on-farm tree effort even below ET_OA1. This level of effort is not an equilibrium, however, because shifts out of ET and into EE as ET falls below ET_ E E reduces Q. As long as CPFM is in place ET = ET_ E E . On-farm tree effort is therefore unambiguously increasing in CPFM stringency. IV.Data and CPFM Descriptive Statistics The key prediction of the model that households experiencing more stringent CPFM will plant more trees on their farms is now tested using household and community level data collected in 2007. The sample is made up largely by subsistence rural households that rely on mixed crop and livestock farming in East Gojam and South Wollo zones of the Amhara Regional State in Ethiopia. Ten village areas called kebeles (often translated as peasant associations) are covered by the survey. Kebeles are 12 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 chosen to ensure variation in terms of characteristics, such as agro-ecology and tree cover, with households randomly selected. Figure 3 shows the location of the study sites. Figure 3 The goals of the empirical analysis are to identify household and community-level determinants of CPFM and test whether better CPFM spurs on-farm tree planting. Because there is very limited literature that analyzes the relationship between tree planting and CPFM in the disaggregated fashion we attempt, our hypothesis is that all indices positively affect agro-forestry. Descriptive statistics are presented in tables 1 to 5. Table 1 here Table 1 shows that 82 percent of households grow trees and on average households have about 241 trees, with a large variation across households. Such a finding suggests that on-farm trees are key household assets. Indeed, as Bluffstone et al (2007) note, on-farm trees on average make up over 50% of household assets. This percentage is so high, because households in Ethiopia do not own the 13 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 agricultural land they use. The government owns all land, though recent initiatives to certify use rights appear to be gaining momentum (Mekonnen and Bluffstone, 2008). As also shown in table 1, about 70% grow eucalyptus and average eucalyptus trees per household is about 197, making eucalyptus the most important planted tree species.vii k Indexij ( Aij Min i ) /( Maxi Min i ) (9) i 1 Table 2 here To estimate the effect of CPFM on tree investments, we use household survey responses to create CPFM indices. We will discuss these critical data in some detail. The survey questions that represent the raw data are based on well-established criteria for well-functioning common property suggested by Ostrom (1990) and Agrawal (2001). Nine indices are created for each household using the formula in (9), which is used by UNDP to compute the human development index and is [0,1]. Aij is the value of index component i for household j and Mini and Maxi are the sample minimum and maximum for component i. CPFM variable definitions, means and standard deviations are presented in Table 2. There are a number of reasons household head perceptions rather than village “leaders” provide the main CPFM data. First, on-the-ground policy implementation in developing countries often corresponds poorly with stated policies. This could be for a number of reasons, including leader misassessments, deliberate attempts to portray local institutions in a positive light or simple difficulties associated with characterizing CPFM details (i.e. imprecision). For example, we know from Ostrom (1990) and Agrawal (2001) that fairness, public participation, clarity of access rules and appropriate social sanctions are key aspects of successful CBFM. These are subjective and subtle aspects that households are likely to perceive differently than leaders. 14 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 For these reasons it is important to focus on household assessments of CPFM. Because CPFM indices in the final analysis are village or kebele variables and all members should in principle (though in actuality may not) be subject to the same rules, perception data are averaged across all kebele members, with one value for each type of CPFM index applied to all member households. These indices are then results are presented in Table 2. At the top of Table 2 is what we call the overall CPFM index, which is an average of institutional characteristics and management tools sub-indices, which are themselves averages of specialized sub-indices. Specialized sub-indices are calculated as averages of the Likert scale survey questions, which are also included in Table 2. For example, different types of community labor are often required to maintain common forests and our labor index includes inputs for planting, thinning, watering and fertilizing. Similarly, social sanctions, penalties, monitoring, payments and clarity of quotas are elements of management tools and those indices are created based on two to four elements, as are the institutional characteristics sub-indices, participation and democracy and fairness. The clarity of access index is based on one survey question. All components are weighted equally, because we have no priors to suggest otherwise. What do we find? Table 2 indicates rather loose management. The average overall CPFM index is 0.39 with standard deviation of 0.20, suggesting relatively weak management with considerable variation across households. Indices for institutional characteristics and management tools are similar at 0.41 and 0.37. Mean sub-indices of the management tools index range from 0.02 (labor requirements) to 0.58 (social sanctions), suggesting that respondents perceive informal social penalties from taking too much forest products. Components of institutional characteristics range from 0.33 (clarity of access) to 0.49 (participation and democracy). These findings, particularly at the aggregated level, are similar to those of Bluffstone et al (2008) focusing on the Bolivian Andes (mean 15 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 overall CPFM index of 0.31 and standard deviation of 0.15). Though more research is needed, this suggests that barring major policy interventions commonalities in CPFM may exist across low-income countries. Table 3 here Table 3 presents correlation coefficients between site dummies and the three