William Pettigrew Corpus Christi College, Oxford (Please do not cite, quote, or circulate, without the written permission of the author: William.Pettigrew@ccc.ox.ac.uk). Debating the ‘National Interest’: Some Under Appreciated Connections between Constitutional Change and National Economic Growth in England, 1660 - 1720 Celia Fiennes’ journeys around England in the 1690s provide one of the earliest, comprehensive descriptions of England’s national economy at work. For Fiennes, forming an ‘Idea of England’ at a time when the nation’s economic landscapes were changing was ‘requisite’ especially for ‘those that serve in Parliament’. Informing ‘themselves ye nature of Land, ye Genius of the Inhabitants’ would assist MPs in what Fiennes believed to be their primary role: ‘to promote and improve Manufacture and Trade suitable to each and encourage all projects tending thereto.”1 Fiennes imagined a national economy and expected the post-1688 Parliament to work to expand that economy. Few historians of the period between the Civil War and the Industrial Revolution have shared Fiennes’ expectation of an instrumental relationship between Parliament and economic growth. This essay seeks to place political and constitutional changes at the centre of Britain’s 18th century economic growth by examining the economic consequences of passing the initiative for state regulation of the economy from the Privy Council to Parliament. It connects this altered regulatory mechanism to the changing structure and pattern of economic growth in this period. Several economic historians have charted the growth of Britain’s national economy during this period. Deane and Cole’s influential account charted a 200% increase in the size of Britain’s economy between 1688 and 1770, at a time when the national population increased by just 57%. Others have supported this view.2 Although Dean and Cole’s narrative begins in 1688, a year typically highlighted in political and constitutional rather than economic histories, the ‘Glorious Revolution’ played no part in their discussion. Deane and Cole, however, explained their concentration on economics by referring to the primacy of observation over explanation in economic history.3 Such observation, can only offer a starting-point for the historian, whose principle concern is with causation. Here the economic history of 18th century national economic growth fails to deliver. In asserting the importance of economic theory as an explanatory device, economic historians fail to appreciate how historically specific such theory is and how economic activity, especially at the macro-economic level, has always been embedded within institutional frameworks that exhibit an important political aspect.4 Economic historians’ views of the nexus between political 1 Barbara Korte, English Travel Writing From Pilgrimages to Postcolonial Explorations (New York, 2000), 32 2 N F R Crafts, ‘British Economic Growth, 1700 – 1831: A Review of the Evidence’, The Economic History Review, New Series, Vol. 36, no 2, (May 1983), 177-199 3 Phyllis Deane and W A Cole, British Economic Growth, 1688 – 1959: Trends and Structures (Cambridge, 1962), 39 4 See Karl Polyani, The Great Transformation (Boston, 1957).Even economic historians sensitive to political factors downplay the importance of constitutional change. William Cunningham dismissed any effect of constitutions on the economy see William Cunningham, Politics and Economics An Essay on the Nature of the Principles of Political Economy (London, 1885), 48 1 institutions and the market range from those who deny its existence to those who characterise politics as epiphenomenal or chaotic, or ‘interrupting’, ‘polluting’ or ‘frictional’ within economic systems.5 Economic historians typically view economic liberalism as a determinant of political liberalism.6 The relationship between constitutional change at the turn of the 18th century and economic growth in the 18th century at least complicates this view and comes close to suggesting a reversed formulation. Historians of politics have also tended not to examine the economic effects of constitutional change. Attributing some connection between the Glorious Revolution and economic growth would seem intuitive according to the assumptions of Whig history, that great celebration of politics. Like economic history, Whig history assumes progress; narrates in a linear, teleological fashion, and subscribes to a timeless notion of human nature; but Whig historians did not implicate constitutional changes in their accounts of economic growth. Whig historians’ desire to fetishise all things political instead led them to brand economic phenomena as predictable. Thomas Macaulay, the most eloquent of Whig historians and rarely one to downplay the importance of political phenomena, described England’s economic growth as an organic and spontaneous process that had often been jeopardised by the intrusions of government: “…profuse expenditure, heavy taxation, absurd commercial restrictions, corrupt tribunals, disastrous wars, seditions, persecutions, conflagrations, inundations, have not been able to destroy capital so fast as the exertions of private of private citizens have been able to create it. …in our own land, the national wealth has, during at least six centuries, been almost uninterruptedly increasing; This progress, became at length, about the middle of the 18th century, portentously rapid, and has proceeded, during the nineteenth, with accelerated velocity. In consequence, partly of our geographical and partly of our moral position, we have, during several generations, been exempt from evils which have elsewhere impeded the efforts and destroyed the fruits of industry.”7 Whig history’s ambitions for politics did not extend to demonstrating how economic outcomes hinged on political changes. Instead political influences on the economy remained ‘evils’ to be guarded against. Historians of the 17th and 18th century Parliaments have, keen to deviate from Whiggish interpretations, concentrated on the content of disputes within the chambers; as well as Parliamentary personnel and procedure. These historians have rightly conceived of Parliament as a group of individuals responding to different 5 Some scholars have underestimated the importance of politics to economic growth: see N S Buchanan and H S Ellis, Approaches to Economic Development, (New York, 1955), 407: “…the really substantive barriers to development are mainly noneconomic…” 6 Typically, the converse argument has been advanced – that economic growth has assisted political liberty. For two similar arguments see Milton Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom (Chicago, 1982) and John Millar, The Advancement of Manufactures, Commerce and the Arts; and the Tendency of this Advancement to diffuse a Spirit of Liberty and Independence (London, 1849, second ed.) col. 1, 279280 2 concerns at different times. Few historians have considered Parliament as a constitutional form whose changing status within the English constitution during the second half of the 17th century had macro-economic ramifications. These concerns have, perhaps unsurprisingly, remained the prerogative of political scientists and economists themselves.8 Those economists (rather than economic historians) who have sought to trace economic growth back to celebrated political milestones, especially the Glorious Revolution, have, however, committed the related historiographical sins of national exceptionalism and linearity. Douglass North and Barry Weingast argued, in a hugely cited article, that the key to British power in the modern era lay in the Glorious Revolution’s cementing of property rights. The ‘sovereignty of Parliament’ prevented the monarch from arbitrarily trampling upon its subjects’ economic interests.9 This greater security for the economy helped to lower the national rate of interest, which stimulated economic growth over the 18th century.10 For North and Weingast, the national economic significance of Parliament after 1688 lay in its foiling previous monarch’s rights to default on state loans. The creation of the Bank of England by statute and the representation of its creditors in Parliament and that Parliament’s socalled ‘sovereignty’ within the state’s regulatory apparatus created an environment in which the macro-economic benefits of a credit-based economy could be enjoyed. The Glorious Revolution has become the founding myth for a new breed of Whig economist historians whose broader historiographical targets connect them to a 8 Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson usefully distinguished between policies and institutions. See Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (Cambridge, 2006), 177 and 218: “Institutions matter because they influence the future allocation of de jure political power; political actors wish to control and change institutions because they want to lock in their current political power.” And 350: “The outcome of the 17th-century conflicts in Britain [sic] was a set of economic institutions that gave property rights to a broad set of people. The result was the ending of the Malthusian cycle and the beginning of modern economic growth.” See also Adam Przeworski, ‘Political Regimes and Economic growth’, in Journal of Economic Perspectives, (1993) and Francesco Giavazzi and Guido Tabellini ‘Economic and Political Liberalizations’ (Centre for Economic Policy Research, No. 4579, 2004) and Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini, ‘Democratic Capital: The Nexus of Political and Economic Change’ (Centre for Economic Policy Research, No 5654, May 2006) 9 See Edmund Burke, Reflections on the Revolution in France, (London, 1793) and Thomas Macaulay, History of England (London, 1906) and then Douglass North and Barry Weingast, ‘Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England’, Journal of Economic History, vol. 49, no 4, (1989). For a thesis that argues how democratisation protects property rights see also Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge, 1990), 51. Acemoglu, Robinson, and Simon Johnson offer a reworking of North and Winegast’s argument in ‘The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth’, The American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 3, 546-575. See also North and Robert Paul Thomas, The Rise of the Western World A New Economic History (Cambridge, 1973), 154 and Gregory Clark, ‘The Political Foundations of Modern Economic Growth: England, 1540-1800’, Journal of Interdisciplinary History, vol. 26, no. 4, (Spring, 1996), 563 -588. Clark noted the ‘Whiggishness’ of North’s position and how property rights had been secured earlier in the 17 th century and that growth did not derive from 1688 (in land values or return on capital). Clark did not examine trade growth, however, or changing regulatory regimes. For a more historical treatment of these issues and their connection to the ‘Glorious Revolution’ see Bruce Carruthers, ‘Politics, Popery and Property: a Comment on North and Weingast, Journal of Economic History, vol. 50, 693-98. 10 Others argued that North and Weingast’s argument could only be sustained in reference to the emergence of a party system that predated the Glorious Revolution. See Bruce Carruthers, City of Capital (Princeton, 1996) and then David Stasavage, Public Debt and the Birth of the Democratic State (Cambridge, 2003). Stasavage noted how commercial classes did not dominate Parliament. The party system played a part in unifying commercial interests with the landed Whig magnates to ensure that those who lent the government money could use Parliament to ensure that those debts would be repaid. 3 nationalistic and occasionally culturally supercilious ‘rise of the West’ tradition.11 For economists, who often regard the premises of economic theory as timeless and universal, political institutions have too often provided a prop for exceptionalist narratives.12 The desire to attribute a similarly fixed constitutional form to the events of the late 1680s and 1690s as political scientists can more satisfactorily attribute to the United States constitution and the convention that led to it has encouraged these ‘New Institutional Economists’ to deploy a simplistic historical narrative to explain the superior economic performance of ‘Western’ states with reference to constitutional forms.13 Similarly, political scientists have sought, as so many economists and deductive thinkers have with reference to historical phenomena, to lift constitutional ideal types out of their historical contexts and have them solve the problems facing contemporary developing economies.14 Their belief in the inevitable, linear relationship between certain constitutional forms and certain beneficial economic outcomes has idealised constitutional change and removed contingency from the historical narrative. The Glorious Revolution formed a part of a much longer process of political and economic change and its implications, as historians have long known, were not always liberalising and ‘Whiggish’. Similar accusations of linearity and idealisation can be levelled at historians of early capitalist ideology and economic thought in the 17th and early 18th centuries.15 These historians of liberalism have typically expressed caution about the Glorious Revolution as a reforming moment, preferring to concentrate on a reaction against liberal economic thought based on that thought’s socially levelling implications and a hardening of economic restrictions as the power of the state increased in the early years of the 18th century and the political and economic nexus became more and more oligarchic in implication. In doing so, their accounts become collapsible into the rhetoric of the country party opposition ideology of the first half of the 18th century and they have become apologists for liberalism. Such historians have sought merely to test the progressive