GDP GROWTH AND STOCK MARKET VALUATION LIMITS: FROM THE GORDON MODEL TO IBBOTSON S&P 500 RETURN DECOMPOSITIONS David A. Brat, Department of Economics and Business Randolph-Macon College, Ashland, VA 23005, 804-752-7353 dbrat@rmc.edu Is the stock market over valued or under valued? In order to assess these claims one must be able to indicate a true value from which deviations may occur. Many economic papers promise to explain valuation and many deliver by providing insights into various relationships between financial variables. However, very few papers have tried to determine a baseline value for the stock market based on supply side economic variables. This paper attempts to tie GDP growth to earnings growth and ultimately to the S&P 500 index price. Several papers have supplied bits and pieces of this puzzle and this paper is an attempt to put them together into one framework. decomposition which will clarify these relationships in more detail. We have made some progress in this study toward that end. FIGURE 1 S&P and GDP 100 Logilinear Scale ABSTRACT Nominal GDP Nominal S&P Price 10 Nominal S&P Earnings Nominal S&P Dividend In the long run, we want to argue that stock market performance cannot exceed the pace set by growth in GDP. Exactly what the relationship between these two variables is remains to be seen. Figure 1, shows GDP, S&P 500 nominal price, nominal earnings, and nominal dividend normalized to a value of 1 on the left axis. Clearly, all four variables increase at similar, but not identical, rates. These series suggest several points immediately. To simplify, let’s assume that nominal GDP has grown at 6% over the long run. Then, assuming capital’s share of income constant, Figure 1 shows earnings growth at the same rate. Earnings paid out in dividends have also grown at about 6% and capital appreciation, nominal S&P Price, has also grown at 6%. Both grow at 3% real rates. Thus, this simple model or graph would suggest that if the total return to the S&P is composed of the dividend payment plus capital appreciation, we should expect a long run total real return of about 6%, assuming zero inflation. According to Diermeier [3] we are not far off as he concludes in his study that the total real return is about 5.4%. However, when one reviews the studies which include the recent run up in stock prices, authors such as Lansing and Ibbotson et. al. [6,4] conclude that the total return on equity is 10.7% over the past century. In any case, we are still left with the question of why GDP growth of 6% can generate total S&P returns of 6% or 10%. What is the upper limit and why is it a limit? We intuitively know that a limit must exist but we are trying to identify an accounting rule and some type of total return 02 97 20 92 19 87 19 82 19 77 19 72 19 67 19 62 19 57 19 52 19 19 19 INTRODUCTION 47 1 Date THE LITERATURE AND FRAMEWORK One way of addressing the stock market value is presented by Roger Ibbotson and Peng Chen. Ibbotson and Chen [4], for example, discuss six ways to decompose historical stock returns into their different components, and then offer two methods to predict future returns using the supply side of equity returns. They use inflation, earnings, dividends, price to earnings ratio, dividend payout ratio, book value per share, return on equity, and GDP per capita as the components of the supply side of returns. They conclude that earnings is in line with output increases. Taking the average return over the previous 75 years, Ibbotson and Chen argue that increases in the P/E ratio account for only a small portion of stock returns, (1.25%). GDP growth and earnings growth account for larger portions of total return. Ibbotson and Chen state that the supply side of equity returns are extremely important to investors, as investors can only expect returns equal to what companies can supply. The six methods offered for deconstructing historical returns are essentially identities, substituting terms for one another in analyzing the supply side of equity returns. The total nominal return on equities from 1926-2000 has been 10.7% according to work done by Ibbotson. This 10.7% can be viewed in many ways. The first and most basic decomposition is 10.7% = 3% inflation + 2% real risk free rate on long-term U.S. bond + 5.24% equity risk premium, the amount investors were compensated for investing in common stocks rather than U.S. bonds. Decomposition two states that 10.7% = 4.28% income or dividend growth + 3 % real capital gain + 3% inflation. Decomposition three indicates that 10.7%=4.28% dividend income + 1.25 % growth in P/E + 1.75% growth in EPS + 3% inflation. The cap gain in two is simply dissected here. Decomposition six indicates