1 Women and Electoral Success in Chicago, 1971-2007: A Draft for an Organizational Analysis Zohar Lechtman, PhD. Draft Presented at Departmental Seminary Lauder School of Government, Diplomacy, and Strategy Interdisciplinary Center (IDC) Herzliya Introduction In the last decades, more and more women compete over and win elected office. Much of the literature on women and representation examines women’s under representation in elected office. This paper examines the opposite: the mechanisms that result in women gaining access to elected positions of power. It suggests that representation as access to elected positions of power begins with inclusion, or incorporation of women as political actors and members in the formal and informal structures and alliances in the political arena. Prevailing gender ideology associates leadership with masculinity, leading to their exclusion by gatekeepers and political players as outsiders to the pursuit of power (Niven, 1998; Sanbonmatsu, 2006). Even many of the prevailing discussions on women and politics construct them as outsiders, absent actors, with little political motivation required in politics (Fox and Lawless, 2004). This paper suggests that availability of niches open for women to act politically and gain access to the complex networks, alliances and rivalries in the political arena, is an important factor in women’s electoral participation and success. If gender shaping the relations between the masculine political actor and the apolitical unmotivated female outsider, then they are gendered patterns of incorporation into politics that shape women’s activity as “insiders”. A question of incorporation requires a concept of the structures to which persons are incorporated and where politics is practiced, and a concept of gender that is integral to these Copies only with author’s permission Please Send Comments to zoharl@uchicago.edu or zoharlechtman@012.net.il structures. This paper suggests that an organizational framework of analysis is an appropriate approach to address this issue. The political arena is an organizational environment made of organizational alliances and rivalries, interacting and competing over control and support of constituents and other players (Burt, 1992). They provide members with different routes, niches, or structural arrangements, for the exchange and acquiring of power and in the process, create political actors (Clemens and Minkoff, 2004). Furthermore, this organizational environment and available routes inside the political arena and the organization of corporate actors in their institutional environment, follows gendered patterns. In this paper, I explore politics as a gendered organizational process, using rich data on candidates’ background and activism, collected as part of a larger research project in Chicago. In the investigative process, I engage with Acker’s theory of gendered organization as an analytical strategy (Acker, 1990). I apply to the organizational environment, and move to suggest that gendering processes can result in meaningful political gains for women. I do so by integrating the political context in Chicago into the analysis, a broad view of organizations and various forms of political positions across the arena. I illustrate gendered incorporation to political organizations on two dimensions: location in the organizational environment, and type of positions available for women in the organizations constituting the political arena. Finally, I examine political gains for women in gendered positions as reflected in political backing by powerbrokers and implications for electoral success. Theoretical Review Since the 1970s, more and more women compete over and win elected office. In 1971, women constituted about 4.5% of state legislators across the United States, and by 2003, their proportion quadrupled to 22.4%. Among decision makers in city government the numbers are 2 even higher.1Available work on women and representation examines for the most part, causes for under representation. This work examines the opposite: increased representation in elected office. Traditionally the subject of control, women were excluded from the modern political sphere, to the private sphere. Femininity has not, and in many ways is still not, associated with power and control, or the pursuit of power and control (Brown, 1995; Niven, 1998; Okin, 1979; Pateman, 1988). Women’s pursuit of elected office is therefore more than a change in the demographic composition of leadership. It is the change in actors included in the political arena, and the actors with legitimacy and popular support to hold power. Available Approaches to Conceptualize Women as Political Actors Outside the Political Arena: Supply of Female Politicians Because women were, and in many cases still are, invisible in the electoral competition, a body of work is dedicated to examine the supply of women for the pool of political actors (Clark, 1991; Carroll, 1994; Carroll, 2003; Githens, 2003; Niven, 1998; Sanbonmatsu, 2006).2 Limited supply of political women is attributed to gender inequality outside the political arena. The result is limited access to needed resources and appropriate preparation, ending with few women 1 Source: CAWP (Center for the American Woman and Politics). 2002. Women in the 50 Largest Cities. New Brunswick, NJ: National Informatiom Bank on Women in Public Office, Eaglton Institute of Politics, Rutgers University. CAWP (Center for the American Woman and Politics). Women in the US Congress 2004. 2004a. New Brunswick, NJ: National Informatiom Bank on Women in Public Office, Eaglton Institute of Politics, Rutgers University. CAWP (Center for the American Woman and Politics). 2004b. Women in the US Senate 1922-2004. New Brunswick, NJ: National Informatiom Bank on Women in Public Office, Eaglton Institute of Politics, Rutgers University. CAWP (Center for the American Woman and Politics). 2004c. Women state Legislatures 2003. New Brunswick, NJ: National Informatiom Bank on Women in Public Office, Eaglton Institute of Politics, Rutgers University. There is a large body of literature on female and male legislators’ socioeconomic background, on sex role and socialization. Here I use a few known examples. For comprehensive reviews, see: Clark, 1991; Carroll, 1994; Carroll, 2003; Niven, 1998; Sanbonmatsu, 2006. 2 3 who can compete in elections. Disparity in professional experience, familial obligations, disadvantages in the labor market that in return limit access to finance, experience, and ties are among the causes explored (Burns, Schlozman, and Verba, 2001; Carroll, 1994; Clark, 1991; Darcy, Welch and Clark, 1994; Sanbonmatsu, 2006; Welch, 1978). Women’s political predisposition may also become a potential obstacle. Socialization to femininity and women’s limited experience with power are suggested as causes for limited political ambition, avoidance of confrontation, or novice attitude to political practices (Burns, Schlozman, and Verba, 2001; Carroll, 1994; Clark, 1991; Costantini, 1990; Eagly, Karau, Miner, and Johnson, 1994; EtzioniHalevi, 1993; Fox and Lawless, 2004; Niven, 1998; Sorenson, Hawkins, and Sorenson, 1995). There is evidence to rethink women’s political naivety. Research shows more similarity then difference between men and women in position of power, as well as willingness on women’s part to confront rivals or engage in competitive behavior (Craig and Pitts, 1990; Johnson, 1993; Mott and Petrie, 1995; Simon Rosenthal, 2000; Walker, Ilardi, McMahon and Fennell, 1996; Watson and Hoffman, 1996). In addition, familial responsibilities are still women’s terrain, regardless of increased participation in the labor market. Comparisons of women’s human capital and political representation show few conclusive results as to a direct relation between women’s education or share in the labor force, and access to political power (Niven, 1998; Paxton and Kunovich, 2003; Sanbonmatsu, 2006). More importantly, it is possible that what defined here as cause and effect is simply the same order in different fields of activity: women face barriers to power across the board, both politics and in the labor market. Inside the Political Arena: Selection Procedures An alternative perspective examines electoral systems and selection procedures, as gate keeping strategies (Norris, 1997). Newcomers like women, other minorities or younger persons, 4 may face entrenched leadership less inclined to allow others in the system. Decentralization of selection processes limits the power of incumbent leadership to block new actors, considered therefore a factor in creating a more diverse body of candidates and leaders (Lovenduski And Norris, 1993; Lovenduski, 1996; Norris, 1997). Cross-national comparisons show that proportional representation in multi-candidate list systems, are more favorable for women and newcomers compared with simple majority systems (Gelb, 1990; Bullock and McManus, 1991; Mutland and Studlar, 1996; Norris, 1993; Norris, 1997; Perrigo, 1995; Sanbonmatsu, 2006). They provide more seats to compete over, compared with the “winner-takes-all” electoral systems. Candidates may not win the top position, but are still able to get in lower slates, and depending on a party’s success, into the legislature. Implications and Directions for Theorizing about Women and Politics Existing explanations illuminate the context and potential obstacles that women face in a society organized around gender differences. At the same time, some aspects need more attention, especially when it comes to an analysis of women’s political activity. One of the main fields in need of more attention is the political process. The alliances, coalitions, and rivalries constituting political relations, the political context, interests and dynamics of political bargaining are absent. Representation in the prevailing discussion is a matter of general societal conditions or procedures applying to individuals who are generally absent from politics, or at least to the point of elections. Practically speaking, there are little analytical tools to discuss and examine how women do engage in politic. It seems as if women and their political representation is not necessarily a political question. It is external to politics, and has to do with the general societal conditions that shape individual abilities, motivations, and inclinations. 5 Without dealing with the political as part of a discussion about representation, implied is a political arena and actors that are abstract and universal. In the “supply” approach, actors are individuals with a set of pre-determined characteristics and predispositions measurable by a standard model of merit and skill. In the “procedural” framework, the arena is the sum of abstract rules of selection. Granted, they serve political purposes, but abstract still. The universality implied in the “supply” or the “procedural” approaches, corresponds to the liberal ideal of politics. Liberalism prescribes a neutral political arena where individuals interact and compete according to universal standards of behavior. Liberalism instructs us to expect an arena that is open for all, where evaluation of aspiring leaders, should be, and is, based on universal principles of merit and skill. Gender, race, ethnicity, or family origin are external burdens that should not matter when it comes to the selection or evaluation of leaders, or in terms of the demands or concerns that political actors may have (Young, 1990). One important implication of the assumption of universality is that an existing state of affairs becomes a normative model rather then an example of a specific case. Thus, a seemingly universal is shaped in the image of those already controlling positions of power, and serves to exclude any diversions from the standard rule. In this case, the standard is shaped by and after the image of men (Brown, 1995; Ferguson, 1984; Young, 1991). Feminist work shows how gender, through the division between public and private, power and subjugation, masculine and feminine, creates masculine political actors and feminine apolitical actors. The modern Democratic and universal political arena, where policy is made and resources distributed, depends on the existence of a subjugated private sphere of the family, where ascribed status and birthright remain basis for hierarchy. In the division of labor between actors, the masculine becomes the modern universal standard a modern masculine political actor, and women remain 6 assigned