China and Brazil after the great recession XVI ENCONTRO DE ECONOMIA DA REGIÃO SUL Área 5: Economia Internacional André Moreira Cunha – PPGE/UFRGS and CNPq. E-mail: andre.cunha@ufrgs.br Julimar da Silva Bichara. UAM/Spain. Email: julimar.dasilva@uam.es Marcos Tadeu Caputi Lélis. Unisinos. Email: mcaputi@uol.com.br Abstract: This paper aims at analysing the impacts of China’s rise on Latin American countries. The literature on the topic has stressed the emergence of an asymmetrical pattern of relationship, where the region would be trapped in a less dynamic status of producer and exporter of raw materials. We focus on identifying the post-global financial crisis trends, providing fresh evidence concerning the characteristics of Sino-Latin American economic relationships, emphasizing the Brazilian experience. Ours results suggest that, particularly in the Brazilian case, there is evidence of the emergence of an increasingly regressive pattern of production and trade specialisation. Key Words: regressive specialisation; great recession; Brazil, China JEL: F5; F63 Resumo: Este trabalho analisa a evolução recente, nos marcos do quadro da grande recessão, das relações entre China e América Latina, com ênfase para o caso do Brasil. A despeito das intenções de reorientação do seu modelo de crescimento, a resposta chinesa à crise reforçou a dependência das exportações e dos investimentos. Assim, para além do papel de fornecedora de recursos naturais, as economias latino-americanas passam a ter uma importância renovada como destino das exportações de manufaturas e capitais chineses. Países com estruturas produtivas mais maduras e diversificadas, como o Brasil, irão deparar-se com o risco de um processo de regressão em seus padrões de especialização. Palavras-chave: especialização regressiva; grande recessão; Brasil; China Introduction This paper offers a Brazilian perspective on China´s rise. Many commentators have argued that the global economy will be increasingly Asian-centred and Sino-centred in the decades to come1, which has stimulated a growing literature about the impacts of such a transformation on Latin American countries (Jenkins, 2010; Phillips, 2011). The emergence of an asymmetrical pattern of relationship, where the region would be trapped in a less dynamic status of producer and exporter of raw materials, has received particular attention (Bittencourt, 2012; Rosales and Kuwayama, 2012; Ferchen, 2012). Accordingly, China´s interaction with the region could reinforce long-term problems such as the “natural resource curse” (Sachs and Warner, 1987; Sinnot, Nash and De La Torre, 2010), the “Dutch Disease” and the deindustrialisation (Rowthorn and Wells, 1987; Palma, 2007). As a consequence the region’s development perspectives could be undermined. This paper highlights how China´s rise as a global power has affected Latin American economies, drawing special attention to the post-2008 period. Most previous analyses have focused on pre-crisis tendencies. Considering that the Sino-Latin American relationship has evolved rapidly we must take into account the new landscape brought about by the great recession2. We provide some fresh evidence 1 See, among others: Goldman Sachs (2007); Castro (2008); Cepal (2011); Canuto and Giugale (2010); Halper (2010); Subramanian (2011); Jacques (2012). 2 Phillips (2011) argues that “(things) are changing very rapidly in Chinese, Latin American and Sino-Latin American landscape, and one wonders, reading these volumes, whether many conclusions that the authors draw from their analyses will stand the test of time”. Moreover, that 1 concerning the characteristics of Sino-Latin American economic relationships, emphasizing the Brazilian experience. While bilateral trade and financial cooperation have surged, China has engaged in a new wave of diplomacy towards Latin America (Dadush and Shimelse, 2012; Ferchen, 2012; Jiabao, 2012). We suggest that China’s increased interest in the region represents a crucial challenge to Brazil. When other major partners, such as the United States and the European Union, tried to promote free trade agreements with Brazil, throughout Mercosur, the country rejected their attempts, because Brazilian negotiators realized that the policy space to stimulate the country’s economy would be reduced, its manufacturing sector would be threatened, and agricultural exports would be restricted by protectionism. Now, China has created new pressures which potentially reinforce regional divergences. The re-emerging power offers a huge market for raw materials and financial support as well (Jinbao, 2012), which seduce many sectors within Brazil and its regional partners. At the same time, China’s exports of manufactured products and capital threaten local producers. In this context, we show evidence that the Brazilian economy’s competitive gaps with China have increased. We have focused Brazil because while small open economies in the region are more prone to explore their comparative advantages and complementarities with Asian emerging countries, particularly with China, Brazil tends to prioritize its manufacturing sector, domestic market and regional partnerships (Cepal, 2011; Eclac, 2012; Rosales and Kuwayama, 2012; Bittencourt, 2012; Estevadeordal, 2012). Moreover, previous studies usually addressed the regional perspective or case studies of other countries rather than Brazil. Our emphasis in Sino-Brazilian relationship is also important because China and Brazil are, respectively, the world’s second and sixth largest economies. Nevertheless, since the early 1980s both countries have experienced markedly different trajectories. While the Brazilian economy has had a weak economic performance, particularly in terms of capital accumulation, productivity gains and physical and social infrastructure, the Chinese economy has experienced one of the most remarkable structural transformations in the modern era (Palma, 2007 and 2012; Rodrik and McMillan, 2012). Our main hypothesis is that despite the intentions of a growth model re-orientation, Chinese policymakers’ response to the great recession reinforced, at least in the short and medium terms, the previous reliance on exports and investments (Ferby, 2011). Considering the sluggish recovery in advanced economies, this strategy will amplify Chinese pressures to access dynamic domestic markets in emerging countries (Rodrik, 2011). In this context, Latin America will represent not only a source of natural resources but an increasingly important market for manufactured products. Accordingly, countries with more diverse productive and export structures might experience a regressive pattern of specialisation. That is, a reversal of the modernisation trends experienced during the developmentalist period (1930s to 1980s) which resulted in the emergence of productive and foreign trade structures characterised, among other things, by: (i) diversification – at sector and product levels; (ii) an increase in manufacturing sector’s share in the total value added; (iii) an increase in manufacturing products’ share in total merchandise exports; and (iv) a significant increase in productivity associated with those structural changes (McMillan and Rodrik, 2011; Thirlwall, 2011; Palma, 2007 and 2011). Therefore, a regressive specialisation should be expected when productivity is stagnated, manufacturing sector value added grows below the GDP average, and exports are increasingly natural resources-oriented. Using different production and trade performance indicators we have identified a reinforcement trend in that direction. We organize our arguments as follows: firstly we present the broader picture of what the literature concerning the impacts of China’s rise on Latin America has argued; then we examine some features of the Chinese internationalisation process and its impacts on the region, emphasising the post-2008 period. We conclude by exploring some potential implications of our results. literature did not incorporate the effects of the great recession. Recent comprehensive research, such as Bittencourt (2012), has also emphasized pre-crisis trends. 