that 10.7% = 4.28% dividend income + 1% growth in factor shares + 2 % growth in GDP/POP + 3% inflation. The most important method in terms of our paper is decomposition six, the GDP method. There are several important findings noted by Ibbotson and Chen. [4] “First, the growth in corporate earnings is in line with the growth of the overall economic productivity as seen in Figure 1. Second, P/E increases account for only 1.25% of the 10.7% total equity returns. Most of returns are attributable to dividend payments and nominal earnings growth (including inflation and real earnings growth). Third, the increase in relative factor share of the equity can be fully attributed to the increase in the P/E ratio. Overall economic productivity outgrew both corporate earnings and dividends from 1926 through 2000. Fourth, despite the record earnings growth in the 1990s, the dividend yield and the payout ratio declined sharply, which renders dividends alone a poor measure for corporate profitability and future earnings growth.” [4] RESEARCH QUESTION We are getting warm enough to make some comments relating to our thesis. First, we have now found a link between GDP growth and stock market returns. However, the surprise is that GDP growth only accounts for 2% of the 10.7% nominal average return over our period. How can this be? Part of our problem may be related to the period examined and the fact that we are dealing with only the mean values over a long period. For example, the dividend income accounted for 4.3% real returns over this period. However, Figure 3 in Ibbotson and Chen shows that the dividend yield has fallen drastically from highs of 6% or so in the 1930s – 1950s to only 1.1% in 2000. In addition, their Figure 4 shows that the dividend payout ratio has fallen from 60% over the bulk of the sample period to the current lows of 32%. In addition, the results above are complicated by the fact that the nominal average return is 10.7% from 1926 – 2000 but if one does not include the period of the recent stock run-up, this number falls. Diermeier [3] for example forecasts the real return to be 5.4% from 1963-1982. An 8.4 % “nominal” return is then reasonable and this is significantly lower than the 10.7% return used in the Ibbotson paper. Which result is relevant in tracking the fundamental value of the stock market? Or should we just expect on average numbers to give us an on average conclusion? In summary, in the Ibbotson paper we have found a gold mine in terms of what we were out to find. They state the exact part of total returns explained by GDP growth and it is small. It appears that we are now faced with another problem. Here, we seem to have the answers as they fall out of accounting decompositions but we lack the theory to explain the upper and lower bounds we seek for these decompositions. In the first and most basic decomposition, how large can the equity risk premium be and what would set the bounds for this number? Historically it has been about 5% but could it have been 10%? Why or why not? Is this payment to investors in any way linked to real output? By looking to the decomposition method alone, the answer seems to be no. GDP growth accounts for only 2% of the 10.7% according to method 6. We have also noted that overall, productivity has outgrown both earnings and dividends and this may bode well for “expected future earnings.” It may also suggest an answer to why S&P returns can exceed GDP growth, as they do. So while we are getting warm and the story gets more interesting, we hope, we need to go back to the theory with the hope of unifying this story. THEORY AND METHOD The remainder of this paper will address the questions posed immediately above in our prior work. [1] First, the paper will show the mathematical links between the Gordon model [5]and the Ibbotson decompositions, and the assumptions necessary to make the decompositions. Second, it will address the sensitivity of these decompositions to changes in the mean values as the sample period changes from 1926-2000 to 1963-1984 to 1984- present. Finally, the paper will review and assess what the appropriate model might be for explaining market behavior today. In brief, the Gordon model gets us from: P0 = ∑ (Dt/(1+k)t to P0=∫Dte-ktdt to k = D0/P0+ g, where P is a share’s price, D is the Dividend and k is the rate of profit. “Translated, the final equation above means that the rate of profit at which a share of common stock is selling is equal to the current dividend, divided by the current price (the dividend yield), plus the rate at which the dividend is expected to grow. Gordon refers to k as the growth rate of profit.” [5] Importantly, the difference between this model