Problem Set III Game Theory and Asymmetric Information (B) 1. Consider a bank B and an entrepreneur E, who applies for a loan to finance an investment project. The entrepreneur has private information about her type: she can be productive (P) or not-productive (N). While the entrepreneur knows her own type, the bank has only a prior probability distribution over entrepreneur types: the bank assesses a probability ¼ that the entrepreneur is of the productive type and of the unproductive type with probability ¾. The application can be for a short-term or a long-term loan. The bank can either approve a loan application or reject it. If the bank approves a short-term loan application, both the bank and the entrepreneur (of either type) receive a payoff of $1 (i.e., the payoffs are $1, $1). If the bank approves a longterm loan application (long-term loan carries a higher interest rate), both the entrepreneur and bank receive a payoff of $2 if the entrepreneur is of the productive type (i.e., the payoffs are $2, $2); both the bank and the entrepreneur receive a negative payoff of one dollar (i.e., the payoffs $-1, $-1) if the entrepreneur is unproductive, since the unproductive entrepreneur is likely to fail in implementing the long-term project, thus wasting his own effort and the bank’s money. If any loan application is rejected, both the entrepreneur and bank receive a payoff of zero dollars each (payoffs: 0, 0). (a) Draw the extensive form of the above game. (b) Show that there are two perfect Bayesian equilibria of this game. (i) A separating PBE where the productive entrepreneur applies for a long-term loan and the unproductive entrepreneur applies for a short-term loan, and the bank accepts all loan applications, inferring the entrepreneur’s true type with probability 1 from the type of loan she requests. (ii) A pooling PBE where both types of entrepreneurs apply only for a short-term loan, with the bank accepting all short-term loan applications and rejecting all long-term loan applications (and inferring that any loan applicant (short-term or long-term) is of the productive type with probability ¼ and unproductive with probability ¾). (c) Apply the Cho-Kreps intuitive criterion to the above equilibria. Which of the above equilibria survives the Cho-Kreps intuitive criterion? Provide detailed computations to justify your answer. Assume for the following three questions that both buyers and sellers are risk-neutral, so that they want to maximize their expected payoff. 2. Consider an example in the spirit of Akerlof. A buyer and a seller can potentially trade a good (car) of uncertain quality; the good is equally likely to be a lemon (=L), or a peach (=H). The buyer has reservation values b=14 for a lemon and b=42 for a peach. The seller has reservation values s=0 for a lemon and s=40 for a peach. (a) Suppose neither the buyer nor the seller can tell the true quality of the car. What quality levels of cars will be traded, and at what range of prices (if at all)? (b) Now assume that the seller knows the true quality of the car while the buyer does not. What quality levels of cars will be traded at what prices (if at all)? 3. Now consider a modified version of Question 2. The good (car) may have three different quality levels: it is equally likely to be a lemon (=L), a melon (=M), or a peach (=H). The buyer has values b=14 for a lemon, b=28 for a melon, and b=42 for a peach. The seller has values s=0 for a lemon, s=20 for a lemon, and s=40 for a peach. (a) As a starting point, suppose neither the seller nor the buyer has any information on the quality of the car. At what price or range of prices can full trade take place, if at all? Here full trade means that all three qualities of cars will be traded. (b) Now suppose the seller becomes partially informed: she now knows a lemon when she sees one, but can’t distinguish a melon from a peach. The buyers’ information level remains the same as before. Now, is it possible to find a price at which lemons, melons, and peaches can all be traded? Is it possible to find a price at which trade can take place partially? Here partial trade means some qualities of cars are traded while other qualities are not: e.g., only lemons are traded or only melons are traded. (c) Now suppose the seller is perfectly informed. The buyers’ information level remains the same as before. Now, is it possible to find a price at which full trade will take place? Is it possible to find a price at which trade can take place partially? (d) In Akerlof, we find that as the extent of asymmetric information (i.e., the difference in information levels between buyers and sellers) increases, the extent of trade decreases. Is this still true if we compare parts (b) and (c)? Could you give a reason for why this (or is not) the case? 4. You find a very old piece of furniture (antique) in your attic. You don’t know the true value of this antique, but only that this value is $100,000 with probability , and $50,000 with probability 1-. You want to sell this to an antique dealer, who, you know, will be able to assess the true value of the object with probability 1. Assume that you plan to make a take-it-or-leave-it offer at price P to the dealer. If the dealer accepts the offer, he has to pay the price P and buy the object. If the offer is rejected, you have to keep the antique furniture in your living room as a decorative piece, which will give you a (personal) reservation value of $30,000. (a) What is the offer price you should set if = 0.8? Focus only on the pure strategy equilibrium. (b) What is the optimal offer price you should set if =0.2? Focus only on the pure strategy equilibrium. (c) Suppose there are two dealers in the market and both know the true value of the object, and there is no collusion between the two. If you auction the furniture using a second-price sealed-bid auction (and both antique dealers participate), what will be the selling price? What is your expected payoff? Justify your answer with an (informal) proof.