2 2. China and Latin America: back to the past? Between the 1820s and 1930s, Latin American countries followed an outward development model, based on production and trade specialisation in agriculture and mining (Prebisch, 1984; Furtado, 2003; Unctad, 2003). The export-led model based on agriculture and mining did not deliver stability, self-sustained growth and the modernization of the institutions and the economy. During this period the region experienced fiscal and external imbalances, which had to be financed by volatile capital flows, thanks to the fact that the export sector, mainly dependent on commodities, was incapable of generating enough hard currency to finance the merchandise imports demand and other financial commitments. Capital flow reversals were frequent, and government used to be pressured by creditors to promote deflationary adjustments in domestic income and absorption. During that period the business cycles of Latin American peripheral countries were tightly correlated with the core countries’ business cycles, led by Great Britain, the then hegemonic power. Industrialisation and urbanisation at the core increased the demand for natural resources at the periphery, which helped to improve the terms of trade. The interwar crisis opened room for a radical change. The breakdown of the global trading system, the collapse of the gold standard, the outbreak of the World War II, and the hegemonic transition from Great Britain to the United States brought to an end the export-oriented model. Latin American countries started to manufacture goods previously imported from the ‘centre’, in a process lately named ‘import substitution’. The ‘development from within’, led by the State, generated reasonable results until its crisis in 1980s (Unctad, 2003). This historical summary is important to our argument because some structural features of the outward oriented model pursued by Latin American countries, particularly the overdependence on production and export of natural resources, has returned, particularly in the early twenty-first century. Differently from the previous period, countries such as Brazil are not fighting to industrialise their economies, but, instead, they are trying to avoid re-primarisation3 of their exports and deindustrialisation. From theoretical and political perspectives, many development economists and other scholars and policymakers have assumed that development implies economic and social structural transformations within countries in order to achieve higher living standards (Thirlwall, 2011). Based on the pioneers of development economics and their contemporary followers it should be argued that: investment is a key determinant of income expansion; the economic growth process is not sector-indifferent or linear and stable; manufacturing leads economic growth thanks to its backward and forward linkages to other sectors; technological progress has, at least in a certain extent, an endogenous dynamics associated with the capital accumulation led by the manufacturing sector; and income-elasticity differences in manufacturing products and natural resource-intensive products to balance of payments constraints to economic growth. The latter is in a context where primary-product prices tend to decline in relation to manufacture product prices in the long run. In short, manufacturing matters and governments should have an active role to support structural transformations. Emphasizing this point, the higher the growth of the manufacturing sector and its productivity, the higher will be the growth of the whole economy and the productivity of other economic sectors. Therefore, in order to achieve growth-cum-stability, governments should prioritise the industrialisation process or avoid deindustrialisation (Palma, 2007; Thirlwall, 2011; Rodrik and McMillan, 2012). Considering this broader picture, it is worth mentioning that since the late 1970s, under the umbrella of Deng Xiaoping’s strategy of reforms and economic opening4, China has been re-emerging as a global power. Its rapid economic growth and internationalisation process resulted in the fact that in 2011 China was responsible for more than 10% of global trade, 10% of the world´s GDP measured at market prices, and 14% of the world’s GDP measured using purchasing-power-parity (IMF, 2012). The Asian superpower has also 3 It refers to the composition of exports, where raw materials share on total exports surpass manufacturing products share, particularly technology-intensive products (Bresser-Pereira, 2009 and 2010; Oreiro and Feijó, 2010). 4 See, among others: Zheng Bijian (2005); Kang (2007); Naughton, (2007); Kurlantzick (2007.); Hao, Wei and Ditter (2009); Halper (2010); Kissinger (2011). 3 become an important player in global financial markets, holding more than USD 3 trillion in foreign exchange reserves and USD 300 billion in foreign direct investment (FDI) abroad. The country is the world’s second largest net creditor5. As argued by Jacques (2012) China might still be a middle income economy, but it is no long a weak country. Even if Chinese economic and technological capabilities cannot match the most advanced countries’ ones, as Nolan (2012) points out, China’s rise can markedly affect other low and middle income countries. China’s re-emergence as a global power is part of a broader process, which is the consolidation of Asia as the most dynamic growth pole of the globalized economy (Yang, 2006; Palma, 2007 and 2011; Canuto and Giugale, 2010; Timmer et al. 2011). In 2010, Asia’s shares in world population, income and exports were, respectively, 55%, 34% and 30%. To put in perspective, in 1980 Latin America accounted for 11% of the world GDP (measured in purchasing power parity), while Asia’s share (excluding Japan) was 9%.Three decades later, Latin America had 8.5% and Asia, 28%. During this period, Asian countries averaged a GDP growth of 7% per year, while Latin American and African countries experienced lower rates, between 2% to 3% (IMF, 2012). Considering the manufacturing sector value added (United Nations, 2012), Asian countries’6 contribution to the world total increased from 4.4% to 27.6%, and Latin America’s7 share decreased from 6.7% to 5.5%. Advanced countries8 and the rest of the world also experienced a relative reduction in their shares, respectively, from 61.1% to 47% and from 27.8% to 20.8%. Similar figures can be found for merchandise trade9. Considering production and technological capabilities, it should be stressed that China’s rapid modernization markedly contrasts with the Latin American and the Brazilian semi-stagnation. Figure 1 shows that Brazil used to be a catch-up country until the late 1970s. Nevertheless, since the early 1980s Asian economies in general, and China, in particular, have experienced impressive records in capital accumulation (panel B) and in efficiency improvements measured both by labour productivity (panel A) and total factor productivity (panel C). Figure 1. Capital Accumulation and Productivity in Selected Economies, 1960-2011 5 See, among others, Deutsche Bank (2011); Unctad (2011), Morrison and Labonte (2011, p.2). Asia 9 = China, India, Korea, Philippines, Indonesia, Hong Kong, Thailand, Singapore and Malaysia. 7 AL 7 = Mexico, Brazil, Argentina, Colombia, Chile, Peru and Venezuela. 8 G7 = United States, Japan, Germany, Italy, United Kingdom, France and Canada. 9 In 1980, Asia 9’s share of the world exports was 4.4%. In 2010, it was 27.2%. In the same timeframe, AL7’s share decreased from 6.7% to 5%. 6 4 (B) Gross capital formation, 1960-2010 (% of GDP) (A) Labour Productivity, 1960-2011 (GDP per Person Employed, in 1990 GK $) 45 80.000 40 68.155 70.000 35 60.000 43.275 20 7.992 1960 East Asia & Pacific (developing only) High income: OECD Latin America & Caribbean Brazil 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 Japan United States Germany 10 1964 15 1.120 Mexico 8.939 1.998 India 4.451 South Korea - 13.690 6.148 Brazil 10.000 25 19.725 14.914 14.196 12.696 China 30.000 20.000 30 29.874 1962 40.000 40.953 1960 45.158 50.000 2011 (C) Total Factor Productivity - Cumulative Growth, 1990- 2009 (1990=100) 180 163 160 158 141 140 120 116 109 98 93 100 89 80 60 40 20 0 Germany United States China India Japan South Korea Brazil Mexico Source: author´s calculation based on (i) The Conference Board Total Economy Database™, January 2012. Available at: http://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/ (obtained on 25/04/ 2012); and (ii) World Bank (2012). To put in perspective, China has invested, on average, more than 40% of its GDP since the early 2000s. In the same period Latin American economies have invested 20% of their GDP (World Bank, 2012). In 2010, China’s gross fixed capital formation amounted USD 1,394 billion, while all Latin American economies invested only USD 628 billion. The Brazilian cumulative investment from 2001 to 2010 was USD 1,262 billion, which is less than Chinese investment in 2010 only10. China’s investment per worker evolved from USD 178 in 1990 to USD 1,747 in 2010, while Brazilian figures were, respectively, USD 1,347 and USD 1,699. As a consequence of its investments, massive pool of workers, and development strategy, China has become the world’s factory. Chinese manufacturing sector produced USD 1,654 billion in 2010, more than three times the production of USD 531 billion observed in all Latin American (United Nations, 2012). China has surpassed Latin America in research and development expenditures as a share of GDP. Between 2001 and 2009, Chinese technology outlays averaged 1.2% of its GDP, while Latin American averaged 0.6% and high income countries 2.4% (World Bank, 2012). It is important to stress that most of the global value chains, trade, research and development, marketing, and finance are under the control of transnational corporations (Nolan, 2012). These corporations come mainly from advanced countries and since the early 1980s have intensified the reallocation of their physical production. Some emerging countries, particularly in Asia, have hosted them and, as a consequence, important shares of exports from emerging countries are, essentially, exports from advanced countries’ corporations located in emerging economies (Gill and Kharas, 2007). In this context, there is a huge difference between “Made in” and “Designed, Marketed or Financed in”. This explains why policymakers in countries such as China have been emphasizing developmental policies aimed to consolidate “national champions” and to up-grade indigenous technological capabilities (Casey and Koleski, 2011; Nolan, 2011; Wong, 2011). 