and the dividend yield (D/P) is the assumption of growth. The latter assumes that the dividend will remain constant. To assume a constant rate of growth and estimate it (the growth rate) to be equal to the current rate appears to be a better alternative. Under this model, the dividend will grow at the rate br, which is the product of the fraction of income retained b, and the rate of return earned on net worth r and so g = b*r. One can also arrive at g directly by taking some average of the past rate of growth in a corporation’s dividend. [5] The average value chosen is one of the topics under investigation in the current paper. Diermeier [3] has specified the final model we will use in our study. It is derived directly from the Gordon model above. In Diermeier, if r= the total return on financial assets, d = the income return, a= the capital appreciation and n = financial net new issues, the two equations relate these variables to each other and to g, the growth rate of financial assets. If r = d +a and n = g – a, where g = b*r from above, then r = d + (g – n) and this is the supply model of expected return we will use to investigate current rates of S&P returns. DATA AND SIMPLE FORECASTS Due to space constraints, I will put forward three simple forecasts using this Diermeier framework in algebraic form. In each case, I will use the same algebraic model, but will fill it in with data from three different sources. First the data from the Diermeier study itself was from the period 1963- 1982, not the most representative S&P trend. r = d + (g - n) 5.4 = 7.5 + (2.6 – 4.7) where a = g -n -2.1= (2.6-4.7) Alternatively, when one uses Ibbotson average data over the period 1926-2000, one obtains the following return: r = d + b * r - (g – a) r = 4.3 + (40%* 4) - (1.6% - 1) = 4.3 + 1.6 – 0.6 = 5.3 % Finally, when one uses current data proxies, one obtains: r = d + b * r - (g – a) r = 1.1 + (60%*1.1) - (.66% - 1) = 1.1 + .66 + .34 = 2.0 % These are all real rates of return. By contrast, the Ibbotson average rate of return over the long run was a nominal figure of 10.7%. A real rate of 7.7% is implied as they use a long-run average of 3% CPI. Ibbotson decomposition two above states that long-run nominal returns of 10.7% = 4.28% income or dividend growth + 3 % real capital gain + 3% inflation. If we plug in the current data proxies used in the Diermeier format above, we find a much lower return in the Ibbotson model. r = 1.1% income or dividend growth + 3% real capital gain + 1% inflation + 0.5% reinvestment return = 5.6% The real return would be 4.6%. Ibbotson reports two forecasts himself. [4] First, the longrun supply of U.S. equity returns based on the earnings model is 9.37%, yielding a 6.37 real return. Second, the forward-looking dividends model is also referred to as the constant-dividend-growth model (or the Gordon model). Using current data, Ibbotson finds an estimate of equity returns = 5.44%. However, they use the long-run CPI average of 3% in forecasting this figure. With a CPI of only 1%, the real equity return forecast would be only 3.44%. CONCLUSIONS The goal of this paper was to find and examine hard links between stock market returns and GDP growth. We found the link we were looking for but it was unexpectedly small, and the link itself was really only between GDP growth and real capital gains. The GDP link to dividend income was not found. We have found that productivity growth outpaced earnings and dividend growth and this may partially explain why equity returns can exceed present GDP growth figures. We then presented several simple but highly influential models forecasting equity returns. We have the upper and lower bounds of forecasts and we continue to seek a more thorough understanding of the link between real economic activity and these equity returns. REFERENCES [1] Armstrong, JC. and Brat, David. “Supply Side Determinants of Stock Market Valuation” Proceedings of SeInforms, 2003. [2] Asness, Clifford. “Stocks versus Bonds: Explaining the Equity Risk Premium.” Financial Analysts Journal 56(2), 2000, pp. 96-113. [3] Diermeier, Jeffrey and Ibbotson, Roger and Siegel, Laurence. “The Supply of Capital Market Returns.” The Financial Analysts Journal, 40(2), 1984, pp.74-80. [4] Ibbotson, Roger G., and Peng Chen. "Stock Market Returns in the Long Run: Participating in the Real Economy." Yale University, International Center for Finance, Working Paper No. 00-44, March, 2002. [5] Gordon, Myron and Shapiro, Eli. “Capital Equipment Analysis: The Required Rate of Profit.” Management Science, Octorber 1956, pp. 102-110. [6] Lansing, Kevin. “Searching for Value in the U.S. Stock Market.” San Francisco Federal Reserve: Economic Letter, 2002.