implications of Whig narratives without, with the exception of John Brewer, formulating new, non-Whiggish means, of analysing the period. These historians of ideology have not sought to test the connections between that ideology and institutional changes’ whose structural impact can be more easily documented. Any attempt to reduce the economic thinking of the period into a catchall ideology runs profound interpretive risks.16 Donald Coleman and Tim Keirn have understood how Parliamentary pamphleteering on economic matters in this period sought to 11 See Paul Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers (New York, 1989) For the problem of historical specificity in economic history see Geoffrey Hodgson, How Economics Forgot History: The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science (London, 2001) 13 This process may have been inspired by Charles Beard’s analysis of the economic rationales for the United States constitution. See Charles Beard, An Economic Interpretation of the Constitution of the United States (New York, 2004) 14 Though one economist who stresses the importance of political freedoms to economic development does not dabble in history in an unhelpful way: Amartya Sen, Development as Freedom, (Oxford 1999) 15 See Joyce Appleby, Economic Thought and Ideology in 17 th Century England (Princeton, 1978) and George Cherry, ‘The Development of the English Free-Trade Movement in Parliament, 1689-1702’, Journal of Modern History, vol. 25, no. 2 (1953) and Steven Pincus, ‘Neither Machiavellian Moment Nor Possessive Individualism: Commercial Society and the Defenders of the English Commonwealth’, The American Historical Review, vol. 103, no. 3, (1998) and Robert Ekelund and Robert Tollison, Politicised Economies (Texas, 1997) 16 Here I am quietly referring to mercantilism and the ideas of Eli Hecksher in Mercantilism (London, 1934) 12 4 weigh up the respective merits of discrete policy proposals from the state or from individuals.17 Economic historians have, however, long lampooned the principles of mercantilists as erroneous and have therefore assumed that any economic growth before Adam Smith must derive from forces beyond human control. But Parliamentary pamphleteers fixated on schemes that would generate economic growth without the need to speculate about theory. Historians ought to take them more seriously. The current literature on economic growth and constitutional change is, then, either subjected to the unfortunate intellectual apartheid that separates both political and economic history and history from political science, political economy, and economics or it remains restrained by a series of reductive dichotomies in which the narrative is either Whiggish of non-Whiggish18; the state is either regulating or deregulating, protectionist or free trade, reactive to private interests or unresponsive.19 Faced with these fault lines in the literature, this essay attempts to formulate a more agile conceptual framework in which I shelve the polarities of the literature and the economic aspects of statecraft are judged as contemporaries increasingly judged them: according to their ability to deliver national economic growth, as crucial components of what pamphleteers called ‘the national interest’. The primacy of Parliament as the regulator of the burgeoning national economy after 1688 assisted the realisation of this national interest. With their inadequacies in mind, but inspired by the ambition, range, and eloquence of all the historians I have cited, I seek to propose a new means to approach the political and economic history of this period, without collapsing all into a discreet political turning point – ‘the Glorious Revolution’; and focusing on the interactions between political and economic change.20 This approach will celebrate the Whig historians’ commitment to a broad field of view, as well as the efficaciousness of human agency, volition, and, indeed, intention via the political process, without resorting to the Whigs’ presentist and exceptionalist ideological concerns about liberal capitalism as the potential nails in historical enquiry’s coffin.21 This approach admits the timelessness of economic rationality at the micro-economic 17 See Donald Coleman (ed.), Revisions in Mercantilism (London, 1969) and Davison, Lee, Hitchcock, Tim, Keirn, Tim, and Shoemaker, Robert, eds., Stilling the Grumbling Hive (Stroud, 1992) 18 One exception is: John Brewer, Sinews of Power (London, 1989) is a challenge to the Whig interpretation. Political scientist Charles Tilly reached this conclusion before Brewer, in fairness. 80: One school of thought about democratisation is that of Charles Tilly, Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990 - 1990 (Oxford, 1990), which saw the origins of democracy in the process of state formation and connected the rise of representative institutions to the monarch’s need to raise funds via taxation. 19 For the debate about whether the English state could be categorised as either regulating or deregulating see J P Cooper, ‘Economic Regulation and the Cloth Industry in 17th-Century England’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 5th series, vol. 20 (1970), 73-99. Cooper’s final verdict was appeared on page 99: “The English state was highly centralised in its control over its finances and their administration and in part of the administration of justice; it was both too strong and too weak to pursue either centralised regulation or laissez faire in its domestic economic and social policies.” Julian Hoppit characterised issues before Parliament as problems to be solved. This view underestimates the extent to which Parliament could act as an organ of government see Hoppit, ‘Patterns of Parliamentary Legislation, 1660-1800’, The Historical Journal, vol. 39, no 1, (March 1996), 109- 13; esp. 116 and 130 20 An ambitious and successful attempt to bring these literatures together appears in Rocco Pezzimenti, Politics and Economics: An Essay on the Genesis of Economic Development (Leominster, 2004) 21 See Francis Fukuyama, The End of History and the Last Man (London, 1992) 5 level but will assume the contingency of macro-economic growth to the vagaries of political phenomena.22 This paper offers a preliminary and exploratory account of some of the ways in which the rising importance of Parliament changed Britain’s national economy. It concentrates on a single problem – the economic consequences of the constitutional changes often fallaciously labelled: ‘Parliamentary sovereignty’. It will examine that problem’s political and economic aspects: first, what were the economic connotations of political reform and, conversely, what were the political determinants of economic growth at the turn of the 18th century in England? We have excellent studies of post 1688 state-building, party systems, financial, and commercial revolutions. But we have no real appreciation of how that pillar of the Whig theory of history, the socalled sovereignty of Parliament, affected the evolution of the British economy. When it comes to assessing the economic implications of the Glorious Revolution, the sovereign Parliament makes an unlikely elephant in the room. Unlike North and Weingast, I consider the ways in which the post-1688 Parliament enfranchised and expanded new economic interests. The phrase ‘Parliamentary sovereignty’ is often deployed to describe the situation in England after 1688 in which the King and Parliament shared sovereignty.23 The phrase nevertheless captures the legislature’s improved power within the constitution after 1688: the Bill of Rights’ presumed power to dictate to William III that the monarch could no longer overrule statutes; but, as important, the Parliament’s control of the monarch’s wealth and spending. In no real sense, however, was Parliament sovereign within England’s constitution after 1688. The need for an executive branch of the constitution was rarely doubted and Parliament was not tolerated to act as a sovereign, arbitrary power.24 Older executive institutions did not die out. Although Parliament began to meet every year after 1688, the monarch retained the right to dissolve its meetings. The King’s Privy Council continued to meet regularly and the King’s courts continued to administer justice. In this period, the executive expanded its powers perhaps more dramatically than the legislative. The treasury and the cabinet provide the two most important institutional expressions of the expansion of executive control. Prior to 1688 (and to a lesser extent afterwards) Parliament appealed to the Privy Council to help resolve issues that had become too complex and because Parliament’s more deliberative format prevented a sound judgement on the Examples of success with this approach are multiple. See especially, F Kearney, ‘The Political Background to English Mercantilism, 1695 – 1700’, Economic History Review, 2nd series, vol. 11, no 3, 1959. I seek, in this essay, to formulate an over-arching argument that suggests smaller case studies. This approach is similar to that adopted by O Brien et al in Patrick O’Brien, Trevor Griffiths, Philip Hunt, ‘Political Components of the Industrial Revolution: Parliament and the English Cotton Textile Industry, 1660 – 1774’, The Economic History Review, New Series, Vol. 44, no 3, (Aug, 1991), 395423 23 For a clear denial of the existence of Parliamentary sovereignty in this period see Frederick Maitland, The Constitutional History of England: A Course of Lectures (Cambridge, 1950). Much of the overstatement about Parliamentary sovereignty derives from a mistaken belief of the practical importance of Locke’s Two Treatises 24 In 1689, Parliament experimented with a new constitutional form: an executive body supported by statute and designed to enforce a traditional state prohibition on the export of wool. But its failure proves that Parliamentary sovereignty was regarded as a form of Parliamentary dictatorship that the Protectorate had helped to discredit. See Robert Lees, “The Constitutional Importance of the ‘Commissioners for Wool” of 1689. An Administrative Experiment of the Reign of William III.” Economica, No. 40. (May 1933), 147-168 22 6 issue.25 The Privy Council met throughout the year. Despite having to meet regularly and for longer stretches of time, the Parliamentary calendar prevented it from being in a position to respond to economic grievances and suggestions throughout the year. The King in Council often responded to requests for proclamations to regulate the economy once bills to the same affect had failed and the Parliamentary session had ended.26 Interested parties often turned to the Privy Council to help enforce statute. Prior to 1688, nearly one fifth of Royal Proclamations about the economy sought to support statutory regulations.27 Nonetheless, Parliament began, after 1688 to gain more experience of the business of government to add to its traditional remits as a vehicle of representation and as a forum for the execution of justice. In the national economic sphere, Parliament’s significance grew. Parliamentary statutes began to compete more successfully with Privy Council orders and Royal Proclamations as state-sponsored means to regulate the national economy.28 From the Restoration to the arrival of William III, the Privy Council issued on average 4 royal proclamations about the economy a year. By the 1690s, however, the Privy Council began to concentrate on routine business to do with the Channel Islands, as well as some judicial and personnel issues, leaving the business of macro-economic regulation largely to Parliament. Accordingly, from 1689 to 1714 the average annual number of royal proclamations concerning the economy reduced to less than 1. By the early 18th century, the Privy Council focused on ships passes, judicial disputes in the colonies, and personnel and probate issues and almost abandoned its traditional control over economic regulation. Much of the Privy Council’s withdrawal from national economic concerns in this period has to do with the career of its sub-committee on commercial matters - the Lords of Trade and Plantations. Founded in 1675, the Lords of Trade, was designed to assist in enforcing the Navigation Acts and impose Royal government on the proprietary and charter governments. As a committee of the Privy Council, the Lords of Trade could ‘command the respect, attendance, or opinion’ of the Admiralty and 25 See records of the Privy Council, The National Archives, Kew (herafter PC), PC/56 1662-64, 15 October 1662, fol. 170, regarding Lindsey Level: “The Board taking into Consideration an Order of the House of Commons in Parliament of the 19th May last (this day…his Majestie present in Councill) whereby the said Houses did humbly recommend to his Majesty that the preservation of the Levell of the fenns called Lindsey Levell, and made it their humble Request to his Majestie to give himselfe the trouble to call all parties…before him and to hear their severall Claymes and Interests and that his Majesty be attended with the Votes, and Report of the said House relateing to that businesse.” 