10 In 2000 constant US$. Source: World Bank (2012). 5 China’s presence in global markets has become a major source of dynamism, whose impacts have deeply affected through trade and financial channels both advanced and emerging economies. This reality also implies that China’s rise has not been perceived as neutral in a geopolitical sense. The recent literature on that topic explores sensitive issues such as whether China will eventually overtake the United States as the major global power, whether its rise will be peaceful or not, whether there is a Chinese model alternative11 to the Western liberal model, and so forth12. China has become a major partner for many countries in Latin America (Cepal, 2011; Eclac, 2012; Rosales and Kuwayama, 2012; Bittencourt, 2012). Trade and FDI have boomed and China’s demand for raw materials has represented an important source of dynamism for countries rich in natural resources, particularly in South America13. Studies about the impacts of China’s rise on Latin America can be divided into, at least, three different perspectives (Jenkins, 2010; Phillips, 2011). The optimistic view stresses that China’s pattern of development and internationalisation has increased export revenues for countries rich in natural resources. 14 The rise in terms of trade has helped to improve fiscal and external accounts; cheap consumer goods and low-cost machinery and parts have increased consumers’ welfare and producers’ competitiveness. China has become a new source of capital to finance infrastructure projects and external deficits. Moreover, local companies would be able to integrate into global production networks through strategic partnerships with Chinese companies. The pessimistic view15 usually admits the potential benefits listed above. Nevertheless, it emphasises that China’s rise represents a return to the classic centre–periphery dichotomy16, in the sense that it tends to reinforce regional specialisation in primary commodity production, while the manufacturing sector contracts in the face of increased Chinese competition both at home and abroad. Another adverse effect could be the FDI diversion, where multinational companies relocate their plants from Latin America to China in Asia. A third perspective17 explores the differentiated impacts of China on the region, where Mexico, Central America and the Caribbean emerge as potential losers, because they face competition from Chinese manufactured goods in the United States’ market and have not been major exporters to China, while South American countries would be the winners who have benefited from Chinese demand for raw materials and food, and supply of cheaper consumer goods. We consider that Brazil must be treated as a mixed case, because, while it is a major producer and exporter of natural resources, it has also a large manufacturing sector. As a consequence, the country has experienced both positive stimulus from Chinese demand for raw material and food and competitive pressures from its exports, particularly to Latin American countries, which are the main destinies for Brazilian exports of manufactured products. 3. New Normal and China’s Response to the Great Recession China was deeply affected by the global financial crisis, particularly through trade channels (Wong, 2011; Nolan, 2011 and 2012; Fenby, 2011). In order to avoid a recession, the policy response was “quick, Breslin (2011) provides an updated discussion on the so-called “China model” debate. Ramo (2004) advanced the term “Beijing Consensus” to illustrate the Chinese pattern of development as an alternative to the Washington Consensus. In a Chinese perspective, Kang (2007), Zheng Bijian (2005), Wu Jinglian (2005) and Hu Angang (2010) believe that China´s rise represents both a positive element to the global order and a stimulus to the own process of Chinese modernization. Nye Jr (2011), Kissinger (2011) and Ikenberry (2011) argue that the United States and China can cooperate and mutually be benefited in the consolidation of a liberal and multilateral new world order in the 21st century. According to then it would be possible to envisage that rise in a global “peaceful and harmonious” landscape. Mearsheimer (2006; 2010) is skeptical about the so-called “peaceful rise”. Halper (2010) and Subramanian (2011) argue that China will overtake the Western powers, while Shirk (2007), Babones (2011), Clark (2011) and Nolan (2012) assume the opposite reasoning. They consider that Chinese power has been overstated and its fragilities have been underestimated. 13 See: CAF (2006); Devlin, Estevadeordal and Rodriguez (2006); Lederman, Olarreaga and Perry (2008); Jenkins (2010); CEPAL (2011); Leão, Pinto and Acioly (2011). 14 Yang (2006), Devlin, Estevadeordal and Rodríguez-Clare (2006); Blazquez-Lidoy, Rodrıguez and Santiso (2006); Castro (2008). Phillips (2011) reviews influent books published between 2008 and 2010. For the Brazilian case see Leão, Pinto and Acioly (2011). 15 Moreira (2007), Paus (2007), Jenkins (2010), Leão, Pinto and Acioly (2011). 16 See Prebisch (1984); Furtado (2003). 17 Rosales and Kuwayama (2007 and 2012); Cepal (2011); Leão, Pinto and Acioly (2011). 11 12 6 determined, and effective” (IMF, 2010, p. 4). On the fiscal front the RMB 4 trillion (or USD 586 billion) public stimulus included infrastructure spending, which resembled the previous reaction during the 19971998 Asian crisis. It also comprised an expansion of social spending (equivalent to 2 to 3 percent of GDP) and incentives to support private consumption. Monetary policy stimulated a massive credit expansion. These policies were successful if one considers that GDP growth stood around 9% between 2008 and 2011. The Chinese post-crisis strategy reinforced the previous path of growth centred in investments and exports. Despite the fact that the 11th and the 12th Five-Year Plans have emphasised income redistribution and improvements in the social safe net in order to bust household consumption18 (Angang Hu, 2010; Nolan, 2012), investment as a share of GDP increased after 2008, while household consumption kept its decline trend19. Nevertheless, the country has consolidated its position as the world’s second largest economy and the world’s largest exporter. Of course, after 2008, economic and political landscape offers new sources of instability and, potentially, new waves of speculation and low economic growth. Advanced economies’ sluggish recovery, the euro zone crisis, Chinese local governments’ indebtedness, speculation on commodity markets and emerging countries assets, to name but a few, are well-known candidates for the next round of turbulences (Wong, 2011; Nolan, 2011, 2012; Fenby, 2011; Chang, 2011; Rodrik, 2011; Cepal, 2011; Eclac, 2012; Rosales and Kuwayama, 2012). For the purpose of this paper it is important to emphasize that three crucial features of Chinese postcrisis strategy are (Aoki and Wu Jinglian, 2013): (i) markets and products diversification; (ii) national companies’ internationalisation; and (iii) a pro-active diplomacy20 to spread its influence among developing countries and in the global governance structures. Here, we provide fresh evidence of the trade performance and the foreign direct investment (FDI). We can see the market diversification through the concentration rate of exports (CR)21,22. In 1995 the CR(10) of Chinese exports was 54%, while in 2011 it was 47%. Western advanced countries still rank as important markets for Chinese exports. Nevertheless, regional partners and emerging countries, such as Brazil, have been representing an increasing share of Chinese trade 23. In order to access the product dimension of Chinese exports diversification, considering their final destination, we calculate the Herfindhal-Hirschman Index (HHI)24. An index below 1,000 suggests lower concentration or higher diversification. Chinese exports can be considered diversified in all final destinies, particularly in Latin America, Asia and Africa. Moreover, since 2003 exports have become even more diversified25. “The 12th FYP is distinctive in its heightened focus on economic restructuring, the environment and energy efficiency, and scientific development. Differences between key targets and how these key targets are categorized in the 11th and 12th FYP reflect changing government priorities. These indicators reveal that the 12th FYP places greater emphasis upon economic development versus simply growth, scientific education, and improving overall welfare.” (Casey and Koleski, 2011, p.2) 19 For the period 2001-2007, consumption as a share of GDP averaged 40.6%. In 2008 to 2010 these figures were, respectively, 35.2, 35.6 and 33.5. Investment as a share of GDP averaged 40.8% between 2001 and 2007, and reached 48.3% in 2009 and 2010. See: Asian Development Bank - Asian Development Bank - Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific 2011 (http://beta.adb.org/key-indicators/2011/country-tables, access – 24/01/2012). 20 See, among others, Kurlantzick (2007), Hao Yufan, Wei and Ditter (2009), Halper (2010), Aladi (2011) and Wen (2012). 