to the private sphere, rendered apolitical. (Baker, 1984; Elshtain, 1981; Okin, 1979; Pateman, 1988; Young, 1990). Here feminist analytical work and research offers a political concept of women and representation. Women are not necessarily absent or apolitical, but excluded. Instead of absent, women are actors whose participation and therefore potential gains are blocked by an ideology of masculinity and male dominated political arena. Empirical evidence shows that the masculine model serves a real barrier for women in politics. It shapes recruitment preferences, politicians’ inclinations in forming alliances or choosing protégés, and party members’ voting preferences (Brown, Heighberger, and Shocket, 1993; Koch, 1999; Kurtz, 1995; Lovenduski and Norris, 1989; Lovenduski, 1996; Niven, 1998; Sanbonmatsu, 2006; Simrell-King, 1995). The feminist approach women’s electoral success into a political question and turns the focus of analysis to the political arena. Following this logic, the direction of change that leads for electoral success, or representation, is the inclusion of women as political actors. The question is where and how. While illuminating the direction for thinking and investigating, implied notion of hegemonic masculinity in the feminist framework limits the span of investigative or analytical possibilities. The effort to expose the masculine underlying the neutral universal standard also requires a way to solve the problem, for women to overcome this obstacle. Otherwise, women, if feminine, will never be able to measure up to a masculine standard, as women. An implied masculine hegemony may not be sufficient, because it means that the only possible solution is the abolition of political institutions and structures based on some hierarchical form, or power all together. In a strange twist, it may even mean that when women pursue power they succumb to their oppressor – the masculine ideology – thus making it less legitimate for women to engage in existing political structures. Dealing with change, therefore, requires a concept of gendered 7 actors that may capture heterogeneity rather than universality, be it abstract or masculine that allows for the possibility of multiple expressions of gender and ways to do power (Scott, 1988). Asking about representation instead of under representation is a question about women gaining access, in the first place, to niches in the political arena for the pursuit and exchange of power. The discussion is not so much about electoral victory as it is about the available paths that lead one to participate in the process, and in return, making political gains that lead to electoral power. It is a question of the incorporation of women into the political arena as legitimate, participant political actors. This requires a concept that enables capturing the locations where women and men do politics and what they do there. Organizational Actors: An Alternative Framework of Analysis An alternative that can prove useful to address issues of incorporation to politics is an organizational framework of analysis, where gender is an integral part of organizational processes and relations in the organizational environment. The point of departure is politics as a dynamic arena of organizations constituted of coalitions and alliances, located in different, yet interacting, positions in the institutional environment, with differential access to power, that serve as a corporate actor, competing over control and influence over policymaking (Laumann and Knocke, 1987). They compete over control over the political arena and the ability to influence policymaking. At the core of the arena are political parties, exerting direct influence by “sending” their representatives to decision-making positions. For social movements, nonprofits, or civic associations, it is an indirect effort in lobbying, negotiating, or demand making. They compete over the support of constituents and other organizations, recruit potential supporters, coopt, or exclude challengers. They may join forces and share recruits and constituents. Elections 8 are simply the culmination of this ongoing organizational effort, where parties are the main player, but other organizations may provide activists, endorsement, or candidates when needed. To integrate gender in the analysis I engage with Acker’s theory of gendered organizations (1990). Acker identifies five processes through which the distinction between man and woman works to organize relations in organizations. They include divisions of labor, time, or space, and assumptions and practices that make the organization’s everyday life, interactions between members, symbols, and identities. “To say that an organization, or any other analytic unit, is gendered, means that advantage and disadvantage, exploitation and control, action and emotion, meaning and identity, are patterned through and in terms of a distinction between male and female, masculine and feminine.” (1990: 146). I use here the first category in Acker’s gendering processes, looking at the division of labor between men and women in the organizational environment. Yet I make the move to suggest that gendering processes can result in political gains for women. The theory of gendered organizations joins the larger feminist project to bring gender as a category of analysis (Scott, 1988) and expose gendered assumptions in seemingly neutral arenas of activity, such as politics or work organizations. Acker exposes assumptions of masculinity in the formal job evaluation process (Acker, 1990). Yet her analysis implies that gendering always reinforces masculine assumptions, and is always organized around men and their interests, thus “gendered” equals “masculinized” (Britton, 2000). The inherent masculinity Acker associated with the organization creates the same difficulties of capturing or identifying actual change that does not include the abolition of organizations all together (Acker, 1991; Britton, 2000). An addition that opens the way to conceptualize gendering that is beneficial for women could work 9 for the concept. By applying organizational models that emphasize their dynamics as sites for negotiation of power, I attempt to add a possibility for change in gendering processes. Gender is a dichotomous mechanism, based on assumption of essential difference, signifying identities, prescriptions for behavior and practices, structural arrangements and meanings, and hierarchical relations (Lorber, 1994). The assumption of difference creates an image of inevitability and stability. Yet gender and gendered structures are always the result of ongoing negotiation over arrangements, behavioral prescriptions, and public expressions of assigned gender categories (Butler, 1990; Scott, 1988; West and Zimmerman, 1987). Gender as a mechanism that signifies relations may not disappear, but it may take alternative political expressions. Instead of one masculine standard that underlies positions, there will be several possibilities for political “masculine” and political “feminine”. The direction of change therefore may not be the opening of masculine positions to women, such as in feminization of former masculine occupations, but the opening more paths, more positions. If women are the alternative or “other” actor, this may mean that instead of “masculine” positions opened for women, there are simply “feminine” positions that become political. I turn the focus to an organizational environment constituted of competing alliances between organizations and inside organizations. I look at persons’ positions and activities as available paths for men and women across the arena and use a relational concept of power that can be exchange, divided, and allocated to a variety of actors. I suggest and then illustrate two gendered dimensions in the process of organized incorporation to the political arena. One is the gendered structure of the organizational environment and location in relation to power. Another is positions available for female and male actors, distinguished in their “political” nature, that is, the type of ties they provide for male and female actors. 10 Working with an organizational analytical framework, I look at organizations as corporate actors actively engaged in seeking influence and control in a complex environment. I draw on several approaches in that may not necessarily share agreement on all aspects of the organization, but all combine to provide a dynamic concept of organizations, especially as it applies to a political arena. First, organizations are corporate actors actively engaged and interact in an environment organized to sectors, fields, or domains, distinguished by the type of actors interacting in section of the environment and their distance from power and influence over policymaking (Laumann and Knocke, 1987). There are various approaches and definitions, some focused on institutional environments, others on populations (see for example, DiMaggio and Powell, 1983). My purpose in this paper is less a distinct notion of environment as much as to call attention to organizations as dynamic structures and the way gender constructs organizational environments. Organizations are engaged in constant bargaining with actors in the environment, including other organizations and the constituents. Organizations compete over support and recruits that can turn loyal members and representatives, protégés and liaison with the constituency. Gender signifies the location of organizations assigned for women and men, and distance from power. Gender distinguishes between the dominantly “masculine” partisan politics, movements and unions, and the more “feminine” margins of local voluntary groups and associations. Civic and voluntary associations have traditionally been an alternative venue for women. Providing a variety of services for the community and concerned with the community’s welfare, they function as a public extension of women’s domestic responsibilities (Koven and Michel, 1990). Posing little threat on centers of power, they provide therefore an alternative form for political actors with limited access to power at the center of the political arena. Women do 11 not dominate voluntary or “semi-political” organizations (Burns, Schlozman and Verba, 2001; Einwohner, Hollander, and Olson; 2000). However, traditionally, it has served as a normative venue for women, compared with partisan politics, and one where women do participate in larger number, compared with partisan politics. Organizations are best understood as sites for the negotiation of power, constituted of alliances and rivalries, where power, best understood as publicly acknowledged social capital is built, expanded, and negotiated (Burt, 1992; Kanter, 1977; Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). Diverse networks of allies, especially for leaders, and direct ties to potential sponsors, for potential protégés, are two aspects of a social capital that can translate to political. For power brokers or leaders, diverse networks of allies and supporters provide opportunities to exchange favors. In work organizations, diverse networks provide managers with opportunities to improve their status and access to higher positions in the market (Burt, 1992). Direct ties between sponsors and protégés expand the potential span of control for power brokers. For potential protégés, leaders act as sponsors make careers by providing them access to their alliances of power, or as gatekeepers excluding them from access to social capital (Kanter, 1977). The second dimension for gendering process therefore, is gender as a signifier of the social capital attached to positions. Research suggests that women’s opportunities to develop diverse networks are usually limited, but that direct sponsorships work for their benefit (Hertsog, 1999; Kanter, 1977; Pfeffer, 1997). Gender may distinguish, therefore between sponsorship attached to positions available for women, and access to complex alliances attached to positions available for men. The final test of political capital is public backing in junctions of allocation of power, such as nomination cycles or elections. Elections are the culmination of organizational effort to amass power and the test for power of corporate actors and power brokers. Elections are a test 12 for one’s status in the organization, whether the organization is willing to run her or him or provide them with backing, endorsements given, and the degree to which these are useful. Running as a candidate endorsed and supported by their organization or sponsors, is already a stamp of approval of one’s “insider”, or political, status. Winning is the final step on the way. When gendering serves only to reinforce the advantages of men, gendered sectors and positions do not translate to participation in elections. Actors remain in their niche and away from the competition. Gendering processes may result political gains when organizations or patrons run and back women assigned to “feminine” niches. Using an organizational model for political exchange enables capturing the complexities of the political arena, and potential points for change. Actors are no longer abstract, but part of the structure of power relations, defined in terms of the alliances they are of, positions and status they hold, or interests they represent. Using gender as an integral mechanism enables examining how exactly female and male actors are incorporated to the system. I illustrate the process by testing three hypotheses reflecting dimensions of environment, positions, and political gains: 1. on the level of the organizational environment: women and men are likely to arrive at the electoral competition from different organizational sectors. Men are more likely to arrive to the electoral arena from partisan organizations and women from civic organizations. 