26 PC/64 1673-4, April 18, 1673, fol. 8 27 This reduced to a fifth after 1688. See also Clayton Roberts, ‘Privy Council Schemes and Ministerial Responsibility in Later Stuart England’ American Historical Review, Vol. 64, No. 3 (April, 1959), 564582 28 I use the same definition of economic to qualify legislative acts and petitions as that used by M R Julian. It includes all public economic bills and private bills whose impact could be felt across the economy such as transport and infrastructure bills. Estate and private naturalisation bills have been excluded. See M R Julian, English Economic Legislation 1660 – 1714, (London School of Economics, M Phil thesis, 1979), 175.I derive information about legislative attempts in Parliament from Julian Hoppit (ed.), Failed Legislation, (London, 1997) and information about Royal Proclamations from R Steele, A Bibliography of Royal Proclamations of the Tudor and Stuart Sovereigns, 1485 – 1714, vol. 1 England and Wales, (Oxford, 1910). PC/64 1673-4, 7 July 1675, fol. 461- petition of the Tanners to continue a statute to allow the export of leather. Some scholars of state regulation of the economy have been too quick to assume a zero-sum relationship between Privy Council attempts to regulate and Parliamentary attempts. See especially R W K Hinton, ‘The Decline of Parliamentary Government under Elizabeth I and the Early Stuarts’, Cambridge Historical Journal, vol. 13, (1957), 116-32 7 Treasury.29 From 1696, the reformed Board of Trade, without access to the constitutional means to act unilaterally, became an information gathering body. Although it had been designed to preserve the monarch’s traditional control over overseas trade revenues, the Board became almost from its inception, effectively a sub-committee of the House of Commons, which regularly called upon the Board’s commissioners, many of whom were MPs, to write reports and present them to the House and its various committees.30 When the Board attempted to initiate reform, as with regards to its proposed reform of the Poor Law in the 1690s, the legislature refused to cooperate.31 The Treasury and Parliament habitually ignored the board’s suggestions about customs duties before the board’s commissioners began to cease to make such recommendations. As the Privy Council disengaged from economic regulation, Parliament became more heavily involved. Parliament achieved 4 economic statutes on average per year from 1660 to 1688 and 11 per year after the Glorious Revolution and before 1714. Before the Glorious Revolution, the Privy Council, via Royal Proclamations maintained, on average, a 68% control over state attempts to influence the national economy. After 1688, that proportion of control had reduced to just 7% (at a time when the average yearly total state attempts to influence the national economy increased by 54% across the periods 1660 – 1688 to 1689 – 1713). The increased number of Parliamentary statutes accounts for the majority of this increase in state interest in the national economy (yearly averages of statutes either side of the Glorious Revolution increased by 166% while the decrease in proclamations was 79%). The success rate of legislative attempts in Parliament also improved. All legislative attempts benefited from an improved success rate after 1688 from 20% between 1660 and 1688 to 50% from 1689 to 1714. The success rate of economic initiatives, according to my own definition, was less impressive, but nevertheless improved from 22% to 36%. The constitutional changes traditionally associated with the Glorious Revolution altered how the English state regulated its economy. ‘Parliamentary supremacy’ perhaps better conveys Parliament’s changed status within the English constitution than ‘Parliamentary sovereignty’. The supremacy of statute and Parliament in economic matters was matched by changes in Parliamentary personnel and procedure. An increased proportion of MPs came from commercial backgrounds, echoing a belief that merchants ought to control commercial policy. The percentages of members of Parliament who were merchants increased from 3.7 per cent in the period from 1660 to 1690 to 7.9 per cent between 1690 and 1715.32 The increased participation of merchants in the Parliamentary process after 1688 confirms the extent to which merchants wished to serve as political representatives of their markets and how they increasingly viewed the state via 29 See Ian Steele, The Politics of Colonial Policy, (Oxford, 1968), 9, 125 see also Robert Lees ‘Parliament and the Proposal for a Council of Trade 1695/6’, English Historical Review, Vol. 54, No. 213, (Jan 1939), 38-66 30 In many instances, the Board of Trade appears to have gathered information for Commons inquiries on the basis of which the Commons, rather than the Board, made decisions. See CO389/23 ff. 256-266 (May 14, 1713) see also ff. 272-286. 31 In relation to the Board’s attempt to reform the poor law in the 1690s, J P Cooper concluded: “The prospect of informed collaboration between Commons and the executive failed.” See Cooper, ‘Economic Regulation and the Cloth Industry in 17th-Century England’, 96 32 For growing mercantile interest in Parliament in this period see Perry Gauci, The Politics of Trade, (Oxford, 2001), 197 8 Parliament as a means to protect and enlarge their economic concerns.33 The House also began to take trade business more seriously. A 1703 ruling dictated ‘no bill relating to trade or the alteration of laws concerning trade be brought into the House until the proposition shall have been first examined and debated in the grand committee for trade, and agreed unto by the House.’ Between 1690 and 1702, committees of the whole house heard 20 per cent of commercial bills. By Anne’s reign the percentage had improved to 57 per cent.34 Plotting Parliament’s increased interest in the economy begs the question: interest in what economy? Such an increase could be explained by a spontaneous increase in the size of the economy that was the cause rather than the result of state intervention. This is to some extent true, for the economy did not wait for state interventions before it could function. But, increased state interest in the economy did not result in a decreasing economic growth. The state had always maintained an interest in the economy. Indeed, economics and politics were inseparable to the early 18th century policy-maker.35 Such classical economic motifs as ‘economic man’ who naturally trucked and bartered describe a timeless human instinct, but were the invention of the late 17th and 18th century. A decreasing proportion of these state enactments about the economy prohibited or regulated trade in a conventional sense and many more stimulated new trades in new areas of the economy or assisted in deregulating other trades completely. An ‘economic state of nature’ had to be invented to make such enactments more palatable. Pamphleteers had to make the case that free trade represented some kind of primordial, default setting for the economy.36 Policy makers, in short, had to be convinced of the merits of deregulation. The growing economic importance of Parliament helped to realise the old idea of a national economy, which was based upon old statutes, especially the Statute of Artificers; balance of trade conceptions of national and international trade; royal proclamations; a national coinage depicting national insignia. From the middle ages, the king’s sovereignty included not only the kingdom’s resources but also his subject’s economic opportunity. Both could be purchased (along with the right to regulate town economies via borough corporations) and the proceeds helped to prevent monarchical reliance on Parliament.37 The Civil Wars of the mid-17th century demonstrated that the monarchy could not retain the national economy as its personal demesne. The House of Commons ensured that the beneficiaries of national economic growth would also be nationally politically enfranchised. The long established link between the House of Commons and the national tax base assisted the understanding that representation increasingly offered a means for individuals not only to protect their economic interests but also to advance those interests. This understanding began to produce dramatic macro-economic affects by the 1690s as Parliament either made 33 For the numbers of these merchants directly involved in the Africa trade debates in Parliament and for changes in political culture that saw merchants engage more with the political process and the changed relationship between politics and economics that this records, William Pettigrew, ‘Free to Enslave: Politics and the Escalation of Britain’s Transatlantic Slave Trade, 1688 – 1714’, William and Mary Quarterly, 3rd series, vol. 64, no. 1, (2007) 34 For the 1703 ruling see Gauci, The Politics of Trade, 227 35 This need not make ‘economic’ legislative actions distinguishable with hindsight 36 I offer a case study concerning the slave trade below to illustrate this 37 Further discussion of the emergence of national economy see Joyce Appleby “Ideology and theory: The Tension between Political and Economic Liberalism in 17th-Century England” AHR, LXXXI, (1976), 504 9 attempts to regulate the national economy more enforceable or offered its representatives the opportunity to sustain lobbying campaigns to deregulate areas of the economy. Within Parliament, the institutional expression of a national economy, there emerged an intellectual construction that summarised the bridges between the policy aims of the government and those Parliamentary lobbyists who increasingly sought to influence state involvement in the economy – the ‘national interest’. Pamphleteers invoked this expression to gain state approval for their proposals and to deflect accusations that their concerns did not extend beyond their own self-interest.38 The phrase came to embody a mixture of concerns: full employment, sufficient national income to sustain military campaigns abroad, and a favourable balance of trade. All of these concerns would be supported by the over-arching meaning of the phrase: national economic growth. Parliament offered the national interest its best constitutional buttress. Statute therefore became the state’s most important economic lever after the Glorious Revolution. Before 1688, Parliament worked alongside the royal prerogative and rulings from Privy Council to regulate the economy. After the arrival of William of Orange, the strengthened Parliament became the senior partner in the process of arbitrating on macro-economic concerns. As one foreign observer recorded of the mentality that informed this belief in the importance of Parliament as the most suitable regulator of the national economy at this time: “que les affaires n'y seraient jamais assez bien regles a moins que ce ne fut le parlement qui en eut la direction”.39 Echoing Celia Fiennes, other contemporaries made a connection between these political reforms and commercial improvements. Charles Davenant asked: “…why the care of liberty and preserving our civil rights should be so much recommended in a paper relating to trade we answer that …. If the wealth and power of a country depend upon good government and stability of its affairs, it must certainly import that all the different ranks of men contribute their utmost that things may be well administer’d.” 40 Davenant followed Machiavelli’s celebration of freedom and greatness that derived from empire. Nicholas Barbon agreed: “, … in England, where the government is not despotical; but the people free; and have as great a share in the sovereign legislative power, as the subjects of any state have, or ever had … and where the flourish of trade is as much the interest of the King as of the people, there can be no such cause of fear.”41 38 The conceptualisation of a national economy was also assisted by political arithmetic and the compilation of national economic statistics. See Mary Poovey, A History of the Modern Fact: Problems of Knowledge in the Sciences of Wealth and Society (Chicago, 1998), 126 39 A rough translation is: ‘Our affairs will never be well enough regulated unless Parliament has the direction’ Frederic Bonet, 13 January, 1696. Frederic Bonet was resident in London on behalf of the elector of Brandenburg. Bonet is quoted in Robert Lees, The Constitutional Importance of the ‘Commissioners of Wool’ of 1689’, 150 fn. 10 40 Charles Davenant, An Essay upon the Probable Methods of Making a People Gainers in the Balance of Trade, (2nd ed. London 1700), 17-18, 261-263 41 Nicholas Bardon, Discourse of Trade (London, 1690), 20 10 As early as the 1640s, Henry Parker believed that Parliamentary systems served to favour economic growth because they enfranchised the mercantile interest: “tis admirable to see what vast revenues are purchased by some nations (especially where democracy takes place) out of mere commerce; and how far other nations in the mean time (especially such as are swayed by monarchs) though more commodiously situated, and advantageously qualified, otherwise do neglect the same. The reason hereof may be, because in popular states the merchant usually has more administration of public affairs: whereas in monarchies, those that have the charge of the rudder, have commonly little insight into trade, and as little regard of traders.” 42 By the second half of the 18th century, this view received more sophisticated discussion. The Scottish political economist, John Millar wrote with the period after 1688 in England at the forefront of his mind: “By a constant attention to professional objects, the superior orders of mercantile people become quick-sighted in discerning their common interest, and, at all times, indefatigable in pursuing it. While the farmer, employed in the separate cultivation of his land, considers only his own individual profit; while the landed gentleman seeks only to procure a revenue sufficient for the supply of his own interest as well as of every other; the merchant, though he never overlooks his private advantage, is accustomed to connect his own gain with that of his brethren, and is, therefore, always ready to join with those of the same profession, in soliciting the aid of government, and in promoting general measures for the benefit of their trade. The prevalence of this great mercantile association in Britain, has, in the course of the present century, become gradually more and more conspicuous, The clamor and tumultuary proceedings of the populace in the great towns are capable of penetrating the inmost recesses of administration, of intimidating the boldest minister, and of displacing the most presumptuous favourite of the back stairs, The voice of the mercantile interest never fails to command the attention of government, and when firm and unanimous, is even able to control and direct the deliberation of the national councils.” 