Updated: 29 May, 2007 MICRO ECONOMICS (ECON 601) Lecture 10 Topics to be covered: a- Allocation of time b- Two good models c- Utility maximization d- Income and substitution effects of a change in w e- Analysis of labor supply f- Dual statement of problem g- Slutsky equation of labor supply h- Cobb-Douglas labor supply i- Effects of non-labor income j- Individual supply curve of labor k- Market supply curve l- Job search theory m-Economies of child bearing n- Transportation choices o- Modeling a union p- Monopolist optimum ECON 601: ADVANCED MICRO ECONOMICS LABOUR MARKETS Nicholson, Chapter 16 Allocation of Time Fixed amount of time 24 hours of the day, the question is how it is allocated between work, sleep, consumption and leisure. A Two Good Model Work, and not working When working a wage of w per hour is earned. When not working the individual is consuming (C) or enjoying leisure (H). Both are composite goods: Utility = U (C, H) Utility is a function of Consumption (C) and leisure (H). Utility is maximized subject to the time constraint that the time spent working (L) plus leisure time (H) has to be equal to 24 hours a day. L + H = 24 The second constraint is that C = wL Combining the two constraints, we have C = w (24 – H) OR, C + wH = 24w 1 Full Income = 24 w The opportunity cost of consuming leisure is w per hour. It is equal to earnings foregone by not working. Utility Maximization Maximize utility subject to the full income constraint: L = U (C, H) + (24w – C – wH) The first order conditions: (1) L U = –=0 C C (2) L U = – w = 0 H H From (1) and (2) U (3) U H w = MRS (H for C) C In order to maximize utility, given the real wage, w, the individual should choose to work that number of hours for which the marginal rate of substitution of leisure for consumption is equal to w. The MRS of leisure for consumption must be diminishing in order for utility to be maximized according to equation 3. 2 Income and Substitution effects of a change in w With a change in w, leisure becomes more expensive and people reduce their consumption of it due to the substitution effect. At the same time as w increases there is an income effect and as leisure is a normal good people will demand more of it. Since leisure and work are mutually exclusive it is not clear if work will increase or decrease if the wage rate (w) is increased. The substitution effect A to S tends to increase the hours worked while the income effect reduces it. Consumption C = w1(24 – H) B C1 S C = w0(24 – H) C0 A u1 u0 H1 H0 Leisure In this case the individual works more (24 – H1) versus (24 – H0) and also consumes more C0 to C1. Substitution effect is stronger than income effect. 3 Consumption C = w1(24 – H) C1 C0 S C = w0(24 – H) u1 u0 24 H0 H1 Leisure In this case the increase in the wage rate from w0 to w1 causes an individual to work less (24 – H1) from (24 – H0) and also to consume more C0 to C1. The income effect is stronger on the labor-leisure choice than the substitution effect. It more than offsets the substitution effect. When the real wage rate increases, a utility maximizing individual may increase or decrease hours worked. The substitution effect increases hours worked, the income effect will tend to reduce hours worked as the individual uses his increased purchasing power to buy more leisure hours. Analysis of Labor Supply Budget Constraint with Non-Labor Income C = wL + N L + H = 24 L = (24 – H) C = w (24 – H) + N C = Total Consumption N is non-labor income. L = U (C, H) + (24w + N – C – wH) 4 (1) L U = – =0 C C (2) L U = – w = 0 H H From 2/1 U H = w U C Consumption C = w0 (24 – H) + N Leisure C = w0 (24 – H) Budget constraint shifts with changes in value of N. Labor supply, L(W,N) will depend on real wage rate and non-wage income. If leisure is normal good then L 0 N Dual Statement of Problem Choose values for consumption (C) and Leisure time H = 24 – L so that amount additional spending E = C – wL to achieve a level of utility U0 = U(C, H) is minimized. (See Chap 5) E =–L w 5 Each $1 increase in w reduces the value of additional spending (E) required $L because this is the change in Labour’s earnings for a $1 change in the wage rate. Slutsky Equation of Labor Supply Equation reflects the substitution and income effects that result from changes in the real wage. Expenditures (E) being minimized in the dual problem plays the role of non-labor income (N) in the utility maximization problem. By definition at the initial optimal point, The combination of L, w, N, U for the substitution effect only labor supply function determine for each. = Lc(w, U) = L [w, E(w, U)] = L (w, N) where Lc(w,U) is the compensated (constant utility) labor supply function and where [L(w, N)] is uncompensated labor supply function. Using the envelope relation. L L E Lc . = W E W W Using, E L L L and W E N L L L L Lc L L = W E W N W L L Lc L = N W W Defining compensated labor supply function as, Lc L = W W u u0 6 L L = W W L u u0 (+) L W L L N (–) >0 u u0 L <0 N The negative income effect works in the opposite direction to the substitution effect and may often more than offset the positive substitution effect. Labor Supply Functions Cobb-Douglas Utility: U(c,h) = c h + =1 Constrained by two equations 1. Consumption is financed by c = w l + N, where N is non-labor income. 2. Total time constraint, set total time available = 1 l+h=1 L U (c, h) wl N c L U (c, h) w(1 h) N c L U (c, h) w wh N c L c h w N wh c L (1) c h 0 c L ( 2) c h w 0 h L (3) w N wh c 0 7 Ls = Ld a + b (w + k) = c – d (w + t) Net wage is now: w** = w* - bk dt bd w**= w* - t, w** is net wage, w* is wage inclusive of t* if k=0 workers derive no benefits. Therefore, w** = w* - dt bd Employees will pay a share of the cost (tax) = d / b + d, the equilibrium quantity of labor hired falls. This held as w S (K= 0) w* w** d d-t L1 L L0 Labor supply function is therefore L (w , N ) = 1 – h = ( 1 - ) - N w Labor supply function: L (w, N) = (1 - ) - N w 8 Properties of the Cobb-Douglass Labor Supply Function 1) If N = 0 l 0 w Person always spends (1 - ) proportion of the time for working no matter what the wage rate. 2) If N 0 then l 0 because the person spends n of it on leisure. w Leisure “costs” w per hour so an increase in the wage means fewer hours of leisure can be bought with non-wage income N. A rise in w increases labor supply. 3) l 0 An increase in non-labor income allow a person to buy more leisure so labor w supply falls. Cobb-Douglas Labor Supply Example 16.1 U= CH Budget constraint, C = wL + N and by a time constraint H=1–L To simplify matters the total time available is set equal to 1. Substituting for C and H, we have, U2 = CH = (wL + N) (1 – L) U2 = CH = wL – wL2 + N – NL U 2 L = w – 2wL – N = 0 If U2 is maximized then U will also be maximized. L= w N 1 N 2w 2 2w 9 If, N = 0, L = 1/2 Person will work ½ of the time no matter what the wage is. The income and substitution effects offset each other. Consider the income effect and substitution effect separately. The income effect in the Slutsky equation is in the case of this example, L L 1 N 1 N 1 = N 4w 4w 2 2 2 w 2 w If N = 0, income effect will be, L L 1 = N 4w Since leisure is a normal good the income effect of an increase in w on amount of labor supplied is negative. To derive the substitution effect if the Slutsky equation L W we u u0 need to derive the indirect utility function as a function of w and N. The indirect utility function is given to us as: U= U- w N 2 2 w w N w w U2 w 2 N 2 2 2 w N= 2 wU w Solving for N from indirect utility function, we have: N= 2 wU w and we use this to eliminate N in the equation for optimal labor choice L = Lc (w, U) = 1 2 wU w 2 2w 10 1 N , giving us 2 2w 1 2 wU w 1 U 1 Lc (w, U) = 2 2w 2w 2 w 2 Lc (w, U) = 1 – U w Lc U W 2w 3 2 Replacing U with indirect utility function, U = w N 2 2 w 1 N Lc = 4w 4w 2 W If N = 0, Lc 1 w 4w Hence, the Slutsky equation, L Lc L 1 1 L 0 w w N 4w 4w The substitution effect completely cancels the income effect of an increase in wage rate. Effects of Non-Labor Income If N is present the precise offsetting of income and substitution effects would not occur. From L 1 N , the individual will always choose to spend half of his or her non-labor 2 2w income on leisure. Leisure “costs” w per hour and a rise in w will mean that less leisure can be “bought” with a fixed number of N dollars. If, for example, N = $2 per hour and w is $10 per hour, from equation L = 1 N 1 2 4 we derive L = . 