high-level CPFM indices, with P-values in parentheses. We find both negative and positive relationships, with many statistically significant at least at the 10% level, suggesting the presence of systematic variation in CPFM across study sites. Substantial cross-site variation was also found for Bolivia by Bluffstone et al (2008). Table 4 here A difference from the analysis in Bolivia is that as shown in Table 4 we find high and statistically significant correlations between CPFM sub-indices. For example, correlations between the overall CPFM index and its two sub-indices are over 0.93, suggesting for analytical purposes we could meaningfully proxy overall CPFM with either of its sub-indices. Indeed, the correlation coefficient of management tools and institutional characteristics is 0.77, which is higher than virtually any found by Bluffstone et al (2008); they find that management tools and institutional characteristics are very weakly correlated (ρ = -0.13). Many specific indices are also highly correlated. For example, while theory may lead us to predict that mutually reinforcing aspects of formal penalties and social sanctions would lead to high correlation (ρ = 0.96), such a tight linkage between access clarity and labor requirements indices is not immediately obvious. We nevertheless find a correlation of 0.74. These results suggest that respondents perceive CPFM in Ethiopia as a set of attributes, which may indicate important synergies. 16 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 V. Econometric Approach The basic empirical approach is to estimate IV models of tree planting (2SLS and GMM), where models allow for a variety of econometric issues, including the possibility that CPFM may be endogenous. Trees are defined in terms of whether households plant any trees on their farms and the number of trees planted. The IV models are all over-identified. We therefore test over-identification restrictions using Sargan, Basmann and Hansen’s J Χ2 methods and confirm all pass these tests. Weak instruments are tested using F and minimum eigenvalue tests and it is found that the set of instruments performs well. The treatment effects models estimate the average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) using nearest neighbor propensity score matching based on observables.viii “Treatment” in these models indicates that households experience kebele average CPFM greater than the median value of the relevant CPFM measure (overall CPFM, institutional characteristics, management tools). Propensity scores are estimated using all exogenous variables in Table 5 subject to satisfying the balancing property. ATTs are estimated with all exogenous covariates from Table 5 as right hand side variables. We find no effect of CPFM indices on tree planting. This finding is robust to tree planting definition (e.g. number of trees, whether trees were planted, number of eucalyptus trees planted, number of trees planted in last five) and CPFM index (overall, institutional characteristics, management tools) tested. We also estimate treatment effects models based on propensity score nearest neighbor matching as an alternative to explicitly modeling endogeneity. Binomial and continuous regression and treatment effects tree planting models are each estimated separately for the overall CPFM index and its two main sub-indices (institutional 17 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 characteristics and management tools). Because of the high correlation between sub-indices, multicollinearity prevents including both variables simultaneously. As was already discussed, though 82% of households plant trees, tree planting is not universal. If this decision process involves sample selection, IV regression would lead to bias (Heckman, 1979; Linde-Rahr, 2003;). We test for sample selection and find evidence of sample selection at the 10% significance levels. We therefore also report Heckman results, which turn out to be very similar to those from models that do not adjust for sample selection. Probit selection equations are estimated using all exogenous covariates in Table 5. Without sample selection the standard method when data are left-censored is to use Tobit, but this is correct only if the process for deciding whether to plant trees is the same as for choosing the number of trees planted. We test this restriction by comparing the Tobit with the model of Cragg (1971), which utilizes a Probit for the first stage followed by a truncated regression model. Using likelihood ratio tests, we cannot reject the Tobit as too restrictive at better than the 10% level in any model. Finally, trees are a count data variable. We therefore estimate the models using Poission regression and find based on a goodness-of-fit Χ2 tests (Prob > Χ2 = 0.00 for all models) that the negative binomial is more appropriate. When results are deliberately selective in the presentation of results. Our independent variables of interest are the overall common property (top of Table 2), institutional characteristics and management tools sub-indices (second row of Table 2). Results on lower-level indices are available from the authors, but to focus the discussion are not reported. CPFM variables are potentially endogenous and indeed recent literature has specifically emphasized endogeneity of forest management institutions (Heltberg, 2001; Baland et al forthcoming). We do not assume endogeneity, however, but test using Wu-Hausman F, Durban Χ2 and GMM C Χ2 tests.ix 18 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 5 here Table 5 presents descriptive statistics for exogenous covariates and excluded exogenous variables along with expected signs and reasons for including. Investments in trees are private decisions and therefore only household variables are included. Variables representing wealth, labor endowments, human capital, market access, land tenure, information and improved stove use are included, because the literature suggests they may affect a variety of investments, including in trees. The excluded instruments presented in Table 5 identify the first stage models of CPFM indices, which endogeneity tests suggest must be treated as endogenous variables. Instruments are chosen, because they are correlated with CPFM indices, uncorrelated with tree plantingxand believed