43 In the1670s, Thomas Sheridan, like Fiennes, saw Parliament as the merchants’ best platform: “Since then it [trade] is so necessary, it deserves the Parliament’s best care to restore it to what it has been, or make it what it should be.”44 For Locke in the Two Treaties on Government, the legislative branch of government provided the purest expression of popular consent and was, therefore the best vehicle for the societal protection of property. But all of these thinkers remained vague about the mechanics of this relationship. How did it operate?45 The rising importance of Parliament as state regulator of the economy formed a part of a larger change of political culture. This modern political culture had two hallmarks: first, adherents appealed to a political (but not party) ideology of natural rights synonymous with individual economic self-interest and offering a politico-economic bond between liberal economics and notions of government. Proponents regarded the individual’s right to pursue economic interests Henry Parker, Of a Free Trade (London, 1648), 3-4 see also Sir William Temple, ‘Essay on Government’ in The Works of Sir William Temple, (London, 1750),110 43 John Millar, ‘The Advancement of Manufactures, Commerce and the Arts; and the Tendency of this Advancement to diffuse a Spirit of Liberty and Independence’ in An Historical View of the English Government, From the Settlement of the Saxons in Britain to the Revolution in 1688, in four volumes, edited by Mark Salber Philips and Dale R. Smith, introduction by Mark Salber Philips (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2006) 44 Thomas Sheridan, A Discourse of the Rise and Power of Parliaments, (London, 1677), 182 45 Though Locke does not proceed to give many details of the mechanics of representation see J R Pole, Political Representation in England and the Origins of the American Republic (London, 1966) 42 11 as politically stabilising and a fundamental duty of government.46 Their political credo advanced their commercial interests and mapped economic concerns onto political methods. By articulating an ideology that celebrated the societal benefits of individual economic self-interest they yoked the cause of political liberalism to economic growth.47 Second, after the Glorious Revolution, political initiative diffused out into the market and, simultaneously and symbiotically, new interest groups buoyed by success in new, (often Atlantic), markets began to emerge, articulating this ‘ideology of interest’, and using reformed and more inclusive political institutions - such as the sovereign Parliament, which became the undisputed arbiter of macro-economic concerns.48 As a result, economic interests could be more efficiently furthered using political means. A comparison of the Privy Council and the Parliament’s mode of regulation helps to clarify the workings of this new political culture. Parliament was, by design, a public and consultative institution unlike the Privy Council, whose meetings were understood to be secret.49 Parliament listened to far more petitions than the Privy Council and its members would, after 1695, inform themselves about debates with the help of printed pamphlets to a much larger extent than the councillors. The Privy Council sometimes received counter-petitions and in Parliament, issues could often be thrown out without reason, but Parliament provided a more open forum, which allowed debate to be influenced by outside petitions and pamphlets.50 Historians have also seen the state’s accommodation of interest articulation as a source of political stability see John Plumb, The Growth of Political Stability in England, 1675 – 1725 (London, 1967), 13 47 The emergence of this political economy of ‘interest’ can be traced to earlier in the 17th century. Its fixation with economic self-interest need not, because of its novelty, deny its ideological character. Primarily conceived of within the political realm, it cannot be dismissed as the mere celebration of economic efficiency, which was itself a novel phenomenon. For the emergence of an ideology of interest in this period see John Gunn, Politics and the Public Interest in the 17th Century (London, 1969), 205-258 and ‘Interest Will not Lie: A 17th Century Political Maxim’, Journal of the History of Ideas, vol. 29. no. 4 (1968), 551–564 and Albert Hirschman, The Passions and the Interests (Princeton, 1977), 37 and more recently, Steve Pincus, ‘Neither Machiavellian Moment Nor Possessive Individualism: Commercial Society and the Defenders of the English Commonwealth’, American Historical Review, vol. 103, no. 3, (1998), 705–736. Not until the Wealth of Nations were economic interests described in terms of their pure macro-economic benefits. Evolving notions of individual interests combined with the mercantilist theory of international relations (referred to in contemporary pamphlets as the ‘national interest’) which assumed Machiavellian competition between nations for scarce resources - and prevented moral obiligations from transcending national boundaries - to enlarge the scale of the slave trade. See Felix Raab, The English Face of Machiavelli (London, 1964), 262. See also Jacob Viner, ‘The Nation State and Private Enterprise’ in Jacob Viner, Essays on the Intellectual History of Economics, (Princeton, 1991), 45. Mercantilist domestic policy did, however, stress the moral importance of full employment. 48 See Alison Gilbert Olson, Making the Empire Work (Cambridge, Mass, 1992), 51-75. 49 See Edward Raymond Turner, The Privy Council of England in the 17th and 18th Centuries, 1603 – 1784 (Baltmore, 1927), 398 50 William Cunningham regarded autocratic political institutions as better suited to regulation. See William Cunningham, The Growth of English Industry and Commerce in Modern Times Vol. 1: The Mercantile System (Of 2 Vols. Cambridge 1925, 6th ed), 19. While Privy Councillors regularly received bribes in the 17th century and before, bribing MPs or Parliamentary officials ran the risk of incurring increasingly severe penalties. The East India Company had secured government favour throughout the 1680s by gifting the monarch huge cash sums. In the 1690s, during Parliamentary discussions of the future of the company’s charter, the company’s payment to the Speaker of the House of Commons (along side other court officials) brought severe and costly reprisals for all concerned. Ekelund and Tollison have argued that the additional cost of lobbying Parliament dissuaded interest groups from seeking to sustain monopolies after 1688 and therefore played a part in deregulating the economy. See 46 12 Parliament’s more deliberative nature endowed attempts to regulate the national economy with the legitimising force of consent. The changed political culture that valued, at least at a rhetorical level, the value of consent supported the more deliberative aspects of Parliamentary procedure as a superior means to enforce statute.51 During this period, votes competed more successfully with pounds as a means to secure political influence, and, as the period went on, the more backers a proposal had (including the more signatories a petition had) the more seriously it was taken. 5253 The Privy Council system of regulation might provide more flexible and specific means to respond to changing economic conditions, but that conciliar response could not equal the more binding Parliamentary judgement that benefited from the input of consent. After 1660, and without Star Chamber Privy Council would always struggle to enforce its order. The shift of regulatory initiative from the Privy Council to Parliament allowed more people a say in defining the national interest. And the more people involved, the greater the economic impact. As the barrister, Batholomew Shower, explained, Parliament was better placed to oversee state regulation of the economy: ‘because each subject’s vote is included in whatsoever is there done: an Act of Parliament hath the consent of many men, both past, present, and to come.’54 Such restrictions were, needless to say, often thwarted, but Parliament proved more effective at enforcing these restrictive statutes because in the context of a more deliberative political system, disadvantaged merchants could use political rather than economic means to make their views felt, what Albert Hischmann famously characterised as ‘voice’ rather than ‘exit’.55 Unlike the Privy Council, appealing to Parliament did not bring the appellant face-toface with government, but against a process of mediation, which involved government. The importance of the distinction between government and the discussion of government was widely held and applied to the role of Parliament. The supremacy of Parliament therefore allowed a platform for groups determined to wrest open cosy relationships between the government and particular economic interests who owed their position to bribes. Rather than lessening in number, after 1688, as other historians have claimed, commercial lobbies increased in number, Robert Ekelund and Robert Tollison, Mercantilism as a Rent Seeking Society: Economic Regulation in Historical Perspective (Texas, 1981), 149. See also Robert McCormick and Robert Tollison, “Wealth Transfers in a Representative Democracy”: in J M Buchanan, Robert Tollison and Gordon Tullock (eds.) , Toward A Theory of The Rent –Seeking Society (Texas, 1980) 51 For the idea that consent made regulations easier to enforce see George Philips, Lex Parliamentaria (Second ed., London, 1734). Despite their deliberative and consensual traditions commentators did not associate consent with the Privy Council or with the monarchy. See John Philip Reid, The Concept of Representation in the Age of the American Revolution, (Chicago, 1989) , 25. See also Paul Langford, ‘Property and Virtual Representation in 18th Century England’, The Historical Journal, vol. 31,1,(1988113: “One of the clear gains to Government in the eighteenth century was that so much anxiety and odium which attached to the use of central power to bring about local change was diverted from the king and his ministers to Parliamentarians in one way or another accountable to their electors and their communities.” 52 See M R Julian, English Economic Legislation, 1660-1714 (M.Phil Thesis, London School of Economics, 1979), 20 53 See Keirn et al, Stilling the Grumbling Hive, 15 54 Shower’s argument is in The English Reports (London, 1900-1932), vol. 89, 498 [1 Show. K.B., 137] 55 Albert Hirschman, Exit, Voice, and Loyalty (Cambridge, Mass., 1970) 13 sophistication, and tenacity. Parliament formally enfranchised every constituency in the country, while the Privy Council favoured metropolitan interests. The larger scale of Parliament in comparison to Privy Council, and the longer hours, and larger number of people, helped to produce solutions that made a superior claim to be based on national consent than the unilateral quality and metropolitan focus of the Privy Council’s decision-making. These commercial lobbyists made their views felt via petitions (and sometime by appearing before Parliament in person). Petitions provide the best example of a constitutional means to connect the ‘freedom’ of a political society and its economic growth. Petitions (as celebrated in the Bill of Rights) and instructions to each of the Privy Council and Parliament, institutions did not always represent the interests they claimed to, but they derived, on the whole, from non-governmental sources. But their use became, alongside Parliamentary statutes, a celebrated aspect of the English political system and civil liberty.56 One Whig Grandee, John Somers, viewed petitioning as the best expression of the people’s appreciation of government’s power as a derivation of their consent: John Somers’ Jura Populi Anglicani pamphlet justifying the right to petition added: ‘Wherever therefore any Government is established there the natural Right which People had to secure what was their own, must be so far at least continued, as to allow them a liberty to Petition for what they think their right, because this is a Priviledge which they could not give up, when they enter’d into Society.’57 Parliament became the more important venue for appeals to influence the state’s decisions about the nation’s economy. Before the 1690s, the Court and (to a lesser extent) the Privy Council, with its executive powers, had provided a forum for petitioning about economic matters. In 1660, 77% of all petitions to do with the economy were addressed to the King.58 In 1696, that number had fallen to 12%. Parliament, and especially the House of Commons became the majority recipient of petitions to do with economic matters. In 1660, the House of Commons received just 6% of such petitions. By 1713 its share had risen to 92%. A rising number of these petitions concerned economic matters. At a time when the total numbers of petitions to the House of Commons increased from 60 in 1660 to 118 in 1713, the percentage of those petitions concerning economic matters increased from 8 per cent in 1660 to 55% in 1713. We see a rise in the number, ambitions, and effectiveness of lobbying groups in this period. In 1660, 1 per cent of petitions to Parliament came from commercial interest groups. By 1696, this proportion had increased to 18% and increased again to 35% in 1713. In 1660, about a quarter of all petitions to do with the economy came from commercial lobbies. By 1713, this figure 56 In my analysis of the Privy Council, I have self-consciously limited myself to petitions, there are other instruments of assertion: letters, ‘informations’, requests, and propositions with distinct purposes. We have a series of studies on the form and significance of petitions (but not for this precise period and not for commerce, though see David Zaret ‘Petitions and the ‘Invention’ of Public Opinion in the English Revolution’, American Journal of Sociology, vol. 101, no. 6, (1996)), but we don’t have a study of their incidence over this period. 