ECON 343 Economic Development and Growth Lecture Notes Francis T. Lui Department of Economics Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (Spring 2008) Chapter 1 Introduction Social scientists often classify countries into “developed” and “less developed” ones. What exactly do we mean by being more developed? A wide range of criteria have been used, e.g., income level, educational level or literacy rate, degree of political freedom or democratization, life expectancy, density of telephone lines, penetration rate of mobile phones or computers, etc. Among these, income level seems to be most commonly used to define the developmental stage of a country. It is something that every country wants to increase. It also shows significant co-movements with many variables that are regarded as good indicators of the stage of development. Quantitatively, we observe great diversity in both income levels and income growth rates across countries. (See Table 1.1) For example, the per capita GNI of Malawi in 2006 (using “purchasing power parity,” or PPP, measurement) was US$720, which was only 1.63% of that of the United States. The huge differences in the average long-term growth rates across countries are often less recognized. From 1978 to 2006, China’s average growth rate in per capita real GDP was 8.46%, while that for aggregate real GDP was 9.69%. This means, per capita real GDP in 2006 was 9.73 times that of 1978 (13.34 times for aggregate GDP). In another period, 185-1994, growth rate in real GDP per annum in the United States was 1.3%, Switzerland 0.5%, Hong Kong 5.3% and South Korea 7.8%. Many of the African countries, however, experienced negative long-term growth. 1 Table 1.1: Per Capita GNI in current US$ and PPP estimates (2006) Countries Per Capita GNI Per Capita GNI PPP estimates as (in current US$) (in PPP US$) % of US United States 44,970 44,260 100.0 Norway 66,530 43,820 99.0 Hong Kong 28,460 38,200 86.3 United Kingdom 40,180 35,580 80.4 France 36,550 33,740 76.3 Japan 38,410 33,150 74.9 Singapore 29,320 31,170 70.4 China 2,010 7,740 17.5 India 820 3,800 8.6 Malawi 170 720 1.6 Source: World Bank, World Development Report 2008. Differences in long-term growth could have far-reaching consequences. If a country today has an income level of $1, but wil grow at 1% a year for 50 years, then its income will be $1.64 after 50 years. If it grows at 7% a year, it will be $29.46! What is significant is that differences in long-term growth rates tend to persist. Many poor countries, which have experienced negative or very slow growth, seem to have fallen into some “poverty trap.” On the optimistic side, the kind of high growth rates that we observe today is a modern phenomenon. Take the example of China again. Table 1.2 presents the estimates by Angus Maddison (1998) for China’s per capita real GDP in “international dollar” from 50 AD to 1978 AD using 1990 prices. As we can readily see, there had been clear stagnancy for a long 2 period of time. Rapid growth only occurred in recent years. Similar phenomenon can be found in Western countries before and after the Industrial Revolution. This may hint that if a country followed the right policy, growth rate could substantially improve. Table 1.2: China’s per capita GDP in international dollars at 1990 prices 50 AD 960 1280 1820 1952 1978 $450 $450 $600 $600 $537 $979 How do we explain the diversity in long-term growth rates and income levels? This is the main focus of the course. Presumably, if we can do it, stagnant economies can learn from fast-growing ones on how they can do better. The implications for human welfare are immense. To explain growth, we need the concept of “engine of growth.” Growth means that the economy keeps on producing more and more. This is like a car that keeps on running. What drives the car or the economy? We need to identify the engine. Even if we have the engine, we need to know how the forces work inside the engine. We need to understand the “mechanics of growth.” In other words, we want to understand how the forces are transmitted through the mechanics. In addition to the mechanical side, we have to pay attention to the human side. Given that people are rational, why and when do they have the motive to go fast or slowly? 3 Chapter 2 Neoclassical or Exogenous Growth Models (2.1) Stylized Facts to be Explained by the Neoclassical Growth Models. Let Q = output, L = labor, K = capital. Also let the notation X*/X represent the growth rate of X, i.e., (dX/dt)/X. The following relations are stylized facts that the neoclassical model seeks to explain. (1) Q*/Q > L*/L. Q*/Q and L*/L are fairly stable. Define q = Q/L. The above implies that q*/q > 0. (2) K*/K is fairly stable. (3) K*/K ≈ Q*/Q. In other words, K/Q is fairly stable. (4) Profit rate is fairly constant in the long run. (This may have to be modified by more recent experiences, since the profit rates in some countries may have changed substantially.) 4 (5) The long-run relative distribution between wages and profits is fairly stable. (This does not seem to fit Hong Kong’s case too well.) (1), (2) and (3) actually imply that K*/K > L*/L. (2.2) The Solow Model. The above are derived mainly from data in the US and other highly developed countries. We should be careful about their applicability to other economies. I shall first discuss a version of the Solow model (with technical change), which is meant to provide a consistent explanation for the stylized facts above. Let the aggregate production function be Q(t) = F(K(t), E(t)), E(t) = L(t) e λt gt λt = L(0) e e , i.e., E*/E = g + λ. F is homogeneous of degree one, i.e., F(aK, aE) = aF(K, E), for a > 0. Thus, (1/E) F(K, E) = F(K/E, 1) ≡ f(k), where k ≡ K/E. Define q = Q/E = f(k). Assume that f’(k) > 0, f”(k) < 0, and f’(0) → ∞, f’(∞) = 0. 5