to affect village norms that are related to CPFM formation (e.g. Ostrom, 1990; Agrawal, 2001). Data are from household and village leader surveys. About 20% of households use improved stoves, with the rest relying on three-stone fires. Households in the sample have an average of 1.15 hectares of land, 3.84 tropical livestock units of animals and family size of 5.5. On average households grow a large number of trees on relatively limited land—land that is also used for producing crops. About 17% of household heads in the sample are female and on average household heads are much less educated (0.81 years) than the most educated household members (5.14 years). This difference reflects major education initiatives since 1995. Land is owned by the government and the possibility of land redistribution exists. Indeed, a land redistribution occurred in the study area in 1997. Some farmers have been issued certificates confirming rights to use land and we find that 44% of households believe land belongs to them. On the other hand, about 19% expect to lose land due to land redistributions within 5 years. We also find about 17% plant trees to increase land tenure security. 19 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Social capital has also been found to be an important feature of investments (e.g. see Nyangena, forthcoming; Kabubo-Mariara and Linderhof, forthcoming). As Nepal (2007) notes, social capital has a number of implications for tree planting and in our study area we believe the primary effect is through information sharing. Whether households report that they trust people in their villages is used to capture social capital and in our sample about 67% of respondents say they trust other villagers. Also related to information is agricultural extension and farmer-to-farmer extension. While on average households are visited by an extension agent once in the previous year, about 36% also benefit from farmer-to-farmer extension. VI. Results We begin our discussion of results with the decision of whether households grew any trees. As shown in Table 1, 82% of households grow trees and variation is rather limited. We test for whether CPFM indices are endogenous to the tree growing decision and cannot reject the null of exogeneity. Table 6 therefore presents Probit results. Table 6 here We see in the table that if anything CPFM is negatively correlated with tree growing. Indeed, the overall CPFM index is negatively and statistically significantly correlated with the existence of onfarm trees, which does not support the predictions of the analytical model. Significant positive covariates include livestock holdings, household head age, distance to town, trust in other villagers and corrugated roof. In addition to the CPFM index, negatively correlated is distance to the nearest road. 20 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 7 here Table 7 presents OLS models of on-farm tree planting. In no models are CPFM indices significant. Significant variables across models include endowments like fraction of boys and girls and livestock holdings. In particular we see that an additional TLU of livestock (e.g. one cow) increases on-farm trees by 41 trees. We test for exogeneity of CPFM variables and find, as presented in table 9, we can reject exogeneity of all CPFM indices at much better than the 1% significance level. There is therefore reason to believe that OLS estimates of the effect of CPFM on tree planting would be biased. Based on these test results we estimate a variety of IV models. Table 8 here Table 8 presents first-stage OLS models of CPFM indices. A number of variables are significant, including household land and animal endowments. Three others—whether a household gave a loan in the last year, whether respondents believe they own their land and whether they expect to lose land in the next five years—have positive and statistically significant associations with all three indices. These results suggest that those rich enough to make loans and those who feel more confident about their security of land tenure perceive more strict CPFM. The results also suggest that households who perceive insecurity in land tenure have perceptions of stricter CPFM. Excluded exogenous variables, including population density, tenure in village and kebele level forest management are also significant and positively associated with CPFM indices. Robust standard errors are adjusted for kebele clustering. Table 9 here Table 9 presents IV results estimated using 2SLS and GMM and we see that results from the two estimation methods are very similar. Relationships between covariates and tree planting are 21 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 limited, which is similar to the OLS results, though in two IV models farmer-to-farmer extension is positively correlated with tree planting and significant at the 1% level. The main difference with the OLS results is that after instrumenting, all CPFM indices are positively correlated with tree planting. Elasticities of tree planting with respect to CPFM indices are also fairly high at from 1.43 (management tools index) to 1.54 (institutional characteristics) and 1.55 (overall CPFM index), suggesting responsiveness. Indeed, with the exception of the strong positive effect of livestock on tree planting (ε ≈ 0.55), the relationship between CPFM and tree planting is the most robust result. Table 10 here Table 10 takes on the issue of lower limit censoring by estimating the model using IV Tobit after testing for whether a double hurdle model using the method of Cragg (1971) is more appropriate. As already noted, we were unable to reject the more restrictive Tobit specification. We see from the table that results are virtually identical to the 2SLS and GMM IV estimates and all CPFM indices are significant at least at the 10% level. Table 11 here Table 11 takes account of the count data nature of the dependent variable by estimating the model using a negative binomial regression. We see little difference with previous CPFM results and elasticities are similar at 1.30 to 1.44. Covariate results are in many cases similar, but more variables are significant than was the case for the IV estimates. In particular, those that gave loans had fewer trees, while more educated households with older household heads, more land and livestock, improved stoves and corrugated roofs on their houses planted more trees. These findings suggest that in addition to CPFM, household wealth and endowments may be important. 