57 [John Somers?], Jura Populi Anglicani: or, the subjects right of petitioning set forth.. Occasioned by the case of the Kentish petitioners… (London, 1701), 33 58 I compiled these lists of economic petitions from Journals of the House of Commons, (London, 1803) and the Journals of the House of Lords, (London, 1770) 14 exceeded 70%. Atlantic merchants dominated the crusades against several restrictive overseas monopoly companies. Used to deregulated markets, these merchants used their wealth, and the politically decentralised British Atlantic polity to help wrest open these monopolies.59 The less unilateral, more inclusive style of regulation that Parliament exhibited influenced patterns of economic legislation. The regulatory primacy of Parliament enfranchised provincial interest groups, which led to a rising proportion of regulatory enactments with local origins and affects. 93% of the proclamations in this period made stipulations about the national economy, whereas only 62% of statutes did. Statute began to account for more national enactments after 1689 improving its share from 43 to 91%. The success rate of local initiatives improved from 29% to 46%. Among these regional interests, attempts to develop local economic infrastructure predominated. Statute proved to be a more popular means to develop infrastructure such as roads, highways, and the reclamation of marshland. Nearly a third (29%) of all statutes in this period attempted these kinds of projects in comparison to just 6% of Royal Proclamations. Again, statutory enactments that sought to use Parliament’s prestige to back infrastructural projects increased from 7% to 24%. While those to do with engineering projects improved from 21 to 45%. Infrastructural projects experienced an overall improvement of 22% to 44%. Those to establish new projects improved from 14% to 48%. These successes speak to the ways in which local lobbying concerns had to improve their lobbying acumen and to the manner in which Parliament provided a superior means to represent local interests. Such schemes had, with less frequency, been handled by the king, by the Privy Council, by local institutions (each local Commission of Sewers), and by the Parliaments of the 1660s, 70s, and 80s. It was not until after 1688, that schemes to navigate the nation’s rivers and improve the nation’s roads began to appear in large numbers. Parliamentary statutes provided the best means to manage and enforce these schemes without incurring the kinds of local opposition that had inhibited them before 1688. The regulatory primacy of Parliament seems to have particularly encouraged provincial river navigations, whose proponents may not have been in a position to deliberate with Privy Councillors. One commentator surmised that “the Parliament seems well disposed” to river navigation.60 Fifteen statutes aiding river navigations, improvements to harbours, and the formation of turnpike trusts to develop the nation’s road network appeared between 1660 and 1689. Between 1690 and 1719, that number almost quadrupled to 59. Navigation schemes were not without their opponents. In the period after 1688, however, the success rate of such schemes improved. Attempts to legislate river navigation and highway construction enjoyed a success rate that improved from 22% to 42% across the two periods. In 1660, the kingdom boasted 685 miles of navigable rivers. By the 1720s, according to Defoe, that figure had risen to 1160 miles.61 The scheme’s 59 For a fuller discussion of the Atlantic dimensions of these debates see William Pettigrew, Free to Enslave. Gilbert Heathcote and Edmund Harrison also lobbied against the Royal African Company and the Russian Company. Samuel Shepherd, John Cary, Robert Atwood, John Lloyd, Nathaniel Gould, and Joseph Martin also lobbied against the Russia Company 60 See S Willan River Navigation in England, 1600-1750 (London, 1964), 30 61 Willan, 133 15 backers in Parliament based their case on the need for cheaper carriage of goods. River transportation proved far less expensive than road transportation, especially for heavy cargoes such as coal and iron. Houghton argued that by 1700, it was possible to carry goods 300 miles by river for 10p what would cost 3 shillings by road.62 Statutes to build roads increased in number and as a percentage of all statutes from 7 (or 6% in the first period) to 38 (or 13%) in the second period. Legislative proposals relating to highways showed a particularly impressive improvement in success rate: from 26% to 62% across the two periods. Statute’s tried-and-tested ability to countenance national monopolies after the Glorious Revolution assisted the formation of independent turnpike trusts who could, after a 1691 statute, levy rates to support road repair.63 By 1706 statutes enabled turnpike trusts to levy tolls to maintain the roads that replaced the parish levies that had singularly failed to support and develop Britain’s network of roads.64 They demonstrate how Parliament bestowed powers of local administration and finance in response to the courting of local interests, in a way that would have been inconceivable and unenforceable via the Privy Council.65 Their enactments helped to lower the cost of the transportation of goods throughout the national economy. One observer stated that the establishment of turnpikes in the early 18th century had lowered the cost of carriage by 30%.66 Road transportation became more efficient. Fewer animals were now required to pull larger weights.67 The shift from Privy Council to Parliamentary regulation of the economy encouraged local interests to lobby the legislature to acquire state authority to develop their respective local economies. The rise of Parliament also assisted the development of Britain’s overseas trade economy. While 41% of the Royal Proclamations in this period explicitly sought to prohibit some aspect of trade, just 8% of statutes had the same ambition. Prohibitions had represented nearly a third (29%) of all attempts at regulation between 1660 and 1688, they accounted for just 7% from 1689 to 1714. With regards to statutes concerning overseas trade, prohibitions accounted for 14% in the second period, a drop from 36% in the former period. Measures relating to overseas trade showed an increased success rate of from 25 to 40%. With those measures attempted to prohibit overseas trade experiencing a deteriorating success rate from 41% to 22%. Economic proposals to use statute to prohibit trade (whether overseas or domestic) witnessed a reduction in their success rate: from 77% before the Glorious Revolution to 22% afterwards. Instead, Parliament supported statutory attempts to ‘encourage’ trade (24%). These ‘encouraging’ statutes often lent statutory force to deregulate markets that had previously been tightly regulated. This changing pattern of legislation greatly altered the structure and output of the British economy. After 1689 Parliament authorised free export of cloth ending a 62 Willian, 119 See 3 William and Mary c. 12 64 See 6 Anne c. 4 65 For the belief that fen drainage in the 18th Century was made easier by having to appeal to Parliament rather than the Privy Council see Paul Langford, ‘Property and Virtual Representation in 18th Century England’, The Historical Journal, vol. 31,1,(1988), 83-115 66 Quoted in William Albert, The Turnpike Road System in England, 1663-1840, (Cambridge, 1972), 180. See also Daniel Bogart, ‘Turnpike Trusts and the Transportation Revolution in Eighteenth Century England’, Explorations in Economic History, 42, (October, 2005), 479-508 67 Albert, 181 63 16 centuries long prohibition.68 Advocates of this policy argued that this statute would assist national economic growth. Edward Ward stated in the House of Lords that: “This general freedom for all persons to export freely will greatly advantage the kingdom.” The long-established Merchant Adventurers Company had its monopoly over cloth trading formally deregulated. Parliament worked to ensure that this deregulation sustained. In 1700, Parliament freed cloth exports from customs duties, the Aulnage, entirely.69 Parliament also liberated the internal trade of hides in 1689.70 Further pressure groups lobbied for the deregulation of the production and exporting of copper, and mundic metals.71 Similarly in 1694, Parliament permitted the free export of English iron and copper to any country except France. This, again, overturned a tendency for preventing the export of English iron that had been supported by Parliamentary statute since the middle ages.72 Other trades followed suit. In 1689, a Parliamentary statute removed the customs duty on corn exports. 73 This policy hugely increased the nation’s production of wheat and other grains by enlarging the scale of both markets.74 Parliament also deregulated the production and trades of brandy, aqua vitae, spirits and bacon75 and salt manufacturing.76 Statutes also created free markets at billingsgate77 and prohibited frauds in the buying and selling of cattle at Smithfield.78 Such was the enthusiasm with which MPs countenanced the deregulation of multiple markets that a pamphleteer in 1694 could speak of ‘the present vogue of free trade’.79 Much of this initiative derived from interest group activity, as with the rising incidence of infrastructure projects. Joint-stock monopoly companies were also victimised by commercial lobbyists. These companies had been protected assiduously by royal proclamation. 80 A pamphlet described how a petition detailing how the African Company’s monopoly restricted the Suffolk woollen trade was submitted to ‘the King and Council’ in the 1680s, ‘but the Duke of York being president of this Company, no redress could be had.’81 A longstanding opponent of the African Company, Edward Littleton, explained that the company benefited, prior to 1688, from the support of ‘some great Men … with whom we were not able to contend.’82 One of these great men was James, then Duke of York, who was the company’s Governor and its most assiduous political supporter. In this way, the shift from a 68 1 Williamm and Mary, c. 23 11 William III c. 20 70 See L A Clarkson, ‘English Economic Policy in the 16th and 17th Centuries: The Case of the Leather Industry, Bulletin of the Institute of Historical Research, XXXVIII (1965) no. 98, 158. For the liberation of the domestic trade in hides see Cherry, Free Trade Movement in Parliament. For the 1689 quote see Journals of the House of Commons (London, 1803, hereafter CJ), vol. 10, 52. 71 see Cherry, 112. See also Statutes of the Realm, (London, 1820), vol. 6, 481 72 See 5 and 6 William and Mary c. 17 73 For an eloquent, compelling, but simplified account see Christopher Hill, The Century of Revolution, 1603 – 1714 (Second ed. London, 1980). See also CJ, vol. 10, 103 and Cherry, 113 74 See Donald Barnes, A History of the English Corn Laws, 1660 – 1846, (New York, 1961), 15 75 See Journals of the House of Lords (London, 1770), vol. 15, 351 76 Statutes, 10, 144 77 Statutes, 7, 513-14 78 Statutes, 10, 291 79 [Anon] The Interest of England Considered in an essay Upon Wool, (London, 1694) 80 PC/64 June 17, 1674, fol. 245 regarding the Merchant Adventurers and 4 November 1674, fol. 299 regarding the Governor and Company of the New Rover Water 81 Roger Coke, Reflections upon the East-Indy and Royal African Companies with Animadversions, Concerning the Naturalization of Foreigners, (1695), 10 82 Edward Littleton, The Groans of the Plantations (1689), 6 69 17 conciliar to legislative arbitration of economic affairs greatly aided those who sought to deregulate overseas trading monopolies. The Glorious Revolution undermined the royal prerogative to the extent that merchants who, before 1688, traded in markets monopolised by monarchicallysponsored charter companies, could successfully argue in court that those charters had been undermined by the flight of James II and that, therefore, they ought to receive compensation for the seizure of their trading goods. The outcome of court cases such as that against the Royal African Company, Nightingale vs. Brydges compelled the directors of joint stock monopoly companies to appeal to Parliament for statutory support for their charters.83 The glorious revolution forced monopoly companies to justify their trading record before a Parliamentary audience that had understood the growth implications of deregulation. Opponents of monopoly introduced the idea that a trade could grow if more traders permitted to trade. Those that did not pass the test had their charters relaxed to allow more traders to participate, without jeopardising the future of their respective trades by complete deregulation. The Privy Council scarcely ever countenanced such deregulation. Arguments in favour of free trade to a large extent derived from constitutional arguments associated with the rise of Parliament with the fall of arbitrary restrictions on the economy. The great onslaughts of commercial lobbies against the London overseas trading companies accounted for nearly a third of all mercantile petitions in this period.84 Such companies had been protected by Privy Council orders that supported their royal charters. Prior to 1688, Parliament preferred to shunt discussion about the future of monopoly companies back to the Privy Council or to the courts (as with the Bermuda Company, whose monopoly ended in 1684 after a quo warranto hearing85). But after 1688, Parliament reached a conclusion about the futures of each of the monopoly companies. In reference to the East India, Royal African, White Paper, and Russia Companies, Parliament legislated compromise arrangements that sustained the monopoly company’s charters but either over certain sectors of the market - as in the case of the White Paper Company - 86 or legalised independent trading either by amalgamating two companies as in the East India example or charging independent involvement in the trade, as in the African and Russian examples.87 These partial deregulations assisted the development of each trade. Such compromise agreements perfectly express the different political styles and outcomes of Parliamentary deliberation and Privy Conciliar discussion. Interest groups not only worked to enact statutes to assist the development of the overseas economy. More people appealed to Parliament at a time when Parliament legislated slightly less on economic issues. This was because many commercial 83 Alexander Renton, ed., The English Reports (London, 1900-1932), vol. 89, 496-502 [1 Show. K.B. 135-145]. 