2. Partisan organizations open specific niches for women. 3. Backing patterns vary in terms of the actors providing backing, based on ties attached to the gendered positions available for men and women. The exact activity and nature of positions, identity of corporate actors participating, depends on the political context in a specific arena, main issues, interests, and concerns in a 13 specific arena, constraints and organizational structure, constituents, and relations between organizations and constituents. The Case Study This paper is based on a project on a larger scale that examined electoral participation and recruitment patterns in Chicago, using multiple methods of data collection and analysis, including electoral returns, media coverage, in-depth interviews, and participant observation. Chicago combines nonpartisan elections to the city council, with few limitations on number of candidates and requirements, with an almost hegemonic control of the Democratic Party in the city. It combines this seemingly homogenous “one party” arena, with divisions along ethnic and racial lines, creating separate political contexts. Women’s representation increased to a third of the council since the 1990s, and at least statistically, women and men are equally likely to win elections, with 13.5% of candidates in each gender group win at their first attempt at office.3 Politics in the city, however, is more complex. The organization of city wards, the Democratic Party’s control over the city, and race and ethnicity, constitute three important aspects that organize political relations in the city. The city of Chicago is divided to fifty wards, each represented by one alderman on the city council. Wards serve as electoral districts in the municipal elections, municipal units for city services, and units in the organizational structure of the Democratic and Republican parties. Each party has a local ward organization that coordinates activities, fund raising, campaigns, recruits members, activists and campaign workers, and in many cases, “provides” political backing or “sends” candidates to elections. Women’s political aspirations and electoral success, varies by ward’s political and ethnic structure. This review of Chicago’s political history is an integrative endeavor based on several major books and texts on the history of the city’s political arena and particular events in the process, and social relations in the city. The complete list of sources is included in the bibliography list. 3 14 The Democratic Party has almost hegemonic power in Chicago. The party has governed the city for the better part of the 20th century and since, using its famed political machine, based on patronage and the cultivation of a clientalistic political culture, where services, jobs, careers, contracts, and other favors exchanged in return for political support. The Democratic ward organization served as the basic unit in the operation of the machine. The ward organization recruited members, mobilized voters, and was the main unit for the recruitment of city workers. A pool of city jobs was allocated to the organization, to be distributed among loyal members and locals. The famous or infamous machine faces its share of local organized challenges in different parts of the city, but none was as strong, or influential as intra-party challenges of the 1980s, and in the same era, institutional constraints in the form of judicial decree prohibiting political hiring. Its heritage lives on. It lives in practice, although less official, in some wards of the city, and as a symbol of all that is bad in Chicago politics in others. Ethnicity and race as a legitimate basis for political bargaining is another aspect of Chicago. Residential segregation sustains this system and ward boundaries, made to include a demographic majority of one racial or ethnic group based on the census, reinforce it. In its beginning in the 1930s, machine politics was based on bargaining between politicians in segregated communities of European descent, constituting more than 80% at the time. Machine leaders bargained with selected politicians in the then small African American minority. The demographic dominance of the White population declined over the years but they remained a majority of 67.2% of voting age population well into the late 1960s. The picture changed since and by 2000 they constituted 40.9%. Replacing White constituency first were African American residents, increasing from 13.4% in 1950 to 20.2% in 1960, and since the 1980s to about a third of voting age population. By then, the Hispanic community entered as a third large constituency, 15 growing from a small minority of 6.5% in 1970 to a sizeable 20% in 2000. Immigrants from Asia or of Asian descent make the remaining percent.4 The composition of wards reflects these changes. If in the municipal elections of 1971, there were 32 wards with a White dominant majority of at least 60%, by 2007, the number of “White wards” declined to 11. The 15 wards with an African American dominant majority increased to 20. Hispanic wards were created only in the 1980s, beginning with 4 wards, and growing to 8 by 2007. Change in the number of wards where neither group constitutes a majority reflect demographic changes: from 3 in the 1970s to 11 in 2007, several of which are made of relatively large Hispanic and White communities. For the most part, members of the dominant majority serve as aldermen, and in the “Mixed” wards all aldermen are White.5 The creation of the first Hispanic wards in the 1980s is an illustrative case of the link between ethnicity and political bargaining. Following the 1980 census, mobilized groups and rising local politicians in the Hispanic community organized to demand wards, as did African Americans when potential loss of majority in two African American wards meant potential loss of two aldermen. The rather heated and well covered campaign resulted in a court appeal and a judicial ordinance, in 1986, the addition of two African American wards, and the creation of four Hispanic wards.5 A variety of partisan organizations and groups attempted challenging the machine and take control over city wards and mayor’s office. The Republican Party ran candidates, and served as potential backer for a variety of challengers. It held a few wards in the northern parts of the city still in the 1950s and 1960s but lost all but one since. Unaffiliated or “independent” organizations and individuals took over selected city wards. The more successful and famous organized attempt was the Independent Precinct Organization (IPO), whose founder and leader 4 Source: Lewis, James H., d. Garth Taylor, and Paul Kleppner. 1997. Metro Chicago Political Atlas 1997- 1998. Springfield, IL: University of Illinois at Springfield United States Census Bureau, 2000. 16 served on the city council in the 1970s. Several “opposition” aldermen, many times Democrats in ideology and affiliation, but antagonistic to the machine, have served on the council. The most serious and successful challenge, however, took place from within, not all of it intended, in the end of the 1970s, creating about a decade of political turbulence. In 1976, the mayor Richard M. Daley, who ran the city since 1955, died in office. His replacement, Michael Bilandic, alderman of Daley’s home base in the 11th ward, served as mayor until 1979. In the 1979 elections he was challenged and lost to Jane Byrne, a Daley protégé herself, who ran against the party’s apparatus in an anti machine campaign, and the support of African American voters. She served for one term, seen today as a disappointing episode, when she ended up relying on factions in the machine, instead of implementing her stated anti-machine policy. In 1983, the late Harold Washington, an African American Democratic congressman challenged Byrne and the machine, winning first the Democratic mayoral primaries against Byrne and the late Daley’s son Richard, and then the mayoral elections, with a coalition of “outsiders” – minorities, organized independents, civic groups, and rising politicians in the Hispanic community. Washington is held high as a symbol for all that is good in government. His first term constituted of an ongoing political battle against an opposition of twenty-nine aldermen on the city council. Despite it, Washington won his second term in office in the 1987 elections. Washington died in the end of 1987. Eugene Sawyer, African American alderman of the 6th ward, who was backed by the twenty nine opposition aldermen, replaced him. In special mayoral elections held in 1989, he faced the late Daley’s son Richard for whom it was the second attempt. Richard J. Daley won the elections, and his repeated victory in 1991 marks the end of that turbulent period. The second Daley has been mayor ever since, with little opposition 17 from mayoral challenges. Compared with his predecessors, he has managed, except for specific policy issues, to win over the support of the city council over the years. Women and Representation in Chicago In 1971, the first two female aldermen were elected to Chicago’s fifty-member city council. It was also the first time more than a handful of female candidates competed, and the first time a woman ran as the Democratic ward organization’s candidate. By 1987, the number of female aldermen increased to 6, by 1991 to 9, and since 1995 it has been within a range of 15-16, making them a third of the city council. The number of female candidates increased too, but not to the same degree. The number of female candidates in the 1970s was 13-17 and in 1983 it increased to 34. Since then it remained relatively stable, on a range of 39 (1995) and 52 (1999). Among male candidates, electoral aspirations were more dynamic, with 107-142 men in the 1970s, 166-222 in 1983-1991, and declined back to 102-157 since 1995. The decline in male aspirations following the heated 1980s means that proportionally, and in spite of relative stability in numbers, women’s proportion increased to a third in 2007. Across Chicago, women and men are as likely to be aldermen, at least in percentage: female and male aldermen make 13.5% of the candidates in each gender group. However, taking ethnicity in consideration, there is a great deal of variation. Since 1971, 35 women have served as aldermen. Of them, 23 are African American, 11 White, and 1 Hispanic. By 2007, women are aldermen in 11 of the 20 African American wards, all aldermen in Hispanic wards are men, and five women are aldermen in the remaining wards. An analysis elsewhere showed that political aspirations provide only partial explanation (Lechtman, 2008). Examining average candidacy rates, it showed that since the 1980s, many more candidates ran in African American wards compared to all other wards, but it was true for both men and women. Furthermore, the number 18 of female aspirants in Hispanic wards was higher than in White wards. Analysis of attitudes measured in the GSS (also in Lechtman, 2008) showed that support of female aspirations among urban African Americans were not significantly higher among other urban dwellers. In general, candidates in Chicago run for office in different political contexts, even when procedures are similar and seemingly open. Candidates in White wards run in communities that managed to remain relatively homogenous in time of change. Candidates in Hispanic wards run in communities that have only recently developed internal political structure. Candidates in African American wards run in a community that has served as Chicago’s neglected minority for almost a century, and was the source of challengers and support of challengers of city elite. Patterns of female (and male) electoral aspirations or success also vary by community. In terms of human capital and opportunities in the labor market, it is in the communities whose members face relatively more disadvantages in American society, that persons make more attempts to win elected office. This takes the discussion back to the question of representation as a political question of incorporation into political structures. Method: Identifying and Measuring Available Paths in Chicago The paper uses data collected as part of a larger research project examining electoral politics in Chicago (Lechtman, 2008). The focus of the paper is the possibility of gendered patterns in the organizational paths available to men and women in the political arena, and implications for backing and electoral success. It covers therefore some form or another of organized effort to influence policymaking, direct or indirect, through partisan organizations and a broad range of civic organizations that enable the community to express concerns, make demands and interact with policy makers (Burns, Lehman-Schlozman, and Verba 2001). 