22 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 12 here Finally, we adjust for sample selection. Table 12 presents the results of two-step Heckman selection models. We find results that are highly consistent with previous findings and all CPFM variables are once again positively related to tree planting and in these models significant at least at the 1.0% level. Elasticities are similar to those previously quoted. VII. Conclusion On-farm trees are a critical source of household wealth in highland Ethiopia and in East Africa a key supplier of tree products like fuelwood. The key research question this paper attempts to analyze is whether the nature of common forest management affects on-farm tree planting behavior. We believe this question is of interest not only for understanding whether more private trees can be expected as common forest management improves in the low-income developing world, but also as part of the more general issue of whether CPFM really affects household behavior. Relatively little research has focused on this general question, though low-income countries across the world have turned to CPFM to bolster declining forest stocks and as it has been recognized that despite the benefit of egalitarianism, open access degrades key forest resources. Our theoretical model strongly suggests that if we observe better CPFM we should also observe more on-farm tree planting. We test this hypothesis using data from the Ethiopian highlands and find that econometric results strongly support the theoretical model; these findings suggest that decisions about numbers of trees to grow are very much influenced by the nature of community forest management. Indeed, overall CPFM, management tools and institutional characteristics indices in all models are positively correlated with numbers of trees grown. CPFM does not, however, encourage the existence of on-farm trees and indeed results suggest that households perceiving better CPFM are 23 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 less likely to plant trees. We note, however, that in the sample 82% of households plant trees, indicating a very widespread practice. Our results suggest that the existence of trees is primarily affected by wealth and market variables. Our results suggest that better social coordination between households dependent on common forests may have profound effects on individual household behaviors. Tree planting on-farm is one example and our findings broadly support those of others, including Nepal et al. (2007) and Mekonnen (forthcoming). A potentially important implication of this paper is for climate change initiatives related to forests, such as the United Nations Collaborative Programme on Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation in Developing Countries (REDD). Our findings indeed suggest that an important carbon benefit of better CPFM is more planting of on-farm trees. Little is known about such benefits, however. Indeed, several research questions remain. As the relationship between CPFM and on-farm tree planting is clarified, it is useful to evaluate whether relationships also exist with other technologies that could substitute for common forests. Such measures may include commercial fuels and improved agricultural inputs. Of perhaps critical importance to the long-term research agenda is to evaluate if, and under what circumstances, constraints imposed by reducing open access actually increase rural incomes. Evaluating policy instruments that increase rents and assure gains from better management reach all parts of households and societies is also critical. References Adhikari, B. 2002. “Property Rights and Natural Resources: Socio-economic Heterogeneity and Distributional Implications of Common Property Resource Management in Nepal.” Paper 24 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Presented at the 2nd World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, Monterey, CA, USA, June 24–27, 2002. Agrawal, A. 2007. “Forests, Governance, and Sustainability: Common Property Theory and Its Contributions,” International Journal of the Commons 1(1): 111–36. Agrawal, A. 2001. “Common Property Institutions and Sustainable Governance of Resources,” World Development 29 (10): 1649–72. Agrawal, A. 2000. “Sustainability on the Commons.” Paper presented at the “8th Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property,” Bloomington, IN, USA, May 30–June 4, 2000. Amacher G.S., W.F. Hyde, and K.R. Kanel.1999. “Nepali Fuelwood Production and Consumption: Regional and Household Distinctions, Substitution, and Successful Intervention,” Journal of Development Studies 35(4): 138–63. ———. 1996. “Household Fuelwood Demand and Supply in Nepal’s Tarai and Mid-Hills: Choice between Cash Outlays and Labor Opportunity,” World Development 24(11): 1725–36. Baland, J-M, P. Bardhan, S. Das, D. Mukharjee and R. Sarkar. Forthcoming. “The Environmental Impact of Poverty: Evidence from Firewood Collection in Rural Nepal,” Economic Development and Cultural Change. Baland, J.-M., and J.-P. Platteau. 1996. Halting Degradation of Natural Resources: Is There a Role for Rural Communities? Oxford: Clarendon Press. ———. 1999. “The Ambiguous Impact of Inequality on Local Resource Management,” World Development 27(5): 773–88. 25 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Bluffstone, R., M. Boscolo and R. Molina. 2008. “Does Better Common Property Forest Management Promote Behavioral Change? On-Farm Tree Planting in the Bolivian Andes,” Environment and Development Economics 13: 137–70. Bluffstone, R.A., M. Yesuf, B. Bushie, and D. Damite. 2007. “Rural Livelihoods, Poverty, and the Millennium Development Goals: Evidence from Ethiopian Survey Data.” RFF Discussion Paper EfD 08-07. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future and Environment for Development. Bromley, D.W. 1990. Essays on the Commons. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press. Cooke, P. 2004. “Community Forests and Private Tree Planting in the Hills of Nepal.” Mimeo. Pacific Lutheran University. Cooke, Priscilla. 