84 Gauci, Politics of Trade, 218 85 See Richard Dunn, ‘The Downfall of the Bermuda Company: A Restoration Farce’, William and Mary Quarterly, 3rd Ser. Vol. 20, No. 4 (Oct 1963) 86 See William Scott, The Constitution and Finance of English, Scottish, and Irish Joint-Stock Companies to 1720, (3 vols. Cambridge, 1919), vol 3, 66 where Scott cites this: “as possibly the earliest case of Parliamentary control of the capitalisation of a company.” 87 For the Russia Company see Jacob M. Price, ‘The Tobacco Adventure to Russia: Enterprise, Politics, and Diplomacy in the Quest for a Northern Market for English Colonial Tobacco, 1676 – 1722’, in Transactions of the American Philosophical Society, vol. 51, part 1, (1961) 18 interest groups began to lobby against statutory proposals to restrict the economy to ensure deregulation. The commercial interest group’s counter petition became an important macro-economic lever. In 1660, less than 1 per cent of Parliamentary petitions could be classified as counter petitions. By 1696 this had increased to 10 per cent and increased again to 24% in 1713. The trend is even more striking for petitions relating to economic matters: in 1660, 1 per cent of petitions to do with economic matters were counter petitions. In 1696, the figure was 20 per cent; in 1705 it became 33% and in 1713 it reached 65%. As soon as the primacy of Parliament as regulator of the national economy became fixed, the logical implications of that arrangement also became apparent: if a statute to regulate the economy failed in the legislature, then a legislative vacuum would assist deregulation. This deregulation could be sustained with the help of another, more famous example of legislative inertia: the expiration of the 1662 Licensing Act in 1695. A counter petitioning campaign based on the anti monopoly refrain prevented the licensing statute from being replaced in 1695.88 The expiration of this legislation allowed Parliamentary deliberation to enter the extralegislative public sphere. Counter-petitioning lobbyists mounted campaigns to defeat regulatory statutes but encouraged Parliamentary deliberation to legitimise the legislative vacuum by referring to points scored in Parliamentary debates in pamphlets. The deregulation of Britain’s transatlantic slave trade was, therefore, helped by a widening notion of representation in this period. By 1700, Parliament could not claim to monopolise the state’s access to national means of representation. The increased use of petitioning provided an alternative representation of the public sphere.89 Extra-Parliamentary means of representation began to flourish further after the expiration of the Licensing Act. Lobbyists who sought to maintain a legislative vacuum to preserve a deregulated market, used Parliament to engineer non-statutory Parliamentary rulings to legitimate their markets in the absence of a statute. Lobbyists had to employ the means to influence both public opinion and its representatives in Parliament to ensure the success of their proposal. Extra-Parliamentary public opinion was not, on its own sufficient. This public opinion had to be subjected to the legitimating gaze of formal Parliamentary consideration before a legislative vacuum could be tolerated.90 The improved powers of Parliament made the potential consequences of legislative failure greater because other branches of the constitution such as the monarchy and Privy Council could no longer be relied upon to resolve issues. This proved to have a profound effect on the evolution of Britain’s economy. With the important exception of the deregulating French Commerce bill in 1713 the large counter-petitioning campaigns opposed attempts to monopolise overseas trade, as with the Hamburg Company in December 1696 and the Royal African Company in November 1696 and again in January 1709. Large counter-petitioning campaigns also helped to discredit movements to limit the export of wool in December 1696 and November 1699, and the import of foreign lace in February 1699. In all cases, however, the weight of petitioning support proved critical to the defeat of the See R Astbury, ‘The Renewal of the Licensing Act of 1693 and its Lapse in 1695’, The Library, Series 5, no 33, (1978), 301 89 See Mark Knights, Representation and Misrepresentation in Later Stuart Britain (Oxford, 2005), 127 and Rosemary Sweet, ‘Local Identities and a National Parliament, c. 1688 – 1835’, in Julian Hoppit, ed., Parliaments, Nations, and Identities in Britain and Ireland, 1660 – 1850 (Manchester, 2003), 50-51 90 See also Tim Keirn, ‘Parliament, Legislation and the Regulation of English Textile Industries, 16891714’ in Stilling the Grumbling Hive, 16 88 19 measure.91The lobbying campaign against the Royal African Company to deregulate the slave trade provides the best example. The ‘Africa trade’ dispute produced more petitions and more pamphlets than any other economic issue before Parliament in this period.92 To liberalise the slave trade, the African Company’s opponents, the ‘separate traders to Africa’ used the breadth of their support to block the company’s attempts to achieve a statutory confirmation for their charter. One pro-company pamphleteer pointed out, prior to the 1698 Act, that separate traders preferred obstructing African company bills to authoring their own: Ever since the Parliament voted that it was the undoubted Right of all the subjects of England to Trade to Foreign Parts – none of those Free Traders have ever brought to the Parliament a Bill to settle this Trade, but still opposed what was offered by the Company ... because those free traders … had just cause to believe that under such a Regulation, whatsoever it should be, they must pay towards what by the Parliament should be thought necessary for the general interest of that trade whereas if they continue that heavy load upon the African Company only by opposing this bill, they should then enjoy their trade without that expence. 93 The company’s opponents initiated proceedings in Parliament in only three out of 16 sessions.94 When anti-African Company proposals appeared, in the 1690s, the company’s opponents seldom advocated statutory alternatives to the company’s monopoly using such vague terms as ‘advantageous regulation’ and ‘a better, more beneficial, and equal establishment’ and ‘liberty, and freedom to trade’.95 Later, separate trader petitions became explicitly anti-regulatory. In 1709 this had evolved to ‘may be continued free and open to all the subjects of Great Britain’. The Africa trade dispute emerged in each Parliamentary session as the result of a petition, usually from the African Company itself.96 Such petitions proved critical to initiate discussion. Subsequent petitioning increased, however, the chances of legislative failure. Far more numerous cultivated counter-petitions from the separate traders often ensured the defeat of African Company measures or stalled Parliamentary attempts to legislate compromise measures such as regulated companies.97 Spontaneous and sincere reactions to legislative progress either in support or in opposition also introduced new concerns and pitfalls for Parliamentary 91 See Gauci, Politics of Trade, 249 Gauci describes how a critical speech against the bill came from a turn-coat, Sir Thomas Hanmer. See also in relation to the Hamborough Company, Cherry, 116. For the French commerce bill of 1713 see also D C Coleman, ‘Politics and Economics in the Age of Anne; the Case of the Anglo-French Trade Treaty of 1713’ in D C Coleman and A H John (eds.), Trade, Government, and Economy in Pre-Industrial England (London, 1976) 92 Another issue of comparable dimensions was that surrounding the leather trade which saw the presentation of over 150 petitions from over 100 different locations between 1697 and 1699 in their two-year-long campaign to have the leather duties repealed see Brewer, Sinews of Power, 233 93 Considerations Relating to the African Bill (1698), 3. This was a reference to Gilbert Heathcote’s resolution of 1694 in relation to the East India trade (see Commons Journals, vol. 11, 8 January 1693-4, 50) 94 These were 1710, 1712, and 1713 95 Commons Journals, vol. 10, ‘Petition of Merchants and Planters trading to and interested in the Island of Barbadoes’ to the House of Commons 22 April 1690, 383 and ‘Petition of Clothiers of Suffolk and Essex’ to the House of Commons 21 April 1690, 382 96 Exceptions include: 1691, 98, 1709, 1712, 1713 97 This occurred in 1690, 93/94, 94/95, 1707/8, and 1708/9 20 drafting committees and therefore made legislation more difficult.98 This was especially true for the Africa trade dispute because it affected so many interest groups. Colonial planters, merchants, manufactures in the woollen trade, the iron, navigation, and firearms industries from the metropolis and throughout the provinces all responded to business as it progressed in the House. Authoring legislation that could satisfy all of these concerns proved challenging. The African Company ultimately proved unable to cultivate sufficient petitions to catalyse its own legislative proposals. Petitioning then, although critical to the commencement of the legislative process in the case of the Africa trade debates, usually served to directly defeat or complicate proceedings. Encouraging Parliamentary deliberation but discouraging statutory resolution became the separate traders’ lobbying motto. The separate traders cultivated extraParliamentary opinion with pamphlets. They steered a middle course in Parliament that aimed to achieve non-statutory Parliamentary rulings that would modify public opinion in favour of open trade and ensure that the legislative vacuum was tolerated. These rulings accrued more public significance the more interest in Parliament increased after 1688. The rulings were meaningful because of the ritualised nature of Parliamentary deliberation. Once a legislative proposal had reached a certain stage, it gathered legitimacy even if the proposal ultimately failed. Non-statutory Parliamentary rulings in favour of an open slave trade appeared in several forms. First, Charles Davenant noted how the Board of Trade’s report to Parliament about the slave trade in early 1709 offered much needed legitimacy to the separate traders’ cause. Davenant noted how such legitimacy proved influential with public opinion and helped, in turn, to influence the political process, ‘for the Separate Traders have taken occasion, from thence to print certain paragraphs of there [sic] own base allegations by way of Extracts out of the said report, as vouchers to gain Credit to the very same allegations again without doors.’ 99 A separate trader pamphlet acknowledged how the Board’s report reflected a deliberate separate trader lobbying strategy, ‘the Report is drawn up with such Exactness and Impartiality, that whensoever the Parliament will please to call for it, I dare take upon me to say, it will justify my present Undertaking, and verify the most, if not all the Suggestions and Allegations here laid down, and give Such a Light and Insight into the whole Matter, that the Publick will be kept no longer in the dark about it.’100 The various stages that each legislative proposal reached provide a second category of non-statutory Parliamentary rulings: from points scored in debate, to votes and resolutions, and to bills. Pamphleteers referred to the perceived outcome of Parliamentary debates or to testimony deemed trustworthy because of submission in the House. One separate trader disputed the utility of the company’s African forts not through any investigation or reasoning on the part of the author but ‘because it hath often been made appear at the Bar, that most of the Negroes brought from Africa are 98 This seems to have occurred in 1709/10 and 1710/11 Charles Davenant’s responses to the Board of Trade’s 1708 report are contained in [Davenant], ‘Some General Observations and Particular remarks on the Report made by the Lords Commissioners for Trade and Plantations the 3rd February, 1708 Touching the Contents of the Royal African Company’s Peticion Referred to them by her Majesty’ in T70/175, f. 87-96 100 Considerations upon the Trade to Guinea, (London 1708), 26 99 21 loaden where we have no settlements.’101 Pamphleteers relayed the perceived outcome of Parliamentary debates to undermine their opponents. The same was true of the Parliamentary votes. These votes effected how the economy functioned. A separate trader pamphlet described how a vote in favour of a regulated company bill led to expansion in the trade ‘…since the vote of the honourable House of commons about eight years ago, that the trade thither was best to be managed by a regulated company, there has been a greater trade driven thither, notwithstanding all the difficulties at home, and hazards of war, than ever was carried on in times of peace.’102 Parliamentary resolutions, unlike – at this stage – the content of the debates themselves (outside partisan pamphlets) were often printed which made them more influential outside the chamber. Parliamentary resolution conferred pseudo-statutory legitimacy for Parliamentary proposals in the absence of a statute. A petition from Exeter