19 Population: the population included all persons who ran for office for the first time in one of the ten regular municipal elections between 1971 and 2007, and won at least two dozen votes. Names of candidates were collected from canvass sheets of the Chicago Board of Elections, and statements of election results. Each candidate was counted once at his or her first attempt. In total, 1199 persons were first time candidates in the ten regular elections since 1971. Elections to the Chicago’s city council are non-partisan. There is not limit on the number of candidates, and the official obstacle is the need of notarized nominating petitions. Regular elections take place in February every four years. Winning requires 50%+1 of the vote, and when no one wins, the two highest scoring candidates compete in an April runoff. Data: source of data was media coverage and public information searched in electronic archives of Chicago’s two leading newspapers: The Chicago Tribune and the Chicago Sun Times. Media outlets catering for specific constituencies, and Google were also used for cross reference. Names of candidates served as keywords, including all combinations and nicknames to cover all potential mentions, not only around campaign periods. I cross referenced by time and outlet for all manifestation of names. All the Chicago Tribune’s published articles are accessible electronically and therefore it served as basis. Chicago Sun Times was available electronically only for 1986 onwards. They were cross referenced across time and A variety of factors influence what may or may not appear on the news. Notions of editors, journalists, and interviewees as to what may constitute relevant or important news are one. During election periods, journals cover candidates in the wards. Background usually includes age and employment and in addition, partisan affiliations, family ties, affiliation with local civic groups and neighborhood association, status and participation in local neighborhood campaigns and policy issues. Coverage of events outside the electoral period included, in 20 addition to city government, also local neighborhood campaigns, events and policy issues or controversies. Status is another factor. “Celebrities”, athletes, entertainers, or politicians, may receive more attention then others. Some individuals have better skills in creating a “buzz” around their activity or their candidacy. Since the purpose of this study is in fact to capture organized activity and status individuals held, it worked in this case. On the other hand, there were cases where journalists reported that a candidate did not respond. In this case, the working assumption was that absence of any report of activity, even during campaigns when candidates have the opportunities to interact with the media, meant that there was none. For quite a few candidates, approximately 400 individuals, no information of any kind was available. It is possible that as a result, the analysis underestimates the involvement of candidates, but in this case, it is preferable over overestimating organized involvement. It was especially important to distinguish between organized alliances and established organizations, and a variety of personal initiatives or crusades. Cross references and multiple searches ensured some level of correspondence between person, biography, and activity. Here too, I used a high threshold for inclusion in the analysis as “organized activity”, excluding all organizations that were not clearly identified, that included one person serving as founder and member, and all candidates described as “community activists” whose activity was not specified. As a result, the analysis included relatively established, quite conventional, and recognized groups in Chicago. Independent Variables Gender: Of the total 1199 first time candidates, 951 were men (79.5%) and 245 were women (20.5%). Data on gender was missing for three cases, resulting in a pool of 1196 cases. Racial Composition of Wards: wards are divided in four categories: “White”, “African American”, “Hispanic”, and “Mixed”, according to a dominant majority of at least 60%. For 21 each candidate, ward category corresponds to the elections he or she ran in at the time. Data that systematically traces changes in ethnic composition of wards does not exist. I reconstruct changes using several sources, each concerned with a particular period and ethnic group. I combined information from the 2000 reports by the Northeastern Illinois Planning Commission, the Department of Planning and Development of the City of Chicago, the Metro Chicago Political Atlas 1997- 1998, and Fremon, 1988. The number of wards changed over time. White wards declined from 32 in the 1970s, to 20 in 1983-1991, 15 in 1995-1999 and 11 in 2003-2007. African American wards increased from 15 in the 1970s, to 16 1983 and 18 in 1987, 19 in 1991-1999, and 20 in 2003-2007. Although in 1986 there were four wards recognized as Hispanic, only three included a Hispanic majority. There were six in 1995-1999, and eight in 2003-2007. The number of “Mixed” wards, without a majority of any group, increased from 3 in the 1970s to 14 in 1983, declined to 9 in 1987 and 8 in 1991 and increased to 10 in 1995-1999, and 11 in 2003-2007. African American wards show the highest number of first time candidates – 561, and the highest number of female candidates, 141 (25.1%). White wards follow with 378 candidates, 56 of them women (14.8%), and Mixed wards with 177 candidates, including 32 women (18.1%). In the Hispanic wards, the most recent to establish and smallest group, there were 80 candidates, 16 of them women (20%). Timing: elections are divided to three periods: 1971-1979, 1983-1991, and 1995-2007. The first corresponds to the last decade of the Daley machine, and the end of White demographic dominance. It includes 3 elections and 285 candidates, including 37 women (13.0%). The second category, 1983-1991, corresponds to the period of increased political heat of the Washington elections, and the regular elections concluding the period in 1991. It is also the first introduction of Hispanic wards in the city. It includes 3 elections, 485 candidates, 98 of them women 22 (20.2%). The last category corresponds to Daley’s continuous terms in office, and general stability. It includes 4 elections, 426 candidates, 110 of them women (25.8%). Table 1 shows the percentage of male and female candidates in each ward category and period category. Dependent variables There are two independent variables: public backing, and winning the first attempt. Each Backing: the media provided information on parties’ ward organization and independent organizations who “sent” candidates or backed them, as well as public endorsements and help provided by individual politicians, mayors, leaders, and interested persons. Backers and endorsers may provide funding, “lend” campaign managers, office space, or volunteers. Two categories of backing are included: “Organizational” and “Individual”. The first refers to formal organizations that publicly support or endorse candidates, or “run” them for office. This includes the Democratic ward organization, the Republican Party, and a variety of other organized groups that “send” a candidate to the elections. The category “Individual” refers to persons endorsing, providing help or even publicly running a candidate, but not as part of a sending organization. Thus, for example, ward regular organization’s backing and the backing of the committeeman in that ward are same - organizational. On the other hand, an alderman in another ward or a former alderman backing a candidate, even if they use an orchestrated network of allies and volunteers, was defined as individual. Here relations between candidate and backer, or volunteers and candidate are based on the personal, even if political, tie between them or between common allies, but not on the basis of an organizational interest. Mayors were also defined as individuals when backing candidates. 23 Results Gendered Politics: Components of Available Paths in Chicago’s Political Arena The first task was “mapping” the organizational routes to the election, examining whether men and women inhabit different niches. The search resulted in several niches, or categories of activity, in partisan or electoral organizations, and in civic organizations. By “partisan”, I refer to any organization, registered as a party or not, whose goal is “sending” persons to policy-making positions. About a third of all candidates (448, 37.4%) were involved in some organized fashion in the public life of their community before running for office. For most candidates, electoral or partisan engagement and civic engagement were mutually exclusive. There were 245 exclusively electoral candidates, constituting 54.7% of “activist” candidates (20.5% of all candidates), and 164 exclusively “civic” candidates (36.6% of “activist” candidates, 13.7% of all candidates). There were 39 candidates who did both. In total, there were 284 “electoral” candidates (23.7% of all candidates) and 203 civic candidates (17% of all candidates). I divide candidates’ profiles in seven categories, by combination of activity, ties, and location. Three reflect any kind of electoral and political work, unpaid and paid, for politicians or political organizations. Two categories reflect campaign experience in larger campaigns: serving as precinct captains in Chicago’s ward organizations, and serving on campaigns for politicians unaffiliated with the ward organization. The category “staff” includes all candidates who served on the staff of another politician at some point or another. The three are mutually exclusive, and so precinct captains or activist who later went on one’s staff, which is a possible link, as I will soon show, are defined as staff. The category “civic engagement” represents members and leaders of neighborhood associations, local nonprofits, and advocacy groups or national ones, and a variety of local community based initiatives and government. 