2 2w 2 2(10) 10 11 This person spends $1 of his or non-labor income on leisure each hour. At a wage of $10 this $1 will buy buy 1 of an hour of leisure. If, on the other hand, if w = $5, the $1 would 10 2 1 2 3 of an hour, and L = 10 2 10 10 From the labor supply function L 1 N L 1 , we have 2 2w N 2 w With non-labor income, therefore, the income and substitution effects of a change in wage rate are not now exactly offsetting the substitution effect dominates and a fall in wages reduces hours of work. An increase in N in this problem will reduce the hours of work. With N = $4 and w = 10. L 1 N 1 4 3 . Then L= . 3/10 of an hour of work supplied. For N = $10, 2 2w 2 2(10) 10 hours of work would fall to zero. If N is interpreted as a subsidy – this explains the negative labor supply effects of income maintenance programs. Individual Supply Curve of Labor Real Wage (w) Real Wage (w) S S S S Hours of work Income effect less than substitution effect Hours of work Income effect greater than substitution effect Short-run supply curves seem to be positively sloped e.g. higher overtime pay rates. In long term labor supply curves seem to be backward lending. 12 Market Supply Curve Market supply is the sum of individual supply curves – Higher wage rates increase labor force participation. Real Wage S2(W) Real Wage Real Wage S1(W) S=S1(W)+S2(W) Wmin2 Wmin1 Individual (1) Individual (2) The Market Wm in this minimum wage for person to enter the labor force. Mandated Benefits Suppose employees are required to give their workers certain benefits. The effect on the labor market is determined by how the benefits are valued by the workers. ls = a + b w ld = c – d w Ls = Ld w ca bd Suppose benefit costs t per unit of labor hired. Unit labor costs are therefore now w + t. suppose benefit has a monetary value to workers of k per unit of labor supplied. 13 c h w (1/2) c h h 1 c w nwh c (1 ) c or c wh (1 ) Full income constraint c = w + N– w h 1 c=w+N- c c c ) w N c ( c c c w N 1 c w N c (w N ) wh w N wh 1 wh wh w N 1 h w w w N 1 w w(1 ) h w N 1 1 w h w N 1 w h w N (w N ) h w Individual spends and shares of full income on consumption and leisure respectively. If k = t the new wage will fall by exactly the amount of the cost. 14 w** = w* - tk dt w* - t bd If k t the equilibrium wage will fall by more than the benefit cost and equilibrium employment will rise. S w S+k w*0 w*1 d d-t L0 L1 L For CES Utility Function: (Ch. 4) L (w, n) = 1 – h = k wl k n 1 1 w 1 If δ = 0.5 and k = -1 Supply function is l (m, n) = If n = 0 l n / w2 1 1 w l 0 because of high degree of substitutability between consumption and w leisure. 15 If δ = -1 and k = 0.5 labor supply is l (m, n) = n=0 l n / w0.5 1 w0.5 l 0 because of smaller degree of substitutability in the utility function. w Job Search Theory Wage Rate W W W S P F O m O S T G Demand for labor in open sector E O D S Q O Open Market Employment QS A B QQV QPr C Quasi-voluntary Unemployed D Number employed Protected Sector Search Unemployment Wm = minimum wage for people who will otherwise search WP = Protected sector (unionized) wage C – B = Quasi – Voluntary Unemployed B – A = Search Unemployment 16 Figure above depicts a labor market in which both search unemployment and the standard type of quasi-voluntary unemployment coexist. The curve SST shows the total supply of labor to this market. There are two employment opportunities the protected sector jobs paying high wages (WP), but they are restricted in quantity. Only the quantity QPr are available. There are plenty of jobs available at a wage of W0. However, if one is working at W0 it lowers the probability of getting a high paying job. Hence, some people would m O prefer to search for a high paying job than work for W0. The curve W S is the supply curve, inclusive of the effect