cited how a resolution in favour of deregulation in a previous session had ‘so far encouraged the petitioners, that it gave a new life to their trade, and some thousands of pieces ... made more than usual, and the price advanced from eleven shillings and six-pence per piece to fifteen shillings and six-pence per piece.’103 Parliamentary resolutions confirmed, especially when originating from the committee of the whole House, that there existed broad Parliamentary approval for the proposed scheme. One pamphlet complained how the company’s assumption that the law of the African trade revert to its 1672 charter after the expiration of the 1698 Act proceeded ‘without any regard to the many resolutions of this honourable House repeated last session, viz. that the African trade ought to be free and open to all her majesty’s subjects’ and went on to describe how ‘Tis true the bill for the National Trade did not pass last year, but even the adversaries thereto did agree, ‘twas not because they were against an open Trade, but that some clauses in that bill were excepted against.’104 This pamphleteer noted how in the post 1688 political world, a non-statutory Parliamentary ruling commanded more public authority than a charter derived from royal prerogative. The open trade bills themselves offered futher evidence of Parliamentary support and provided some of the information about how the trade might function without a statute. Pamphleteers deemed previous bills to be binding of future Parliamentary deliberations, ‘Who but this company would come to Parliament, to ask an exclusive trade, when but 7 or 8 months before the House passed a bill for a free and open trade?’105 The separate traders also used their bills on the African coast to convince 101 An Answer to a Paper Called Short Remarks on the African Trade, (1711) Reasons Humbly Offered by the Merchants and Traders to Guiney and the West-Indies, against the Bill for Settling the Trade to Africa (1698) 103 Commons Journals, vol. 10, ‘Petition of Mayor, Aldermen, and Common Councilmen of the City of Exon and also of the merchants, serge-makers, fullers, and other trading people, employed in and about the woolen manufactury within the said city and county of the same and parts adjacent’, 9 December 1691, 579 104 The belief that anti-company legislation failed for reasons other than a lack of support was commonplace. See also The Present Case of the African trade Truly Stated, with Reasons for the Bill for Establishing the Same Now Depending (1713), 1 and The Case of the National Traders to Africa, (1714), 1 see also The Anatomy of the African Company's Scheme for Carrying on That Trade in a Joint-Stock Exclusive, … (1713), 2 105 The Anatomy of the African Company's Scheme for Carrying on That Trade in a Joint-Stock Exclusive, … (1713), 2 102 22 African traders not to deal with the company, ‘We believe ye Separate Traders’ captains and officers may impose on you and ye rest of our servants by magnifying the pretended advantages they gained this Parliament, but we must observe to you, that tho’ they had prevailed to far as to have ye liberty of offering a bill to the House in order to lay open the trade to Africa, the House did not think fit to pass that bill but adjourned ir from day to day until ye session was ended.’106 Countless other resolutions of this kind proved formative for other industries and trades. A resolution obliged traders to sell their goods by ‘inch of candle’.107 Comparing the African Company’s fortunes after the expiration of the 1698 statute in 1712 with those of the Hudson’s Bay Company after the expiration of its statute in 1697 confirms the importance of extra-Parliamentary support to sustain a legislative vacuum in favour of open trade. For unlike in 1712, legislative inertia in the context of the Hudson’s Bay Company favoured monopoly. Political interests opposed to the Hudson’s Bay Company were far less broadly based than those against the Royal African Company, and they made less of an attempt to win over public opinion to discredit the Hudson’s Bay Company’s monopoly.108 The separate traders’ political victory dramatically affected the volume of Britain’s slave trade. The peacetime capacity of the trade when the Royal African Company’s monopoly came closest to being enforceable during James II’s reign in 1686 reached 37 voyages. By 1730, the open trade in slaves achieved 120 voyages. The resulting expansion of the slave trade as a result of the demise of the Royal African Company led, of course, to expansion in the sugar and tobacco industries which the British government taxed. One contemporary disputant in the Africa trade debate believed that each slave contributed between an extra 30 and 40 shillings per annum to the fisc. If the demise of the African Company increased the volume of the slave trade by 59 per cent (a conservative estimate), this represented more than £30,000 more customs revenue for the state per year and nearly £3,000,000 worth between 1730 and 1807.109 The expanded slave trade also increased iron and wool production as demand in Africa increased.110 This enlargement represented a small piece of the overall growth of overseas trade as a result of lobbying campaigns to deregulate access to overseas trading markets. Overseas trade was, to contemporaries and to many historians, the most important engine of British economic growth during this period. Daniel Defoe spoke for many others when he saw the discovery of and more efficient manipulation of overseas markets as the surest method to improvements in trade.111 The figures are impressive. 106 T70/52, Royal African Company to Sir Dalby Thomas, 5 May 1709, f. 223 and Royal African Company to William Hickes, 5 May 1709, f. 226 107 Cherry, 114 108 In other cases, it was clear that the lapsing of an Act in this period – and the Licensing Act in 1695 is a famous example – was a deliberate victory for those interests who benefited. For the Hudson’s Bay Company see E.E. Rich, The Hudson’s Bay Company, 1670 – 1870 (London, 1958), vol. 1, 363 109 See Some Considerations Humbly Offered to Demonstrate How Prejudicial It Would be to the English Plantations, Revenues of the Crown, the Navigation and General Good of This Kingdom, that the Sole Trade for Negroes Should Be Granted to a Company with a Joynt-Stock Exclusive to All Others [1698?], 2 110 See Joseph Inikori, Africans and the Industrial Revolution in England: A Study in International Trade and Economic Development (Cambridge, 2002) 111 See also Stilling the Grumbling Hive, 17 23 The value of overseas trade almost doubled from £7.9 million in the 1660s to £14.5 million by the 1720s. Imports increased by a third, and exports by more than half, in the period 1663 to 1701. The majority of this increase derived from increases in domestic exports after 1700. 112 Most of this increase came from England’s traditional export good, cloth, although iron and corn greatly contributed. Demand for British goods and especially manufacturing increased with the expansion of her colonies. There was, however, nothing intrinsic and natural about Parliament’s encouragement of deregulation. Parliament did not move solely in the direction of deregulation, however, as some scholars have alleged.113 Interest groups also sought to protect their economic interests via regulation. This was especially true for manufacturing. The number of statutes seeking to encourage (or protect) manufacturing increased from 10% to 47% over the same period. The success rate of measures to encourage manufacturing improved from 11% to 24%. These protectionist acts proved as formative for the structures of national economic growth as those that deregulated the economy.114 Parliament nurtured Britain’s young linen and silk industries with statutes designed to price foreign competition out of Britain’s domestic market. Legislation in 1689 prohibited the importation of silk from turkey, Persia, India and china.115 In 1690 a statute laid a 20 % duty on Indian calicoes with a rebate on reexport. In 1699, a statute added a further 15% on eastern silks. Statutes such as ‘For the more effectual employing the Poor by encouraging the Manufactures of this Kingdom’ proved a massive stimulus to Britain’s burgeoning cotton and textile industries. A 1702 Act assisted Britain’s cotton industry by heralding the beginning of the end of cheap competition from Asian imports.116 Also, tariffs on imported iron helped to develop Britain’s iron industry. The number of blast furnaces in England nearly doubled during this period.117 Protectionist legislation helped to develop this industry as well as the silk, paper, linen, and woollen industries.118 Statutory tariffs on foreign tobacco and sugar helped to stimulate the growth of British America’s staples, which played a critical part in developing the colonial population, which, in turn, stimulated demand for the products of Britain’s protected manufacturing industries.119 This regulatory structure, of course, did not operate independently from the government’s foreign policy initiatives. Customs legislation demonstrates to what extent the reformed Parliament could impersonate the Privy Council’s efficiency and governmental aspect. Customs bills derived from the executive Treasury department and sped through legislative resolutions in its own Commons Committee on Ways and 112 D C Coleman, The Economy of England, 1450- 1750, (Oxford, 1977), 133, 134 See especially Cherry, Free Trade Movement in Parliament 114 For a supporter of the protection of new manufacturing see William Petyt who urged the government to encourage and superintend new manufacturing in Britannia Languens, (London, 1689), 125 115 For the protests see Statutes, vol. 10, 359 116 See O’Brien et.al, Political Components of the Industrial Revolution, 414 117 See M W Flinn, ‘The Growth of the English Iron Industry, 1660 – 1760’ Economic History Review, New Series, Vol. 11, No. 1 (1958), 146: The increases of blast furnaces in this period were as follows: Kirby, Leighton, Cwn Avon, Caerphilly, Allensford Mill (Durham), Blakeney, Flaxley, Mearheath (8)1689 – 1716: Bank Upper, Bank Lower, Melbourne, Treforest, Neath, Ynyscedwyn, Cynseu, Blackbarrow, Leighton, Elmbridge, Lamberhurst, Whitehill, Doddington, Vale Royal (14) 118 A substantial tariff kept the price of foreign imports up to protect and nurture the domestic industry. See Flinn, fn 1,152, 153. For tariffs on imported silk see O’Brien et al, Political Components, 412 119 See Ralph Davis, English Overseas Trade 1500 – 1700 (London 1973) 113 24 Means.120 Revenue bills rarely failed in Queen Anne’s reign.121 These enactments therefore engineered growth because of the rising importance and efficacy of the executive branch of the constitution when working in tandem with the reformed legislative branch. The Privy-Council-Parliament regulatory mechanisms prior to 1688 did not lead to the protection of developing industries. Tariffs on overseas trade could not be drawn up via Privy Council. Such enactments had been at the legislature’s pleasure since at least the mid 17th century. Duties on import trades quadrupled between 1690 and 1704.122 These helped to stimulate investment in industry as well as financing Britain’s war against Louis XIV. The improved prestige and power of statute after 1688 could also be brought to bear on overseas trading monopolies as well as protectionist tariffs. Although Parliamentary enactments to endorse monopolies declined slightly (3 to 2%) as a proportion of total enactments of the economy, the period after 1689 witnessed the emergence of a statute not before seen: the statute to monopolise overseas trade, typically via an overseas trading monopoly. There were 4 of these statutes between 1689 and 1714 (two supporting the monopoly of the East India Company and two supporting that of the South Sea Company). The Hudson’s Bay Company received temporary statutory support in 1698.123 The Royal Lustring and South Sea Companies began life as statutory creations after 1688, the first as part of the state’s desire to develop and protect the nation’s fledgling silk manufacturing industry, the second a means to transfer massive public debts into a consolidated trading stock. The protection that statutory support for the Royal Lustring Company’s monopoly provided assisted a 20 fold increase in the scale of Britain’s silk industry between 1660 and 1713, most of it achieved after the company’s foundation in 1692.124 Far from precipitating the end of the monopoly company as some have argued, the period after 1688 produced a boom in company foundations. Of the companies that existed in 1695, 85 % had arisen after 1688.125 The history of the East India Company’s monopoly shows how Parliament’s representative and governing remits could operate in concert. Parliamentary consideration temporarily liberated the trade, bringing into the company’s management an energetic new group of traders. Because of a successful lobbying campaign against it, the East India Company became split into Old and New Companies. The difference that the incorporation of ‘New’ elements had on the existing company can be appreciated by examining the difference in size of the governmental loans each company proposed as a means to sustain their respective charters.126 The bidding war between the two factions saw the Old Company propose a £700,000 loan at 4%. The New Company, which represented a rising class of traders 120 Stilling the Grumbling Hive, 10 Stilling the Grumbling Hive, 20 fn 12 122 Ralph Davis, ‘The Rise of Protection in England, 1689-1786’, Economic History Review, New Series, Vol 19, no 2 (1966), 306-317 123 For the Hudson’s Bay Company see E.E. Rich, The Hudson’s Bay Company, 1670 – 1870 (London, 1958), vol. 1, 363 124 See Gerald B Hertz, ‘The English Silk Industry in the 18th Century’, The English Historical Review, Vol. 24, no 96 (October 1909), 710- 727 125 See Hecksher, Mercantilism, 412 126 As a result of the Parliamentary dispute about the future of the East India Company, the company could not mount a successful campaign against the domestic textiles interests who wished to restrict the imports of Indian textiles. 