24 In addition, I include a category “family ties” that captures the degree to which candidates were family members of politicians and power brokers. Kinship is not considered an integral part of the modern political arena. It is included because, at least in Chicago, kinship constitutes political capital. It is quite acceptable for sons or daughters to inherit their father’s seat, by appointment or election, or for, usually fathers, but sometimes mothers, to appoint or run family members or family members of allies, to a variety of city, county and state elected and non-elected positions. Two categories reflect prior political aspirations and elected positions. The category “Elected Officials” includes candidates who had held an elected position prior to the race, from state congressmen to committeemen. I include all persons who ever ran to another elected position in the category "prior aspirants”. The Precinct Captain: the precinct captain in the ward organization was the most frequent electoral experience for candidates. There were 65 persons who, when running for office did not hold in any higher position in the political hierarchy (5.4% of all candidates) but a total of 107 who have served at some point or another as precinct captain but since then moved to other positions in the system (8.9% of candidates). These 65 persons constitute 5.4% of all candidates, and about 28.4% of all persons who were engaged in some electoral or partisan activity. Precinct captains and assistant precinct captains are members of the ward organization and serve as liaison between local leaders and the constituents throughout the year all in order to mobilize voters in elections. The power of the precinct captain I seemingly limited to the number of precincts he is responsible for where he maintains interaction with constituents. He is one of several precinct captains who may also have political interests of their own, but may also serve as a basis for alliance. He has ties to the key power broker in the ward, the committeeman, and 25 with his or her backing, he gains the loyalty of the organization as a whole. The precinct captain position is not only the gateway to the ward but to city jobs, reward for loyalty and work, and for politically skilled precinct captains, to the committeeman’s alliances. Precinct captains may get on a politician’s staff, elected committeemen, and up to city, county, or state office. It is a man’s job and a characteristic of White wards. Men constituted 89.2% of candidates with only precinct captain experience, higher than their percentage in the population (79.5%), and women 10.8%, lower than their proportion in the population (20.5%). All male precinct captains, including those who moved to bigger things in politics, constituted 9.7% of male candidates (92 persons) and 6.1% of female candidates (15). Of only precinct captains, 53.8% ran in White wards (compared with the 31.6% of White wards candidates), 32.3% in African American wards (compared with 46.9% in the population), 12.3% in “Mixed” wards, and only one person in Hispanic wards. Over time, the number of precinct captains declined, reflecting among other things, decline in the number of White wards. Campaign Activists: independent campaigns are an alternative way to acquire campaign experience. Like precinct captains, they mobilize voters in elections, but their location in the arena and duration there are different. The precinct captain in the ward organization is part of a complex and longtime operation of power. The “campaign activist” has the potential of ties to political alliances, but outside the major center of power, and in Chicago, usually challengers of centers of power. About 55 candidates did campaign work for candidates or other political organizations outside the Democratic establishment in Chicago. Proportionally to their size in the candidate population, women were slightly more likely to engage in this activity. They constituted 30.9% of campaign workers (17 women), somewhat higher than their 20.5% of the population. The proportion of candidates in Hispanic and “Mixed” wards among campaign 26 workers was higher than their proportion in the population, and the opposite in White and African American wards. A small increase in the number of campaign activists in the last decades may reflect the increase in Hispanic and “Mixed” wards. Staff: the category “staff” includes aides, assistants, chiefs of staff and others on the staff of aldermen and elected officials in the city, county, state, or national legislatures. About 81 first time candidates served as staff members. Employment on a politician’s staff is a way to reward and nurture loyal operators and protégés or potential protégés and a way to maintain allies in close distance. Assistants arrive from within the circles of loyal activists, friends or allies, and not least important, family members or family members of allies and friends. Ties are direct to the boss, who may serve as a potential sponsor or patron. Proportionally, women are more likely to serve as staff members (30.9%). There is little difference between wards, but a higher number of “staff” candidates proportionally to the number of candidate that decade. Civic Engagement: about 203 persons or 17% of first time candidates since 1971 were engaged in at least one civic organization. It should be noted, that this is not a representative sample of civic engagement in Chicago, but the civically engaged among electoral aspirants. About a third (67, 33.0%), were involved in more than one such organization either simultaneously or in a series of commitments. About half (101, 49.8%) were presidents, chairpersons, directors, board members or committee chairs. In addition, about 42 individuals (20.7%) were employed coordinators, directors, or administrators. They include neighborhood associations, organizations with a particular cause for social change, as well as bureaucratized, or less bureaucratized community organizations. This also includes community based participative governing such as local school council that replaced PTAs, or local policing committees. 27 Men are the majority of candidates and are also a majority among “civic” candidates, but women’s proportion among civic candidates (31.0%) is somewhat higher than their proportion among candidates. Among women, civic candidates constituted 25.7% compared with 14.7% among men. Rates were highest for candidates in Hispanic wards (12.3% of civic candidates compared with 6.7% of candidates), followed by Mixed wards (18.2, and the opposite for White and African American wards. The proportion of civic candidates in 1995-2007 exceeded their proportion among candidates (47.3% compared with 35.5%) and the opposite for the two other periods, reflecting for some degree the increase in candidates in Hispanic wards. Among presidents, directors, board members, or committee chairs men were about two thirds and women a third (63.3% and 36.7%) or 6.7% of male candidates (64 men) and 15.1% of female candidates (37 women). Women were more likely to be involved in more than one organization: 10.2% of female candidates (25 women) and 4.4% of male candidates (42 men). Family Ties: there were 72 individuals, whose family ties in Chicago known to the public through the media, and who ran for office, constituting 6% of first time candidates. They included 24 wives, sons, or daughters, 12 siblings or members of the extended family, and 31 other relatives and members of prominent families. In fact, 27 of the aldermen who ran for the first time since 1971 were family members of established political players in the city. The family route is another alternative for women. Among female candidates, 9.8% (24 women) arrive from “political families” compared with 5% among male candidates (48 men). Elected Officials: about 44 individuals (43.1%) held an elected office at least once before running for alderman. Majority of about two thirds, are 29 ward committeemen (and ran as such in the election). The rest held, for the most part, seats on county boards, or state legislatures. Among them were 10 women (22.7%) and 34 men (77.3%) corresponding to the distribution 28 among candidates (20.5% women and 79.5% men). Several state representatives attempted to translate incumbency to the ward level, and others ran as part of “personnel reshuffle” in accordance with organizational needs. Prior Aspirants: this category reflects general political aspirations, regardless of status and position, reflected in running for another office at some point in one’s career prior to the first attempt at the aldermanic seat. About 102 first time aldermanic candidates (8.5%) have tried their luck elsewhere before, in elections to county boards (41 candidates), ward committeeman (33), in primaries for the state House, state Senate, or the United States House (17), and for judge or mayor (25). Over time, their number declined from 33 or 11.6% in the 1970s to 47 or 9.6% in the 1980s, and then to 22 or 5.2% in 1995-2007. The proportion of prior aspirants among men was slightly higher than among women: 84 men (8.8%) and 18 women (7.4%). When only losing aspirants are included, there are 50 men and 8 women. Summary: the descriptive data suggests that the organizational environment where persons who end up running for office are engaged in, is gendered. First, it is gendered in the sense, that men dominate the field of political aspirants, even if not the field of winning political aspirants. More important for this discussion, they are gendered in terms of distinct niches that are available for men and women in the arena, and from which persons end up running for office. The data suggests that the precinct captain in the ward organization is a masculine niche, in the sense that it is a niche available particularly for men. This niche serves Chicago’s traditional hierarchy of power, with the ward organization at the basis of the machine, and the basic unit where a person may develop his political ties. The ward organization as a location that “creates” electoral aspirants, or that recruits and sends aspirants has declined over the years, as did the number of White wards in the city. 29 The results also suggest that other niches, outside the inner circle of political power in Chicago serve as “feminine” niches, in the sense that they serve as an alternative niche for women. Women are more likely to be active in campaigns outside the ward organization and more likely to be involved in civic organizations. In that sense, women “begin” their political involvement in locations that have the potential to form ties that are outside the traditional centers of power in Chicago. Alternative ties for women are the seemingly apolitical family ties, although in Chicago they may serve as a political capital in its own right and in that sense an “internal” component, at least in comparison to the “external” civic or “campaign” categories. Another feminine niche is position on the staff of a politician. Much like the family, and unlike the three components mentioned, this position is tied directly to a particular political person, and therefore, its ”internal” or “external” depends on the status of the boss. At this point, it is important to examine whether positions are in fact “masculine” and “feminine” as such, or that gendering is a matter of constellation of political context, or structural factors. For this purpose, I have included a logistic regression analysis to examine whether it is gender, political context in terms of period or ward, and structure in terms of available positions. Table 3 shows the results of four regression models. Three regression models examine the effect of being female, ward, and time on serving only as a precinct captain, as a campaign activist and in civic organizations. The fourth model examines the effect of gender, context, and positions on serving on the staff of a politician, who may serve as a potential patron or sponsor. In this model, the precinct captain category is inclusive, including anyone who has ever served as a precinct captain. White wards are reference for wards and the 1970s are reference for time periods. Shown in table 3, it is clear that being female has a significant and positive effect on engagement in “outsider” politics: in civic organizations and on non-ward campaigns (p<.05). As 30 for the precinct captain position, when controlling for ward and timing, there is no significant effect for being female. There is, however, significant negative effect for serving as precinct captain when running after the 1970s, confirming that the traditional center of power declined as an exclusive niche for the creation of aspirants. In other words, that it is not enough to be “only” precinct captain in order for a person to move into the electoral competition, but requires another stop on the way. This leads to the model for staff position. The fourth model shows that staff members, who move to the electoral competition, are more likely to be recruited from among precinct captains (Odds 5.90, p<.001). It also shows that staff members, especially those ending seeking electoral power are more likely to be recruited from among loyal campaign activists, although for a lesser degree (3.34, p<.001). Being female has a positive significant effect on serving as staff member, independent of any service to the ward organization or to the politician on his or her campaign, and of family ties (1.98, p<.01). The effect is smaller than that of any form of electoral work, but exists, and in similar manner, so is the effect of family ties. Involvement in civic organizations has no significant effect. A comment about the general involvement of men and women is in place. As shown in Table 2, women are more likely to arrive with background in civic organizations. They are also more likely to arrive with some experience in campaign activity. When combining all precinct captains, campaign activists, and staff members, they constitute 15.9% of men (152 men) and 20% of women (49 women). Even with the selected number of candidates who did both civic and campaign work, it seems that while the number of male aspirants is much higher, many more arrive with little political background, except for aspirations, compared with women. 