21 We calculate the concentration rate using GTIS (2012). CR(1) is the share of the major trade partner in total exports; CR(2) is the share of the two largest trade partners, and so on. 22 For this and the following trade performance indicators (Herfindhal-Hirschman Index, trade intensity, trade complementarity etc.) data were disaggregated according to the CNAE 1.0 (Classificação Nacional das Atividades Econômicas – IBGE) which corresponds to the three-digit level of the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC rev 3), except from the H-H Index that was calculated at the two digit level. 23 In 2002, high-income countries absorbed 85% of China’s exports, while developing countries responded for 15%; in 2010, these figures were, respectively, 74% and 26% (World Bank, 2012). 18 We calculated the Exports Concentrations Index using the formula: ; where: (i) pi represents sector “i’s” share in total exports of the country “j”, normalized by the number of observations, “n”. See: Hoekman, Mattoo and English (2002). 25 The 2008-2011 averages in each market were: 939.9 (USA); 905.0 (Euro zone); 712.3 (Africa); 713.2 (Asia, exc. China, Macau, Taiwan and Hong Kong); 703.1 (Latin America). Source: authors’ estimations based on GTIS (2012). 24 7 We also estimate the trade intensity index of Chinese exports26. For the 2008-2011 period, the average figures ranged from 1.02 (Africa) to 1.73 (United States). Euro zone index was 0.66, which means that trade between China and the Euro Zone is less intense than it would be expected considering the importance of the region as a destination of the world’s exports. We also noticed a slight reduction of trade intensity between China and the United States after 2008; and that trade intensity between China and its partners in Africa and Latin America increased rapidly in the last few years. China’s trade pattern has also deeply changed. In 1995, primary products and manufactured products that are labour, natural resource and scale intensive represented 81% of total exports, while high-technology, high-value added and other products accounted for 19%. In 2011, these figures were, respectively, 60% and 40%27. In the imports side there was a major increase in both natural resource and science based products. It has been argued that important bulks of these exports represent labour-intense activities of each industry value chain, which, ultimately, is controlled by advanced countries’ transnational corporations (Nolan, 2012). Nevertheless, in a dynamic analysis, and considering the perspective of low and middle income countries, that upgrade has intensified competitive pressures upon local producers. If, in the next years, Chinese companies succeed in their effort to catch-up with advanced economies leading companies, that pressure might be even greater. The rapid internationalisation of Chinese companies, particularly the state-owned ones, has been a major trend in the post-2008 period. Trying to estimate the amount of FDI originated in China can be a tricky exercise (Salidjanova, 2011). Official figures reported by the Ministry of Commerce (Mofcom, 2011) and mainly reproduced by the United Nations Commission on Trade and Development (Unctad, 2011) usually diverge significantly from official data of host countries and, moreover, from the investments announced by the Chinese companies themselves. One major methodological problem is that official data ignores companies’ strategies to use Hong Kong and tax havens as transit points (hubs) for their investments. For example, according to MOFCOM, 2/3 of Chinese FDI stock is hosted in Hong Kong. Non-official sources, such as the Heritage Foundation (2012) or FDI Markets (2012) have tried to track what Chinese companies have actually been doing. They report important differences for the same trend. Nevertheless, all sources converge in a fundamental point: since 2008 Chinese outward investments have boomed, despite the great recession. It is reasonable to assume that Chinese companies invested abroad something between USD 230 to 240 billion from 2005 to 2010. The Unctad (2011) informs that FDI stock abroad was about USD 297.6 billion in 2010, which makes China the eighteenth largest investor with 1.5% of world total stock. Nevertheless, in 2010, and considering not stocks, but flows, China was the fifth largest source of foreign investments, amounting USD 68 billion. In order to characterise the geographical distribution of the Chinese FDI Table 1 ranks regions according to the relative intensity of the investment. Emerging regions, such as Latin America, Africa and Middle East, which are abundant in natural resources, have been receiving more attention from Chinese companies than the world’s average. Table 1. China – FDI Regional Distribution Announced Investments, 2005-2011 (until June) Latin America Middle East Africa Asia and Oceania Europe North America A. China B. World 14.7% 11.6% 19.5% 38.1% 12.0% 4.2% 4.5% 4.6% 9.7% 51.9% 16.8% 12.4% Relative Intensity (A/B) 3.26 2.52 2.00 0.73 0.71 0.34 26 Authors’ estimations based GTIS (2012) data. We use the formula: Tij = (xij/Xit)/(xwj/Xwt), where: (i) xij and xwj are the values of country i’s exports and of world exports to country j; and (ii) Xit and Xwt are country i’s total exports and total world exports, respectively. An index of more (less) than unity suggests that their bilateral trade flow is larger (smaller) than expected, given the partner country’s share in world trade. See Hoekman, Mattoo and English (2002). 27 Author’s estimation using Pavitt (1984) taxonomy and data from GTIS (2012). 8 Source: authors’ estimations based on FDI Markets (2012). Evidence suggests that the great recession has been perceived as an opportunity to China’s companies. FDI has been a major driver to access markets, new technologies and strategic natural resources (Nolan, 2011, 2012). In the next section we explore how these new trends have affected Latin American countries. 4. China and Latin America with a special reference to Brazil Since 2002, the Latin American and Caribbean region has been reducing its income gap relative to industrialised countries. Inflation is no longer a dramatic problem in most of the countries. Improvements in the terms of trade marked the post-2002 period, as a reflection of commodities’ price boom. In this context, most countries experienced current account surpluses, which helped to reduce the external vulnerability. External debt as a share of the GDP or exports revenues was reduced. Governments produced fiscal primary surpluses and public debt/GDP ratio decreased (Cepal, 2011; Rosales and Kuwayama, 2012). The new landscape was a result of the international buoyant markets of the 2003 to 2008 period, combined with the implementation of national policies aimed to redistribute income and to overcome decades of low levels of investment, both by public and private sectors. Notwithstanding, many Latin American countries experienced a re-primarisation of its exports. Trade with Asia is particularly characterized by a North-South pattern, where Latin American countries export natural resource-intensive products and import manufactured products. Considering the Latin America’s export structure to its main destinations it is remarkable that, except for intra-regional trade and the Mexico-United States trade, the North-South pattern is dominant (Cepal, 2011; Rosales and Kuwayama, 2012). It is worth mentioning that most of South American countries already had a highly specialized production and trade structures. Countries such as Argentina, Chile, Colombia and Venezuela, among others, have had 60% to 95% of their exports concentrated in primary products. Brazil and Mexico, who have the largest manufacturing sectors in the region, experienced a structural change in their trade profile after 1970, characterized by an increase in the manufactured products’ share in total exports. Nevertheless, since 2002 primary exports share has increased, particularly in Brazil. Echoing Prebisch (1984) and the Latin American structuralism (Unctad, 2003), Figure 2 shows business cycles synchronization between Brazil and its main trade partners between 1975 and 2010, measured trough the 15 year-window rolling correlations of real output fluctuations using Hodrick-Prescott filter (Baster and King, 1999). It suggests that the country’s business cycles have been much more correlated with Asian economies, particularly China, and with its Latin American neighbours, than with the United States, Brazil’s former main trade partner, or the other advanced countries. Following the empirical strategy pioneered by Frankel and Rose (1998) and expanded by Calderón (2008), the Appendix provides an exercise which suggests that bilateral trade intensity helps to explain that synchronisation. Calderón (2008) found similar results considering Latin American countries in their relation to China and India. Cesa-Bianchi et al. (2011) also showed that because of trade channels the long-term impact of a China GDP shock on the typical Latin American economy has tripled since the mid-1990s, while the longterm impact of a US GDP shock has halved. In a recent report, the Inter-American Development Bank (IADB, 2012) assumes that the evolution of Chinese economy has increasingly become important to the region. Figure 2. Business Cycles Synchronization between Brazil and Its Main Trade Partners, 1975-2010* 9 (B) Asia (A) Main Partners 1 1 0,8 0,5 0,6 0,4 0,2 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 0 -0,2 