2000. “Changes in Intrahousehold Labor Allocation to Environmental Goods Collection: A Case Study from Rural Nepal, 1982 and 1997.” IFPRI Discussion Paper, no. 87. Washington, DC: IFPRI. Cragg, J. 1971. “Some Statistical Models for Limited Dependent Variables with Applications to the Demand for Durable Goods,” Econometrica Vol. 39, 829 – 844. Dayton-Johnson, J. 2000. “Choosing Rules to Govern the Commons: A Model with Evidence from Mexico,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 42 (1): 19–41. Edmonds, E. 2002. “Government-Initiated Community Resource Management and Local Resource Extraction from Nepal’s Forests,” Journal of Development Economics 68: 89–115. EFAP (Ethiopian Forestry Action Program). 1994. The Challenge for Development. Vol. II. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia: EFAP. Field, B. 2001. Natural Resource Economics: An Introduction. Boston, MA, USA: McGraw Hill. 26 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Gordon, H.S. 1954. “The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery,” Journal of Political Economy 62(2): 124–42. Hardin, G. 1968, 1992. “The Tragedy of the Commons.” Originally published in Science 162 (3859): 1243–48 (DOI: 10.1126/science.162.3859.1243). Reprinted in Environmental Economics: A Reader, edited by A. Markandya and J. Richardson. London: Palgrave MacMillan. Hartwick, J.M., and N.D. Olewiler. 1998. The Economics of Natural Resource Use. New York: Addison-Wesley Educational Publishers. Hegan, R., G. Hauer, and M. Luckert. 2003. “Is the Tragedy of the Commons Likely? Factors Preventing the Dissipation of Fuelwood Rents in Zimbabwe,” Land Economics 79(2): 181–97. Heltberg, R. 2001. “Determinants and Impacts of Local Institutions for Common Resource Management,” Environment and Development Economics 6 (2): 183–208. Heltberg R., A. Arndt, and N.U. Sekhar. 2000. “Fuelwood Consumption and Forest Degradation: A Household Model for Domestic Energy Consumption in Rural India,” Land Economics 76(2). Jodha, N.S. 1986. “Common Property Resources and Rural Poor in Dry Regions of India,” Economic and Political Weekly 21(27): 1169–81. Kabubo-Mariara, J. and V. Linderhof. Forthcoming. “Tenure Security and Incentives for Sustainable Land Management: A Case Study from Kenya,” in Agricultural Productivity in East Africa: Investment, Sustainability and Poverty Reduction. R. Bluffstone and G. Köhlin eds. Resources for the Future Press, forthcoming 2010. Linde-Rahr, M. 2003. “Property Rights and Deforestation: The Choice of Fuelwood Source in Rural Vietnam,” Land Economics 79(2): 217–34. 27 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Mekonnen, A. 2009. “Tenure Security, Resource Endowments, and Tree Growing: Evidence from Rural Households in the Amhara Region of Ethiopia,” Land Economics (forthcoming). Mekonnen, A., and R. Bluffstone. 2008. “Policies to Increase Forest Cover in Ethiopia: Lessons from Economics and International Experience. In “Policies to Increase Forest Cover in Ethiopia,” edited by J. Bane, S. Nune, A. Mekonnen, and R. Bluffstone, proceedings of the Environmental Economics Policy Forum for Ethiopia forest policy workshop at the Ethiopian Development Research Institute, Addis Ababa, September 18-19, 2007. Nepal, M., A. Bohara, and R. Berrens. 2007. “The Impact of Social Networks and Household Forest Conservation Efforts in Rural Nepal,” Land Economics 83(2): 174–91. Nyangena, W. Forthcoming. “The Role of Social Capital in Sustainable Development: An Analysis of Soil Conservation in Rural Kenya,” in Agricultural Productivity in East Africa: Investment, Sustainability and Poverty Reduction. R. Bluffstone and G. Köhlin eds. Resources for the Future Press, forthcoming 2010. Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA, USA: Harvard University Press. Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press. Platteau, J., and A. Abraham. 2002. “Participatory Development in the Presence of Endogenous Community Imperfections,” Journal of Development Studies 39(2): 104–36. Sethi, R., and E. Somanathan. 1996. “The Evolution of Social Norms in Common Property Resource Use,” American Economic Review 86(4): 766–88. Tumcha, B. 2004. “The Vision of Ministry of Agriculture on Natural Resources of Ethiopia by 2025.” In Proceedings of the Public Meetings on Integrated Forest Policy Development in Ethiopia, 28 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 edited by Seyoum Mengistou and Negussu Aklilu, 1-11. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia: Forum for Environment and Interchurch Organization for Development Cooperation. Wade, R. 1988. “Village Republics: Economic Conditions for Collective Action in South India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. World Bank. 2005. The Little Green Data Book. Washington, DC: World Bank. 29 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 1 Descriptive Statistics on Tree Growing Variable label Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Grows trees 0.82 0.39 0 1 Grows eucalyptus trees 0.70 0.46 0 1 Number of trees grown 241.38 492.58 0 4011 Number of eucalyptus trees grown 196.95 459.84 0 3950 Table 2 Definitions and Descriptive Statistics of CPFM Indices. All indicesi [0,1] as per (9). Unless noted, survey answers coded such that (5=definitely, 1=definitely not) Overall Common Property Index (CPFMINDEX) X =0.39, σ = 0.20 Institutional Characteristics Sub-Index (INSTICHAR) X = 0.41, σ =.22 Management Tools Sub-Index (MGTOOLS) X = 0.37, σ = 0.15 SPECIFIC SUB-INDICES MAKING UP EACH SUB-INDEX AND ASSOCIATED SURVEY QUESTIONS CLARITY OF FOREST ACCESS INDEX X = 0.33, σ=0.21 *Is the system that determines who is allowed to gather forest products clear and understandable? FAIRNESS IINDEX X = 0.43, σ = 0.30 * Do you feel you and others can take the amount of forest products that is needed, but not more? * Are you get enough forest products to meet your needs, but not more? PARTICIPATION & DEMOCRACY INDEX X = 0.49, σ = 0.29 * Do you have influence on policies for deciding how much forest products people can take? *Do you help decide who are the managers of the forest? * Do you expect that in the future you will have the opportunity to manage the common forest? * Are the managers democratically chosen? CLARITY OF QUOTA INDEX X = 0.21, σ= 0.24 * Are you allocated a fixed allotment of fuelwood per year? * Are you allocated a fixed allotment of fodder and grazing rights per year? MONITORING INDEX X = 0.53, σ = 0.34 * Do village authorities carefully monitor who takes what products? * Do villagers generally watch who takes forest products? * Are you either formally or informally involved in monitoring common forest lands? FORMAL PENALTIES INDEX X = 0.52, σ = 0.33 * If you took more fuelwood from the forest than you were allowed to take would you be penalized? * If you took more fodder from the forest than you were allowed to take would you be penalized? * Could you lose some or all of your rights to collect forest products if you were caught taking more than your allotment? SOCIAL SANCTION INDEX X = 0.58, σ= 0.35 * Would other villagers be very unhappy with you if they found that you had taken more than your allotment? * Would you be embarrassed or feel bad if you took more than your allotment of forest products? 