31 Political Consequences: Backing and Winning Public Backing: Public backing is one of the two political gains examined here. A close to a third of first time candidates (30.6%, 367), were backed by an organization or a politician. Partisan, independent, and ward organizations, civic organizations and organized groups were behind almost a quarter (23.9%, 286). Of them, about half ran with the regular Democratic ward organization, or factions in it (49%, 140), and about a third with the backing of other parties and “independent” organizations (36%, 103). The rest (15%, 43) had the backing of other organizations, including 20 who ran with backing of a union local or a coalition of unions7. There are no apparent differences between men and women. Organizations “sent” or backed 22.4% of female candidates and 24.3% of male candidates. Individual politicians publicly supported 15.9% of female candidates and 14.2% of male candidates. Individual politicians endorsed, donated, provided manpower or other help, to 14.6% (175 candidates). They make a diverse group. The mayors publicly and directly endorsed about 70 candidates (40% of candidates backed by individuals). Former aldermen or aldermen in other parts of town backed 56 candidates (32%), and the rest got backing from legislators, civic leaders, businessmen, and other power brokers and interested individual. Table 4 shows the results for three regression models testing the effect of gender, ward, period, and components of political paths, on three backing variables: by an organization, by an individual, and “any backing” – by organization or individual. The model includes mutually exclusive categories of electoral activity: only precinct captain, campaign worker, staff member. It includes holding elected office, prior races, civic activity, and family ties. White wards serve as reference for wards, and the category 1971-1979 is reference for period. As Table 4 shows, gender has no significant effect. 32 Most activities have a positive and significant effect, independent of other factors. Serving as an elected official, who is in many cases, the leader of a ward organization had the highest odds for the probability of organizational backing. For persons who have not yet gained an elected position of power, serving only as precinct captain or on the staff of a politician was the best source of organizational backing. The difference between the odds probability for the “masculine” precinct captain (4.71) and the “feminine” staff position (4.96) is very small. The rest of the “feminine” niches are behind, but are still positive for backing. For endorsement and public backing of individual politicians, the “feminine” family ties and campaign work had the highest odds (3.98 and 3.80, correspondingly), followed by serving as a precinct captain (2.59), on staff (2.46) and civic engagement (2.31). Again, the difference between the effect of serving only as a precinct captain or as staff is small. The only activity that did not prove to have any significant effect on backing is running for office, including both winners and failed attempts. Candidates in African American wards were significantly less likely to have backing from any organization, compared with White wards, but were no different when it came to “unorganized” individual politicians. It is possible that compared with White wards, usually the most stable and powerful organizations, African American wards have fewer “sending” organizations. Note, also that the number of African American candidates is very high. Therefore, the ratio of organization per candidate may simply be too low. Running in a Hispanic, or Mixed wards increased the odds for individual backing, but had no significant effect on organized backing compared with White wards. These are the same ward with a relatively smaller number of candidates running after serving a ward organization. 33 Winning Elections: at first attempt at office, rates of electoral success are similar for men and women across Chicago: 13.5% of male and female candidates won their first attempt at office. The question is whether niches have their particular contribution for winning elections. I add a variable to control for the advantage of incumbency for first time candidates, referring here to appointments for office prior to the elections, a common practice in Chicago. An appointment is the surest way to the aldermanic seat. About a quarter of first time candidates were appointed to their position (41, 24.7%), and 36 of them won their first attempt the following elections. When illness, unexpected death, or resignation of an alderman occurs within the second half of the term, another is appointed to complete it and stands for elections only in the regular electoral cycle. Aldermen may resign to move to another elected office, or due to incarceration or indictment. Resignation a few months prior to the regular elections provides a protégé or a favorable candidate with the advantage of incumbency ahead of time. Officially, the mayor makes appointments. However, local leaders or resigning aldermen endorse a replacement for the mayor to appoint, and for the most parts, an alderman’s wishes prevail. Only in a handful of cases, the mayor selected an appointee against, or regardless, of an alderman’s wishes. A third of appointees are women (34.1%, 14). Half of the appointments were made in 1995-2007, mostly of staff members, which may explain the increase in women’s ability to win elections in Chicago. Staff members and family members are the most likely appointee. Staff members constitute 48.8% of appointed first time candidates, but 6.8% of all first time candidates, and family members constitute 22% of appointees compared with 6% of candidates. The percentage of precinct captains among appointees is lower, 14.6%, but much higher then their 5.4% among candidates. On the other hand, persons with civic background constitute 24.4% of appointees but also 17% of candidates. It is a small difference, but it may suggest that 34 in the case of a selected set of cases, civic organizations served as a source of recruits to the center of power. There are only two appointees who had been campaign in their past. Table 5 shows the results for three logistic regression models. The first tests the effect of gender, ward, and period, niches, aspirations, and family ties. The second adds political backing, and the third controls for the advantage of appointments. The first and second models show that organizational backing is the best predictor of electoral victory. Reflecting the centrality of the ward organization, having being “sent” by an existing organization contributes to the odds probability to win elections more then other factors (Odds are 11.61, p<.001). Controlling for political backing reduces the effect of all positions that had a significant and positive effect on winning elections. Among them, the effect of serving only as precinct captain is now highest, replacing the advantages of holding an elected office (5.66, p<.001). It suggests that serving only as a precinct captain is still meaningful for a political player. This is true, to a somewhat lesser degree for the staff position (Odds = 3.84). Elected office, in it and of itself, when controlling for backing, has no dramatically more or less advantages than working for the ward organization or on politicians’ staff. For civic engagement, family ties, as well as holding an elected office, effect decline and so did significance (p<.05 in Model 2). In it and of itself, that is, when controlling for backing, elected office is advantageous for winning elections in levels that are in between the precinct captain or the staff position. Model 3 adds control for appointments. Here only organizational backing and the precinct captain position remain significant. The alternative “feminine” niches are no longer significant, as they are the most likely appointees. Finally, there are two positions that have no advantages or disadvantages for winning elections: campaign outside the ward and running for another office. Campaign activists may enjoy some backing, but since most of their ties are 35 outside the center of power, backing does not guarantee, nor prevents, success. It also seems that political motivation as such, has no implication for success or failure. There is a negative effect for timing, because since 1983, the number of candidates was much higher, compared with the 1970s. Mathematically, the likelihood of winning for a candidate running against just one opponent in the 1970s is higher than for a candidate running against five in the 1990s. In summary, the results suggest that political gains measured in backing and victory do not vary for men and women independently of structural factors in the political arena in Chicago. This “ungendered” pattern is shaped by the gendered patterns through which men and women participate in the arena, and their path to the competition itself. There is correspondence in time and location, of an increase in the number of women, and increase in the recruitment or entry of actors that have spent their public career outside Chicago’s traditional organized power – the Democratic ward organization, and decline in the status of ward organization as a “sender” of candidates. It is true that the precinct captain position continues to hold a political advantage, controlling for timing, but it is also true that the actual number of only precinct captains running for office, or the wards where they do so, declined. Conclusions The motivation behind this analysis was discomfort with available frameworks for the analysis of gender relations in politics, particularly the discussion on “women and politics” that construct the arena as a mass market of atomistic actors, and depoliticizes issues, actors, and women. Feminist critique of exposing masculine underlying assumptions about political actors, influences the analysis. There I have identified a missing conceptual bridge between the condition of male dominated political arena and a possibility for increase in women’s representation. This paper is an attempt to add to that aspect of the discussion, emphasizing 36 incorporation to the political arena as the bridge between the inactive external, and the insider successful electoral candidate. In particular, the paper offers an organizational analytical framework, calling attention to the organized structure of the political arena, and based on organizational models focusing on organizations as sites for the negotiation of power, and social capital as a form of political capital. The paper illustrate the organizational patterns involved in the process of incorporation and the way gender shapes organizational structures and in return, increased representation for women. To do so I used Chicago’s political arena as a case study, bringing in the particular political context, interests, constraints, identifying the main players that are specific to the arena and the forms of interaction between corporate actors, and the arena. I examine available gendered patterns defined as positions that are more likely to be inhabited by men or positions inhabited by women, and the amount of potential power attached to them. Bringing the actual political context, and the organizations, in the analysis, enables to overcome the assumption of universality of politics in prevailing discussions on women and politics, and overcome the assumption of hegemonic masculinity