Speaking points for Euro50-Natixis Breakfast Seminar

advertisement
Euro50-Natixis breakfast seminar
Financial globalisation and excess liquidity:
monetary policies and new uncertainties
Remarks by
Lorenzo Bini Smaghi
Member of the Executive Board
European Central Bank
Willard Intercontinental Hotel
Crystal Room
1401 Pennsylvania Avenue, Washington DC
Sunday, 21 October 2007
Understanding liquidity
I would like to start my remarks by distinguishing two different – but related – concepts of
liquidity. The first concept of liquidity is related to the easiness with which a certain asset
can be converted into cash, which by definition is the most liquid asset. More broadly, it is
the easiness with which financial and real assets can be purchased and sold. We can call it
“market liquidity”.
In addition to the intrinsic characteristics of the financial instrument, market liquidity is
inversely related to the degree of information asymmetry prevailing among economic
agents: as shown by Akerlof in his celebrated analysis of the “market for lemons”, a market
may altogether disappear (the most extreme form of illiquidity) if information is
sufficiently asymmetric. The degree of information asymmetry can vary over time,
reflecting both fundamental factors as well as shifts in market sentiment. This is what is
happening in the present market turmoil. Liquidity is thus a time-varying variable.
Liquidity has to be distinguished from riskiness. A financial asset can be very risky but at
the same time very liquid, if its risk is precisely and broadly understood. Having said this, it
is also more likely for a risky asset to be subject to asymmetric information. Therefore, risk
appetite and liquidity often go hand in hand. A general re-pricing of risk may be
accompanied by shifts in the degree of liquidity of the market.
The second concept of liquidity is the quantity of liquid assets held by households and
firms. This reflects, for the most part, portfolio decisions by economic agents in relation to
prevailing monetary and financial conditions, the latter linked to, inter alia, the stance of
monetary policy. We can call this second concept “macro liquidity”.
Over recent years we have seen a surge in macro liquidity, in tandem with an unusually low
level of short and long-term interest rates. In my opinion, and as I have argued elsewhere1,
financial globalisation has substantially contributed to the creation of global macro
liquidity. This has been due to the combination of high savings in developing countries
such as China, which have increased the appetite for liquid assets (due to precautionary
1
L. Bini Smaghi (2007): Global imbalances and monetary policy, Journal of Policy Modeling, 29, pp. 711727.
motives and the willingness to accumulate foreign reserves), and insufficient production of
financial liabilities, as a result of the still underdeveloped legal and financial technology.
The net result of this process may have been a downward push on real (short-term and
long-term) equilibrium interest rates, which explains the apparently paradoxical coexistence of strong global growth and low real interest rates. This has allowed central banks
in advanced countries to keep interest rates low without igniting inflationary pressures.
However, expansionary monetary policies and carry trades may have contributed to
temporarily rising global macro liquidity, and it is not easy to disentangle these temporary
phenomena from more long-lasting influences.
The two concepts of global liquidity that I have described are different but related. If
financial globalisation has been pushing down expected returns, it might also have affected
incentives towards risk-taking in financial markets (not only by households but also by
financial intermediaries, especially portfolio managers). This is what is commonly referred
to as the “search for yield”. It may also have affected the incentives to collect information
in financial markets, which (in the spirit of Grossman and Stiglitz) is a commodity like any
other and is influenced by market prices (expected returns in this case). Low interest rates
may therefore have directly contributed to creating information asymmetries, sowing the
seeds for the liquidity problems that we experience nowadays.
The relationship between market and macro liquidity is not necessarily stable. Indeed, in
normal times abundant global macro liquidity tends to be associated with high market
liquidity, reflecting low interest rates and spreads. However, at times of financial turmoil,
market liquidity may dry out even in the presence of abundant macro liquidity if, as is
currently the case, the latter is not exchanged between market participants who want to
retain for themselves available financing rather than trading it. Also in this case, in
financial markets quantities are not always the mirror image of prices.
What can central banks do?
Central banks can do mainly three things to take into account the impact of changing
liquidity conditions on the economy.