30 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 LABOR INPUT INDEX X = 0.02, σ = 0.05 All coding below (0, 1, 2, 3,>3 days during past month) * Number of days planting common forests * Number of days watering common forests * Number of days thinning common forests * Number of days fertilizing common forests Table 3 Correlation between Site Dummies and CPFM Indices (p-values in parentheses) Site Amanuel D. Elias Kebi Wolkie Telma Sekladebir Godguadit Adismender Chorisa Management tools index Institutional characteristics index 0.141 0.0728 0.1596 (0.0000) (0.0267) (0.0000) -0.0464 -0.1470 0.0423 (0.1671) (0.0000) (0.1776) -0.0996 -0.1577 -0.0315 (0.003) (0.0000) (0.3159) 0.1449 0.1304 0.1481 (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) -0.0167 0.0537 -0.0703 (0.6197) (0.1024) (0.0248) -0.352 -0.3492 -0.3098 (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) -0.1189 -0.038 -0.1565 (0.0004) (0.2474) (0.0001) -0.0046 0.0423 -0.0409 (0.8915) (0.1989) (0.1925) 0.2253 0.2588 0.1585 (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) 0.0862 0.1066 0.0691 (0.0101) (0.0012) (0.0275) CPFM index Adisgulit 31 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 4 Correlation between Aggregated and Disaggregated CPFM Indices Overall CPFM Overall CPFM Institutional characteristics Labor requirements Sanction Penalty Monitoring Clarity of quota Participation and democracy Fairness Clarity of access Institutional characteristics Labor requirements Sanction Penalty Monitoring Clarity of quota Participation and democracy Fairness Clarity of access 1 0.93 Management tools Management tools 1 (0.00) 0.94 0.77 (0.00) (0.00) 0.70 0.72 0.62 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 0.79 0.93 0.57 0.58 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 0.84 0.96 0.64 0.67 0.96 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 0.93 0.86 0.89 0.65 0.73 0.75 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 0.73 0.73 0.63 0.64 0.56 0.69 0.51 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 0.88 0.70 0.95 0.49 0.52 0.56 0.88 0.48 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 0.82 0.62 0.91 0.52 0.40 0.49 0.74 0.60 0.80 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 0.95 0.84 0.94 0.74 0.68 0.76 0.84 0.73 0.84 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0.80 1 (0.00) * p-values in parentheses; predicted values of indices used. 32 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 5 Descriptive Statistics for Covariates, Expected Sign and Reason for Including in Models of Tree-Growing Variable label Mean Std. Dev. Min Expected Sign and Reason for Including Max EXOGENOUS COVARIATES Wealth Endowments – with imperfect credit markets, own wealth finances trees Land size in hectares (LANDSIZ) 1.15 1.02 0 6.02 Corrugated roof (1 if yes) (CRRGTHS) 0.77 0.42 0 1 Livestock in TLU (tropical livestock units) (LIVESTOK) 3.84 3.25 0 31.19 Gave loan in last year (1 if yes) (givenloan) 0.10 0.29 0 1 (+) Wealth indicator; complements trees (+) Wealth indicator (+) Wealth effect; animals fed by trees (+) Indicator of liquidity Labor Endowments – labor complements trees, but investing in on-farm trees saves labor Family size (FAMSIZE) 5.48 2.18 1 15 (+/-) Labor complement or substitute Fraction of boys (6–14 years) (FRACTIONBOYS) 0.15 0.15 0 0.67 (+) Higher dependency incents labor saving Fraction of girls (6–14 years) (FRACTIONGIRLS) 0.14 0.15 0 0.75 (+) Higher dependency incents labor saving Fraction of female adults (>14 years) (FRACTIONFEMAD) 0.32 0.19 0 1 Fraction of male adults (>14 years) (FRACTIONMALAD) 0.31 0.19 0 1 (+/-) Labor complement or substitute (+/-) Labor complement or substitute Human Capital – education and experience may complement trees Max. years of education of household members (MAXEDUCHH) 5.14 3.71 0 16 Gender of head (1 if male) (HEADSEX) 0.83 0.38 0 1 51.05 14.87 20 97 0.81 2.21 0 12 Age of head in years (HEADAGE) Years of education of head (HEADEDUC) (+) Education (+/-) (+) Experience (+) Education Market Access – trees may be planted for sale and therefore proximity may increase planting Walking distance to town in minutes (DISTTOWN) 82.76 58.32 0 280 (-) Market access Walking distance to road in minutes (DISTROAD) 38.42 37.25 0 180 (-) Transport costs Land Tenure – trees are long-term investments and are therefore promoted by tenure security Believes the land belongs to household (OWNSLAND) 0.44 0.50 0 1 (+) Expects to lose land in next 5 years (1 if yes) (EXPLNSZ5YRS) 0.19 0.39 0 1 (-) Information – tree planting often requires silvacultural and market information to be successful Trusts people in village (TRUSTGOT) 0.67 0.47 0 1 (+) Trust encourages information search 33 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Number of visits by extension agent (NUMDAVISIT) 0.94 1.32 0 4 Farmer to farmer extension (1 if yes) (FARMERTOFARMER) 0.36 0.48 0 1 (+) Extension agents offer silvacultural info. (+) Technological Substitute – improved stove reduces wood consumption and substitutes for trees on-farm Uses improved stove (1 if yes) (IMPROVEDSTOVE) (-) 0.20 0.40 0 1 EXCLUDED EXOGENOUS VARIABLES – EXPECTED RELATIONSHIP IS WITH CPFM VARIABLES Village-Level Survey Woreda* numerical indicator (WOREDA) N/A Village Population density (POPDENSITY) 2.79 2.21 .55 8.78 Kebele-level forest management dummy (KEBELEMGT) .513 .500 0 1 (+) Lower-level administration of forests reduces transactions costs Community forestry dummy (COMMUNITYFOREST) 0.79 0.41 0 1 (+) Forest perceived as community forest easier to coordinate 20.66 12.26 0 78 ? Location fixed effects. (+) Higher population density encourages social coordination Household-Level Survey Years respondent in village (YEARS) (+) More years in village improves knowledge of norms and increases perception of coordination * Woreda is an administrative district that is roughly comparable to a county. 