in feminist analyses of political processes. Non-universal does not necessarily mean too particular to generalize. The relevance of the particular positions in Chicago is in terms of general forms of social capital they provide for actors, in terms of the type of ties they provide for actors that are translatable to political achievements. I have explored the distribution of male and female political aspirants across positions in the organizational environment in Chicago’s political arena, the effect of positions on political backing, and the effect of position and backing on winning elections. In general, the findings confirm most of the arguments and stated hypothesis suggested in the analysis. The findings confirm the first hypothesis. The findings show that women and men 37 are more likely to arrive at the competition from different sectors or niches in the organizational environment. Women are more likely to arrive at the competition with background in civic organizations than men do. In fact, at least for candidates, women arrive from higher positions in the internal hierarchy of civic organizations. I should note that the paper broadens the range of political corporate actors assumed to play a part in the political arena, to include any organized attempt to participate in, or influence policymaking, directly or indirectly (Burns, LehmanSchlozman, and Verba; 2001). The findings confirm the second hypothesis. Men were more likely to have held a precinct captain position, a position that puts them in complex alliances that tie them to peers as well as potential patrons, with the potential to create a network of allies. Women are more likely to have arrived as former staff members of politicians, tying them directly to one or more patrons, rather than positing them as part of a more complex alliance. A broader view shows that the organizational environment in Chicago is gendered beyond the distinction between staff and precinct captain. The internal structure of the arena is gendered in a way that corresponds to two gendered dichotomies: the masculine-center/femininemargin and the private-feminine/public-masculine dichotomy (Elshtain, 1981; Baker, 1984; Okin, 1979). Overall, women are more likely to arrive at the political competition from outside the ward organization, traditionally the most important corporate actor in the ward. Women are more likely to arrive at the competition with background in civic organizations, in “independent” campaigns that usually challenge Democratic machine incumbents, from among the apoliticalpolitical arena of kinship, and as staff members. In fact, while staff members are chosen from among precinct captains, the staff position is also an alternative route for women as such, and is linked to other “external” statuses – the campaign activist and family members. 38 The distinction between the masculine and feminine as distinct arenas of activities therefore remains at least in this sense, stable. This dichotomy should not be understood as a verdict of powerlessness for women as political actors in the city. Women and men enjoy similar levels of backing and are as able to win elections, at least when their gender in it and of itself is examined. There is no difference between men and women when it comes to public endorsements by organizations or individual power brokers. Men and women do not vary when comparing backing regardless of mediating factors, and when controlling for mediating factors. Both “masculine” and “feminine” positions provide some level of backing. In fact, any involvement with politicians, and even civic engagement, provides some level of backing. One conclusion is that gendering processes are not inherently masculine in nature. Rather, they hold the possibility that gendering processes can result in power for women as a group. Moreover, the effect on backing, of the “masculine” precinct captain, and the “feminine” position on the staff on backing are similar. Thus, in general, the findings do not confirm the third hypothesis. What are the machinations of gender therefore, as revealed in this analysis? The seemingly gender neutral result in terms of backing and electoral success, are structured through gendering processes. First, it means that organizations in the political arena play a role in incorporating women into the electoral competition. Proportionally, women are as likely and as I will soon show, even more likely, to arrive at the electoral competition with some background in organized activity and crossover from one arena to another. They play a role by providing women niches for activity that are, if not unique to women, available for them compared with other niches, and men. Another look into the findings reveals a more complex picture. When testing for backing the effect of all feminine niches but the staff member is lower than that of the precinct captain. 39 When testing for winning the effect of all “feminine” niches is lower than that of the precinct captain, and disappears when controlling for appointments, another relatively “feminine” niche. Here is where Acker’s assumption of masculinity continues to hold ground. Specifically, the positions available for women are the positions serving as an alternative to what remains, even over time, even when the number of actual ward organizations as senders of candidates declines, the masculine niche of the precinct captain. Once all other forms of intervening factors such as backing, or more important, appointments, are taken into consideration, these niches lose their effect. In terms of political capital, that is, ties that positions provide, these are also the positions that create direct relations of dependence between patron and protégé. These are the staff member of a politician, a family member of a politician, or campaign workers for politicians disconnected of major powerful alliances that work in the particular context of a candidate’s ward. When patron succeeds so does protégé and vice versa. The pessimistic conclusion is that the heart of politics and the alliances that constitute it, at least in Chicago, remains masculine, and that women need alternative solutions to get in. The optimistic view is that it does not really matter, as long as women as a group gain or devise routes to elected positions of power. To support this optimistic view I bring the reality of Chicago into the story. In Chicago, elected aldermen for the most part, are here to stay. Most aldermen, appointees and competitors, men and women, remain in office over many many terms, regardless of original circumstances or patrons. There are several directions for analysis arising from the findings. One touches a question researchers are most concerned with: why women do not run? (Fox and Lawler, 2004) Men are the dominant majority of aspirants in Chicago, but the findings suggest that aspirations alone did not have a significant effect. Unless engaged in some form of activity or alliance, running 40 resulted in losing. Men are the dominant majority among aspirants, but less politically experienced. When all candidates, including precinct captains, combined, women had somewhat more political involvement, in civic or partisan organizations. There are more men running for office, but even more men without any background that proves effective. The question to ask if not why women do not run but why so many men run. Another direction for further investigation is the gendered meanings attached to positions and structures. This paper was limited to the structure of the political arena, and focused on the political gains of positions that were open to women. The analysis did not focus on what Acker defines as the organizational logic (Britton, 1997; Britton, 2000). A promising next step will be a detailed analysis of the meanings that actors in Chicago attach to women’s political activity, and political aspirations in general that could address the question of motivation of men and women. Finally, findings also reveal change in the structure and identity of corporate actors involved in Chicago’s political arena. These changes include increased participation of women, but also varying forms of participation of the African American and Hispanic community, combined with decline in the ward organization as the sender of candidates. A more expansive in topic and volume of potential change in organizational form in Chicago and organizational strategies for coping with changing arenas, will provide better understanding of the organizational structure of the political arena, and examine women’s participation in a larger political context. 41 Bibliography Acker, Joan. 1990. “Hierarchies, Jobs, Bodies: A Theory of Gendered Organizations.” Gender and Society. 4:139-158. Baker , Paula. 1984. “The Domestication of Politics: Women and American Political Society, 1780-1920.” American Historical Review. 89(3): 620-647. Banfield, Edward C. 1961. Political Influence. New York, NY: Free Press. Britton, Dana M. 1997. “Gendered Organizational Logic: Policy and Practice in Men’s and Women’s Prisons”. Gender and Society. 11(6): 796-818. Britton, Dana M. 2000. “The Epistemology of the Gendered Organization”. Gender and Society. 14(3): 418-434. Brown, Clyde, Neil, R. Heighberger and Peter A. Shocket. 1993. “Gender Based Differences of Male and Female City Council Candidates.” Women and Politics. 13:1-17. Brown, Wendy. 1995. “Finding the Man in the State.” In States of Injury. Wendy Brown. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bullock, Charles S. and Susan A. MacManus. 1991. “Municipal Electoral Structure and the Election of Councilwomen.” Journal of Politics. 53, 75-89. Burns, Nancy, Kay Lehman-Schlozman, and Sidney Verba. 2001. The Private Roots of Public Action: Gender, Equality, and Political Participation. Cambridge, MA and London, England: Harvard University Press. Burt, Ronald S. 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Butler, Judith. 1990. Gender Trouble: Feminism and the Subversion of Identity. New York, NY: Routledge. Carroll, Susan J. 1994. Women as Candidates in American Politics. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press. 2nd Ed. Carroll, Susan J. Ed. 2003. Women and American Politics: NewQuestions, New Directions. Oxford: Oxford University Press. CAWP (Center for the American Woman and Politics). 2002. Women in the 50 Largest Cities. New Brunswick, NJ: National Informatiom Bank on Women in Public Office, Eaglton Institute of Politics, Rutgers University. 42 CAWP (Center for the American Woman and Politics). Women in the US Congress 2004. 2004a. New Brunswick, NJ: National Informatiom Bank on Women in Public Office, Eaglton Institute of Politics, Rutgers University. CAWP (Center for the American Woman and Politics). 2004b. Women in the US Senate 1922-2004. New Brunswick, NJ: National Informatiom Bank on Women in Public Office, Eaglton Institute of Politics, Rutgers University. CAWP (Center for the American Woman and Politics). 2004c. Women state Legislatures 2003. New Brunswick, NJ: National Informatiom Bank on Women in Public Office, Eaglton Institute of Politics, Rutgers University. Clark, Janet. 1991. “Getting There: Women in Political Office”. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. 515, 63-76. Clark, Terry N., and Vincent Hoffman-Martinot, eds. 1998. The New Political Culture. Boulder, CO: Westview. Clark, Terry N. Ed. 2002. Trees and Real Violins: Building Post-Industrial Chicago. Book Draft. Chicago, IL. Clark, Terry N. Ed. 2003. The City as an Entertainment Machine. Research in Urban Policy. Clemens, Elisabeth S., and Debra C. Minkoff. 2004. “Beyond the Iron Law: Rethinking the Place of Organizations in Social Movement Research”. In The Blackwell Companion to Social Movements. David A. Snow, Sara A. Soule, Hanspeter Kriesi. Eds. Pp. 155-170. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishing Ltd. Cohen, Adam, and Taylor, Elizabeth. 2000. American Pharaoh: Mayor Richard Daley, His Battle for Chicago and the Nation. Boston, MA, New York, NY, and London, UK: Little, Brown, and Company. Costantini, Edmond. 1990. “Political Women and Political Ambition: Closing the Gender Gap”. American Journal of Political Science. 34:741-770. Darcy, R., Susan Wlech, and Janet Clark. 1994. Women, Elections, and Representation. 2nd Ed. Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska Press. Department of Planning and Development. 