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 0 -0,5 -0,4 -0,6 -1 Argentina USA (C) Latin America 0,5 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 0 -1 Bolivia Chile Colombia Ecuador Mexico Uruguay Venezuela Indonesia Japan Korea Malaysia Thailand (D) Advanced Economies 1 -0,5 India 1 0,8 0,6 0,4 0,2 0 -0,2 -0,4 -0,6 -0,8 -1 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 China Canada France GB Germany Italy Source: author’s elaboration from World Bank (2012). Figure 3 reveals that the manufacturing sector had an increasing external deficit between 2008 and 2011, while primary products performed a massive surplus. Using OECD sector classification it is possible to envisage that, except from low-technology manufactures, all other sectors experienced trade deficits. Among low-technology sectors, labour-intensive sectors such as textiles, leather, footwear, manufacturing and recycling products used to be surplus sectors until recently. In 2010 and 2011 they all had trade deficits. On the other hand, food products, beverages, tobacco, wood, pulp, paper, paper products, printing and publishing, which, essentially, process raw materials, can produce trade surplus. Therefore, Figure 3 displays the contradictions of the Chinese-effect on the Brazilian economy, where Chinese demand stimulates overall trade surplus through the natural resources trade surplus, while Chinese competition both at home and abroad, in a context of buoyant internal markets and currency overvaluation in Brazil, has been pointed out as a source of the manufacturing sector trade deficit. It also expresses the debate about the risks of further deindustrialisation28 (Bresser-Pereira, 2010; IEDI, 2011). Figure 3. Brazil – Trade Balance in Selected Sectors, 1996-2011 (USD billions) 28 In 1980 Brazil had the largest manufacturing sector among developing countries, ranked in the eighth position with a 2.6% percent of the world total production. To put in perspective, China ranked twelfth, with 1.7%, and South Korea ranked twentieth-eighth with 0.6%. In 2010, Brazil ranked eleventh, behind China, South Korea, India and Mexico (Unctad, 2012; Palma, 2011) 10 (A) Total (B) OECD technology-intensity classification 80.000 60.000 60.000 40.000 40.000 20.000 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 -20.000 1998 1997 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 -20.000 1996 20.000 -40.000 -40.000 -60.000 Total -60.000 Manufacturing Sector (*) High technology (I) Medium-high-technology (II) Agriculture, Mining and other raw material Medium-low technology (III) Low technology(IV) Source: MDIC (2012) Since its apex in the early 1980´’s, right before the debt external crisis, the manufacturing sector has reduced its relative share on Brazilian GDP29 (from 33% in 1980 to 16% in 2010) and on total employment. As stressed by Palma, Brazil apparently suffered from a premature deindustrialisation (Palma, 2007). The exports structure also changed. Between 1997 and 2011, primary products and natural resource intensive manufactures increased their share in total exports from 52% to 68%, while labour and scale-intensive manufactures experienced a share reduction from 33% to 19%30. These sectors have been subject to intense competitive pressures from China and other Asian economies, both at home and abroad, particularly in Latin American markets. Moreover, according to the exports concentration index31, Brazilian exports have concentrated, particularly in markets located in Africa and Asia. Emerging and developing countries, such as China, Argentina, Chile, Russia, Venezuela, South Korea and Mexico, among others, have been upgrading their shares as final destinies for Brazilian exports. However, the bulk of manufactured products goes to South American neighbours. Not surprisingly, Brazilian trade is more intense with Latin American countries (Leão, Pinto and Acioly, 2011; Lélis, Cunha and Lima, 2012; Bittencourt, 2012). Except from the African countries, China’s exports have been much more complementary to all highlighted markets than the Brazilian exports. It is worth mentioning that Brazilian and Chinese trade complementary indexes markedly diverged in the most important markets for the Brazilian exports of manufactured products, namely the United States and Latin America (Figure 4). Figure 4. Trade Complementarity Index (TCI)*, Brazil and China – 1999-2011 29 At current US dollars prices. Source: United Nations Statistics Division - National Accounts. Author’s estimation using Pavitt (1984) taxonomy and data from GTIS (2012). 31 We followed the same procedure reported to the Chinese index. The 2008-2011 averages in each market were: 879.0 (USA); 1,099.7 (Euro zone); 2,705.2 (Africa); 1,831.1 (Asia); 1,016.3 (Latin America, excl. Brazil), 2,594.4 (China) Source: authors´ estimations based on the Global Trade Information Services (GTIS) data. 30 11 (C) Euroland (B) USA (A) Great Britan 58 65 60 58 56 60 56 54 54 55 52 52 50 50 50 48 46 48 45 44 China Brasil 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 Brasil China (D) Latin America 2001 1999 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Brasil 46 40 2000 42 China (F) Africa (E) Asia 58 54 56 65,0 52 Brasil China China* 40,0 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Brasil 2010 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 40 45,0 2009 40 2008 42 50,0 2007 42 2006 44 44 2005 46 55,0 2004 46 2003 48 48 2002 50 60,0 2001 50 1999 52 2000 54 Brasil China Source: authors’ estimations based on GTIS (2012). n m k , j xk ,i TCI 100 (*) i, j 2 k 1 Where: mk , j sector “k’s” share in total imports of the country “j”; and x k ,i share in total exports of sector “k” in total exports of the country “i”. The index is 100 when the export and import shares exactly match and zero there is no trade. Considering the relevance of intra-regional trade to Brazil it must be asked if China has been displacing Brazil in Latin American and other markets for manufactured products. Recent research suggests that this might be the case (Bittencourt, 2012; Lélis, Cunha and Lima, 2012; Jenkins and Barbosa, 2012). According to this literature both Brazilian and Chinese exports of manufactured products to Latin America have boomed, particularly in the post-2003 period. The region economic recovery after 2002 has opened space for that expansion. Nevertheless, since 2007 Chinese manufactured-products exports trend has been growing faster than the Brazilian manufactured-products exports trend. The Chinese exports to Latin America are less concentrated than Brazilian exports to the same region 32, while Chinese exports matched Latin American imports more than Brazilian exports (Figure 4). In 1999, trade complementary index33 for Chinese exports to Latin America (excluding Brazil) was 50.9, while in 2011 it was 55.9. In the same period, the trade complementary index for Brazilian exports was, respectively, 48.9 and 42.6. Lélis, Cunha and Lima (2012) report evidence which strongly suggests that the Chinese exports have been dislocating the Brazilian exports in the region, because of their volume-effect and diversification. Similar dislocation effect can be observed in other markets (Jenkins and Barbosa, 2012). 32 Exports Concentration Index (HHI) of Brazilian exports fluctuated around 1,000, between 1996 and 2008, and reached 1007 in 2008, while the same Index for Chinese exports had evolved from 895 in 1996 to 685 in 2008 (Lélis, Cunha and Lima, 2012). 33 TCij = 100 – sum (|mik – xij| / 2), where: (i) xij is the share of good “i” in the global exports of country “j”; and (ii) “mik” is the share of good “i” in all imports of country k. When the index is zero, no goods are exported by one country or imported by the other. When the index is 100 the export and import shares exactly match (Hoekman, Mattoo and English, 2002). 12 To sum up, the robust Chinese growth in recent years has created some externalities for Latin American countries. The Chinese demand for agricultural and mineral commodities has contributed to the trade surpluses observed in countries rich in natural resources. Therefore, it has supported the virtuous cycle of growth with less external and fiscal vulnerabilities (Cepal, 2011; Dadush and Shimelse, 2012; Bittencourt, 2012; Ferchen, 2012; Rosales and Kuwayama, 2012; Timmer et al., 2012). Countries already characterised by a high degree of specialisation in commodities production and exports, such as Argentina, Chile, Venezuela, to name but a few, have reinforced their pattern of international integration. However, countries with a larger manufacturing sector, such as Brazil, have concentrated their exports on commodities and experience large trade deficits in the manufacturing sector. Therefore, a renewed stimulus to the previous process of deindustrialisation might be emerging. Moreover, Latin American economies became strongly dependent on China, so any major slowdown in the Chinese economy might cause a crisis in these countries (Iadb, 2012). China has also become a source of capital to the region, particularly FDI. Therefore, we can suggest that there is no “one size fits all” pattern of relationship between China and Latin American countries. The ultimate results of this interaction will depend, mostly, on how Latin American countries will respond to the Chinese presence in the region. Small and open economies that are highly specialized as producers and exports of raw materials would probably try to deepen its trade ties with Asian countries, exploring their comparative advantages and complementarities. Not surprisingly Chinese leaders have emphasised this pattern of relationship (Dadush and Shimelse, 2012; Ferchen, 2012; Jiabao, 2012), offering financial and technical cooperation and demanding more market access. Considering the Brazilian case, and allowing for the fact that further research will be necessary to clarify the connections between trade and deindustrialisation, we cannot cast aside the possibility that a closer relationship with China would result in a regressive pattern of specialisation34. Previous studies showed evidence that China’s exports have been dislocating other countries’ exports and, therefore, stimulated deindustrialisation among developing and advanced countries35. 