121 25 with massive capital reserves, proposed to lend the government £2 million at 8%. The New Company won out, but the Old Company managed to sustain itself and contributed £315,000 (with the New Company again providing the lion’s share of £1,662,000) to a further government loan before an amalgamation in 1709. Because the 18th century East India Company incorporated its most impressive competitors, its trading figures and its dividend rate began to stabilise and then improve with a record dividend payment of 13% in 1713.127 It began to reform its business practices and improved its financial and political strength once Parliament fully countenanced its charter from 1708. This stabilised the trade and enabled it to proceed, as well as broadening its membership and significantly improving the expertise and experience of its directorate. With its political controversies shelved until the end of the century, the new, statutory East India Company contributed massively to the economic life of the nation throughout the 18th century.128 The company’s monopoly endured because it offered a means for the British state to raise money and to, to some extent, regulate its relationships with the India subcontinent. It remained highly profitable throughout the 18th century. Statutory support for the East India Company’s monopoly provides the most important example of statutory monopolisation of the overseas economy that produced significant effects on the growth of Britain’s national economy. Parliament engineered economic growth via regulatory statutes. Parliament, therefore, continued to govern the economy statute as the Privy Council had done through conciliar rulings.129 But the consent attached to statute provided regulations countenanced by Parliament with a superior means of enforcement. The improved success rate of legislation in this period therefore does not solely reflect the increasing power of newly enfranchised interests within the reformed polity. 130 Instead it shows the extent to which Parliament achieved success as a tool of 127 K N Chaudhuri, The Trading World of Asia and the English East India Company, (Cambridge, 1978), 87 128 But see also D. W. Jones, ‘London Overseas Merchant Groups at the End of the 17th Century and the Moves Against the East India Company’ (Oxford Dphil Thesis, 1970), 370: “Nothing could alter the fact, however, that merchants, in a way which had not been true under the management of Sir Josiah Child, had gained access to the East India trade.” 129 Tim Keirn has rightly stressed the significance for the British state’s regulation of the economy of the shift from conciliar to legislative means of regulation in this period. Parliament’s ability to govern the economy through statute enabled it to impersonate the Privy Council as an economic regulator. This also meant that the British state could be as proactive as reactive in macro-economic matters. See Tim Keirn, ‘The Reactive State: English Governance and Society, 1689 – 1750’ in Lee Davison, Tim Hitchcock, Tim Keirn, and Robert B Shoemaker, eds., Stilling the Grumbling Hive (Stroud, 1992), i-xli 130 According to the Hoppit calculation, fewer and fewer bills failed during this period. Between 1688 and 1714, bills had a 50 per cent chance of failing. Economic issues such as the Africa trade dispute proved especially difficult to legislate with a 67–80 per cent failure rate. See Julian Hoppit, ed., Failed Legislation, (London, 1997), 5 – 10. In achieving only two statutes out of 15 attempts, the Africa trade issue manifested an 88 per cent failure rate. The connection between political reform and legislative failure can, at the present time, only be made in relation to the Africa trade dispute. See Failed Legislation, 21-22, ‘Despite the increasing vigour of forms of external pressure on Parliament, this was not associated with an increase in the failure rate of legislation. Pressure from extra-Parliamentary sources did not lead either to the introduction of an increasing proportion of measures without serious hope of passing, or to the defeat of an increasing proportion of proposals. At most, it was associated with the rise in numbers of certain kinds of failed initiative (especially constitutional measures). It was also associated with an increasing tendency for certain other initiatives that were to fail, to fail at an early stage in the Parliamentary process.’ 26 government and to what extent the sovereign Parliament could be managed to become an effective substitute for its less deliberative, less representative, conciliar forbears. Improvements in the efficiency of Parliamentary procedure allowed oligarchic interests allied with government to restrict the economy, but, as we have seen, nonetheless aid economic growth. More effective commercial lobbies also worked to defeat regulating statutes to aid growth in the economy via legislative failure, legislative vacuum, and, without the intervention of other constitutional means to influence the ensuing deregulation. In this way, national economic growth depended as much upon the retreat of other constitutional branches from the business of state regulation of the economy as it did on the extension of Parliament’s influence. Parliament as a regulator depended upon the weakness of its constitutional competitors as well as its interactions with that other great shibboleth of the second half of the 17th century, the public sphere. My analysis shows how commercial life benefited from this sphere as much as that sphere developed as a result of the emergence of commercial life, as Jurgen Habermas argued.131 The political reforms broadly associated with the Glorious Revolution then did not either exclusively encourage the liberalisation of the English economy or solely foster greater protectionism as various historians have argued.132 At times Parliament governed via statute to restrict (or develop) the economy with monopoly companies or other regulatory systems. At other times, Parliament provided the forum for new interests to achieve deregulating statutes or defeat regulating statute and monopolies and fuel economic growth through deregulation. Parliament also allowed interest groups to protect their economic interest with regulation. The Augustan British state therefore could be proactive as well as reactive in relation to the way in which it regulated the burgeoning British economy.133 When markets did become deregulated, however, they did so more as a result of the reformed political process than any theoretical discussion of the benefits of deregulated economies (and such discussion was, in this period, marginal). Free trade and economic growth had important political determinants. Although contemporaries expected the state to aid the development of the economy and believed that a ‘free state’ was best positioned to aid that influence, they did not appreciate the precise mechanics of the connection between the reform of Parliament and the development of the national economy. 134 Historians of Parliament have largely missed the extent to which the post-1688 Parliament began to impersonate the Privy Council to engineer economic growth with the help of a new cadre of economically literate policy advisers and how the 131 Jurgen Habermas, The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere (Cambridge, 1989) For those who believed the Glorious Revolution fostered free trade see above and William James Ashley, Surveys Historic and Economic (London, 1900), 270-303 and Robert Ekelund and Robert Tollison, Politicised Economies (Texas, 1997). For those who see the rise of protectionism and the survival or ‘rent seeking’ see Joyce Appleby, Economic Thought and Ideology in Seventeenth Century England, (Princeton, 1978), and Ralph Davis, ‘The Rise of Protection in England’ in Economic History Review, vol. 19, no. 2, (1966), 306. 133 Compare with Tim Keirn, ‘The Reactive State: English Governance and Society, 1689 – 1750’ in Lee Davison, Tim Hitchcock, Tim Keirn, and Robert B Shoemaker, eds., Stilling the Grumbling Hive (Stroud, 1992), xli 134 For the tendency for economic historians to allow economic phenomena to remain ‘selfinterpreting’ see Carruthers, City of Capital, 3-27. For accounts of an emergence of economic theory that precipitated (or attempted to precipitate) economic deregulation in this period see Appleby, Economic Thought and Ideology in Seventeenth Century England, and William Letwin, The Origins of Scientific Economics (London, 1963) 132 27 deliberative process made its statutory regulations easier to enforce. Statute ought to be considered alongside other constitutional regulatory means, rather than as part of a zero-sum game. As the state’s means of regulating the national economy transferred from the Privy Council to the Parliament, the state’s power over the economy changed from the dispensing power to the power of suspension. Economists and political scientists have also missed how the economic growth that the transfer from Privy Council to Parliament depended upon the enfranchisement of oligarchic interest groups, or rent-seekers, as economists label them. British economic growth in the 18th century required the participation of mercantile interest groups in the Parliamentary and regulatory processes. Rather than emerging within mature political systems to hinder economic growth, as Mancur Olson argued, economic interest groups represented, in the British case, the architects of political reform and its beneficiaries, but their contribution also helped to create economic growth.135 Private interests augmented the national interest, as Adam Smith preached, but via regulation as well as deregulation. International comparisons confirm the importance of these dual sources of growth that the British economy benefited from. In Holland, deregulation, and in France, complete regulation, made both economies less competitive.136 The source of Britain’s regulatory flexibility derived from Parliament, which, as we have seen, could impersonate government, and could represent the market, better than its continental competitors and better than its conciliar predecessors. The freedom that Davenat, Fiennes, Temple, Parker, and Millar celebrated when connecting economic growth to political institutions in Britain included the state’s ability to respond to requests from representatives of the market to regulate and deregulate trade. All of these developments can be connected to the Glorious Revolution. They show what the nation could procure for itself in return for footing the bill for the Prince of Orange’s war with Louis XIV. The Parliamentary process after 1688 with its increasing regularity and its longer sessions, allowed both William and the political nation to extract something new. For William it was the £130 million to pay for the war.137 MPs exchanged war finance for constitutional concessions. In 1694, one member reported how the statute to charter the Bank of England had been secured by the King in return for granting the Triennial Act: “[O]ur affairs go on merrily with relation to the land forces, for which the gentlemen will have the triennial bill.”138 But what was the ensuing primacy of Parliamentary deliberations actually worth? Overall, the transfer of national economic regulatory initiative from the Privy Council to Parliament assisted the development of Britain’s infrastructure, especially river navigations and roads. It helped interest groups secure protection for their manufacturing industries, and allowed marginalized traders to deregulate trades and open access to all. It also conferred statute’s authority onto monopolies, such as the East India Company. How can these legislative enactments be compared with other, presumably more profound determinants of economic growth in this period, such as 135 For an influential thesis arguing that interest groups inhibit macro-economic growth, see especially Mancur Olson, The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities, (New Haven, 1982) see also Paul Brace, Youssef Cohen, Virginia Gray, David Lowery, ‘How Much do Interest Groups Influence State Economic Growth?’, The American Policiation Science Review, Vol. 83, no 4, (December, 1989), 1297-1308 136 See also O’Brien et al, Political Components, 418 137 For the £130 million cost figure see Michael Jabbin, ‘Economic Policy and Economic development’ in Jeremy Black (ed.), Britain in the Age of Walpole (Basingstoke, 1984) 138 See Henry Horwitz, Parliament, Policy and Politics in the Age of William III (Manchester, 1977), 138 28 adjustments in the international economy, the disruptions of war, demographic changes, and most importantly, the accumulation of capital? Measuring the impact of these changes on the economy with any precision is impossible. It is clear, however, that these changes did not create £130 million of growth in the short term.139 But these changes in structure altered the capacity of the British economy in ways that would, in the long term, help the British economy to reap a return on its investment made between 1689 and 1713. These changes also show the limitations of the prevailing view that constitutional change resulted solely from Parliamentary control over finance. The economic results of the primacy of Parliament as well as contemporaries belief in Parliament’s potential to generate economic benefits confirms that a theory of Parliament existed to not only assist with the raising of government finance, but also to help generate economic growth, however ill distributed it may have been. 139 Indeed, for one influential view that argued how growth could have been more substantial see J U Nef, The Rise of the British Coal Industry, (London, 1932) 29