1993. Population by Race and Latino Origin for Census Tracts, Community Areas, and Wards 1980, 1990. Chicago, IL: City of Chicago. DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1983. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” American 43 Sociological Review. 48: 147-160. Eagly, Alice H., Steven J. Karau, John B. Miner, and Blair T. Johnson. 1994. “Gender and Motivation to Manage in Hierarchic Organizations: A Meta Analysis”. Leadership Quarterly. 5:135-159. Einwohner, Rachel L., Jocelyn A. Hollander, and Toska Olson. 2000. “Engendering Social Movements: Cultural Images and Movement Dynamics”. Gender and Society. 14 (5): 679-699. Elshtain, Jean B. 1981. Public Man, Private Woman. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Etzioni-Halevi, Eva and Ann Illy. 1993. “Women in Legislatures: Israel in a Comparative Perspective.” In Women in Israel. Azmon, Yael and Dafna Izraeli. Eds. Pp. 237-251. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press. Fox, Richard L., and Jennifer Lawless. 2004. “Entering the Arena? Gender and the Decision to Run for Office.” American Journal of Political Science. 48: 264-280. Fowlkes, Diane L. 1984. “Ambitious Political Woman: Counter Socialization and Political Party Context.” Women and Politics. 4:5-39. Fremon, David K. 1988. Chicago Politics, Ward by Ward. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press. Gelb, Joice. 1990. Feminism and Politics: A Comparative Perspective. California: University of California Press. Githens, Marianne. 2003. “Accounting for Women’s Political Involvement: The Perennial Problem of Recruitment.” In Women and American Politics: New Questions, New Directions. Ed. Susan J. Carroll. Pp.33-55. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Granger, Bill, and Lori Granger. 1980. Fighting Jane: Mayor Jane Byrne and he Chicago Machine. New York, NY: Dial Press. Grimshaw, William J. 1992. Bitter Fruit: Black Politics and the Chicago Machine 19311991. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press. Guterbock, Thomas M. 1980. Machine Politics in Transition: Party and Community in Chicago. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press. Hertsog, Hannah. 1999. Gendering Politics: Women in Israel. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. 44 Johnson, Kathleen B. 1993. Compassionate Authority: Democracy and the Representation of Women. New York, NY: Routledge. Jones, Mark P. 1996. “Increasing Women’s Representation Via Gender Quotas: The Argentine Ley De Cupos”. Women and Politics. 16: 75-98. Kanter, Rosabeth Moss. 1993. Men and Women of the Corporation. New York, NY: BasicBooks. 2nd Edition. Kleppner, Paul. 1985. Chicago Divided: The Making of a Black Mayor. DeKalb, IL: Northern Illinois University Press. Koch, Jeffrey W. 1999. “Candidate Gender and Assessments of Senate Candidates”. Social Science Quarterly. 80(1): 84-96. Koven Seth, and Sonya Michel. 1990. “Womanly Duties: Maternalist Politics and the Origins of the Welfare States in France, Germany, Great Britain, and the United States, 1880-1920”. The American Historical Review. 95(4). Pp. 1076-1108. Lechtman, Zohar. 2008. Gendering Chicago Politics: Institutionalization of Women in Positions of Power. PhD. Thesis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago. Laumann, Edward O., and David Knoke. The Organizational State. Madisson, WI: The University of Wisconsin Press. Lehman-Schlozman, Kay, Nancy Burns, Sidney Verba, and Jesse Donahue. 1994. “Gender and Citizen Participation: Is There a Different Voice?”. American Journal of Political Science. 39:267-293. Lorber, Judith. 1994. Paradoxes of Gender. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Lovenduski, Joni and Pippa Norris. Eds. 1993. Gender and Party Politics. California: 1993. Lovenduski, Joni. 1996. “Sex, Gender and British Politics”. Parliamentary Affairs. 49, 1-16. Matland, Richard E., and Donley T. Studlar. 1996. “The Contagion of Women Candidates in Single-Member District and Proportional Representation Electoral Systems: Canada and Norway”. The Journal of Politics. 58(3): 707-733. Mier, Robert, Wim Wiewel, and Lauri Alpern. 1992. “Decentralization of Policy Making Under Mayor Harold Washington”. In Politics of Policy Innovation in Chicago. Mott, Helen and Helen Petrie. 1995. “Workplace Interactions: Women’s Linguistic 45 Behavior”. Journal of Language and Social Psychology. 14: 324-336. Niven, David. 1998. The Missing Majority: The Recruitment of Women as State Legislative Candidates. Westport, CT: Praeger. Norris, Pipa. 1993. “Conclusions: Comparing Legislative Recruitment”. In Lovenduski, Joni and Pippa Norris. (Eds.). Gender and Party Politics. Califronai: Sage. Pp. 309-330. Norris, Pippa. Ed. 1997. Passages to Power: Legislative Recruitment in Advanced Democracies. Cambridge, UK and New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Northeastern Illinois Planning Commission. 2004. Census 2000: Basic Population Profiles for Chicago Community Areas and Chicago Wards. De Kalb, IL: Northeastern Illinois Planning Commission. http://www.nipc.cog.il.us/PLProfiles.htm Okin, Susan Moller. 1979. Women in Western Political Thought. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Pateman, Carole. 1988. The Sexual Contract. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Paxton, Pamella, and Sheri Kunovich. 2003. “Women’s Political Representation: The Importance of Ideology”. Social Forces. 82(1): 87-113. Perrigo, Sarah. 1995. “Gender Struggles in the British labor Party From 1979 to 1995”. Party Politics. 1: 407-417. Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1997. New Directions for Organization Theory: Problems and Prospects. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Phillips, Anne. 1991. Engendering Democracy. University Park, PA: The Pennsylvania State University Press. Rakove, Milton. 1975. Don’t Make No Waves…Don’t Back No Losers: An Insider’s Analysis of the Daley Machine. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press. Rakove, Milton L. 1979. We Don’t Want Nobody Nobody Sent: An Oral History of the Daley Years. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press. Royko, Mike. 1971. Boss: Richard J. Daley of Chicago. New York, NY: E.P. Dutton and Co. Inc. Sainsbury, Diane. 1993. “The Politics of Increased Women’s Representation: the Swedish Case”. In Lovenduski, Joni and Pippa Norris. (Eds.). Gender and Party Politics. California: Sage. Pp. 263-290. 46 Sanbonmatsu, Kira. 2006. Where Women Run: Gender and Party in the American States. Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press. Scott, Joan W. 1988. Gender and the Politics of History. 1988. New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Pp. 28-50. Simon Rosenthal, Cindi. 2000. “Gender Styles in State Legislative Committees: Raising Their Voices in Resolving Conflict”. Women and Politics. 21(2): 21-45. Skjeie, Hege. 1993. “Ending the Male Political Hegemony: the Norwegian Experience”. In Lovenduski, Joni and Pippa Norris. (Eds.). Gender and Party Politics. California: Sage. Pp. 231-262. Sorenson, Paula S., Katherien Hawkins and Ritch L. Sorenson. 1995. “Gender, Psychological Type and Conflict Style Preference”. Management Communication Quarterly. 9:115-126. Walker, Henry A., Barbara C. Ilardi, Anne M. McMahon and Mary L. Fennell. 1996. “Gender, Interaction and Leadership”. Social Psychology Quarterly. 59:255272. Watson, Carol and L. Richard Hoffman. 1996. “Managers as Negotiators: A Test of Power versus Gender as Predictors of Feelings, Behaviors and Outcomes”. Leadership Quarterly. 7:63-85. Welch, Susan. 1978. “Recruitment of Women for Public Office.” Western Political Quarterly. 31: 372-380. West, Candace, and Don Zimmerman. 1987. “Doing Gender.” Gender and Society. 1(2): 125-151. Whalen FitzGerald, Kathleen. 1981. Brass: Jane Byrne and the Pursuit of Power. Chicago, IL: Contemporary Book. Young, Iris M. 1990. Justice and the Politics of Difference. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 47 Tables Table 1: Percentage of Men and Women among Candidates in Each Ward and Period (N in parentheses) Wards Percentage Men Percentage Women White 85.2 (322) 14.8 (56) 1971-1979 87.0 (248) 13.0 (37) African American 74.9 (420) 25.1 (141) 1983-1991 79.8 (387) 20.2 (98) Hispanic 80.0 (64) 20.0 (16) 1995-2007 74.2 (316) 25.8 (110) Mixed 81.9 (145) 18.1 (32) Table 2 Percentage Men Period Percentage Women Distribution of Gender, Ward Category, and Period of Race, in Precinct Captain, Campaign Worker, and Assistant Categories (N in parentheses) Precinct Work Campaign work 5.4 (65) 4.6 (55) 6.8 (81) 17.0 (203) Gender Men Women 89.2 (58) 10.8 (7) 69.1 (38) 30.9 (17) 69.1 (56) 30.9 (25) 69.0 (140) 31.0 (63) 79.5 20.5 Ward White African American Hispanic Mixed 53.8 (35) 32.3 (21) 1.5 (1) 12.3 (8) 23.6 (13) 38.2 (21) 9.1 (5) 29.1 (16) 32.1 (26) 45.7 (37) 8.6 (7) 13.6 (11) 27.1 42.4 12.3 18.2 (55) (86) (25) (37) 31.6 46.9 6.7 14.9 Period 1971-1979 1983-1991 1995-2007 53.8 (35) 27.7 (18) 18.5 (12) 25.5 (14) 43.6 (24) 30.9 (17) 19.8 (16) 46.9 (38) 33.3 (27) 20.2 (41) 32.5 (66) 47.3 (96) 23.8 40.7 35.5 All Staff Civically Engaged 48 Table 3 Logistic Regression Models for Serving as a Precinct Captain, on Non-ward Campaigns, on Civic Organizations, or on Staff, 1971-2007 Only Precinct Captain Odds Female .55 African American Ward .26 Hispanic Ward .68 Mixed Ward .59 1983-1991 .34 1995-2007 .30 Coef. -.59 (.41) -1.37 (1.05) -.39 (.42) -.52 (.31) -1.09*** (.31) -1.21*** (.37) Non Ward Campaign Civic Engagement Staff Odds Coef. Odds Coef. Odds 1.95 .67* (.31) .18 (.39) .90 (.59) 1.15** (.41) -.27 (.37) -.58 (.42) 2.00 .70*** (.18) -.11 (.20) .74*** (.31) .38 (.25) -.18 (.23) .34 (.23) 1.98 1.20 2.46 3.16 .77 .56 .90 2.10 1.47 .83 1.41 0.85 1.68 0.83 1.80 1.44 Any Precinct captain 5.90 Non Ward Campaign 3.34 Civic Engagement 0.58 Family Ties 2.12 Constant .035 Observations Standard errors in parentheses p<.05; ** p<.01; ***p<.001 -3.36* (0.32) 1196 .34 1.10*** (.27) 1196 0.29 -1.25*** (.11) 1196 0.30 Coef. .68** (.27) -.16 (.30) .52 (.49) -.19 (.40) .59 (.34) .36 (.37) 1.78*** (.30) 1.21** (.41) -.55 (.37) .75* (.36) -1.20 (.28) 1196 49 Table 4 Logistic Regression Models for Organizational Support, Backing of Individual Leader, and Any Type of Backing Organizational Support Odds Female .85 African American Ward .53 Hispanic Ward .90 Mixed Ward .94 1983-1991 .57 1995-2007 .50 Held Elected Office Prior races 9.28 .93 Staff 4.71 Precinct captain only 4.96 On non ward-affiliated campaign 2.72 Civic Engagement 1.98 Family Ties 2.17 Constant 8.98 Observation Standard errors in parentheses * p<.05; ** p<.01; ***p<.001 Coef -.16 (.20) -.65*** (.18) -.11 (.33) -.06 (.23) -.57** (.19) -.70*** (.21) 2.23*** (.48) -.07 (.34) 1.55** (.26) 1.60*** (.28) 1.00** (.31) .68*** (.19) .78** (.28) 2.20*** (.31) 1196 Individual Backing Odds .88 1.02 2.63 1.81 1.23 .96 2.99 .67 2.46 2.59 3.80 2.31 3.98 2.35 1196 Coef -.13 (.22) .02 (.23) .97** (.34) .59** (.27) .21 (.24) -.04 (.26) 1.09* (.56) -.40 (.42) .89** (.29) .95** (.33) 1.33*** (.31) .84*** (.21) 1.38*** (.28) .85** (.32) Any Backing Odds .92 .63 1.61 1.29 .60 .48 12.35 .94 5.43 5.35 4.11 1.90 4.03 29.92 Coef. -.09 (.18) -.47 (.17) .50 (.30) .26 (.22) -.51** (.18) -.73*** (.20) 2.51*** (.52) -.07 (.32) 1.69*** (.27) 1.68*** (.29) 1.41*** (.32) .64*** (.18) 1.39*** (.29) 3.40*** (.35) 1196 50 Table 5 Logistic Regression Models for Winning First Aldermanic Attempt, 19712007 Model 1 Odds Female .88 African American Ward 1.17 Hispanic Ward 1.55 Mixed Ward 1.04 1983-1991 .41 1995-2007 .38 Held elected office Prior race 8.97 .62 On non-ward Campaign 1.33 Precinct captain only 8.59 Staff 6.20 Civic Organization 2.55 Family ties 3.16 Coef. -.12 (.24) .15 (.23) .44 (.42) .04 (.31) -.89*** (.24) -.96*** (.24) 2.19*** (.57) -.48 (.46) .28 (.39) 2.15*** (.29) 1.82*** (.28) .94*** (.23) 1.15*** (.30) Organizational Backing Model 2 Odds .99 1.57 1.45 .85 .41 .39 4.05 .68 .62 5.66 3.84 1.74 2.04 11.61 Backing by individual 5.24 Coef. -.01 (.28) .45 (.26) .37 (.48) -.16 (.35) -.89** (.28) -.94** (.31) 1.40* (.63) -.39 (.53) -.48 (.43) 1.73*** (.34) 1.35*** (.32) .56* (.27) .71* (.35) 2.45*** (.23) 1.66*** (.25) Appointment Constant Observations Model 3 Odds .86 1.59 1.82 .83 .33 .24 3.97 .79 .77 5.09 20.5 1.69 1.86 8.22 6.15 23.75 4.05 1.40 (.32) 1.68 1196 .52 (.37) 5.61 Coef. -.15 (.30) .46 (.27) .60 (.51) -.18 (.38) -1.10*** (.29) -1.42*** (.34) 1.38* (.62) -.23 (.52) -.29 (.43) 1.63*** (.35) .72 (.38) .52 (.28) .62 (.37) 2.11*** (.24) 1.82 (.26) 3.17*** (.58) 1.72*** (.45) 1196 Standard errors in parentheses * p<.05; ** p<.01; ***p<.001 51