of searching that faces the open market. The lateral distance O between this supply curve and the prior supply curve, SS , is the quantity of search m unemployment corresponding to a given open market wage. When the wage is W , the m number of workers who opt for search unemployment is equal to the distance W E, O whereas it is the difference between F and G at the open market wage W . This distance m is greatest at the wage W , the minimum wage at which all those not working for the protected sector would prefer to remain unemployed while searching for protected sector jobs instead of accepting open sector jobs. As the open market wage rises, fewer and fewer workers are willing to forgo open market earnings in order to seek protected sector P jobs, until, finally, as the open market wage approaches the protected sector wage, W , the quantity of search unemployment approaches zero. Economics of Child Bearing 1. Cost of child raising is primarily the foregone wages of the care givens: as w there is an income effect that suggests that more children would be demanded, at the same time the wage rate will increase the “price” of children leading to a substitution effect to cause people to have fewer children. 17 Transportation Choices Time savings are the principal benefit of transportation investments. –time saved is valued at between 50 and 100 percent of the wage they earn while working. Compensating Differentials Differences in location, job characteristics, may cause large differences in wage rates for same skill. For example, truck drivers wages in Florida $100/day versus Alaska $300/day concept of supply price of labor very important. – The competitive price at which a sufficient number of workers will make themselves available to work in a given occupation, at a given place, under given working conditions. Compensating Difference Real Wage Sunpleasant SP wu wP D Lu 18 LP Quantity of labor Labor Unions Unions as a monopoly facing a demand curve for Labor. Wage S w2 E2 S2 E1 w1 S1 w3 S3 D O L2 L1 L3 MR (1) Quantity of labor per period Union may try to maximize the wage bill wL. This is at L1 where MR = 0 and the wage rate will be w1. At w1 there will be an excess supply of labor of S1 – E1 that must not be allowed to enter the job market and bid down the wage. (2) Union may try to maximize the total economic rent accruing to its members. This will occur at the point where MR = Supply price or L2 and a wage of w2. This generates an excess supply of S2 – E2. Union must restrict entry e.g. in Germany a person must be an apprentice for 10 years to be a plumber. Doctor’s in U.S. control entry by exams for entry, but no reexamination. (3) The third possibility is to maximize the employment of its members. This involves the choosing of w3L3 which is the perfectly competitive solution. 19 Modeling a Union 1. Supply curve of workers L = 50 w Coal mine is a monopsonist. Assume: 2. MRP = 70 – 0.1 L From (1) 3. w = L 50 L2 Total wage bill Lw = 50 TC 2 L L = ME L 50 25 Monopsony position of coal mining company: ME = MRP L = 70 – 0.1 L 25 0.1 L + L = 70 25 1 1 L = 70 10 25 7 L = 70 50 50 L = 70 = 500 7 w= L 500 = = 10 50 50 Monopsonist solution is L = 500 and w = 10. If mine hired people competitively. 20 If equated demand and supply and behaved like a competition. Then MRPL = w 70 – 0.1L = w and L = 50 w Hence, 70 – 0.1 (50) w = w 6w = 70 w = 11.66 If L = 50 w then, L = 50 (11.66) = 583 Therefore, L = 583 and w = 11.66 Monopolist optimum If union behaved like a monopolist then it would set marginal increment yield to union members equal to the supply price of union or L . 50 Income to union members = L(MRP) ( L.MRP ) ( L(70 0.1L)) = 70 – 0.2L dL dL w= L 50 Hence, L = 70 – 0.2L 50 L = 3500 – 10L 11L = 3500 L = 318 at L = 318, then MRPL = 70 – 0.1 (318) = $38.2. 21 The wage would be set at $38.2. Monopolist position L = 318, w = 38.2 Monopsonist position L = 500, w = 10 Competitive position L = 583, w = 11.66 As the various positions are very different, the final outcome will have to come about by bilateral bargaining. The End 22