First, central banks should monitor both indicators of liquidity. This is important from both
a monetary policy and a financial stability perspective. In fact, shocks affecting monetary
and credit aggregates and more generally liquidity conditions have the potential, as we are
seeing now, to affect asset prices, confidence, credit conditions and ultimately inflationary
pressure. This is why it is important to monitor liquidity, in a broad sense, from a monetary
policy perspective.
The two-pillar strategy of the ECB is an asset in this respect. Indeed, the monetary analysis
pays close attention to trends in monetary and credit aggregates and to the behaviour of the
banking sector. In the current market turmoil, it enables the provision of information on
several key variables which would not be available under simpler frameworks.
Central banks have to be aware, of course, that financial innovation and globalisation may
complicate the monetary analysis and affect the impact of monetary policy on the creation
of liquidity by the private sector. In particular, the recent market turmoil may have
increased the amount of reserves in central bank money that banks need in order to carry
out their intermediation role, leading to a dampening of the money multiplier.
Second, central banks should warn market participants not to take liquidity for granted,
especially market liquidity, and to test their portfolio decisions also under stressful
conditions. The ECB has repeatedly expressed the concern that buoyant global liquidity
and risk appetite could result in an abrupt re-pricing of risk and sudden shifts in liquidity,
as we have witnessed in recent months. For example, the June 2007 Financial Stability
Review (FSR), prior to the August turmoil, stated: “If history is any guide, liquidity can
vanish abruptly from financial markets when investor uncertainty and risk aversion rise…
and primary issuers… could struggle to find investors for their securities. Some banks
would also face heightened counterparty risks if the institutions they have extended credit
to are thrown into financial distress.”
Finally, a central bank should stand ready to ensure the proper functioning of the payment
system and the money market, even in case of disruption, so that its monetary policy
impulse is adequately transmitted to the economy. The ECB and other central banks have
done so since early August, lending funds to market participants with a view to promoting
appropriate market liquidity conditions. However, the restoration of normal conditions over
the whole maturity spectrum does not hinge only on central bank action but also on the
return of confidence and trust by market participants, both in the other participants and in
themselves. Financial institutions still fear the risk that some counterparties may face
funding problems, as reflected in the high spreads on credit default swaps. They also seem
to fear the risk of not being able themselves to access funding in the market, if needed, in
particular towards the end of the year when financial accounts will be completed. Financial
institutions are thus aggressively bidding for funds and keeping these funds on their
balance sheets rather than lending them to other banks, thus taking advantage of the high
spreads. Some kind of end-of-the-year fear, similar to the Y2K problem experienced at the
start of this century, seems to have developed.
This fear is totally unjustified. Central banks have clearly shown their willingness and
availability to intervene in the market to maintain orderly conditions. The ECB, in
particular, has recently announced its intention to intensify its actions aimed at reducing the
variability of the overnight rate around the MRO rate.2 This has partly contributed to
reducing the spread on the three-month interbank rate. The ECB will continue this strategy,
including around the end of the year, if the need arises. There can be no doubt about this.
There should thus be no Y2K-type fear in the markets. The experience of Y2K itself has
shown that central banks are fully equipped to manage this type of situation.
MRO stands for main refinancing operation. A press release on 8 October 2007 stated that “The ECB
continues to closely monitor liquidity conditions and aims at further reducing the volatility of very short term
rates around the MRO minimum bid rate. For this purpose, the ECB will reinforce its policy of allocating
more liquidity than the benchmark amount in main refinancing operations to accommodate the demand of
counterparties to fulfil reserve requirements early within the maintenance period. The difference between the
allotted and the benchmark amount is envisaged to decline gradually in the course of the maintenance period,
taking into account the prevailing market conditions. The ECB still aims at balanced liquidity conditions at
the end of the maintenance period. The ECB will steer liquidity towards more balanced conditions also during
the maintenance period, in a way which is consistent with the objective to keep very short term rates close to
the minimum bid rate. The ECB will follow this policy for as long as needed.”
2
Download