5. Summary and Conclusions In this paper we have analysed how China’s rise as a global power has affected Latin American economies, paying special attention to the post-2008 period. Most previous analyses focused on pre-crisis tendencies. Considering that the Sino-Latin American relationship has evolved rapidly we have tried to contribute providing fresh evidence and exploring what could potentially be considered as new trends. We have showed that despite intentions of a growth model re-orientation, Chinese policymakers responded to the 2008 financial crisis with massive fiscal and monetary stimulus that reinforced, at least in the short and medium terms, the previous investment-intensive and export-led growth pattern. As a consequence, Chinese pressures to access dynamic domestic markets in emerging countries were amplified. In this context, Latin American countries represented not only a source of natural resources but also an increasingly important market for manufactured products. Our evidence allows us to conclude that, particularly to the Brazilian case: (i) China’s influence might amplify a regressive pattern of production and trade specialisation; and (ii) there is a strong connection between business cycles and trade intensity which seems to be associated with that specialisation pattern. Thus, it must be expected that policymakers will react to avoid what would probably be perceived as a major threat36. Nevertheless, further research will be necessary to clarify: (i) the role played by Chinese (or other emerging economies) exports of manufactured products in dislocating the Brazilian and the other Latin 34 See, among others, Gallagher and Porzecanski (2010), Barbosa (2011), Amaral (2011), Dadush and Shimelse (2012) and Ferchen (2012). See, among others, Greenway, Mahabir, Milner (2008); Giovannetti and Sanfilippo (2009); Wood and Mayer (2010), Gallagher and Porzecanski (2010), Giovannetti, Sanfilippo and Velucchi (2011); Lélis, Cunha and Lima (2012); Jenkins and Barbosa (2012). 36 According to Cepal (2011): “Since the beginning of the recent global economic crisis, many countries, including some in Latin America and the Caribbean, have initiated anti-dumping investigations into imports from China. ... Most of the new investigations (81% of the total) were initiated by Argentina and Brazil. The main items involved are iron and steel products, textiles, footwear, domestic appliances and tyres.” (p.21). 35 13 American countries exports; and, as a consequence (ii) the connections between trade and deindustrialisation. Notwithstanding, our results have explored new trends and have reinforced the conclusions of correlated studies, such as Moreira (2007), Paus (2007), Greenway, Mahabir and Milner (2008), Jenkins (2010), Giovannetti and Sanfilippo (2009), Wood and Mayer (2010), Leão, Pinto and Acioly (2011), Cesa-Bianchi et al. (2011), Lélis, Cunha and Lima (2012), Jenkins and Barbosa (2012), Bittencourt (2012), among others. We have assumed that China’s rise might be a major challenge to Brazil, which is major producer and exporter of natural resources and has a large manufacturing sector as well. As a consequence, the country has experienced both positive stimulus from Chinese demand for raw materials and food and the competitive pressures from its exports. The balance between opportunity and threat will depend on the evolution of the Sino-Brazilian relationship. It is an open question whether China will treat Brazil and other Latin American countries as partners in a South-South pattern, or as markets in a North-South style. Brazil, as many other Latin American countries, has improved its economic and social performance. Growth acceleration, lower inflation, lowers levels of public and external debt, income redistribution, among other economic indicators, represent a new beneficial combination. In the past, particularly during the period of industrialisation, the country experienced high economic growth, but in a context of similarly high levels of macroeconomic imbalances and social inequalities. However, despite recent progress, the country has not yet recovered from a quarter of a century of semi-stagnation (Palma, 2007 and 2011). In order to overcome old and new structural problems and to avoid the negative trends potentially associated with the well-known “natural resource curse” the country and its neighbours must recover their capacity to implement robust development strategies. In the Brazilian case, this means that government must: (i) re-orient its macroeconomic policy to preserve growth and employment; (ii) manage exchange rate and capital flows in order to reduce the impacts of external turbulences; (iii) improve income distribution, invest in human capital and reduce social gaps; (iv) implement robust and sustainable development policies aimed to reduce the infrastructure bottlenecks, to increase competitive capabilities of local enterprises, to attract FDI and, moreover, to preserve the environment and the country’s biodiversity. This is an ambitious, complex and still open agenda. 6. References Aladi. 2011. Debate sobre el Rol de China en la Región. Montevideo, Aladi. Amaral, S. O Desafio da China, 2011. See: http://www.itamaraty.gov.br/sala-de-imprensa/artigosrelevantes/o-desafio-da-china-o-estado-de-s.-paulo-23-01-201, Access on 20/03/2012 Angang Hu. 2010. China and the World: Assessment and Prospect of the “Post-Crisis” Era. TMD Working Paper Series, No. 040, Department of International Development. University of Oxford. Aoki, M; Wu Jinglian. 2012. The Chinese Economy: a new transition. Palgrave McMillan. Babones, S. 2011. ‘The Middling Kingdom – The hype and the reality of China’s rise’. Foreign Affairs, September/October, Vol. 90, N. 5, p. 79-88. Barbosa, R. 2011. Os Desafios da Ásia Para o Brasil. See: http://www.itamaraty.gov.br/sala-deimprensa/selecao-diaria-de-noticias/midias-nacionais/brasil/o-estado-de-sao-paulo/2011/11/22/osdesafios-da-asia-para-o-brasil-artigo-rubens/print-nota, Access on 20/03/2012. Baxter, M.; King, R. G. 1999. ‘Measuring Business Cycle: Approximate Band-Pass Filters form Economic Time Series’. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 81 (4): 575-93. Bittencourt, G. (ed.). 2012. El Impacto de China en América Latina: comercio e inversiones. Montevideo: Red Mercosur de Investigaciones Económicas. Blazquez-lidoy, J., Rodriguez, J., Santiso, J. 2006. Angel or Devil? China’s Trade Impact on Latin American Emerging Markets. Working Paper No. 252, OECD DEVELOPMENT CENTRE, 2006. 14 Breslin, S. 2011. ‘The China Model and the Global Crisis’. International Affairs, Volume 87, Number 6, November, p. 1323-1343, November. Bresser-Pereira, L. C. (Editor). 2010. Doença holandesa e indústria. Rio de Janeiro: Editora FGV. CAF. 2006. América Latina en el Comercio Global. Ganando Mercados. Caracas: Corporación Andina de Fomento. Calderón, C. 2008. Trade, specialization, and cycle synchronization: explaining output comovement between Latin America, China, and India. In. LEDERMAN, D., OLARREAGA, M. e PERRY, G. (Ed.), China’s and India’s challenge to Latin America. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Canuto, O.; Giugale, M. (Editors). 2010. The Day After Tomorrow: a handbook on the future of economic policy in the developing world. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Casey, J., Koleski, K. 2011. Backgrounder: China’s 12th Five-Year Plan. U.S.-China Economic & Security Review Commission, June 24 (http://www.uscc.gov/researchpapers/2011/12thFiveYearPlan_062811.pdf, Access: 01/10/2011). Castro, A. B. 2008. ‘From Semi-Stagnation to Growth in a Sino-Centric Market’. Revista de Economia Política, Vol 28, nº 1, Jan-Mar. Cepal. 2011. La República Popular China y América Latina y el Caribe. Hacia una nueva fase en el vínculo económico y comercial, Junio. Santiago de Chile: Comisión Económica para América Latina. Cesa-bianchi, A.; Pesaran, M. H., Rebucci, A. Xu, T. 2011. China’s Emergence in the World Economy and Business Cycles in Latin America. IDB WORKING PAPER SERIES No. IDB-WP-266, September. Inter-American Development Bank. Chang, H. J. 2011. The 2008 World Financial Crisis and the Future of World Development. In: Calhoun, c.; Derluguian, G. (eds). Aftermath – A New Global Economic Order? New York University Press. Clark, I. 2011. ‘China and the United States: a succession of hegemonies?’ International Affairs, Vol. 87, N. 1, January, p. 13–28. Crandall, R. 2011. ‘The Post-American Hemisphere. Power and Politics in an Autonomous Latin America’. Foreign Affairs, May/June, Volume 90, Number 3, p. 83-95. Dadush, U.; Shimelse, A. 2012. China’s Rise and Latin America: a global, long-term perspective, Thursday, March 8. International Economic Bulletin – Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Available at: http://carnegieendowment.org/ieb/2012/03/08/china-s-rise-and-latin-america-globallong-term-perspective/a1g6, access on 04/07/2012. Deutsche Bank. China´s financial integration into the world economy, November 23, 2011. Available at: http://www.dbresearch.com, 04/07/2012. Devlin, R., Estevadeordal, A., Rodriguez, A. (Editors). 2006. The Emergence of China: opportunities and challenges for the Latin America and Caribbean. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank and Harvard University. Eclac 2012. The People’s Republic of China and Latin America and the Caribbean: dialogue and cooperation for the new challenges of the global economy. Santiago de Chile: Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. Eichengreen, B. 1992. Should the Maastricht Treaty Be Saved? Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 74, International Finance Section, Princeton. 15 Estevadeordal, A. 2012. Economic Integration in the Americas: an unfinished agenda. In: The Brookings Institution. The Road to Hemispheric Cooperation: Beyond the Cartagena Summit of the Americas. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. FDI Markets. 2012. FDI Dataset. Disponível em; http://www.fdimarkets.com. Access on 02/02/2012. Fenby, J. 2011. China´s Domestic Economy. In: Shambaugh. D. Charting China’s Future: domestic and international challenges. Routledge. Ferchen, M. 2012. China’s Latin American Interests. http://carnegieendowment.org/2012/04/06/china-s-latin-american-interests/a7av, 06/07/2012. Available access at: on Frankel, J.; Rose, A. 1988. ‘The Endogeneity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria’. The Economic Journal, 108, 1009–1025. Furtado, C. 2003. Raízes do subdesenvolvimento. Rio de Janeiro: Civilização Brasileira. Gallagher, K. P.; Porzecanski, R. 2010. The Dragon in the Room: China and the future of Latin American industrialization. Stanford University Press. Gill, I.; Kharas, H. 2007. An East Asian Renaissance: ideas for economic growth. Washington, DC: World Bank. Giovannetti, G., Sanfilippo, M. 2009. ‘Do Chinese Exports Crowd-out African Goods? An Econometric Analysis by Country and Sector’. European Journal of Development Research, v. 21, N. 4, p. 506530. Giovannetti, G., Sanfilippo, M., Velucchi M. 2011. The “China effect” on EU Exports to OECD markets – A focus on Italy. Working Paper n. 17, December. Universita' degli Studi di Firenze (http://www.dse.unifi.it/upload/sub/WP17_2011.pdf. Access in 13/03/2012). Goldman Sachs. 2007. BRICs and Beyond. The Goldman Sachs Group/Global Economics Department. (http://www2.goldmansachs.com/our-thinking/brics/index.html, access on 01/10/2011. Greenaway, D., Mahabir, A., Milner, C. 2008. ‘Has China displaced other Asian countries' exports?’ China Economic Review, Volume 19, Issue 2, June, pp. 152–169. GTIS. 2012. Global Trade Information Service. Disponível em: http://www.gtis.com/english/. Access on 01/02/2012. Halper, S. 2010. The Beijing Consensus: how China’s authoritarian model will dominate the twenty-first century. New York, Basic Books. Hao Yufan, C. X., Wei, G., Dittmer, L. (Editors). 2009. Challenges to Chinese Foreign Policy: Diplomacy, Globalization and the Next World Power. The University Press off Kentucky. Heritage Foundation (2012). China Global Investment Tracker: 2012. www.heritage.org/research/reports/2012/01/china-global-investment-tracker-2012 01/06/2012). Available (accessed at: in Hoekman, B. M.; Mattoo, A.; English, P. 2002. Development, Trade, and the WTO: A Handbook (World Bank Trade and Development Series). Washington DC: The World Bank, 2002. Hongbo Sun, 2012. Strengthening solidarity. Available at: http://europe.chinadaily.com.cn/business/201206/30/content_15538750.htm, access on 02/07/2012. IADB. 2012. The World of Forking Paths: Latin America and the Caribbean facing global economic risks. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. 16 IEDI. 2011. A indústria de transformação por intensidade tecnológica: o desafio de crescer sem deteriorar ainda mais o saldo comercial. Carta IEDI, São Paulo, IEDI, n. 454, 11 de fevereiro. Ikenberry, G. J. 2011. ‘The Future of the Liberal World Order: internationalism after America’. Foreign Affairs, May/June, Vol. 90, N. 3, p. 56-68. IMF. 2010. People’s Republic of China - IMF Country Report No. 10/238, July. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF. 2012. World Economic Outlook, April. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Jacques, M. 2012. When China Rules the World, Second Edition. London, Penguin Books. Jenkins, R. 2010. ‘China’s Global Expansion and Latin America’. Journal of Latin American Studies, Vol. 42, Part 4, November, 809–837. Jenkins, R.; Barbosa, A. F. 2012. ‘Fear for Manufacturing? China and the Future of Industry in Brazil and Latin America’, The China Quarterly, 2012, pp 59-81. Kang, D. C. 2007. China Rising: peace, power and order in East Asia. Columbia University Press. Kenen, P. 1969. The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: An Eclectic View. In: Mundell, R., Swoboda, A. (eds.) Monetary Problems of the International Economy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Kissinger, H. 2001. On China. Penguin Press HC. Krugman, P. 1993 Lessons of Massachussets for EMU. In: Torres, F., Giovazzi, F. Adjustment and growth in the European Monetary System, Cambridge University Press. Kurlantzick, J. 2007. Charm Offensive: how China´s soft power is transforming the World. New Republic Book. Leão, R. P. F.; Pinto, E. C.; Acioly, L. (Editors). 2011. A China na Nova Configuração Global - Impactos Políticos e Econômicos. Brasília: IPEA. Lederman, D., Olarreaga, M., Perry, G. (Ed.). 2008. China`s and India`s challenge to Latin American. Washington, DC: World Bank. Lélis, M. T. C., Cunha, A. M., Lima, M. G. 2012. ‘El desempeño de las exportaciones de China y el Brasil hacia América Latina, 1994-2009’. Revista de la Cepal, N. 106, Abril, p. 57-77. McKinnon, R. 1963. Optimum Currency Areas. American Economic Review vol. 53 (September) pp.717725. McMillan, M. S., Rodrik, D. 2011. Globalization, structural change and productivity growth. Working Paper 17143, June. NBER Working Paper Series. Mearsheimer, J. J. 2006. China's Unpeaceful Rise. Current History, Vol. 105, No. 690, April, pp. 160-162, 2006. (Available at: http://mearsheimer.uchicago.edu/all-pubs.html, Access on 01/09/2011) Mearsheimer, J. J. 2010. ‘Imperial by Design’. The National Interest, No. 111, January/February, pp. 1634. MIDC (2012). Exportação-Importação brasileira dos setores industriais por intensidade tecnológica. Ministério do Desenvolvimento Indústria e Comércio. Available at: http://www.desenvolvimento.gov.br/sitio/interna/interna.php?area=5&menu=1113&refr=608, Access on 02/05/2012. Mofcom. 2011. 2010 Statistical Bulletin of China's Outward Foreign Direct Investment. Beijing: Ministry of Commerce – People´s Republic of China. 17 Moran, T. H. 2010. China's Strategy to Secure Natural Resources: Risks, Dangers, and Opportunities. Policy Analyses in International Economics 92, July. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics. Moreira, M. M. 2007. ‘Fear of China: Is There a Future for Manufacturing in Latin America?’ World Development, Vol. 35, No. 3, pp. 355–76 Morrison, W. M.; Labonte, M. 2011. China’s Holdings of U.S. Securities: Implications for the U.S. Economy. September 26, Congressional Research Service. Mundell, R. 1961. ‘A Theory of Optimal Currency Areas’, American Economic Review (September) vol.51 pp.657-65 Naughton, B. 2007. The Chinese Economy: transitions and growth. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Nolan, P. 2011. China and the Global Economy. In: Shambaugh. D. Charting China´s Future: domestic and international challenges. Routledge. Nolan, P. 2012. Is China Buying the World? Malden, Polity Press. Nye, Jr, J. S. N. 2010. ‘The Future of American Power: dominance and decline in perspective’. Foreign Affairs, November/December, Vol. 89, N. 6, p. 2-12. Palma, G. 2007. Four Sources of ‘De-industrialisation and a New Concept of the ‘Dutch Disease’. HSRC EGDI Roundtable, May. Palma, G. 2011. Why has productivity growth stagnated in most Latin American countries since the neoliberal reforms? Cambridge Working Papers in Economics (CWPE) 1030, July. Available at http://www.econ.cam.ac.uk/dae/repec/cam/pdf/cwpe1030.pdf. Access on 09/01/2011. Paus, E. 2009. ‘The Rise of China: Implications for Latin American Development’. Development Policy Review, vol. 27, no. 4, pp. 419–56. Pavitt, K. 1984. ‘Sectoral patterns of technical change: towards a taxonomy and a theory’. Research Policy, vol. 13, n. 19, 343-373. Phillips, N. 2011. ‘Re-Ordering the Region? China, Latin America and the Western Hemisphere’. European Review of Latin American and European Studies, Number 90, April, p. 89-99. Prebisch, R. 1984. Five Stages in My Thinking on Development. In Meier, G. M; Seers, D. (Edit.). Pioneers in Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ramo, J. C. 2004. The Beijing Consensus. London: The Foreign Policy Centre. Rodrik, D. 2011. Growth after the Crisis. In: Calhoun, C.; Derluguian, G. (Editors). Aftermath – A New Global Economic Order? New York University Press. Rodrik, D., McMillan, M. 2011. Globalization, Structural Change, and Productivity Growth. NBER Working Paper No. 17143, June. Rosales, O., Kuwayama, M. 2012. China y América Latina y el Caribe Hacia una relación económica y comercial estratégica. Santiago de Chile, CEPAL. Rowthorn, R. E.; Wells, J. R. 1987. De-industrialization and foreign trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sachs, J.; Warner, A. 1997. Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth. Center for International Development and Harvard Institute for International Development. Cambridge MA: Harvard University. 18 Salidjanova, N. 2011. Going Out: an Overview of China’s Outward Foreign Direct Investment, March. U.S.-China Economic and Security Review Commission Research Archive. (Available at: http://www.uscc.gov/researchpapers/research_archive.php, Access on 15/10-2011). Shirk, S. L. 2007. China: Fragile Superpower: How China's Internal Politics Could Derail Its Peaceful Rise. Oxford University Press. Sinnot, E., Nash, J., De La Torre, A. 2010. Natural Resources in Latin America and the Caribbean – Beyond Booms and Busts? Washington, DC: The World Bank, 2010. Subramanian, A. 2011. ‘The Inevitable Superpower: Why China’s Dominance is a Sure Thing’. Foreign Affairs, September/October, Vol., N. 5, p. 66-78. Thirlwall, A. P. 2011. Economics of Development. Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan. Timmer, H., Dailami, M., Irving, J., Hauswald, R., Masson, P. 2012. Global Development Horizons 2011. Multipolarity: The New Global Economy. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Unctad. 2003. Trade and Development Report 2003. Geneva, United Nations Trade and Development Commission. Unctad. 2011. World Investment Report 2011. Geneva: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. United Nations. 2012. National Accounts. Available at United Nations Statistics Division: http://unstats.un.org/unsd/snaama/Introduction.asp. Access on 05/05/2012. Wen Jiabao. 2012. Trusted Friends Forever. Premier of the State Council of the People's Republic of China At the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean of the United Nations, Santiago, 26 June 2012. Available at: http://europe.chinadaily.com.cn/china/201206/27/content_15527065.htm, Access on 02/07/2012 Womg, R. B. 2011. Chinese Political Economy and the International Economy: linking global, regional and domestic possibilities. In: Calhoun, C.; Derluguian, G. (Editors). Aftermath – A New Global Economic Order? New York University Press. Wood, A., Mayer, J. 2010. Has China De-industrialized other Developing Countries? QEH Working Papers Series Number 175, June. World Bank. 2012. World Development Indicators. Available at: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator, access on 01/07/2012. Wu Jinglian. 2005. Understanding and Interpreting Chinese Economic Reform. Mason: Thomson. Zheng Bijian. 2005. China’s Peaceful Rise: Speeches of Zheng Bijian 1997-2004. The Brookings Institution. (http://www.brookings.edu/events/2005/0616china.aspx, Access on 30/09/2011). Yang, Yongzheng. 2006. China’s Integration into the World Economy: implications for developing countries. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, Volume 20, Issue 1, pages 40–56, May. 19 Appendix: Business Cycles Synchronization and Trade In order to assess if the Brazilian business cycle synchronization with its main trade partners is associated with the trade intensity, we use the empirical strategy pioneered by Frankel and Rose (1998) and expanded by Calderón (2008). This methodology represents an innovative way of measuring the integration and structural specialisation relationship.37 Kenen (1969) argues that the symmetry of business cycles across countries is related to the similarity of economic structure. Eichengreen (1992) and Krugman (1993) complete this idea and conclude that trade would produce productive specialisation derived from comparative advantages in intra-regional trade. With this perspective, Frankel and Rose (1998) suggest that this relation is not, in principle, deterministic, especially in the context of a common monetary policy: “closer international trade could result in either tighter or looser correlations of national business cycles” (p.1013). Assuming by hypothesis that higher intensity trade leads to more specialization and lower business cycles correlation, they argue that this is an open question that can only be solved empirically. We used the GDP, at constant prices in local currency, from World Bank - World Development Indicators (WDI), to measure the business cycle through two different methodologies: Hodrick-Prescott (HP) and Baxter-King (BK). We use 50 countries in our exercise: Algeria, Argentina, Australia, Belgium, Bolivia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Egypt, Finland, France, Germany, India, Indonesia, Iran, Italy, Japan, Korea, Kuwait, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Netherlands, Nigeria, Norway, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Portugal, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Thailand, Turkey, Ukraine, United Arab Emirates, United Kingdom, United States, Uruguay and Venezuela. The Bilateral Trade Intensity between countries i and j, in time t, are calculated using two proxies, also proposed by Frankel and Rose: 1. (ITT) Trade Intensity weighted to the total trade: ITTijt = (Xijt + Mijt) / (Xit + Xjt + Mit + Mjt) Where Xijt represents the total export of country i to country j, in the time t; Xit and Mit represents the total export and import of the country i, respectively. 2. (ITY) Trade Intensity weighted to the GDP, is represented by Y: ITYijt = (Xijt + Mijt) / (Yit + Yjt) The data of trade are from IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics, and the GDP data is from WDI-World Bank. Thereafter we estimate the relationship between business cycle and trade intensity using the model of Frankel and Rose (1998), i.e.,: Corr (v, s)ijt = α + β ITijt + εijt (1) Corr (v, s)ijt denotes the correlation of business cycles between country i and j, at time t. IT refers to the intensity of trade. Finally, α and β are the regression coefficients to be estimated. Therefore, we estimate the equation: Corr (v, s)ijt = α + β ITijt + εijt, where: Corr (v, s)ijt = GDP correlation between countries i and j; IT = trade intensity. The Appendix details the methodology and data sources. Table A1 reports the results: β was statically significant in our four estimations. According to the underlying literature, a positive β suggests that higher trade intensity is positively correlated with business cycles synchronization, and the intra-industrial shocks dominate. If β is negative, the economies operate 37 Mundell (1961), McKinnon (1963) and Kenen (1969) are the seminal contributions to this debate, which became even more important in the 1990s because of the analysis of the costs and benefits of European Monetary Union (EMU). Eichengreen (1992), Krugman (1993), Frankel and Rose (1998), among others, contributed throughout the development of new theoretical insights and empirical methodologies to estimate and to interpret the relationship between integration, industrial specialization, business cycles synchronization and integration costs. 20 more independently and the Ricardian effect of trade would be expected, with countries increasing the production of the export goods. Table A1. Effects of Trade Intensity on Business Cycles Synchronization – Brazil and China, 1975-2010 Filter GDP GDP Baster King Hodrick Prescott BRAZIL CHINA ITT ITY ITT ITY 11.178* 21.466* -7.083* -6.658* (-0.03) (-0.06) (-0.01) (-0.01) 25.807* 46.466* -8.434* -7.762* (-0.04) (-0.08) -0.02 (-0.02) * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 Standard Deviation in parenthesis ITT - trade intensity weighted by total trade; ITY - trade intensity weighted by GDP Coefficients were multiplied by 100. To estimate the equation we used trade intensity (IT) as Instrumental Variable (IV) to solve the homogeneity between trade and GDP. The IT was estimated through a traditional gravitational model, i.e., using Language, Frontier and Distance as instruments. After that we estimate the equation using a Panel Data model. The Hausman test shows that Two-Stages Least Squares (2SLS) is efficient and the Sargan Test support the null hypothesis that the all the instruments (IV M odel) were valid. It is also worth mentioning that all estimations returned a negative β for the Chinese case. Accordingly, trade intensity does not contribute to business cycles synchronizations, but does contribute to a structural specialization across countries. At the same time, the Brazilian economy seems to be more sensitive to intraindustry shocks, and therefore business cycles may become more similar across countries through trade. The opposite is true in the Chinese case, if one considers the trade intensity effect within China. Therefore, according the international trade theory and our estimation, we expect that China and Brazil’s international trade tends to lead an industrial specialisation in a Ricardian sense. 21