34 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 7 Dependent Variable Number of Trees. Ordinary Least Squares with Kebele Clustering Model 1 CPFMINDEX Model 2 Model 3 235.2 (156.2) INSTICHAR 459.4*** (129.3) MGTOOLS 146.0 (176.4) OWNSLAND LANDSIZ CRRGTHS LIVESTOK GIVENLOAN FRACTIONBOYS FRACTIONGIRLS FRACTIONFEMAD FRACTIONMALAD FAMSIZE MAXEDUCHH HEADSEX HEADAGE 27.41 27.34 27.92 (43.48) (43.71) (44.03) 35.92 28.56 37.63 (39.53) (38.60) (38.19) 13.54 10.17 14.29 (30.88) (29.74) (31.32) 39.88** 39.42** 39.94** (12.73) (12.57) (12.76) 11.17 8.813 13.29 (68.29) (67.57) (70.63) 187.3 197.4 185.2 (138.8) (136.1) (141.3) 371.4* 384.7* 367.7* (176.5) (175.3) (180.3) 204.7 223.2 199.1 (133.6) (133.9) (138.7) 59.45 81.69 54.41 (78.55) (71.95) (79.96) 13.21 13.54 13.30 (13.16) (13.01) (13.31) 0.548 0.347 0.619 (4.979) (4.934) (4.994) 13.46 13.71 13.72 (47.87) (47.32) (47.82) 1.649 1.610 1.658 (1.556) (1.564) (1.562) 35 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 HEADEDUC 11.31 11.46 11.17 (8.317) (8.376) (8.294) -0.00549 -0.0797 0.0387 (0.385) (0.362) (0.424) -0.0747 -0.0997 -0.0818 (0.345) (0.347) (0.338) 21.59 24.66 20.26 (45.61) (44.57) (43.98) 20.14 19.76 19.84 (49.06) (48.70) (49.12) 17.61 20.67 16.35 (20.78) (20.46) (19.66) 33.67 38.38 31.45 (36.14) (36.53) (35.64) 55.83 52.98 57.85 (50.22) (49.80) (49.55) -446.3*** -542.2*** -412.0*** (110.5) (123.1) (102.0) Observations 1,080 1,080 1,080 R-squared 0.116 0.120 0.116 DISTTOWN DISTROAD EXPLNSZ5YRS TRUSTGOT NUMDAVISIT FARMERTOFARMER IMPROVEDSTOVE CONSTANT Unless otherwise noted, robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Kebele is often translated as “peasant association” and includes several village settlements 36 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 8 First Stage Regression (OLS with Kebele Clustering) Dependent Variables → Overall CPFM Index Institutional Characteristics Management Tools Index 0.0219** 0.0170* 0.0248*** (0.00718) (0.00875) (0.00592) -0.0157 -0.00846 -0.0209* (0.00987) (0.00926) (0.00966) -0.0226** -0.0165 -0.0259*** (0.00768) (0.00999) (0.00621) 0.000773 0.00203 -1.21e-06 (0.00126) (0.00174) (0.000935) 0.0335*** 0.0282*** 0.0323*** (0.00778) (0.00629) (0.00923) -0.0181* -0.0247* -0.00988 (0.00913) (0.0119) (0.00950) -0.0243** -0.0297** -0.0171 (0.00971) (0.0112) (0.0113) -0.0347* -0.0509** -0.0139 (0.0171) (0.0194) (0.0183) -0.0105 -0.0332 0.0104 (0.0251) (0.0298) (0.0220) 0.00587** 0.00435* 0.00634** (0.00212) (0.00209) (0.00211) 0.000419 0.000880 0.000345 (0.000746) (0.00111) (0.000599) 0.000355 -0.00167 0.00356 (0.00598) (0.00639) (0.00577) 0.000234** 0.000331** 0.000140 (8.20e-05) (0.000113) (8.16e-05) 0.000435 0.000118 0.000864* (0.000420) (0.000462) (0.000389) 1.30e-05 -0.000109 0.000155 (0.000124) (0.000168) (9.79e-05) Exogenous Covariates OWNSLAND LANDSIZ CRRGTHS LIVESTOK GIVENLOAN FRACTIONBOYS FRACTIONGIRLS FRACTIONFEMAD FRACTIONMALAD FAMSIZE MAXEDUCHH HEADSEX HEADAGE HEADEDUC DISTTOWN 37 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 DISTROAD 0.000126 0.000427** -0.000101 (0.000227) (0.000174) (0.000280) -0.0164** -0.0125* -0.0176** (0.00637) (0.00666) (0.00569) 0.00661*** 0.00975*** 0.00333 (0.00189) (0.00258) (0.00190) -0.00894*** -0.0106*** -0.00674*** (0.00184) (0.00204) (0.00201) -0.00867 -0.0110 -0.00698 (0.00517) (0.00628) (0.00444) 0.0121** 0.0121*** 0.0106** (0.00411) (0.00343) (0.00429) -0.00583 -0.00413 0.00518 (0.00893) (0.00804) (0.00874) 0.0184 0.0179 0.0166 (0.0106) (0.0101) (0.00911) 0.122** 0.136** 0.131** (0.0429) (0.0449) (0.0422) 0.00120*** 0.000900** 0.00127*** (0.000312) (0.000305) (0.000299) 0.0708 0.0638 0.0712 (0.0606) (0.0595) (0.0615) 0.211** 0.231*** 0.150* (0.0759) (0.0674) (0.0774) Observations 1,106 1,106 1,106 R-squared 0.57 0.56 0.65 EXPLNSZ5YRS TRUSTGOT NUMDAVISIT FARMERTOFARMER IMPROVEDSTOVE Excluded Exogenous Variables WOREDA POPDENSITY KEBELEMGT YEARS COMMUNITYFOREST CONSTANT Unless otherwise noted, robust standard errors in parentheses ** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Kebele is often translated as “peasant association” and includes several village settlements 38 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 9 Dependent Variable is Number of Trees Planted by Households. IV GMM Estimates Marginal Effects Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Endogenous Variables CPFMINDEX 875.7*** (251.0) INSTICHAR 813.1*** (231.7) MGTOOLS 869.5*** (246.4) Exogenous Covariates OWNSLAND LANDSIZ CRRGTHS LIVESTOK GIVENLOAN FRACTIONBOYS FRACTIONGIRLS FRACTIONFEMAD FRACTIONMALAD FAMSIZE MAXEDUCHH HEADSEX 26.25 28.99 26.49 (33.05) (32.85) (33.02) 31.01 27.23 37.52 (28.59) (28.72) (27.90) 15.05 8.138 24.73 (31.09) (30.35) (31.62) 37.79*** 36.17*** 36.29*** (9.850) (9.677) (9.860) 13.79 19.49 4.047 (66.62) (66.35) (67.20) 229.1* 237.0* 230.4* (137.1) (136.7) (137.4) 441.0*** 450.1*** 447.3*** (170.8) (170.3) (171.5) 211.9 238.5* 194.7 (135.5) (135.2) (135.5) 88.49 125.6 52.20 (141.1) (141.4) (140.5) 1.726 3.947 -2.160 (13.55) (13.58) (13.49) 2.663 2.613 2.648 (6.144) (6.127) (6.151) 16.05 17.63 26.65 (42.10) (41.63) (41.89) 39 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 HEADAGE HEADEDUC DISTTOWN DISTROAD EXPLNSZ5YRS TRUSTGOT NUMDAVISIT FARMERTOFARMER IMPROVEDSTOVE CONSTANT Observations 0.996 0.853 0.950 (1.098) (1.084) (1.102) 9.609 9.295 8.708 (8.423) (8.380) (8.426) -0.444 -0.299 -0.500 (0.337) (0.313) (0.344) 0.484 0.213 0.670 (0.503) (0.484) (0.522) 50.93 42.87 57.49 (41.61) (41.27) (41.97) 23.64 23.09 26.80 (34.48) (34.33) (34.61) 23.73 23.25 20.29 (16.17) (16.06) (16.14) 34.56 37.14 27.75 (41.09) (40.74) (41.51) 45.83 47.77 54.59 (45.74) (45.50) (45.91) -627.6*** -635.1*** -595.2*** (183.8) (184.2) (178.0) 1,080 1,080 1,080 Goodness of Fit Tests R-squared 0.106 Wald Χ (22) 2 93.55 (p = 0.000) 0.115 *** 94.25 (p = 0.000) 0.101 *** 93.15 (p = 0.000) *** Exogeneity Tests GMM C Statistic Χ2 (1) 13.776 (p = 0.000) *** 5.959 (p = 0.015) ** 19.071 (p = 0.00) *** Overidentifying Restriction Tests Hansen’s J Χ2 (4) 3.929 (p = 0.416) 4.036 (p =0.401) 3.584 (p = 0.4652) Weak Instrument Tests F Test F(5, 1053) = 165.86 F(5, 1053) = 182.32 (p = 0.000) *** (p = 0.000) *** F( 5, 1053) = 203.89 (p = 0.000) *** Unless otherwise noted, robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Kebele is often translated as “peasant association” and includes several village settlements 40 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 11 Dependent Variable Number of Trees. Negative Binomial Regression Marginal Effects Endogenous Variables (Predicted Values Used) CPFMINDEX 1000.053** (453.7) 925.7307** INSTICHAR (388.99) 897.9774** MGTOOLS (375.63) Exogenous Covariates OWNSLAND LANDSIZ CRRGTHS LIVESTOK GIVENLOAN FRACTIONBOYS FRACTIONGIRLS FRACTIONFEMAD FRACTIONMALAD FAMSIZE MAXEDUCHH HEADSEX -1.911566 6.672677 -3.45183 (39.635) (35.916) (35.891) 33.18507** 25.63066 34.93438** (16.478) (18.279) (16.444) 63.01478* 56.53123* 62.59852** (34.634) (32.033 ) (30.628) 16.32231*** 15.67822*** 17.45322*** (5.75394) (5.29226) (6.27335) -51.14181* -44.0903 -48.6115* (27.35) (31.675) (29.109) 316.5914* 321.9054* 326.2179* (184.71) (173.28) (184.17) 499.898*** 500.9367*** 512.0168*** (189.2) (176.82 ) (197.42) 240.7476 251.8902* 222.8084 (160.47) (154.14) (138.1) 189.7823 214.7518* 178.0077 (140.03) (131) (146.36) -1.612992 0.374738 -2.36674 (4.56769) (4.76142) (5.44339) 9.772137*** 9.367929*** 10.1945*** (2.7289) (3.06867) (3.24048) 46.79797 47.64126 43.62842 41 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 HEADAGE HEADEDUC DISTTOWN DISTROAD EXPLNSZ5YRS TRUSTGOT NUMDAVISIT FARMERTOFARMER IMPROVEDSTOVE CONSTANT Wald Χ2 Goodness of Fit Χ2 Observations (37.047) (39.067) (33.884) 1.500204 1.53426 1.621104* (1.00233) (1.0603) (0.98168) 5.049276 5.385478 4.270956 (6.29778) (6.58252) (5.33613) -0.3154592 -0.16609 -0.31176 (0.34221) (0.39111) (0.51431) 0.2991159 -0.05067 0.566199 (0.53443) (0.44664) (0.5121) 34.4642 28.96023 39.47187 (22.101) (19.704) (24.666) 18.62002 15.64525 16.08052 (32.841) (30.5120 (31.201) 22.31148 22.67942 20.51303 (16.576) (15.036) (13.202) 42.58449 45.42149* 38.42002 (31.376) (25.724) (29.882) 22.16745 25.05938 28.35921 (29.175) (28.529 ) (32.395) 0.340 0.342 0.533 (0.8520) (0.7760 (0.704) Χ2 (22) = 1467 Χ2 (22) = 2030 Χ2 (22) = 1696 Prob > Χ2 = 0.00 Prob > Χ2 = 0.00 Prob > Χ2 = 0.00 Χ2 (1057) = 52055 Χ2 (1057) = 517552 Χ2 (1057) = 52195 Prob > Χ2 = 0.00 Prob > Χ2 = 0.00 Prob > Χ2 = 0.00 1,080 1,080 1,080 Robust Bootstrapped (100 Repetition) Standard Errors Adjusted for Kebele Clustering.; Kebele is often translated as “peasant association” and includes several village settlements Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 42 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Table 12 Dependent Variable Number of Trees. Heckman Selection Model Marginal Effects Endogenous Variables (Predicted Values Used) CPFMINDEX 1,179*** (318.1) MGTOOLS 1,103*** (332.1) INSTICHAR 1,004*** (323.3) Exogenous Covariates OWNSLAND LANDSIZ CRRGTHS LIVESTOK GIVENLOAN FRACTIONBOYS FRACTIONGIRLS FRACTIONFEMAD FRACTIONMALAD FAMSIZE MAXEDUCHH HEADSEX HEADAGE 32.91 40.83 29.21 (42.67) (49.61) (42.86) 26.38 17.22 31.27 (38.68) (33.46) (30.71) 43.10 34.54 49.16 (38.44) (42.99) (46.65) 38.18*** 36.95*** 38.79*** (13.63) (11.81) (12.33) -31.05 -21.37 -27.36 (81.82) (69.88) (84.53) 291.0 299.9* 284.4 (187.6) (171.2) (177.7) 532.5** 538.1** 526.5** (229.9) (216.0) (238.1) 326.2* 348.0** 302.3* (180.0) (166.9) (170.4) 173.1 206.8 146.9 (193.4) (186.7) (187.5) 12.80 15.48 12.24 (19.08) (17.96) (18.84) -1.754 -2.222 -1.117 (8.156) (6.915) (7.591) 16.52 19.88 18.52 (54.68) (55.81) (64.09) 0.954 0.937 1.041 43 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 (1.618) (1.280) (1.567) 15.72 15.92* 14.91 (11.61) (9.091) (11.98) -0.657* -0.482 -0.591 (0.397) (0.342) (0.363) 0.529 0.127 0.738 (0.629) (0.630) (0.565) 35.16 29.21 35.33 (56.76) (53.66) (56.81) 8.500 5.692 9.902 (36.66) (38.98) (41.42) 26.90 27.31 23.43 (19.53) (21.18) (21.39) 37.70 39.48 30.81 (52.67) (44.15) (52.37) 32.83 34.94 42.57 (51.82) (51.04) (50.67) -4.472e+10* -4.489e+10** -5.018e+10** (2.470e+10) (2.192e+10) (2.221e+10) -812.1*** -819.8*** -745.8*** (252.2) (217.5) (245.4) HEADEDUC DISTTOWN DISTROAD EXPLNSZ5YRS TRUSTGOT NUMDAVISIT FARMERTOFARMER IMPROVEDSTOVE INVERSE MILLS RATIO CONSTANT Observations Wald Χ 2 1,080 1,080 1,080 Χ (22) = 94.48 Χ (22) = 90.70 Χ (22) = 108.84 Prob > Χ2 = 0.000 Prob > Χ2 = 0.000 Prob > Χ2 = 0.000 2 2 2 Robust, Bootstrapped (100 Repetition) Standard Errors Adjusted for Kebele Clustering.; Kebele is often translated as “peasant association” and includes several village settlements Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 44 | P a g e Draft – Not for Citation. Comments Welcome. October 25, 2010 Endnotes i Because it is now recognized that it is not the common nature of resources but the openness of access that causes the tragedy, in modern terminology, it would be referred to as the tragedy of open access. ii Food and Agricultural Organization, http://www.fao.org/forestry/site/countryinfo/en/. iii This model is based on, but extends the theoretical treatment in Bluffstone et al (2008). Such behavior is sometimes described as “myopic,” but this label does not seem appropriate given the constraints. iv v This parsimonious arrangement, where we particularly abstract from the details of food production, is done in the interest of focusing on our variables of interest. vi This approach is taken merely for convenience. Formulating constraints on forest extractions would be equivalent. vii Surveys in 2000, 2002, and 2005 of the same households showed that eucalyptus trees were the most important trees in terms of number of households growing and trees grown (see Mekonnen [forthcoming]). viii In all models the propensity score specification satisfies the balancing property. ix As tree leaves may be an important source of fodder for animals, we test for exogeneity of animal stocks to the tree planting decision. In no models, however, can we reject exogeneity. Animals are therefore treated as exogenous. x Mean and median Spearman correlations between excluded exogenous variables and the number of trees are 0.06 and 0.08. 45 | P a g e